1. Introduction
1.1. Background and Motivation
Digital information technology is accelerating the spread of two-sided manufacturing platforms, attracting significant attention. A report by Grand View Research projects that the global market of two-sided manufacturing platforms is expanding at an annual rate of 8.8% and is expected to reach USD 101.12 billion by 2028. For example, Alibaba.com and XoMetry.com connect manufacturers and customers who need customized parts and prototypes. These manufacturing platforms act as intermediaries by providing basic services to facilitate component trading between suppliers and manufacturers, charging both sides access fees for profitability [
1,
2].
Exemplifying a bilateral market structure that integrates suppliers and manufacturers, the two-sided manufacturing platform exhibits a distinct market characteristic, that is, the cross-network externality symmetry, which refers to the correlation and mutual influence of joining utility between suppliers and manufacturers [
3,
4]. This symmetry reflects an equilibrium where both sides of the market exert comparable and interdependent effects on each other’s participation incentives. Given the effects of the cross-network externality symmetry, two-sided platforms widely use pricing strategies such as subsidizing one side and charging the other side in practice [
5,
6,
7]. However, with rapid development of the platform and the intensification of competition among two-sided platform enterprises, the subsidization strategy considering the cross-network externality symmetry no longer remains effective as usual in expanding the market scale [
8,
9]. Instead, the level of value-added service (VAS) investment (hereafter referred to as VAS level), a highly profitable and rapidly growing business, has become a more effective operational strategy for two-sided platforms [
10,
11,
12]. Commonly used VAS for two-sided manufacturing platforms include functions such as priority ranking, effective matching, payment security, and logistics supervision, which aim to enhance participants’ engagement and expand the positive effect of the symmetry of cross-network externalities [
13,
14]. This symmetry reflects an equilibrium where both sides of the market exert comparable and interdependent effects on each other’s participation incentives.
Although VAS investment can stimulate participants to access more, it also increases the cost and affects the platforms’ pricing and VAS provision strategies. In practice, the costs associated with value-added services are often substantial, covering expenses such as servers, module management, specialized staff salaries, and other related expenses. Some platforms, like China texnet.com and the Shenyang Iron & Steel i5 platform, have faced issues of over-investment, resulting in reduced revenues and even website closures [
9]. Moreover, outsourcing has become an effective strategy because it reduces heavy operating costs and allows platforms to focus on their core competencies [
15,
16]. For example, HOIZAL.com outsources its software service and financing services to third-party service providers (e.g., Delixi electric; KMES software company; and Haier financial services), and 1688.com outsources its logistics services to third-party service providers (e.g., S.f.Holding express and China cainiao express) [
2]. However, platforms may suffer from a bad reputation and low access rates due to low-quality services provided by third parties. Consequently, these examples indicate that when VAS costs are high, platforms must optimize their service strategies and maintain quality to ensure sustainable competitiveness.
1.2. Research Questions and Innovations
Following established practices, we examined a two-sided platform with symmetric cross-network externalities to determine its optimal bilateral pricing and VAS provision strategy. In detail, we aimed to answer the following questions: (1) What are the optimal pricing decisions for bilateral participants that a platform should adopt, particularly under conditions of symmetric interdependence where suppliers and manufacturers exhibit balanced cross-network influences? Moreover, how do the relative strengths of these symmetry cross-network externalities—reflecting the degree of equilibrium in mutual participation effects—interact with the VAS level to shape the platform’s optimal pricing and service strategies? (2) Platforms have two VAS provision mode options, including providing VASs in-house or outsourcing VASs to a third party. Which strategy can enable the platform to achieve more profits? (3) What impact does a VAS cost-sharing contract have on supply chain members’ optimal operational decisions and profit distributions? Is there a mutually acceptable VAS cost-sharing arrangement between a platform and third party? And which conditions must be met for the platform and third party to accept this contract?
To answer the above questions, this study examines a two-sided manufacturing platform that facilitates component trading and operates as a monopoly. Utilizing a stylized game model and analyzing the utility of suppliers and manufacturers, this study derives the bilateral participants’ optimal pricing decisions and the profits of both parties (e.g., the platform and the third party) under two different VAS provision strategies. Then, we compare the proposed two VAS provision strategies to explore the service outsourcing choice of the platform under equilibrium. The results show that if the outsourced VAS cost coefficient is sufficiently high or the outsourced VAS quality and cost coefficient are relatively low concurrently, the platform should choose to provide VASs by itself. Only when the outsourced VAS quality is relatively high and cost coefficient is in a low range should the platform opt to outsource the VAS to the third party. Finally, we examine the role of VAS cost-sharing contracts in improving the performance of the platform and third parties. We find that a VAS cost-sharing contract is successful in improving the whole supply chain’s performance when the outsourced VAS cost coefficient is relatively high. Additionally, we give the optimal VAS cost-sharing ratio and clarify the conditions for achieving the VAS cost-sharing contract.
Within the contemporary landscape of Industry 4.0, while platform-mediated servitization is gaining attention [
17,
18], the strategic implications of symmetric cross-network externalities and the comparative analysis of different VAS provision models remain underexplored. This paper delivers three major contributions:
(1) Motivated by emerging VAS business practices, we examine how a VAS outsourcing strategy affects a two-sided platform’s optimal decisions, thereby supplementing the literature on two-sided market service outsourcing. By constructing two different VAS provision modes that account for balanced reciprocity between platform sides, our findings reveal how symmetrical interdependence shapes optimal strategies. These results offer practical guidance for pricing bilateral participants on platforms. They specifically address maintaining equilibrium under symmetric cross-network externalities, where equivalent utility flows between suppliers and manufacturers create mutually reinforcing effects.
(2) We discuss the optimal VAS provision choice for the platform when introducing the third-party service provider and offer a comparative analysis of three VAS provisioning models and the optimal decisions, revealing the non-obvious trade-offs in each, which is crucial for strategic decision-making in Industry 4.0.
(3) This study identifies a complete characterization of an optimal VAS cost-sharing ratio and clarifies the conditions for achieving a VAS cost-sharing contract. Additionally, we demonstrate that a VAS cost-sharing contract can improve the overall performance of a platform and third party as well as achieve a “win-win” outcome.
1.3. Paper Organization and Structure
The rest of this study is organized as follows.
Section 2 briefly reviews the relevant literature.
Section 3 describes the model.
Section 4 compares the two proposed VAS provision strategies and identifies the optimal VAS provision strategy that maximizes both participant access rates and platform entrance fees.
Section 5 investigates the role of a VAS cost-sharing contract.
Section 6 extends the main model to a bilaterally differentiated VAS setting.
Section 7 summarizes the main findings and summarizes and discusses their managerial implications. All proofs are included in the
Appendix A.
3. The Model
This study investigates the bilateral pricing problem and VAS provision strategy for two-sided platforms characterized by symmetric cross-network externalities—where suppliers and manufacturers exhibit balanced, reciprocal influences that create equilibrium in platform participation dynamics. We consider a two-sided manufacturing platform (e.g., XoMetry.com, DHGate.com, etc.) owner that facilitates the trade of components between suppliers (
s) and manufacturers (
m). The basic framework is illustrated in
Figure 1. Due to the attractiveness of the VAS strategy [
9,
12], the platform needs to rethink the best strategy for providing VASs. To this end, we construct two theoretical models that are established to capture the platform’s divergent strategic pathways, namely, (1) self-operate VASs (Model PS) or (2) the platform outsources VASs to a third-party service provider (Model OS). Specifically, the former mode allows the platform to attract more bilateral participants through ensuring user-compatible service levels, but it weakens platform core business attention and bears additional operating costs. The latter mode allows the platform to offer VAS levels at a controllable investment cost but with an unstable quality of service.
In Model PS, the platform offers basic services,
, namely, the intrinsic value of joining the platform (e.g., information browsing and searching), and charges the
(
) side participants an access fee,
. Consistent with prior studies, we assume the basic services follow uniform distributions, that is,
. Moreover, suppliers and manufacturers make rational decisions based on the perceived value and network size. We use
and
to represent the positive cross-network externality symmetry between suppliers and manufacturers, that is, increased supplier participation enhances component matching probability for manufacturers, while greater manufacturer presence creates additional value for suppliers, where
[
51]. For analytical tractability and to maintain focus on platform VAS strategy, we explicitly exclude intra-side cross-network externalities from our model specification [
4,
11].
represents the VAS utility provided by platform. Hence, referring to previous research by Armstrong (2006) [
4], Zhang et al. (2021) [
13], and Sui et al. (2024) [
9], suppliers and manufacturers who use the platform for access find the following utility:
;
.
The modeled platform firm’s revenue mainly stems from suppliers and manufacturers’ participation fees [
8,
10]. In addition to basic services, value-added services (e.g., priority ranking, payment security, and logistics supervision) are being introduced by many platforms to tap into the potential of users’ participation. Meanwhile, the platform needs to spend a certain amount on providing VASs, which will affect the platform’s VAS investment levels and pricing. Referring to Dou et al. (2016) [
10] and Dan et al. (2018) [
11], we suppose that the variable cost of unit VAS is
, where
represents the constant marginal cost. The variable costs of VASs such as installation, cleaning, and financial services have a linear relationship with the service level. In
Section 6, we expand our base model to take into consideration a scenario in which the platform provides its bilateral players with differential VAS investment levels.
In Model OS, an independent third-party service provider is hired by the platform to provide a VAS for its bilateral participants. For example, HOIZAL.com outsources its software service and financing service to third-party service providers (e.g., Delixi electric; KMES software; and Haier financial services), and 1688.com outsources its logistics services to third-party service providers (e.g., S.f.Holding express and China cainiao express). In this context, the players follow the Stackelberg game. As a game leader, the third-party service provider first announces the price
to the platform of providing the unit VAS
. The platform, as the follower in the Stackelberg game, decides the bilateral participants’ prices
. Meantime, the third-party service provider needs to spend a certain amount on providing unit VAS. Similarly, we adopt a variable cost function
to describe the VAS investment cost, where
is the VAS cost coefficient of the third-party service provider. The variable cost of the VAS
increases with the service level
. The main notations used in this study are summarized in
Table 2.
3.1. Self-Operate VAS (Model PS)
In Model PS, the platform conducts its own service system and offers the VAS by itself. In this case, the platform decides the participants’ price
and offers the VAS
for its bilateral participants. The superscript “PS” denotes Model PS. Based on the analysis above, we can obtain the profit function of the platform, which is given by
Recall the utility of a supplier and the utility of a manufacturer accessing the platform; the supplier and the manufacturer will access the platform only if its utility is non-negative (
). Thus, bilateral participants’ access rate of the platform can be expressed as
Solving the system of Equations (2) and (3) simultaneously, we can obtain the access rates of bilateral participants as follows:
It is easy to know from Equations (4) and (5) that
and
are affected by two aspects, which are the negative impact of the platform’s access fees and positive impact of the VAS utility. Thus, the profit function of the platform can be further rewritten as
By computing the Hessian matrix of
about
, it is known that the Hessian matrix is positive definite. And our analysis is conducted under the following conditions:
. The results characterize the equilibrium decisions of the platform under Model PS in Lemma 1. In addition, proofs of the positive definite condition and equilibrium results are given in
Appendix A. Our analysis is conducted under the following conditions:
.
Lemma 1. Under Model PS, the optimal solutions of the platform are
, , , .
Based on Lemma 1, we can obtain the results below which describe how the key factors, including the cross-network externality symmetry degree and VAS level, affect the optimal decisions of the platform in Model PS.
Proposition 1. When the platform undertakes a VAS, we have the following:
- (i)
With the increase of , the optimal prices and optimal access rate increase;
- (ii)
With the increase of , the optimal prices
and optimal access rate
increase, while
decreases;
- (iii)
With the increase of
, the optimal prices
and optimal access rate
increase, while
decreases.
Proposition 1(i) indicates that when the VAS level provided by the platform for its bilateral participants increases, bilateral participants have a higher willingness to access because they derive more service utility, thus promoting bilateral participants’ access rate too. Meanwhile, the platform will also increase the price for bilateral participants to make more profits and make up for the cost of improving the service level for bilateral participants. Propositions 1(ii) and (iii) reveal that when the manufacturers’ (suppliers) cross-network externality degree increases, the platform will increase the price for suppliers (manufacturers) but decrease the price for manufacturers (suppliers). This result is consistent with the findings of many other studies, such as Zheng et al. (2023) [
52] and Dou et al. (2024) [
53], that suggest platforms should charge a lower price to those who exhibit higher network externality and a high price to the other side which benefits from the increasing cross-network utility. The reason behind this outcome is that the platform is willing to attract more manufacturers (suppliers) when
(
) increases, thus the platform will decrease the price for manufacturers to encourage them to access. Under symmetric equilibrium conditions, suppliers and manufacturers experience mutually balanced cross-network utility flows, where suppliers gain proportional benefits from manufacturer participation that improve their access rate, while simultaneously manufacturers receive equivalent utility gains from supplier participation that enhance their own access rate, maintaining perfect reciprocity in platform value exchange. Therefore, the platform will also increase the price for suppliers and make up for the loss of decreasing the price for manufacturers.
Figure 2 presents some numerical examples to exhibit the impacts of the service level
and cross-network externality symmetry
on the platform’s optimal solutions
.
Corollary 1. According to the optimal profit of the platform not providing the VAS (), which is shown in Zhang et al. [13], the value of the platform providing the VAS by itself (Model PS), , is given by , where denotes the platform’s profit without providing the VAS. Commonly used VASs for two-sided manufacturing platforms, including priority ranking, effective matching, payment security, and logistics supervision, are strategically designed to amplify the symmetrical nature of cross-network externalities. These services simultaneously enhance engagement for both suppliers and manufacturers in balanced proportions, thereby reinforcing the reciprocal value exchange and maintaining equilibrium in platform participation dynamics. According to Corollary 1, the platform should offer VASs and take into consideration the allure of the VAS approach. This finding further illustrates that investing in VASs as a highly profitable and rapidly growing business has become a more effective operational strategy for two-sided platforms [
10,
11,
12]. In addition, Zhang et al. (2021) [
13] also show that when bilateral participants have higher degrees of cross-network externality symmetry, a two-sided platform is better able to provide VASs. In the following, we concentrate more on a platform’s calculated decision to offer VAS provision.
3.2. VAS Is Outsourced to the Third Party (Model OS)
In Model OS, the platform hires an independent third party to provide a VAS. In this case, the third party provides the VAS
for the platform’s bilateral participants and announces the price
of each unit VAS. The platform decides the participants’ price
. The decision sequence in Model OS is as follows: the third party announces the unit outsourcing price and provides the VAS first, then the platform decides the bilateral participants’ price. The superscript “OS” denotes Model OS. Based on the analysis above, we can obtain the profit function of the platform and the third party as follows.
The utility of a supplier under Model OS is equal to
. And the utility of a manufacturer under Model OS is equal to
. Both sides’ participants will access the platform only if its utility is non-negative (
). Thus, we obtain
Following a similar solving approach as described in
Section 3.1, we can calculate the access rates of bilateral participants as follows:
Then, the profit function of the platform and the third-party can be further rewritten. In this dynamic game, we solve for the subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium, such that
is the best response when
are given. Details of the calculation process can be found in the
Appendix A. Then, we obtained the optimal decisions of the platform and the third party in Lemma 2. And our analysis was conducted under the following conditions:
.
Lemma 2. Under Model OS, platform’s optimal solutions are
, , , . The optimal solutions of the third-party are , .
Based on Lemma 2, we discuss how the outsourced VAS level affects the optimal decisions and profits of the platform and the third party, as Proposition 2 shows.
Proposition 2. When the service is outsourced to the independent third party, we have the following:
- (i)
With the increase of , the optimal access rate and profits increase when ; otherwise, decrease when ;
- (ii)
With the increase of , the optimal prices increase.
Proposition 2(i) shows that when the VAS level provided by the third party increases, the platform will increase the price for bilateral participants and the price of unit VAS simultaneously. The platform increases the bilateral participants’ prices for two aspects, one is the higher service utility that bilateral participants obtained as stated in Proposition 1(i), and the other reason is the increased payment to the third party for improving the VAS level. To ground this finding in a tangible context, our simulation models a scenario akin to a logistics platform (e.g., similar to FedEx’s SenseAware service), introducing advanced, real-time tracking (VAS). This quantitatively validates the theoretical mechanism: the platform capitalizes on the enhanced utility for users (who can now track their shipments in near real-time) while also passing on part of the higher costs incurred for the third-party service provider to maintain this advanced infrastructure. In the low outsourced VAS cost scenario (e.g., a software marketplace where adding a new AI-powered code-review tool primarily involves marginal cloud computing costs), both platform participation and profits surge with VAS enhancement. The simulation outputs indicate a profit growth of over 30% for both parties when the VAS level is high under this cost structure. Conversely, in the high outsourced VAS cost scenario (e.g., a financial technology platform integrating a new, compliance-heavy fraud detection system that requires significant regulatory licensing and expert manpower), the picture changes dramatically. As shown in
Figure 3, beyond a certain VAS threshold, profits begin to decline despite a modest increase in user access rate. The managerial insight is that third-party providers must conduct a rigorous cost–benefit analysis before committing to high-cost value-added feature development, ensuring that the anticipated demand expansion is sufficient to offset the substantial costs involved.
In conclusion, our model and simulations collectively paint a nuanced picture: strategically increasing a VAS is a powerful lever for growth, but its success is contingent on the economic reality of the service being offered. The key is not merely to add features, but to intelligently select and price those value-added services whose cost structures allow for a net positive return, thereby truly enhancing ecosystem value without falling into the trap of excessive, profit-eroding investment [
54].
Figure 3 presents some numerical examples to better understand the findings of Proposition 2.
4. Comparative Analysis
Having analyzed both models independently, we now compare the equilibrium outcomes of Model PS and Model OS to guide platforms’ outsourcing decisions. In the following Proposition 3 and 4, we will analyze which VAS provision strategy choice can determine larger entry fees and access rates for its bilateral participants.
Proposition 3. The following formulas are established by comparing the variables of the two modes:
- (i)
The optimal suppliers’ price: (a) if , , (b) if , when ; otherwise, when .
- (ii)
The optimal manufacturers’ price: (a) if , , (b) if , when ; otherwise, when , where , , , and .
Proposition 3 compares the optimal bilateral participants’ price of the two VAS provision modes. First, the platform charges a higher bilateral suppliers’ price under Model PS than under Model OS only when the VAS level provided by the third party is relatively low. That is to say, the platform has stronger pricing power to set a higher price for its suppliers when the platform offers a relatively high VAS level by itself. Conversely, when the VAS level provided by a third party is relatively high, the platform will set a lower price for suppliers to compensate for the lower service utility that suppliers obtain. Second, the platform charges a higher bilateral manufacturers’ price under Model PS than under Model OS only when the VAS level provided by the third party is relatively low. The fundamental reason for the optimal manufacturers’ price is similar to the supplier-side price.
Proposition 4.
The optimal bilateral participants’ access rate:
- (i)
If , when ; otherwise, when .
- (ii)
If , .
The threshold defines when outsourcing (the OS model) becomes optimal for the platform. Outsourcing is attractive when the VAS utility provided by the third-party service provider exceeds a critical level. This critical level decreases with the platform’s internal VAS costs c and the competitive VAS quality intensity , meaning the platform is more likely to outsource when its own operations are costly or the market is competitive. However, a strong third-party service provider’s VAS cost, k, raises the bar for outsourcing, as it makes in-house operation more valuable. Thus, Proposition 4 shows that the optimal bilateral participants’ access rate under Model OS is greater than that of Model PS only when the outsourced VAS cost is low and VAS level provided by the third party is in a high range. The rationale is straightforward: enhanced VAS provision (whether platform-supplied or third-party) boosts bilateral participants’ service utility, thereby directly increasing their access probability. In other cases, such as when the outsourced VAS cost is high or the VAS level provided by third party is relatively low, Model PS can determine a larger access rate for its bilateral participants. This is because the relatively low outsourced service quality may hurt bilateral participants’ enthusiasm to join the platform.
Proposition 5. A platform’s optimal VAS provision strategy under symmetric cross-network effects—where balanced, reciprocal influences between participants create equilibrium conditions—is jointly determined by and
, presented as follows:
- (i)
When and , the platform should implement Model PS; otherwise, the platform should implement Model OS when . The profit comparison of the platform and the third party under two models is shown in Figure 4.
- (ii)
When
, the platform should implement Model PS.
Figure 4.
Platform’s optimal VAS provision choice ().
Figure 4.
Platform’s optimal VAS provision choice ().
Observe that the key factors for whether the platform should choose the option of outsourcing its VAS are the outsourced VAS’s quality and cost of the third party. To translate this finding into actionable strategy, we define “low cost and level” as scenarios where a third party offers a basic, cost-efficient service (e.g., a simple data analytics dashboard for an e-commerce platform). Counterintuitively, the model reveals that in these cases, the platform’s profit is maximized by bringing the service in-house (Model PS). The simulation shows that under these conditions, self-provisioning yields a 10–15% higher profit for the platform compared to outsourcing. The rationale is that the platform can leverage its existing infrastructure and brand trust to offer a marginally better version of this basic service, thereby capturing all the value and exercising greater pricing power over its users, without the burden of managing a third-party relationship for a non-differentiating service. However,
Figure 3 also demonstrates that in the “low-cost, high-level” quadrant, outsourcing (Model OS) becomes unequivocally superior, boosting the bilateral participants’ access rate by over 20% and overall platform profit by a similar margin. Here, the value generated by the third party’s superior service in attracting and retaining users far outweighs the loss of direct control. This mirrors the real-world strategy of platforms like Shopify, which relies on an ecosystem of expert app developers to provide high-value services that Shopify itself does not build. Moreover, the platform should opt for self-provided VASs when encountering excessive outsourcing costs that undermine operational efficiency, as Proposition 5(ii) reveals. This quantifies the severe financial damage of a poor outsourcing decision and underscores the non-negotiable need for cost-effective partnerships. Next, we aim to incentivize the third party to provide high-quality VAS level in terms of the VAS cost-sharing contract design.
5. VAS Cost-Sharing Contract Design
In this section, we propose a VAS cost-sharing contract (Model CS) in which the platform shares a portion,
μ, to the third party when the VAS is outsourced to the third party. Under the cost-sharing contract, the platform pays the service fee
per participant to the third party and additionally shares a fraction,
, of the third party’s service cost
. We use a superscript, “CS”, which denotes Model CS. In Model CS, the utility functions of the bilateral participants are the same as those of Model OS, but the profit functions change. The profit functions are presented as follows:
With a similar calculating procedure as that employed in Model OS, we provide the optimal solution of the platform and the third party in Lemma 3.
Lemma 3. Under Model CS, , , , and ; and .
Next, we look at how the platform and the third party’s best choices are impacted by the VAS cost-sharing agreement. Based on the optimal solutions characterized in Lemma 2 and 3, we derive the following key properties.
Proposition 6. The VAS cost-sharing contract can decrease the outsourced price of unit VAS and increase the bilateral participants’ price while decreasing the access rate of the bilateral participants. Put mathematically, , , .
Proposition 6 shows that the platform may obtain favorable outsourced pricing of unit VAS with the use of a VAS cost-sharing contract. The third-party provider has clear economic incentives to reduce service prices when the platform shares a portion of VAS costs, as this cost-sharing arrangement effectively lowers the provider’s marginal costs. However, for the platform, the funds paid for the VAS cost primarily come from the platform increasing the bilateral participants’ price. Improving the price for its participants leads to a decrease in the access rate of the bilateral participants. Therefore, the bilateral participants’ price is high and bilateral participant access rates are systematically lower when operating under VAS cost-sharing contracts than in scenarios without such arrangements.
Proposition 7. Given an active VAS cost-sharing agreement between the platform and third-party provider, there exists a Pareto zone, , , in which both the platform’s and the third party’s profits will improve, where .
Proposition 7 reveals the coordination conditions of the VAS cost-sharing contract. Intuitively, when the platform shares part of the cost, the third-party service provider can benefit from the VAS cost-sharing contract. However, Proposition 7(i) shows that” when the outsourced VAS cost coefficient is relatively low, there exists a “lose-lose” outcome, i.e.,
,
. In this case, the third party is incentivized to deliver high-quality services to maximize compensation while simultaneously optimizing operational efficiency to minimize costs. Therefore, the VAS cost-sharing agreement will not be accepted by the third party. To accomplish the objective of raising the player’s overall performance and achieving a win-win situation, Proposition 7(ii) shows the VAS cost-sharing contract as a successful strategy when the outsourced VAS cost coefficient is relatively high. In
Figure 5, we simulate the players’ profit with the change in the VAS cost-sharing ratio
by setting
. When the platform considers utilizing the VAS cost-sharing contract, the platform’s and the third party’s profits should satisfy the condition:
,
. We find that only when
,
, the conditions are satisfied concurrently. Through adopting the VAS cost-sharing contract, the platform should initially bear some part of a relatively high service cost to obtain a relatively low outsourced VAS price and attract the third party to accept the contract.
6. Model Extensions
To assess the robustness of our core findings, in this section, our baseline model is extended to construct a platform that provides differentiated VASs to its bilateral participants. Specifically, (1) when the platform offers a VAS by itself, the utility of bilateral participants are and . We use a superscript, “P-BD”, to denote this scenario. (2) when the platform hires the independent third party to provide a VAS, the utility of bilateral participants is ; . We use a superscript, “O-BD”, to denote this scenario.
Based on Equation (1), the profit function of the platform under Model P-BD is
Based on Equations (7) and (8), the profit function of the platform and the third party under Model O-BD are
With a similar calculating procedure as those employed in Model PS and Model OS, we provide the optimal solution of the platform and the third party in
Table 3. In addition, proofs of the equilibrium results are consistent with Model PS and Model OS. Thus, we omit them here.
We discovered certain findings, which are summed up in Remark 1, by using numerical analysis, as illustrated in
Figure 6.
Remark 1. When considering the bilateral differentiated VAS strategy, the main results of the platform’s VAS provision strategy choice in the basic model also hold. The platform should implement Model P-BD so long as the outsourced VAS cost coefficient is high. Otherwise, the platform should implement Model O-BD only when the outsourced VAS cost coefficient is low and the VAS level is a high range.
In
Figure 6a, we simulate the profit of the platform under Model P-BD and Model O-BD with the change in the outsourced VAS level by setting
. Under this scenario (
), even if the outsourced VAS level is high, the platform is always prone to offering bilateral differentiated VAS to its participants by itself, which is in line with the findings of Proposition 5(ii). Similarly, in
Figure 6b, we simulate the profit of the platform under Model P-BD and Model O-BD with the change in the outsourced VAS level by setting
. Under this scenario (
), there exists a Model O-BD dominant range in which the platform is inclined to hire the independent third party to provide bilateral differentiated VASs. Notably, the Model O-BD dominant range must satisfy the condition of the third-party service provider’s VAS cost coefficient being low and VAS level being high. This result is also consistent with the findings of Proposition 5(i). Therefore, we demonstrate that the results of the optimal platform’s VAS provision strategy choice continue to hold qualitatively both in identical and differentiated VASs.
7. Conclusions
The strategic value of two-sided platforms for manufacturer–supply chain collaboration has grown substantially, driven by concurrent developments in information technology and the intensification of economic globalization. Meanwhile, value-added services (VASs) provided by platforms have become a critical part of enhancing competitiveness, and platforms are facing the challenge of whether to outsource VAS investment. To address the challenge, we first developed a basic model for a two-sided platform in which the VAS level and cross-network externality symmetry strength affected the participating utility of suppliers and manufacturers through pricing decisions. On this basis, we constructed two theoretical models, which were Model PS and Model OS, to derive the optimal solutions for the platform and the third party and explore the platform’s optimal selection of VAS mode. Moreover, we considered VAS cost-sharing contracts to further explore platform cooperation strategies and tested the models’ robustness considering differentiated bilateral VASs.
7.1. Main Conclusions
This paper yields three main findings that complement the operating mechanism of two-sided manufacturing platforms. First, we obtained optimal bilateral participant pricing strategies and analyzed the impact of key parameters, such as the cross-network externality symmetry and the VAS level, on the platform’s and the third party’s optimal decisions. In addition, in comparison with not providing VAS, our analysis revealed that two-sided platforms derive greater strategic advantages from VAS provision when participants exhibit positive degrees of cross-network externality symmetry, where balanced, reciprocal utility flows between user groups create mutually reinforcing participation incentives. Second, a platform’s preferred VAS provision strategy is jointly determined by a third party’s outsourced VAS quality and cost coefficient. So long as the outsourced VAS cost coefficient is high, the platform should choose Model PS. When the outsourced VAS quality and cost coefficient are relatively low concurrently, the platform should also select Model PS. Only when the outsourced VAS quality is relatively high and cost coefficient is in a low range should the platform opt for Model OS. Additionally, this optimal VAS provision strategy also remains unchanged when considering platforms that provide differentiated VASs for its bilateral participants. Third, we gave the optimal VAS cost-sharing ratio and clarified the conditions for achieving a VAS cost-sharing contract. Introducing a VAS cost-sharing contract is helpful to improve the performance of the platform and the third party when the outsourced VAS cost coefficient is relatively high. Conversely, when the outsourced VAS cost coefficient is relatively low, VAS cost-sharing contracts should not be implemented.
7.2. Managerial Insights
Several significant managerial implications can be derived from our findings, offering actionable guidance for platform managers across different growth stages. (1) In the preliminary stage, it is crucial for a two-sided platform to ignite network effects by providing targeted VASs to both participant groups. By capitalizing on symmetry in cross-network effects, the platform can design VASs that create reciprocal value, simultaneously boosting attraction for both sides. For example, a nascent B2B industrial equipment platform might provide digital inventory management software for manufacturers and financing solutions for buyers. These VASs reduce friction and enhance participation value for both user groups, creating a virtuous cycle of growth. (2) During the development process, as platform scales and internal VAS costs rise significantly, a strategic transition toward third-party provisioning becomes essential to maintain innovation and cost-efficiency. The key is to curate a high-quality ecosystem of partners. For example, an expanding smart-home two-sided platform ecosystem (e.g., Samsung SmartThings) would shift from building all compatible devices itself to certifying thousands of third-party device manufacturers. This strategy rapidly expands variety for consumers while the platform focuses on core platform stability and standards. (3) In the latter stage of platform development, implementing VAS cost-sharing contracts with key third-party providers can deepen partnerships and create sustainable “win-win” outcomes. This involves sharing risks and incentives to align interests closely. For example, an established two-sided software platform (e.g., Salesforce) might partner with a consulting firm to develop a specialized industry module. The platform shares the development cost, incentivizing the partner to offer the solution at a preferential rate to the platform’s clients. This enhances the platform’s value proposition while giving the consulting firm access to a vast customer base.
7.3. Further Research
Further research can be conducted in the following aspects. First, although the management implications derived from this study are theoretically clear, a limitation lies in the fact that a comprehensive numerical sensitivity analysis of the model parameters has not yet been conducted. Future research can quantitatively test the robustness of the conclusions of this study by systematically perturbing key (small) parameters. Second, participants on one or both sides often lack information regarding the prices charged to participants on the other side. Therefore, considering how information availability influences price structures would be a challenging yet fascinating area for further study. Third, as platforms play a solely functional role as intermediaries, an increasing number of concerns have been raised about the insufficient corporate social responsibility of platforms [
55]. Further research should consider how the factor of corporate social responsibility on platforms’ development goals shape the existing results.