Baseline Results: Using System GMM
Table 3 displays the results of the two-step dynamic system GMM estimator. Using the previously given Equation (11) and the results of the GMM system, we calculate the IQ threshold over which the impact of the debt turns positive.
The coefficient of debt is significantly negative across all the models, with the coefficient value ranging from −0.237 to −1.010, indicating that higher levels of debt are related to a substantial decline in economic growth. Moreover, the strong statistical significance of these coefficients (mostly at the 1% level) underscores the reliability of this negative relationship in the sample. The results imply that debt is a critical factor that countries need to manage carefully, as excessive debt accumulation can substantially hamper their economic growth prospects.
In the context of IQ, the coefficient of IQ measured by VAA is 0.686 in Column 1 and 0.237 in Column 2. This suggests that when VAA improves, it indicates greater freedom of expression, media independence, and public participation, which can have a positive impact on economic growth.
In Columns 3 and 4, the IQ is measured by PSV, and the coefficients are 0.664 in Column 3 and 0.199 in Column 4, with p < 0.01, suggesting that PSV has a positive relationship with economic growth. The strong positive effect indicates that a politically stable environment significantly promotes economic growth, likely by minimizing uncertainty, deterring conflict, and encouraging investment.
The coefficients for GEF are 0.599 and 0.234 in columns 5 and 6, respectively. These results imply that improvements in public service quality, civil service competence, and policy formulation significantly contribute to economic growth. GEF enhances policy credibility and public investment efficiency, allowing for the resources to be allocated where they are most productive.
The IQ measured by REQ, with coefficients of 0.233 and 0.275 in columns 5 and 6, shows strong and consistent positive effects on economic growth. These results are theoretically supported by endogenous growth models, where efficient regulatory frameworks reduce market distortions and transaction costs, thereby enhancing innovation, entrepreneurship, and TFP.
The IQ measured by ROL shows the coefficients of 0.228 and 0.263 in columns 9 and 10, respectively. The positive and highly significant values reflect that strong legal institutions characterized by property rights protection and contract enforcement directly boost economic growth. This shows that a well-functioning ROL reduces uncertainty, fosters investment, and ensures the efficient resolution of disputes.
The IQ measured by COC shows the coefficients of 0.420 and 0.153 in models 11 and 12, respectively. The positive coefficients suggest that COC has a meaningful impact on improving economic performance. Corruption increases the cost of doing business. Controlling corruption enhances institutional efficiency and ensures that public and private sector interactions are governed by fair and predictable rules. Overall, all the indicators show a positive relationship with economic growth.
Moreover, the results of the interaction term, which are the main results in this study, indicate that in the second model (column 2), where the interaction term () is introduced, the interaction term is significantly positive (0.129, p < 0.01). This indicates that although debt is harmful in general, its adverse effect diminishes as IQ measured by VAA improves. In other words, IQ plays a moderating role, mitigating the negative impact of debt on economic growth. The turning point analysis reveals that the harmful impact of debt disappears when the IQ index exceeds a threshold value of approximately 7.55 (on the normalized 0–10 scale). According to column 2, the marginal value is −1.103 + 0.129 × VAA, indicating that debt may boost economic growth in nations with VAA values more than 7.55. Therefore, nations with a VAA less than 7.55 find that debt has an unfavorable effect on economic growth.
Column (4) introduces the interaction term to explore whether political stability conditions mitigate the effect of debt on economic growth. The results show that the interaction term is positive and highly significant (0.143, p < 0.01). This indicates a moderating effect, meaning that the negative impact of debt on economic growth weakens as political stability improves. In other words, in politically stable environments, countries are better able to manage and utilize debt in a way that does not hinder economic performance. To quantify this moderating effect, a threshold value for IQ can be calculated using the formula given by Equation (11), and the calculated threshold value for PSV is 7.04. This implies that when PSV exceeds a value of approximately 7.04, the net effect of debt on economic growth becomes neutral or even positive. This threshold is meaningful for policy, especially in developing countries seeking to leverage public borrowing for growth-enhancing investments without destabilizing their economies.
Column (6) provides the results of incorporating the interaction term, which measures the moderating role of GEF in the debt and economic growth nexus. The results indicate that although the baseline results have an adverse effect of debt on economic growth, the interaction term is positive and statistically significant (0.114, p < 0.01), suggesting that GEF helps to mitigate the negative impact of debt. This finding suggests that governments with effective institutions are better able to allocate debt resources efficiently, implement counter-cyclical policies, and maintain public trust in fiscal governance. As the interaction is positive, it implies that the harmful effects of debt diminish as the GEF improves. A threshold analysis indicates that once GEF exceeds 7.68, the net effect of debt on economic growth becomes neutral or positive. This implies that countries with GEF above this value can potentially absorb and manage higher debt levels without economic growth being compromised.
In column (8), the interaction term is positive and statistically significant (0.091, p < 0.01), suggesting that as REQ improves, the detrimental effect of debt is attenuated. This implies a moderating effect, where strong regulatory institutions help buffer the economy against the adverse consequences of public borrowing. The net effect of debt on economic growth becomes less negative as REQ increases, and a threshold analysis shows that the turning point occurs around 7.23. Hence, when the REQ exceeds 7.23, the negative impact of debt on economic growth may be neutralized or even reversed. These findings are theoretically consistent with frameworks that emphasize the role of IQ in fiscal policy effectiveness. Countries with sound regulatory systems are better equipped to design credible and growth-enhancing debt-financed investments while minimizing risks like corruption, inefficiencies, or policy reversals.
In column (10), the results show that the interaction term is positive and significant (0.095, p < 0.01), signifying that improvements in ROL attenuate the negative effect of debt on economic growth. This supports the theoretical proposition that legal institutions, through stronger enforcement of laws, protection of property rights, and judicial efficiency, enhance public accountability and ensure that debt is used more productively. The fiscal governance literature asserts that strong legal systems are crucial for debt sustainability and efficient public investment. To identify when the moderating effect offsets the negative debt-economic growth relationship, a threshold level of IQ is 7.24. This implies that once the ROL exceeds approximately 7.24, the net effect of debt on economic growth becomes neutral or potentially positive. Thus, column (10) provides strong evidence that while debt tends to suppress economic growth, countries with stronger ROL can effectively mitigate this impact and potentially harness debt for development purposes.
The results in Column (12) show that the coefficient of the interaction term is positive and significant (0.140,
p < 0.01). This suggests that control of corruption significantly moderates the adverse effect of debt on economic growth. In practical terms, this means that in countries with stronger anti-corruption institutions, debt is less harmful and can even become growth-supportive if corruption is sufficiently contained. Theoretically, this finding asserts that corruption undermines the efficiency of public spending, distorts fiscal policy, and increases the likelihood of debt mismanagement. When corruption is controlled, however, debt-financed expenditures are more likely to be channeled into productive investments such as infrastructure, education, or health. A threshold analysis can quantify the COC at which the debt’s negative effect is neutralized when the value of COC is greater than 7.21. This implies that when a country’s COC index exceeds 7.21, the net effect of debt on economic growth turns neutral or positive. This threshold is policy-relevant, as it indicates the minimum quality of COC needed to ensure that public borrowing does not impede economic growth. The result emphasizes the importance of transparency, accountability, and institutional checks in managing debt sustainably and promoting inclusive development. Results of the marginal effects of debt on IQ using the WGI dataset are presented in
Table 4.
Overall, the interaction terms between debt and the various dimensions of IQ consistently exhibit positive and statistically significant coefficients across all relevant models. These findings suggest that strong institutional frameworks can effectively mitigate the adverse impact of debt on economic growth. While debt alone exerts a significant negative influence, indicating that excessive borrowing may hinder economic growth through mechanisms such as debt overhang or fiscal crowding-out, these institutional variables appear to act as moderators that cushion or reverse this harmful effect. For instance, a higher level of GEF or REQ may ensure that debt-financed expenditures are channeled into productive investments, thereby offsetting the drag on economic growth. Similarly, political stability and ROL likely reduce uncertainty and transaction costs, making debt more manageable and growth-enhancing. These results align well with the theoretical foundations of New Institutional Economics and the fiscal governance literature, which emphasize that the IQ determines whether debt becomes a burden or a tool for development. Thus, in countries with strong institutions, debt may not necessarily impede economic growth, as the institutional environment provides the necessary capacity, accountability, and efficiency to manage it sustainably.
Moreover, the results of lagged GDP per capita show that the coefficient on lagged GDP per capita is mostly negative and statistically significant, except in a few specifications (e.g., columns 3 and 5) where it is small and insignificant or even slightly positive (e.g., column 5: 0.010). A negative coefficient suggests conditional convergence, meaning that countries with higher initial income levels grow more slowly over time. However, the magnitude is relatively small (e.g., −0.020 to −0.141), indicating slow convergence rates, typical in cross-country panel studies.
The coefficient on TFP is positive and highly significant (
p < 0.01) across all specifications, ranging from 0.127 to 0.318. This robust result indicates that improvements in productivity strongly enhance economic growth, which is consistent with endogenous growth models (e.g., Romer [
64,
65]) that highlight innovation, technological efficiency, and factor reallocation as key drivers of long-run output growth. The largest coefficients appear in models with stronger IQ, which suggests that TFP gains are more effective when institutions are sound.
Inflation shows a positive and statistically significant coefficient across all models, though the magnitudes are very small (0.001 to 0.050). While inflation is typically considered harmful for economic growth beyond a certain threshold, mild inflation in developing economies can indicate healthy demand or currency stability, possibly explaining this result. Also, some models (e.g., REQ and ROL) show stronger positive coefficients (up to 0.050), suggesting that inflation’s impact may be nonlinear or context-dependent, supporting findings from Barro [
66] and Dornbusch and Fischer [
67], who note that moderate inflation can be tolerable or even growth-neutral when macroeconomic management is credible.
The coefficient on government size is consistently negative and highly significant in all columns (from −0.052 to −0.631). This implies that increased public consumption may crowd out private investment or reflect inefficient spending, particularly in countries with weaker institutions. These findings resonate with Barro’s [
68] view that while productive government spending (e.g., on infrastructure) can enhance economic growth, excessive or unproductive public expenditures reduce efficiency and can increase fiscal burdens.
Exports have a positive and statistically significant impact across all models, with coefficients ranging from 0.016 to 0.035. This affirms the classical view that openness to trade fosters economic growth through improved resource allocation, scale economies, and technology spillovers (e.g., Grossman and Helpman [
69]). Export-led growth is particularly important for developing economies, and the consistent significance of this variable reinforces the role of external competitiveness in fostering sustained output growth [
70].
The coefficient on urbanization is mostly negative and statistically significant, with a few exceptions. For instance, in models using GEF (column 7), urbanization has an extremely large negative coefficient (−2.396, p < 0.01), whereas in some cases (e.g., COC), it becomes statistically insignificant or even positive. These results suggest that urbanization alone does not guarantee growth, especially if not accompanied by effective urban planning, infrastructure development, or job creation. In poorly governed or rapidly urbanizing countries, urbanization may lead to congestion, slums, or unproductive agglomeration effects, reducing their growth potential.
In addition, in System GMM, instruments are lagged values of endogenous variables used to address potential endogeneity issues (e.g., simultaneity, omitted variables, measurement error). The number of instruments reported (e.g., 101 to 114 in your table) reflects the count of these instrumental variables used in the estimation. A larger number of instruments can improve efficiency but may also lead to instrument proliferation, which risks overfitting the endogenous variables and weakening the power of specification tests. It is important to balance having enough instruments to address endogeneity without overfitting.
The Sargan test checks the validity of the instruments by testing the null hypothesis that the instruments are exogenous (i.e., uncorrelated with the error term). A high p-value (close to 1), as seen from our results (0.901 to 1.000), indicates failure to reject the null hypothesis, meaning that the instruments are valid and not correlated with the error term.
The Arellano–Bond test for AR(2) examines whether the differenced error terms exhibit autocorrelation of order 2. The null hypothesis is that there is no second-order autocorrelation in the differenced residuals. A p-value greater than 0.05 indicates failure to reject the null, confirming that the model residuals do not have problematic autocorrelation and the instruments are likely valid. Our results show p-values ranging from about 0.249 to 0.877, well above 0.05, indicating no evidence of AR(2).