The Impact Mechanism of Non-Economic Policies on Social and Investor Disagreement in China: A Dual Analysis Based on Empirical Evidence and DSGE Models
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
2.1. Investor Disagreement
2.2. Macroeconomic Policy and Economic Regulation
2.3. The Interplay Between DSGE and Behavioral Economics
2.4. Review of the Literature
3. Research Design
3.1. Research Framework
3.2. Data Sources
3.3. Definitions of Variables and Concepts
3.3.1. Social Disagreement and Investor Disagreement
3.3.2. Non-Economic Policies and Related Variables
3.3.3. Descriptive Statistics and Preliminary Analysis
4. Evidence on the Influence of Non-Economic Policies
4.1. The Role of Non-Economic Policies in Shaping Social Disagreement
4.2. The Contagion Mechanism of Social Disagreement to Investor Disagreement
4.2.1. The Contagion Mechanism
4.2.2. Evidence of Contagion
- (1)
- Data Independence Basis
- (2)
- Correlation Analysis
5. Further Analysis Based on a DSGE Model Incorporating Social Disagreement and Non-Economic Policies
5.1. Model Setup
5.1.1. Non-Economic Policies
5.1.2. Behavioral Investors and Social Groups
- (1)
- Social disagreement
- (2)
- Behavioral Investors
5.1.3. Stock Price Forecast
5.2. Parameter Calibration
5.3. Numerical Simulation
5.4. Impulse Response Analysis
6. Suggestions and Conclusions
6.1. Policy Analysis and Suggestions
- (1)
- Prioritize the Publication of Central Regulations
- (2)
- Optimize Administrative Approval Processes
- (3)
- Promote Interdepartmental Collaboration
- (4)
- Monitor and Evaluate Policy Interaction Effects
6.2. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
- (I)
- Household
- (1)
- Consumption, Income, and Expenditure
- (2)
- Labor Supply with Wage Stickiness
- (II)
- Production Sector
- (1)
- Final Goods Firms
- (2)
- Intermediate Goods Firms
- (3)
- Price Setting for Intermediate Firms
- (III)
- Government Sector
References
- Sharpe, W.F. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J. Financ. 1964, 19, 425–442. [Google Scholar]
- Hong, H.; Stein, J.C. Disagreement and the stock market. J. Econ. Perspect. 2007, 21, 109–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, S. Preferences, Beliefs, Information, and Securities Prices; Shanghai People’s Publishing House: Shanghai, China, 2002. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Wu, H. Heterogeneous Interpretations, Overconfidence, and Market Reactions to Public Information: A Study Based on the Perspective of Investor Sentiment Disparities. Investig. Res. 2022, 41, 91–112. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Giacomini, R.; Skreta, V.; Teles, P. Heterogeneity, Inattention and Bayesian Updates. Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 2020, 12, 282–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kim, J.S.; Ryu, D.; Seo, S.W. Investor sentiment and return predictability of disagreement. J. Bank. Financ. 2014, 42, 166–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shi, Y.; Li, F. Short Selling Restrictions, Convergence of Opinions, and the Price Effect of Information Disclosure: Empirical Evidence from the A-Share Market. Financ. Res. 2012, 08, 111–124. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Liu, Y.; Zhu, H. Individual and Institutional Investors: Who Influences A-Share Price Changes? A Perspective Based on Heterogeneous Beliefs of Investors. Chin. Manag. Sci. 2018, 26, 120–130. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Jiang, H.; Sun, Z. Dispersion in beliefs among active mutual funds and the cross-section of stock returns. J. Financ. Econ. 2014, 114, 341–365. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cookson, J.A.; Niessner, M. Why Don’t We Agree? Evidence from a Social Network of Investors. J. Financ. 2020, 75, 173–228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, X.; Xiang, Z.; Xu, W.; Yuan, P. The causal relationship between social media sentiment and stock return: Experimental evidence from an online message forum. Econ. Lett. 2022, 216, 32–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sanford, A. Does Perception Matter in Asset Pricing? Modeling Volatility Jumps Using Twitter-Based Sentiment Indices. J. Behav. Financ. 2022, 23, 262–280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, T.; Liu, J.; Ma, J.; Tai, Y. Uncovering the hidden impact: Noninvestor disagreement and its role in asset pricing. J. Risk 2023, 25, 25–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Friedman, M. The role of monetary policy American Economic Review (1968) 58, March, pp. 1–17. In A Macroeconomics Reader; Routledge: London, UK, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Mankiw, N.G.; Romer, D.; Weil, D.N. A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth. Q. J. Econ. 1992, 107, 407–437. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kydland, F.E.; Prescott, E.C. Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans. J. Political Econ. 1977, 85, 473–491. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, T.; Chen, X.; Liu, J. Economic Policy Uncertainty and Enterprise Financing Efficiency: Evidence from China. Sustainability 2023, 15, 8847. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chen, Y. The Connotation and Implementation of Demand-Side Management: The Perspective of "Three-in-One" Macro Policy. Social Sciences in Chinese Higher Education. Institutions 2021, 6, 94–100. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Zhang, J. Exploring the Construction of a New System and Direction for Macroeconomic Regulation Policies with Chinese Characteristics. J. Xiangtan Univ. (Philos. Soc. Sci. Ed.) 2023, 47, 97–106. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Azariadis, C. Self-fulfilling prophecies. J. Econ. Theory 1981, 25, 380–396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Farmer, R.E.; Guo, J.T. Real business cycles and the animal spirits hypothesis. J. Econ. Theory 1994, 63, 42–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Benhabib, J.; Farmer, R.E. Indeterminacy and increasing returns. J. Econ. Theory 1994, 63, 19–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sargent, P.B. The diversity of neuronal nicotinic acetylcholine receptors. Annu. Rev. Neurosci. 1993, 16, 403–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- De Grauwe, P. Animal spirits and monetary policy. Econ. Theory 2011, 47, 423–457. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wen, X. Investor Sentiment, Monetary Policy Adjustment and Stock Market Boom-bust Cycles: Based on a Heterogeneous Expectation Stock Market DSGE Model. J. Cent. Univ. Financ. Econ. 2017, 08, 23–36+46. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Liu, C.C.; Liang, X.D.; Jiang, W. Research on Chinese Entrepreneur Confidence, Investor Confidence and Macroeconomic Fluctuation under DSGE Framework. J. Qingdao Univ. (Nat. Sci. Ed.) 2023, 36, 116–123+130. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Antweiler, W.; Frank, M.Z. Is all that talk just noise? The information content of internet stock message boards. J. Financ. 2004, 59, 1259–1294. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hatfield, E.; Cacioppo, J.T.; Rapson, R.L. Emotional Contagion; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1994. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Simon, H.A. A behavioral model of rational choice. Q. J. Econ. 1955, 69, 99–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Woodford, M. Optimal interest-rate smoothing. Rev. Econ. Stud. 2003, 70, 861–886. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Smets, F.; Wouters, R. Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. Am. Econ. Rev. 2007, 97, 586–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Christiano, L.J.; Eichenbaum, M.; Evans, C.L. Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. J. Political Econ. 2005, 113, 1–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Challe, E.; Giannitsarou, C. Stock prices and monetary policy shocks: A general equilibrium approach. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 2014, 40, 46–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Anderson, S.P.; De Palma, A.; Thisse, J.F. Discrete Choice Theory of Product Differentiation; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1992. [Google Scholar]
- Brock, W.A.; Hommes, C.H. A rational route to randomness. Econom. J. Econom. Soc. 1997, 65, 1059–1095. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Castelnuovo, E.; Nistico, S. Stock market conditions and monetary policy in a DSGE model for the US. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 2010, 34, 1700–1731. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nisticò, S. Monetary policy and stock-price dynamics in a DSGE framework. J. Macroecon. 2012, 34, 126–146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bofinger, P.; Debes, S.; Gareis, J.; Mayer, E. Monetary policy transmission in a model with animal spirits and house price booms and busts. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 2013, 37, 2862–2881. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mei, D.; Gong, L. Currency Mismatch, Revaluation and Output Fluctuations. Quant. Econ. Tech. Econ. Res. 2011, 28, 37–51. [Google Scholar]
- Smets, F.; Wouters, R. An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2003, 1, 1123–1175. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Calvo, G.A. Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. J. Monet. Econ. 1983, 12, 383–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Variable | Proxy | Variable | Proxy |
---|---|---|---|
Number of department work documents in the past 5 days | Bgn5 | Number of industry regulations in the past 5 days | Hgn5 |
Number of department normative documents in the past 5 days | Bgfn5 | Number of administrative license approvals in the past 5 days | Xxn5 |
Number of departmental regulations in the past 5 days | Bgzn5 | Number of judicial interpretation documents in the past 5 days | Sfn5 |
Number of internal Party regulations in the past 5 days | Dfn5 | Number of published documents in the past 5 days | Fbn5 |
Number of State Council normative documents in the past 5 days | Gfn5 | Number of joint agencies in the past 5 days | Jgn5 |
Number of group regulations in the past 5 days | Tgn5 | Number of central government regulations in the past 5 days | Zyn5 |
The lagging term of stock excess return | ; |
Variable | ADF Statistics | p-Value | Mean | Std Dev | Variable | ADF Statistics | p-Value | Mean | Std Dev |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
−5.2909 | 0.0000 | −1.2157 | 0.7855 | −23.6285 | 0.0000 | −0.0001 | 0.0161 | ||
Bgfn5 | −4.9215 | 0.0000 | 0.2959 | 0.4791 | Hgn5 | −4.1998 | 0.0000 | 0.3147 | 0.5197 |
Sfn5 | −6.6097 | 0.0000 | 0.0027 | 0.0432 | Xxn5 | −5.3944 | 0.0000 | 0.4668 | 0.6486 |
Fbn5 | −6.8194 | 0.0000 | 0.2995 | 0.4755 | Jgn5 | −5.9422 | 0.0000 | 2.2433 | 1.3640 |
Gfn5 | −68272 | 0.0000 | 0.0108 | 0.0859 | Zyn5 | −7.5392 | 0.0000 | 0.0810 | 0.2311 |
) | |||
---|---|---|---|
Variable | Coef. | Variable | Coef. |
Fbn5 | 0.1432 *** | Fbn5 | 0.4798 *** |
Zyn5 | −0.0926 *** | Zyn5 | −0.4361 *** |
Jgn5 | 0.0425 *** | Jgn5 | 0.1834 *** |
Bgfn5 | −0.1120 *** | Bgfn5 | −0.3573 *** |
Gfn5 | 0.1231 ** | Gfn5 | 0.5336 *** |
Sfn5 | 0.3007 *** | Sfn5 | 0.7358 *** |
Hgn5 | −0.0703 *** | Hgn5 | −0.2506 *** |
Xxn5 | −0.0348 *** | Xxn5 | −0.1012 ** |
Fbn5 × Bgn5 | −0.0761 *** | Fbn5 × Bgn5 | −0.2813 *** |
Fbn5 × Bgzn5 | 0.6392 *** | Fbn5 × Bgzn5 | 1.7391 *** |
Fbn5 × Dfn5 | 0.2424 *** | Fbn5 × Dfn5 | 0.8678 *** |
Fbn5 × Xxn5 | −0.0499 *** | Fbn5 × Xxn5 | −0.2240 *** |
Zyn5 × Bgfn5 | 0.1096 * | Zyn5 × Bgfn5 | 0.4992 ** |
Zyn5 × Xxn5 | 0.1126 ** | Zyn5 × Xxn5 | 0.3186 ** |
Jgn5 × Sfn5 | −0.3649 ** | Jgn5 × Sfn5 | −0.6075 ** |
Control: | 0.0258 | Control: | 0.8565 |
Control: | −0.1699 | Control: | 1.0700 |
Control: | 0.3464 | Control: | 0.9761 |
Control: | −0.4013 | Control: | −1.3656 |
_cons | 0.3230 *** | _cons | −1.3891 |
0.0805 | 0.0813 |
Cosine Similarity | JS Disagreement | ||
---|---|---|---|
Average Similarity | 0.0043 | JS Disagreement Degree | 0.2652 |
Highest Similarity | 0.2216 | LDA Keywords | |
Highest Similarity Keywords | Topic1 | refueling, life, hehe, low-carbon, flowers | |
China; electricity; new energy; company; year; more; | you; years; submit; what; I wish you; company; lose money | Topic 2 | company, green, project, China, development |
Lowest Similarity | 0.0000 | Topic 3 | It’s, like, a. What, yes, reply |
Lowest Similarity Keywords | Topic 4 | received, approval, car, new energy, ask | |
BMW; expected; year; listing; overseas; media; | may I ask; company; what; disclose; annual report | Topic 5 | market, today, shareholder, company |
Parameter | Calibrated Value | Parameter Description | Reference Source |
---|---|---|---|
0.99 | Indicates a risk-free annual interest rate of 4% | (Castelnuovo & Nisticò, 2010; Nisticò, 2012; Challe & Giannitsarou, 2014; DE Grauwe, 2011; Bofinger et al., 2013); [24,36,37,38] | |
5 | Generally ranges between 1 and 5, but in asset pricing literature, it can be as high as 12 | ||
0.2 | Labor supply elasticity η typically ranges from 0 to 1 | ||
4 | Elasticity of substitution between product types, generally between 3 and 10 | ||
4 | Elasticity of substitution between labor types, generally between 3 and 10 | ||
0.8 | Wage stickiness, wages adjust every 5 quarters, more frequently than prices | ||
0.66 | Price stickiness, prices adjust every 3 quarters, more frequently than wages | ||
0.36 | Share of labor income in output | ||
20 | Length of the window period | ||
0.5 | Memory coefficient of investors for past performance | ||
1 | Fixed value for disagreement | ||
2 | Sensitivity of stock price volatility variance to the magnitude of forecast disagreement | ||
1 | Coefficient of investor rationality | ||
1.5 | Response coefficient of nominal interest rate to output gap | Mei & Gong (2011); Wen (2017) [25,39] | |
0.6 | Response coefficient of nominal interest rate to inflation gap | ||
0.75 | Interest rate smoothing coefficient | ||
2 | Response coefficient of nominal interest rate to stock price gap | ||
3/1.5/0.5/−1.5 | Sensitivity coefficient of social disagreement affecting non-economic policies | This model simulates both positive, negative, and various sizes of coefficients | |
−2.5/2.5 | Sensitivity coefficient of non-economic policies required to match economic policies | Previous studies (current ratio of economic policies to non-economic policies) | |
3 | Coefficient for the impact of increased social disagreement on investor expectations (sentiment) | (Liu et al., 2023) [13] | |
−0.15 | Impact of social disagreement on stock price expectations | (Liu et al., 2023) [13] | |
0.1 | Impact coefficient of non-economic policies on social disagreement | ) | |
0.4/0.2/0.1/0.1 | Memory coefficient of people in society for past performance | Var result of data from Section 4.2.2 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2024 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Liu, J.; Ma, J.; Tai, Y. The Impact Mechanism of Non-Economic Policies on Social and Investor Disagreement in China: A Dual Analysis Based on Empirical Evidence and DSGE Models. Systems 2024, 12, 538. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12120538
Liu J, Ma J, Tai Y. The Impact Mechanism of Non-Economic Policies on Social and Investor Disagreement in China: A Dual Analysis Based on Empirical Evidence and DSGE Models. Systems. 2024; 12(12):538. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12120538
Chicago/Turabian StyleLiu, Jianing, Junjun Ma, and Yafei Tai. 2024. "The Impact Mechanism of Non-Economic Policies on Social and Investor Disagreement in China: A Dual Analysis Based on Empirical Evidence and DSGE Models" Systems 12, no. 12: 538. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12120538
APA StyleLiu, J., Ma, J., & Tai, Y. (2024). The Impact Mechanism of Non-Economic Policies on Social and Investor Disagreement in China: A Dual Analysis Based on Empirical Evidence and DSGE Models. Systems, 12(12), 538. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12120538