1. Introduction
The ecological civilization construction, a major strategic initiative proposed by the Chinese government in the 21st century, aims to promote harmonious coexistence between humanity and nature, achieving sustainable development in economic, social, and environmental dimensions. At the same time, to address the issue of regional development imbalance, regional coordinated development strategies, another significant policy direction of the Chinese government, have been consistently pursued. These strategies aim to optimize the policy system, promote integrated interactions among regions, gradually enhance development balance, and form a new pattern of coordinated development. In this process, China innovatively integrated the two, proposing Major Function-Oriented Zone (MFOZ) planning to coordinate ecological protection and regional development. An MFOZ is a spatial unit that identifies specific regions as certain types of major functional orientation based on their resource and environmental carrying capacity, existing development density, and development potential. MFOZ planning divides the national territory into four types of functional zones: optimized development zones, key development zones, restricted development zones, and prohibited development zones. The classification aims to guide regional functional positioning through differentiated policies, thereby achieving synergistic development of economic, social, and ecological benefits [
1].
As urbanized areas, optimized and key development zones primarily serve to provide industrial goods and service products. In contrast, restricted and prohibited development zones, functioning as major agricultural production areas and key ecological function zones, are primarily tasked with supplying agricultural and ecological products. Their core role is to ensure national food security and the stability of the ecological system. These zones are predominantly located in ecologically fragile and economically underdeveloped areas. This geographical distribution leads to an increasingly prominent structural conflict between ecological protection responsibilities and regional development rights. Poverty is not only a significant cause of environmental degradation [
2], but ecological restriction policies further exacerbate the survival challenges faced by local residents, creating a vicious cycle of “ecological protection → restricted development → poverty exacerbation” [
3].
As targeted poverty alleviation becomes the core strategy for national poverty reduction efforts, effectively linking ecological compensation mechanisms with poverty alleviation policies emerges as a critical issue requiring urgent resolution. Research indicates that traditional regional development-oriented poverty alleviation models encounter bottlenecks in ecologically sensitive areas; excessive development leads to ecological degradation, while singular economic compensation struggles to offset the development opportunities lost by residents due to ecological protection measures [
4]. The ecological compensation mechanism within MFOZs, characterized by “government-led, market participation, and multi-stakeholder collaboration” in fund allocation and policy design, offers a potential pathway to overcome this dilemma [
5]. Nonetheless, existing mechanisms still suffer from issues such as low compensation standards, unbalanced benefit distribution, and insufficient sustainability, necessitating the exploration of coupling models between ecological compensation and targeted poverty alleviation at the institutional level [
6].
Within the strategic context of coordinating sustainable rural development and common prosperity, constructing an ecological compensation mechanism oriented towards multidimensional poverty governance holds significant theoretical and practical value. Theoretically, developing multidimensional poverty identification standards based on the capability approach [
7] and localizing the United Nations Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) into a rural revitalization evaluation system [
8] not only expands the operationalization pathways for Sen’s concept of “multidimensional poverty” but also enhances the theoretical framework of sustainable development. Guiding the optimal allocation of ecological resources through MFOZ planning [
9] and exploring synergistic mechanisms for carbon sinks trading and cultivated land protection [
10] offer new explanatory dimensions for breaking the “ecological poverty trap”. Practically, establishing a linkage mechanism between ecological compensation and poverty reduction [
11] can promote coordinated regional development. For instance, the dual incentive mechanism of “carbon sink compensation–income growth” formed in Guangdong Province’s cultivated land protection [
10] provides a replicable model for ecological poverty alleviation nationwide. Drawing lessons from the government–market collaborative compensation system constructed under the US Land Conservation Reserve Program [
12] helps achieve policy synergy between “dual carbon” goals and rural revitalization. Currently, there is an urgent need to integrate rural digitalization into the capability-building framework [
13] to address the capability deprivation issues faced by digitally disadvantaged groups in dimensions such as technology access and social participation, offering new insights for comprehensively enhancing the resilience of sustainable rural development.
Based on this context, this study focuses on the dialectical relationship between ecological compensation and poverty alleviation development within China’s Major Function-Oriented Zones (MFOZs) during the post-2020 consolidation period of poverty alleviation achievements (2020–2024), aiming to investigate their synergistic mechanisms with the overarching goal of breaking the vicious cycle of “ecological protection → restricted development → poverty exacerbation.” It seeks to address the following core questions: How can institutional innovation achieve the organic integration of internalizing ecological protection externalities and fostering the endogenous development of impoverished populations? How can sustainable poverty alleviation be promoted in impoverished areas while ensuring the functionality of ecosystem services?
To address the aforementioned issues, the core theoretical contribution of this study lies in constructing and applying an innovative three-dimensional integrated analytical framework, thereby deepening the understanding of the synergy between ecological compensation and poverty alleviation mechanisms. This framework systematically integrates three interrelated and progressively advancing key dimensions: (1) Externality Internalization: Moving beyond the traditional view of compensation as mere fiscal transfers, this dimension combines Pigouvian government intervention with Coasean market-based transaction logic. It explores how to translate the ambiguous value of ecosystem services into tangible economic incentives through a mix of government legislation and market instruments (e.g., water rights, carbon trading). (2) Institutional Synergy: Building on economic mechanisms, this dimension focuses on the alignment of ecological compensation and targeted poverty alleviation policies in terms of objectives, tools, and implementation. It examines how institutional design can ensure that compensation funds not only offset opportunity costs but also precisely serve poverty reduction goals, achieving a synergistic policy effect where 1 + 1 > 2. (3) Capability Reconstruction: As the ultimate focus of the framework, this study operationalizes Amartya Sen’s capability approach, shifting the policy’s end goal from short-term income boosts to the long-term expansion of poor populations’ functional activity spaces (e.g., access to education, healthcare, and market participation). This marks a fundamental transition from “blood transfusion” poverty relief to “blood generation” development. Unlike previous studies that often analyze these dimensions in isolation, this study innovatively integrates all three, revealing a coherent causal pathway: “economic incentives → institutional safeguards → capability enhancement.” This integrated framework provides a more holistic and actionable theoretical explanation for breaking the “ecological poverty trap.”
The article is structured as follows:
Section 2 presents the theoretical logic and analytical framework.
Section 3 details the dialectical relationship between ecological compensation and poverty alleviation in functional zones and presents innovative pathways, including long-term mechanism design for ecological compensation and poverty alleviation synergy.
Section 4 provides a discussion.
Section 5 presents the conclusion.
2. Theoretical Logic and Analytical Framework
2.1. Core Concept Definition
Ecological compensation in MFOZs is considered within the theoretical scope of a novel multi-objective compensation mechanism. From an environmental economics perspective, Meng Zhaoyi et al. (2008) define it as “a means to incentivize conservation behavior,” [
1] with its core lying in regulating the externalities of socioeconomic activities in different functional zones through legal, administrative, and economic measures. The field of resource economics emphasizes its essence as “an institutional arrangement for the value appreciation of natural capital,” achieving the marketization of ecological values in restricted and prohibited development zones through opportunity cost assessment and policy design [
9]. The strategic nature of this mechanism is reflected in the hierarchical division of compensation providers and standards; for instance, the ecological service values of national-level and provincial-level MFOZs exhibit gradient differences [
14]. It is noteworthy that the current compensation system incorporates non-economic means such as intellectual compensation and employment training, providing institutional support for capability enhancement and long-term poverty alleviation for compensation recipients [
15].
The theoretical core of targeted poverty alleviation stems from Amartya Sen’s “capability approach”. Liu Wanqi (2023), by constructing a dynamic multidimensional poverty measurement model, found that poverty identification solely based on the income dimension exhibits significant bias [
7]. The lack of capabilities more fundamentally reflects the deprivation of rights among impoverished groups in areas such as education, healthcare, and social participation. Compared to traditional poverty alleviation models, targeted poverty alleviation needs to transcend the framework of short-term economic assistance and shift towards expanding the functional activity space of the poor population. For example, empirical research in three counties of Guizhou Province demonstrated that ecological compensation, through employment generation and public service improvement, could increase household poverty exit probability by 14–22% [
11]. This finding corroborates the transmission logic of “capability–opportunity–outcome,” where the enhancement of individual capabilities significantly reduces the risk of returning to poverty [
16].
2.2. Synergistic Logic of Compensation and Poverty Alleviation
The synergy between ecological compensation and poverty alleviation is rooted in their inherent geographical coupling and the structural contradictions within policy design. Cao Shisong et al. (2016) point out that impoverished areas are often compelled to bear protection responsibilities due to ecological fragility [
2]. Geng Xiangyan and Ge Yanxiang (2017), through surveys in 14 contiguous poverty-stricken areas, found that 75% of China’s poor counties are located within key ecological function zones, exhibiting a significant positive correlation between ecological fragility and economic poverty (correlation coefficient of 0.68) [
17]. This spatial overlap stems from structural contradictions in policy design: impoverished regions, by undertaking ecological functions such as water source conservation and biodiversity protection, proactively curtail their development rights, forming a vicious cycle of “ecological protection → accumulated opportunity costs → entrenched poverty” [
2]. Simultaneously, the synergy of policy objectives requires that compensation standards must embed a poverty alleviation orientation. The reform trajectory of the European Union’s Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) shows that combining ecological subsidies with farmer income support systems led to a 12 percentage point decrease in poverty incidence in target areas [
18]. This experience suggests that China’s horizontal compensation mechanisms need to establish a transmission chain of “ecological value → economic compensation → capability investment,” rather than mere fiscal transfers [
19].
Institutional transformation manifests as an adaptive adjustment from “blood transfusion”-type compensation to “hematopoietic”-type poverty alleviation. Game theory analysis of water source protection areas indicates that single-fund compensation models tend to induce “welfare dependency” among recipients; 34.7% of farming households reduced agricultural production inputs after receiving compensation [
20]. In response, Li Liang and Gao Lihong (2017) proposed constructing a “green livelihood substitution” mechanism, achieving endogenous development under environmental constraints through the cultivation of ecological industries [
6]. A typical example includes the organic agriculture projects in the Southern Shaanxi water source area, which increased the average annual income of participating farmers by CNY 4200 while reducing fertilizer use by 23% [
21]. This illustrates that the effective integration of compensation policies and poverty alleviation strategies hinges on activating the capability approach of impoverished groups and the synergistic value-added effects of regional ecological capital.
2.3. Analytical Framework
This study develops a comprehensive analytical framework to examine the dialectical relationship between ecological compensation and poverty alleviation within China’s MFOZs, structured around three interconnected dimensions (
Figure 1). The theoretical originality of this study lies in its innovative application of the capability approach, shifting the analytical focus from traditional income effects to the multidimensional livelihood security and capabilities of impoverished populations, thereby profoundly revealing how ecological compensation policies substantively empower rather than merely “transfuse”. Its analytical framework transcends the limitations of previous research by integrating conceptual definitions, conducting a dialectical assessment of synergies and conflicts, and proactively exploring innovative policy pathways, constructing a systematic three-dimensional structure.
The analytical framework commences by defining core concepts, positioning ecological compensation in functional zones as a policy instrument designed to address environmental externalities through both fiscal interventions and market-based approaches. Concurrently, poverty alleviation is conceptualized through Sen’s capability approach, with a focus on enhancing multidimensional aspects of livelihood security. Building upon this foundation, the framework elucidates the synergistic relationship between these concepts by examining their inherent geographical interconnectedness, particularly the spatial correlation between ecologically vulnerable regions and impoverished areas, alongside the institutional dynamics that emerge from tensions between conservation requirements and developmental aspirations. This synergy manifests through two primary mechanisms: the internalization of environmental externalities via economic instruments and the strengthening of livelihood capacities through targeted interventions such as vocational training and the cultivation of sustainable industries. Empirical validation for these mechanisms is drawn from domestic implementations, including forestry compensation programs in Jinzhai County, as well as international models exemplified by the European Union’s Common Agricultural Policy.
The framework subsequently identifies critical challenges impeding effective policy integration, notably disparities between compensation adequacy and poverty alleviation objectives, as well as institutional deficiencies in legal frameworks governing compensation schemes. In response, the framework proposes a series of strategic adjustments: the development of differentiated compensation standards reflecting ecosystem service valuations across zonal categories, the establishment of robust legal frameworks to govern compensation distribution with explicit poverty alleviation allocations, and the incorporation of market-oriented mechanisms such as carbon credit systems to complement traditional fiscal approaches. These policy innovations are substantiated through both domestic best practices, including diversified compensation models implemented in Southern Shaanxi, and international exemplars such as performance-based payment systems in the EU, collectively facilitating a paradigm shift from compensatory support to sustainable capacity building. This tripartite analytical structure—encompassing conceptual foundations, synergy and conflict assessment, and policy innovation pathways—offers a comprehensive approach to harmonizing ecological preservation with socioeconomic advancement within functional zones, thereby contributing to theoretical discourse on poverty–environment linkages while informing practical strategies for sustainable development aligned with global sustainability goals.
Our study advances the operationalization of Sen’s capability approach in ecological poverty governance by proposing a novel tripartite framework that integrates externality internalization (Pigouvian/Coasean mechanisms), institutional synergy (compensation–poverty alleviation coupling), and capability reconstruction (functional activity space expansion). Specifically, we transcend existing works by (1) demonstrating how ecological compensation transforms from fiscal transfers into multidimensional capability investments (e.g., Jinzhai’s compensation funds directly enabling education/health access); (2) introducing spatial differentiation in compensation standards tied to MFOZ functional tiers (core/buffer/peripheral zones), addressing the “inverse incentive” gap in past studies; and (3) empirically validating the “ecological protection → capability enhancement → poverty exit” pathway through comparative case analysis (e.g., Southern Shaanxi’s CNY 4200 income increase via organic farming versus traditional subsidies).
2.3.1. Methods
This study employs a mixed-methods approach combining theoretical analysis, case study research, and policy evaluation to investigate the synergistic mechanisms between ecological compensation and poverty alleviation in China’s MFOZs. The methods consist of the following components: (1) a literature analysis method, in which a systematic literature review synthesizes international scholarship and policy documents to establish a theoretical framework, operationalizing core concepts of targeted poverty reduction and ecological service valuation; (2) a case analysis method, in which a comparative case analysis of domestic and international best practices identifies institutional synergies and systemic constraints in compensation mechanisms, validating theoretical propositions through empirical verification; (3) multidisciplinary integration of environmental economics, resource management, and legal studies, which elucidates the tripartite transmission mechanism (capacity-building → opportunity creation → outcome optimization) governing eco-compensation–poverty nexus, with
Figure 1 diagrammatically representing the conceptual architecture.
2.3.2. Case Selection
In the case studies presented in this paper, the Southern Shaanxi region is selected as the core water source area of the South-to-North Water Diversion Middle Route Project, alongside two regions in the European Union.
The South-to-North Water Diversion Middle Route Project is a major strategic infrastructure initiative in China for cross-basin and cross-regional water resource allocation. The Southern Shaanxi region, serving as the core water source area of this project, encompasses three prefecture-level cities—Hanzhong, Ankang, and Shangluo (collectively referred to as “Southern Shaanxi Three Cities”)—covering 28 counties and over 90 townships. In 2024, the region had a permanent population of 7.6528 million and a regional GDP of CNY 383.086 billion, with an urbanization rate of 51.53%. The three cities in Southern Shaanxi boast superior ecological advantages, abundant mineral resources, and rich biodiversity, making them a key ecological functional zone of the Qinba Mountains and an important water conservation area for the South-to-North Water Diversion Middle Route Project. However, the economic scale of these three cities is relatively small, with limited industrial clusters and underdeveloped infrastructure. Innovation-driven support remains insufficient, and 23 counties are classified as restricted development zones (focusing on key ecological function areas). Most of these counties lie within the water conservation area of the South-to-North Water Diversion Middle Route Project, placing significant pressure on ecological protection. Additionally, some impoverished areas in the water source region achieved “poverty alleviation and removal of poverty” status by 2020, yet they continue to face weak economic foundations, difficulties in fiscal revenue growth, and constrained development space. The region also bears heavy pollution control responsibilities and struggles with the challenge of effectively linking the consolidation of poverty alleviation achievements with rural revitalization. Consequently, the conflict between water source protection and socioeconomic development has further intensified.
The Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) of the European Union, implemented since 1962, has been one of the bloc’s most significant policies. Initially, its objectives were to enhance agricultural labor productivity, stabilize agricultural markets, and ensure “fair” income for farmers. Over time, however, the CAP has evolved from a purely market-oriented policy to a more comprehensive approach that prioritizes ecological protection, social equity, and sustainable development. Its core goals now include strengthening agricultural competitiveness, achieving sustainable management of natural resources, and promoting balanced regional development. This transformation makes the CAP an ideal case study for exploring the synergistic mechanisms between ecological protection and rural poverty alleviation, as its policy design and implementation processes have carefully considered multiple objectives—economic, social, and environmental.
2.3.3. Data Source
The data used in this case study is sourced from the 2025 statistical yearbooks on economic and social development, public financial data, and “14th Five-Year” environmental protection plans for the three cities in South Shaanxi. Specific data on forestry compensation in Jinzhai County is sourced from the “13th Five-Year” Forestry Development Plan of Jinzhai County, including key indicators such as compensation standards (150 CNY/hectare) and funding proportions (accounting for 40–45% of poverty alleviation funds). Data on the protection of the South-to-North Water Transfer source water areas is integrated from the “Hanzhong Danjiang River Basin Water Quality Protection Regulations” of Shaanxi Province. The European Union’s Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) case directly references official reports from the European Commission, such as “Direct payments to agricultural producers—graphs and figures” and “Financial report of the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council on the European Agricultural Guarantee Fund.” These sources provide comprehensive and reliable data for the analysis of the synergistic effects of ecological compensation and poverty alleviation in Jinzhai County.
4. Discussion
This study provides compelling evidence of the significant synergistic potential between ecological compensation and targeted poverty alleviation within functional zones. This synergy stems from their inherent geographical coupling (the high overlap between ecologically fragile areas and poverty-prone regions) and complementary objectives (internalizing externalities to compensate for development rights losses, and capacity building to promote sustainable livelihoods). The following discussion aims to elaborate on the challenges of this study, its theoretical insights, and its limitations, while also offering recommendations for future research directions.
4.1. Institutional Paradoxes in Eco-Poverty Nexus
The synergistic potential between ecological compensation and poverty alleviation in key functional zones is fundamentally constrained by three institutional paradoxes. First, the “compensation disequilibrium syndrome” manifests in Jinzhai’s case, where forest conservation payments (580 USD/ha/year) lag 62% behind local opportunity costs (1500 USD/ha/year), creating a tripartite conflict between ecosystem valuation complexity (revealed vs. stated preferences), fiscal capacity limitations, and urgent livelihood demands. This structural imbalance induces perverse incentives (41% of monitored households reported reduced conservation effort) and poverty entrenchment (27% increase in multidimensional poverty indices). Second, the “dependency dilemma” in Southern Shaanxi reveals that 68% of poverty reduction gains derive from transfer payments rather than endogenous capacity building, risking welfare dependency (34.7% reduction in productive investments) and market competitiveness erosion. Third, the legal vacuum surrounding cross-jurisdictional compensation mechanisms—particularly benefit-sharing between upstream conservation zones (e.g., Jinzhai) and downstream beneficiaries (e.g., Hefei)—creates systemic governance fractures. The absence of standardized frameworks for compensation subjects (83% of cases), payment formulas (76% ad hoc determination), and accountability mechanisms (89% lacking third-party audits) perpetuates regional inequities and program fragility.
At a deeper level, these institutional paradoxes are rooted in and exacerbated by underlying governance failures, manifesting specifically as a “participation deficit” and an “accountability vacuum.” First, the “participation deficit” directly contributes to the structural imbalance in compensation standards (Paradox 1). Under the current top-down decision-making model, upstream residents—who bear the core responsibility for ecological protection—are often excluded from meaningful participation in negotiating and setting compensation standards. Their livelihood opportunity costs, local knowledge, and developmental demands are rarely fully incorporated into the evaluation system, resulting in compensation standards that reflect fiscal affordability rather than the true ecological contributions and sacrifices made. This deprivation of participatory rights is itself a manifestation of capability poverty, undermining the legitimacy and fairness of compensation policies from the outset and triggering perverse incentives or even resistance. Second, the “accountability vacuum” exacerbates the “welfare dependency” dilemma (Paradox 2) and entrenches the absence of legal frameworks (Paradox 3). On one hand, in the allocation and utilization of compensation funds, the lack of transparent, publicly monitorable accountability mechanisms leads to misallocation—either through fund diversion or egalitarian distribution—failing to target households most in need of capacity-building. Consequently, compensation devolves into short-term “welfare” rather than a long-term investment in development. On the other hand, the legal void in cross-regional compensation is essentially an institutional reflection of the political–economic power asymmetry between regions. When downstream developed regions, acting as “rational economic actors,” lack payment willingness, the absence of a higher-level, robust cross-jurisdictional governance mechanism to define responsibilities, enforce compliance, and impose penalties renders legal provisions mere “paper promises.” The case of Jinzhai County’s water supply to Hefei City epitomizes this lack of cross-regional accountability. Thus, without confronting these fundamental governance barriers, any institutional design confined to technical or economic adjustments will struggle to resolve the structural tensions between ecological protection and regional development.
4.2. Theoretical Implications: Enriching the Frameworks
This study operationalizes Sen’s capability approach within ecological poverty governance contexts, demonstrating that ecological compensation mechanisms—through economic opportunity creation (as evidenced in Shaanbei’s diversified livelihood programs) and public service enhancement (infrastructure investments in the Wudu case)—constitute effective pathways for multidimensional poverty alleviation. The research reveals a novel theoretical mechanism: the “ecological protection → opportunity cost accumulation → capability deprivation → poverty entrenchment → environmental degradation” vicious cycle, establishing critical intervention nodes (opportunity cost compensation, capability-building investments) to break this poverty–environment trap.
The findings advance SDG implementation frameworks by providing: (1) synergistic pathways integrating SDG1 (No Poverty), SDG2 (Zero Hunger), SDG6 (Clean Water), SDG13 (Climate Action), and SDG15 (Life on Land) through spatially explicit compensation designs; (2) a typology of compensation–investment portfolios demonstrating 23–37% greater poverty reduction efficacy when environmental safeguards are embedded in development planning (as quantified in Jinzhai’s agro-ecological transition); (3) institutional innovation pathways for reconciling biodiversity conservation with rural revitalization, contributing novel empirical evidence to the Global Environment Facility’s (GEF) Poverty–Environment Nexus framework.
4.3. Research Limitations and Future Directions
The study’s spatial scope exhibits inherent limitations. While focused on representative cases (Shaanbei, Jinzhai, Wudu) and international benchmarks (EU model), the generalizability of findings across China’s differentiated functional zones—particularly between prohibited development nature reserves and restricted development agricultural production bases—requires validation through multi-regional comparative studies.
While quantitative metrics (income increments, poverty reduction rates) are incorporated, the analysis demonstrates methodological gaps in micro-level econometric validation of synergistic mechanisms. Critical knowledge voids persist regarding (1) the cost–benefit ratios of alternative compensation modalities, (2) the causal pathways of capacity-building interventions, and (3) spatial–temporal variations in intervention efficacy. Future research could employ mixed-methods longitudinal panel data analyses combined with randomized control trials to enhance causal inference.
The discussion on institutional design, while conceptually significant, inadequately addresses meso-level governance complexities. Particularly underdeveloped are analyses of (1) power dynamics among stakeholders (local governments, enterprises, communities, and households), (2) institutional inertia in policy implementation, and (3) adaptive governance capacity in resource-dependent economies. Future studies should integrate political ecology perspectives with institutional analysis and development (IAD) frameworks to unpack these governance puzzles.
Future research could focus on innovating ecosystem service value monitoring and compensation mechanisms empowered by digital technology. For instance, blockchain technology, through smart contracts, can achieve full traceability and transparency of compensation fund flows. In Grain for Green projects, farmers’ ecological protection behaviors (e.g., tree survival rates, soil carbon sequestration) could be monitored in real time by IoT devices and uploaded to the blockchain, triggering automatic compensation payments and reducing administrative overhead [
13]. Concurrently, the construction of ecological compensation performance evaluation systems needs to integrate multidimensional poverty indicators, such as capability deprivation and social exclusion, to dynamically adjust compensation standards and methods [
27]. On the international level, China’s ecological compensation practices can align with the United Nations Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs), drawing on design experience from mechanisms like the Global Environment Facility (GEF) to explore frameworks for cross-border ecological compensation cooperation [
25]. Furthermore, it is necessary to improve horizontal compensation systems by promoting market-based compensation mechanisms between regions based on transactions like water resources and carbon sinks and integrating ecological compensation into the green “Belt and Road” initiative [
5]. Through technological and institutional synergy, ecological-compensation-based poverty alleviation is poised to contribute a Chinese solution to the global sustainable development agenda.