Gender Equality and Economic Diversification
Abstract
:1. Introduction
- First, gender gaps in opportunity, such as in education, harm diversification directly by constraining the potential pool of human capital. In particular, in countries where girls’ education lags that of boys, female human capital cannot accumulate optimally, therefore slowing down technology adoption and innovation (“human capital channel”).
- Second, gender gaps impede the development of new ideas indirectly by decreasing the efficiency of the labor force. Gender gaps in labor force participation shrink the pool of talent from which employers can hire and limit the number of female entrepreneurs (Cuberes and Teignier 2016; Esteve-Volart 2004; Christiansen et al. 2016a, 2016b). This limitation, in turn, impedes a country’s ability to create and execute ideas, i.e., to diversify (“resource allocation channel”).
- First, we present empirical evidence that gender inequality is negatively associated with both output and export diversification in low-income and developing economies. The effect of gender inequality on economic diversification comes on top of the effect of the standard drivers of diversification identified in the literature. While the negative effects of gender inequality and the positive effects of diversification on economic growth have found support in these two separate literatures, to our knowledge, the connection between them has not yet been established.
- Second, our results suggest that both inequality of opportunities and lower female labor force participation are associated with lower economic diversification. These findings support our two main hypotheses. The negative relationship between inequality of opportunity and diversification supports the hypothesis of the human capital channel, while the association between female labor force participation and diversification supports the premise of the resource allocation channel, which reduces the creation of ideas and development of sectors.
- Third, we provide evidence on causality. Gender inequality and diversification are interlinked phenomena and, as described in more detail in Section 2, the literature so far has mainly focused on how structural transformation coincides with episodes of improvements in gender equality (Akbulut 2011; Olivetti and Petrongolo 2014; Ngai and Petrongolo 2017; Rendall 2013). The novel aspect of our study is to examine whether gender inequality affects diversification and to address endogeneity concerns in our regressions.
2. Literature Review
- Despite significant cross-country heterogeneity, greater diversification has been associated with improved macroeconomic performance: higher growth, reduced volatility, and increased resilience to external shocks (Koren and Tenreyro 2007; Cadot et al. 2011). Singer (1950) demonstrated that a country’s initial level of diversification is positively correlated with economic growth. Using an Instrumental Variable Bayesian Model Averaging approach to move beyond correlations, IMF (2014a) finds that for low-income countries, extensive diversification (introducing new product lines), intensive diversification (creating a more balanced mix of existing products), and the broader process of output diversification are indeed drivers of economic growth. Diversification also involves shifting resources from sectors with high volatility, such as mining and agriculture, to sectors with less volatility, such as manufacturing, resulting in greater stability. Countries with more diversified production structures tend to have lower volatility of output, consumption, and investment (Moore and Walkes 2010; Mobarak 2005).
- There is a non-linear relationship between diversification and development (Imbs and Wacziarg 2003). As countries develop, they diversify until they reach a critical point. Beyond this point, they start specializing in low-volatility sectors (Imbs and Wacziarg 2003; Koren and Tenreyro 2007; Cadot et al. 2011).
- Education. Studies have confirmed the negative effect of gender inequality in education on growth (Hill and King 1995; Engelbrecht 1997; Forbes 2000; Dollar and Gatti 1999; Klasen 1999; Knowles et al. 2002; Klasen and Lamanna 2009; Seguino 2010). Dollar and Gatti (1999) find that gender inequality in education negatively impacts growth in countries where female educational attainment is high. Klasen (1999) demonstrates that the negative effect is present in all economies.2 Berge and Wood (1994) provide support for the hypothesis that an educated female labor force is a determinant of manufacturing exports growth. Using broader measures of gender inequality going beyond education gaps, a recent study by Amin et al. (2015) confirms their strong negative impact on economic growth but only in poor countries.
- Occupation. Occupational choice models are based on the assumption that men and women have the same distribution of talent (Cuberes and Teignier 2012; Esteve-Volart 2004). Gender gaps in entrepreneurship distort the efficient allocation of talent (Cuberes and Teignier 2012). As a certain percentage of women are prevented from becoming entrepreneurs, they are forced to work as employees, thus increasing the supply of labor. As a result, equilibrium wages and aggregate productivity fall. Gender gaps in labor force participation are modeled as preventing a fraction of women from supplying labor to the market, hence decreasing income per capita. Cuberes and Teignier (2016) present an updated version of the model in which women also have the choice to become self-employed, in addition to being entrepreneurs and workers. In this version of the model, women face two additional exogenous restrictions: only a fraction can become self-employed, and those who become workers receive lower wages than men do. The main results are not qualitatively different. Esteve-Volart (2004) makes explicit the negative endogenous effect of gender gaps in education on growth: the suboptimal allocation of managerial talent explicitly leads to lower female human capital accumulation and thus, slower technology adoption and innovation, which reduces aggregate output and obstructs economic growth. The negative effects of gender discrimination in managerial talent allocation are more serious for sectors where high-level skills are needed, such as the non-agricultural sector, whereas restricted female labor force participation in general impacts all sectors, including agriculture. Finally, using a model of endogenous savings, fertility, and labor market participation, Cavalcanti and Tavares (2016) show that an increase of 50 percent in the gender wage gap could lead to a decrease in income per capita by 35 percent.
- Aggregate measures of gender inequality and growth. Recent empirical evidence, using an extended version of the UN’s Gender Inequality Index (GII), shows that several dimensions of gender inequality (health, empowerment, education attainment, and labor force participation) are strongly associated with lower growth, in particular in low-income countries (Gonzales et al. 2015b; Hakura et al. 2016). Box 1 in Section 3 describes the GII in more detail.
- Gender wage inequality has had a positive effect on export-led growth in semi-industrialized export-oriented economies, while it has had a negative effect in low-income agricultural countries (Seguino 2000, 2010). On the other hand, accounting for the different productivity of male and female workers, Schober and Winter-Ebmer (2011) do not find support for the hypothesis that increased gender inequality contributes to growth, but argue that it may indeed hamper it.
3. Empirical Strategy
- represents the measure of either export or output diversification as defined in Box 1 for country i at time t.
- The main contribution of our paper is to test whether gender inequality exerts a significant effect on diversification. tests for this effect at two levels: first, to account for the combined effect of several dimensions of gender inequality, we use the extended version of the United Nations Gender Inequality Index, i.e., a combination of gaps in labor force participation, education, and reproductive health, as well as female seats in parliaments as described in Box 1. In a second step, to test for the effect of individual measures of gender inequality, the index is replaced by the female-to-male gross enrollment ratio in secondary school, the female labor force participation rate, the share of female seats in parliament, the adolescent fertility rate, and the risk of maternal death. As the relationship between diversification and gender inequality may vary across levels of development, we include a low-income and developing country interaction term () in our main regressions.
- may significantly impact a country’s ability to diversify. We therefore include real GDP per capita and its square in the regression to account for the overall level of development, as well as the turning point after which countries re-concentrate their export or output structure (IMF 2014b; Dabla-Norris et al. 2013). The baseline regressions also include population size to capture the pool of workers potentially able to produce different products in a country, along with an index of human capital to account for a country’s ability to generate and implement new ideas. In addition, we test whether being resource-rich exhibits a negative effect on diversification by introducing the share of mining in GDP or the share of fuel exports into the regressions.
- shape the environment in which businesses operate and the ease of entering a market to implement an idea or to produce a new product. To account for this impact, our regressions use both general institutional quality (e.g., Frasier Institute Summary Index), as well as specific dimensions of the regulatory environment (e.g., legal systems and property rights).
- may boost or compress a certain sector in the short term, therefore impacting diversification over time. We therefore introduce macroeconomic variables, such as terms-of-trade, real effective exchange rates, and real GDP growth into our regressions.
- may foster economic diversification. Here, we test for several policy dimensions, such as more openness to trade (through an index of globalization, the degree of freedom to trade internationally, and average tariff rates), financial development (an index of financial reform, and interest rate controls and private sector credit-to-GDP as robustness checks), the scale of investment in the economy (investment in percent of GDP and per worker), and infrastructure development (density of landlines and length of road network).
- To capture other factors over time and by country, we includethat is country fixed effects and time fixed effects into our baseline regressions. represents the error term.
4. Results: Gender Inequality Impedes Diversification
- Gender inequality, as measured by the extended version of the UN’s Gender Inequality Index, is strongly associated with export diversification, in line with our hypothesis. In particular, moving from a situation of absolute gender inequality to perfect gender equality measured by the index could decrease the Theil index of export diversification, i.e., increase export diversification in low-income and developing countries, by 0.6 to 2 units. The magnitude of this effect is equivalent to up to about two standard deviations of the index across low-income and developing countries. Looking beyond low-income and developing countries, the results show that higher levels of gender inequality are significantly associated with lower levels of export diversification across all levels of development.
- The effect of gender inequality comes on top of structural characteristics previously highlighted in the literature. Our results confirm the U-shaped relationship between export diversification and development (Dabla-Norris et al. 2013) in which countries diversify until they reach a certain level of development but re-concentrate afterwards. As expected, a higher share of mining in output is associated with a less diversified export base. In line with a larger pool of talent, population size (in most of our specifications) and human capital (in some specifications) are associated with higher export diversification.
- The impact of gender inequality remains when controlling for policies associated with export diversification. In particular, we show that institutions—creating a better business environment, e.g., as measured by the Frasier Summary Index of Institutions or legal systems and property rights—are significantly and positively associated with higher levels of diversification. A higher degree of openness in international trade expands the possible pool of trading partners and demand for exports, and our results confirm a positive and significant relationship with export diversification. Better infrastructure is also strongly associated with higher degrees of export diversification.
- Finally, macroeconomic factors also appear to play a role. Real exchange rate appreciation and terms-of-trade improvement are associated with lower degrees of export diversification, possibly reflecting the effect of lower price competitiveness in the short term and higher quantities of exports of main sectors when their prices are high.5
5. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Summary Statistics
Full Sample | LIDC | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variable | Source | Obs | Mean | Std. Dev. | Min | Max | Obs | Mean | Std. Dev. | Min | Max |
Export Diversification Theil | IMF Diversification Toolkit | 6378 | 3.5 | 1.2 | 1.0 | 6.4 | 2159 | 4.2 | 0.9 | 1.8 | 6.4 |
Output Diversification Theil | IMF Diversification Toolkit | 7065 | 0.3 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 1.7 | 2259 | 0.3 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 1.6 |
Log(GDP per capita) | World Economic Outlook | 6141 | 8.5 | 1.2 | 5.2 | 11.7 | 1910 | 7.2 | 0.5 | 5.2 | 8.8 |
Log(Population) | PWT 8.1 | 6141 | 1.7 | 1.9 | −3.2 | 7.2 | 1910 | 1.8 | 1.4 | −2.6 | 5.1 |
Human capital index (5-year lag) | PWT 8.1/ Barro Lee | 4385 | 2.1 | 0.6 | 1.0 | 3.6 | 1289 | 1.6 | 0.4 | 1.0 | 2.9 |
Mining as share of GDP | IMF Jobs and Income Surveillance toolkit | 4831 | 21.0 | 11.6 | 0.8 | 85.6 | 1865 | 17.7 | 11.6 | 0.8 | 75.9 |
GII Index | IMF GDI GII database | 2580 | 0.5 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 0.8 | 774 | 0.6 | 0.1 | 0.3 | 0.8 |
Ratio of female tertiary teachers | WDI | 2105 | 0.3 | 0.1 | 0.0 | 0.8 | 521 | 0.2 | 0.1 | 0.0 | 0.8 |
Unmarried women; equal property rights | Women, Business, and the Law | 3707 | 0.9 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1470 | 0.9 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Married women; equal property rights | Women, Business, and the Law | 3688 | 0.8 | 0.4 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1431 | 0.7 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Married women; head household | Women, Business, and the Law | 3723 | 0.6 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1466 | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Married women; legal proceedings | Women, Business, and the Law | 3763 | 0.9 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1506 | 0.8 | 0.4 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Married women; bank account | Women, Business, and the Law | 3742 | 0.9 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1490 | 0.8 | 0.4 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Equal inheritance, sons and daughters | Women, Business, and the Law | 3688 | 0.7 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1431 | 0.6 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Joint titling of property | Women, Business, and the Law | 3582 | 0.4 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1354 | 0.4 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Full community marital property regime | Women, Business, and the Law | 3589 | 0.1 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1351 | 0.0 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Partial community marital property regime | Women, Business, and the Law | 3589 | 0.4 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1351 | 0.3 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Separate property marital property regime | Women, Business, and the Law | 3589 | 0.4 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1351 | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Guaranteed equity | Women, Business, and the Law | 3734 | 0.9 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1501 | 0.9 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Nondiscrimination clause | Women, Business, and the Law | 3734 | 0.4 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1501 | 0.4 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Valid customary law | Women, Business, and the Law | 3734 | 0.3 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 1501 | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Female labor force participation rate | WDI | 3591 | 0.5 | 0.2 | 0.1 | 0.9 | 1197 | 0.6 | 0.2 | 0.1 | 0.9 |
Secondary enrollment ratio | WDI | 4371 | 0.9 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 3.1 | 1230 | 0.7 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 2.1 |
Women in parliament | WDI | 2425 | 14.1 | 9.9 | 0.0 | 56.3 | 753 | 12.0 | 9.1 | 0.0 | 56.3 |
Maternal mortality ratio | WDI | 3591 | 272.0 | 374.7 | 3.0 | 2900.0 | 1218 | 623.4 | 422.8 | 29.0 | 2900.0 |
Adolescent fertility rate | WDI | 3696 | 65.0 | 49.3 | 3.1 | 228.6 | 1218 | 106.6 | 48.3 | 18.0 | 222.4 |
Fraser Institute Summary Index | Fraser Institute | 3655 | 5.9 | 1.4 | 2.0 | 9.2 | 1100 | 5.1 | 1.1 | 2.0 | 7.5 |
Legal system and property rights | Fraser Institute | 3509 | 5.3 | 1.9 | 1.1 | 9.6 | 989 | 4.0 | 1.1 | 1.6 | 6.8 |
Freedom to trade | Fraser Institute | 3820 | 5.8 | 2.4 | 0.0 | 10.0 | 1215 | 4.3 | 2.1 | 0.0 | 8.8 |
Globalization index | KOF Index of Globalization | 4451 | 46.3 | 19.2 | 9.6 | 92.9 | 1728 | 31.4 | 10.2 | 9.6 | 63.1 |
Length of road network | Calderon-Serven database | 3755 | −1.2 | 1.4 | −5.2 | 1.6 | 1043 | −2.0 | 1.4 | −5.2 | 0.0 |
Log(Landlines per 1000 workers) | Calderon-Serven database | 3765 | 3.7 | 2.0 | −0.6 | 7.2 | 1043 | 1.8 | 1.1 | −0.6 | 5.2 |
Terms of Trade | World Economic Outlook | 4334 | 109.7 | 48.7 | 5.5 | 602.9 | 1477 | 124.5 | 69.5 | 5.5 | 602.9 |
Log(REER) | IFS | 3350 | 4.7 | 0.7 | 0.7 | 15.3 | 1171 | 4.9 | 1.0 | 0.7 | 15.3 |
Average Tariff Rates | Trade Index | 3194 | 0.7 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 999 | 0.7 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Investment per worker | PWT | 4012 | 4589.1 | 5361.8 | −832.1 | 46,086.0 | 1500 | 537.9 | 555.2 | −832.1 | 5207.6 |
Financial reform index | IMF Index of Financial reform | 2527 | 0.5 | 0.3 | 0.0 | 1.0 | 558 | 0.3 | 0.2 | 0.0 | 0.9 |
Gini index | WDI | 1035 | 40.7 | 10.3 | 16.2 | 99.9 | 233 | 43.0 | 9.1 | 25.9 | 69.5 |
Income ratio (top 20%/bottom 20%) | WDI | 1034 | 10.5 | 11.6 | 2.2 | 278.2 | 233 | 12.6 | 20.0 | 3.7 | 278.2 |
Agriculture, value added (% of GDP) | WDI | 5099 | 19.0 | 15.5 | 0.0 | 74.3 | 1806 | 33.5 | 13.6 | 3.1 | 74.3 |
Rural population | WDI | 7044 | 50.9 | 24.8 | 0.0 | 97.2 | 2259 | 71.3 | 14.8 | 23.0 | 97.2 |
Fuel exports | WDI | 4516 | 16.2 | 29.1 | 0.0 | 359.3 | 1025 | 13.2 | 30.1 | 0.0 | 359.3 |
Domestic credit to private sector | WDI | 5731 | 37.8 | 35.8 | 0.1 | 312.2 | 1781 | 15.3 | 11.5 | 0.2 | 114.7 |
Real GDP per capita growth rate | World Economic Outlook | 5981 | 0.0 | 0.1 | −1.1 | 1.0 | 1861 | 0.0 | 0.1 | −0.7 | 0.7 |
Appendix B. Country Sample
Appendix B.1. Non-LIDC Countries
Appendix B.2. LIDC Countries
References
- Agénor, Pierre-Richard, Otaviano Canuto, and Luiz Pereira da Silva. 2014. On Gender and Growth: The Role of Intergenerational Health Externalities and Women’s Occupational Constraints. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 30: 132–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. 2006. Joseph Schumpeter Lecture—Appropriate Growth Policy: A Unifying Framework. Journal of the European Economic Association 4: 269–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Akbulut, Rahşan. 2011. Sectoral Changes and the Increase in Women’s Labor Force Participation. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15: 240–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alesina, Alberto, Paola Giuliano, and Nathan Nunn. 2013. On the Origins of Gender Roles: Women and the Plough. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 128: 469–530. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Amin, Mohammad, and Asif Islam. 2014. Are There More Female Managers in the Retail Sector? Evidence from Survey Data in Developing Countries. Journal of Applied Economics 17: 213–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Amin, Mohammad, Veselin Kuntchev, and Martin Schmidt. 2015. Gender Inequality and Growth: The Case of Rich vs. Poor Countries. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 7172. Washington, DC: World Bank. [Google Scholar]
- Bal-Gunduz, Yasemin, Era Dabla-Norris, and Carla Intal. 2015. What Drives Economic Diversification? International Monetary Fund Working Paper. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Bandiera, Oriana, and Ashwini Natraj. 2013. Does Gender Inequality Hinder Development and Economic Growth? Evidence and Policy Implications. The World Bank Research Observer 28: 2–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barro, Robert J., and Jong-Wha Lee. 1994. Sources of Economic Growth. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 40: 1–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barro, Robert. J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1995. Economic Growth. New York: McGraw Hill. [Google Scholar]
- Berge, Kersti, and Adrian Wood. 1994. Does Educating Girls Improve Export Opportunities? Institute of Development Studies Working Paper. Brighton: Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex. [Google Scholar]
- Cadot, Olivier, Céline Carrère, and Vanessa Strauss-Kahn. 2011. Export Diversification: What’s Behind the Hump? Review of Economics and Statistics 93: 590–605. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Çağatay, Nilüfer, Diane Elson, and Caren Grown. 1995. Introduction. In World Development. Geneva: International Labour Organization, pp. 1827–36. [Google Scholar]
- Cavalcanti, Tiago, and José Tavares. 2008. The Output Cost of Gender Discrimination: A Model-Based Macroeconomic Estimate. Paper presented at German Development Economics Conference, Zürich, Switzerland, March 17–19. [Google Scholar]
- Cavalcanti, Tiago, and José Tavares. 2016. The Output Cost of Gender Discrimination: A Model Based Macroeconomic Estimate. The Economic Journal 126: 109–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Christiansen, Lone, Huidan Lin, Joana Pereira, Petia Topalova, Rima Turk, and Petya Koeva Brooks. 2016a. Unlocking Female Employment Potential in Europe. Drivers and Benefits. International Monetary Fund European Department and Strategy, Policy, Review Department Departmental Paper. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Christiansen, Lone, Huidan Lin, Joana Pereira, Petia Topalova, and Rima Turk. 2016b. Gender Diversity in Senior Positions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Europe. International Monetary Fund Working Paper 16/50. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Cuberes, David, and Marc Teignier. 2012. Gender Gaps in the Labor Market and Aggregate Productivity. Sheffield Economic Research Paper SERP 2012017. Sheffield: University of Sheffield. [Google Scholar]
- Cuberes, David, and Marc Teignier. 2014. Gender Inequality and Economic Growth: A Critical Review. Journal of International Development 26: 260–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cuberes, David, and Marc Teignier. 2016. Aggregate Effects of Gender Gaps in the Labor Market: A Quantitative Estimate. Journal of Human Capital 10: 1–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dabla-Norris, Era, Alun Thomas, Rodrigo Garcia-Verdu, and Yingyuan Chen. 2013. Benchmarking Structural Transformation across the World. International Monetary Fund Working Paper 13/176. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Deere, Carmen Diana, Abena D. Oduro, Hema Swaminathan, and Cheryl Doss. 2013. Property Rights and the Gender Distribution of Wealth in Ecuador, Ghana and India. Journal of Economic Inequality 11: 249–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli, Leora Klapper, and Dorothe Singer. 2013. Financial Inclusion and Legal Discrimination against Women: Evidence from Developing Countries. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 6416. Washington, DC: World Bank. [Google Scholar]
- Doepke, Matthias, and Michele Tertilt. 2009. Women’s Liberation: What’s in it for Men? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124: 1541–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dollar, David, and Roberta Gatti. 1999. Gender Inequality, Income, and Growth: Are Good Times Good for Women? Washington, DC: The World Bank Development Research Group, vol. 1. [Google Scholar]
- Duflo, Esther. 2012. Women Empowerment and Economic Development. Journal of Economic Literature 50: 1051–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Elborgh-Woytek, Katrin, Monique Newiak, Kalpana Kochhar, Stefania Fabrizio, Kangni Kpodar, Philippe Wingender, Benedict Clements, and Gerd Schwartz. 2013. Women, Work, and the Economy: Macroeconomic Gains from Gender Equity. International Monetary Fund Staff Discussion Note SDN/13/10. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Engelbrecht, Hans-Jürgen. 1997. International R&D Spillovers, Human Capital and Productivity in OECD Economies: An Empirical Investigation. European Economic Review 41: 1479–88. [Google Scholar]
- Esteve-Volart, Berta. 2004. Gender Discrimination and Growth: Theory and Evidence from India. DEDPS 42. London: London School of Economics. [Google Scholar]
- Fernandez, Raquel. 2007. Alfred Marshall Lecture: Women, Work, and Culture. Journal of the European Economic Association 5: 305–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Forbes, Kristin J. 2000. A Reassessment of the Relationship between Inequality and Growth. American Economic Review 90: 869–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Galor, Oded, and David N. Weil. 1996. The Gender Gap, Fertility, and Growth. American Economic Review 85: 374–87. [Google Scholar]
- Goldin, Claudia. 1994. The U-Shaped Female Labor Force Function in Economic Development and Economic History. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 4707. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
- Gonzales, Christian, Sonali Jain-Chandra, Kalpana Kochhar, and Monique Newiak. 2015a. Fair Play: More Equal Laws Boost Female Labor Force Participation. International Monetary Fund Staff Discussion Note 15/02. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Gonzales, Christian, Sonali Jain-Chandra, Kalpana Kochhar, Monique Newiak, and Tlek Zeinullayev. 2015b. Catalyst for Change: Empowering Women and Tackling Income Inequality. International Monetary Fund Staff Discussion Note 15/20. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Hakura, Dalia, Mumtaz Hussain, Monique Newiak, Vimal Thakoor, and Fan Yang. 2016. Inequality, Gender Gaps and Economic Growth: Comparative Evidence for Sub-Saharan Africa. International Monetary Fund Working Paper 16/111. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Hill, M. Anne, and Elizabeth King. 1995. Women’s Education and Economic Well-being. Feminist Economics 1: 21–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Imbs, Jean, and Romain Wacziarg. 2003. Stages of Diversification. American Economic Review 93: 63–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- IMF. 2014a. Sustaining Long-Run Growth and Macro Stability in Low-income Countries: The Role of Structural Transformation and Diversification—Background Notes. International Monetary Fund Policy Paper. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- IMF. 2014b. Sustaining Long-Run Growth and Macroeconomic Stability in Low-Income Countries—The Role of Structural Transformation and Diversification, International Monetary Fund Policy Paper. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
- IMF. 2016. Time for a Policy Reset. In Regional Economic Outlook: Sub-Saharan Africa, April 2016. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Klasen, Stephan. 1999. Does Gender Inequality Reduce Growth and Development? Evidence from Cross-Country Regressions. World Bank Policy Research Report Background Paper No. 7. Washington, DC: World Bank. [Google Scholar]
- Klasen, Stephan, and Francesca Lamanna. 2009. The Impact of Gender Inequality in Education and Employment on Economic Growth: New Evidence for a Panel of Countries. Feminist Economics 15: 91–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Knowles, Stephen, Paula K. Lorgelly, and P. Dorian Owen. 2002. Are Educational Gender Gaps a Brake on Economic Development? Some Cross-country Empirical Evidence. Oxford Economic Papers 54: 118–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Koren, Miklós, and Silvana Tenreyro. 2007. Volatility and Development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 122: 243–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lagerlöf, Nils-Petter. 2003. Gender equality and long-run growth. Journal of Economic Growth 8: 403–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lorgelly, Paula K., and P. Dorian Owen. 1999. The effect of female and male schooling on economic growth in the Barro-Lee model. Empirical Economics 24: 537–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mobarak, Ahmed Mushfiq. 2005. Democracy, Volatility, and Economic Development. Review of Economics and Statistics 87: 348–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Moore, Winston, and Carlon Walkes. 2010. Does Industrial Concentration Impact on the Relationship between Policies and Volatility? International Review of Applied Economics 24: 179–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ngai, L. Rachel, and Barbara Petrongolo. 2017. Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 9: 1–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Olivetti, Claudia, and Barbara Petrongolo. 2014. Gender Gaps across Countries and Skills: Demand, Supply and the Industry Structure. Review of Economic Dynamics 17: 842–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Papageorgiou, Chris, and Nikola Spatafora. 2012. Economic Diversification in LICs: Stylized Facts and Macroeconomic Implications. International Monetary Fund Staff Discussion Note 12/13. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Quisumbing, Agnes. R., and Lauren Pandolfelli. 2010. Promising Approaches to Address the Needs of Poor Female Farmers: Resources, Constraints, and Interventions. World Development 38: 581–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Razavi, Shahra. 2003. Introduction: Agrarian Change, Gender and Land Rights. Journal of Agrarian Change 3: 2–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rendall, Michelle. 2013. Structural Change in Developing Countries: Has It Decreased Gender Inequality? World Development 45: 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schober, Thomas, and Rudolf Winter-Ebmer. 2011. Gender Wage Inequality and Economic Growth: Is There Really a Puzzle?—A Comment. World Development 39: 1476–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Seguino, Stephanie. 2000. Gender Inequality and Economic Growth: A Cross Country Analysis. World Development 28: 1211–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Seguino, Stephanie. 2010. Gender, Distribution and Balance of Payments Constrained Growth in Developing Countries. Review of Political Economy 22: 373–404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Singer, Hans W. 1950. US Foreign Investment in Underdeveloped Areas: The Distribution of Gains between Investing and Borrowing Countries. American Economic Review 40: 473–85. [Google Scholar]
- Stotsky, Janet G. 2006. Gender and Its Relevance to Macroeconomic Policy: A Survey. International Monetary Fund Working Paper. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Stotsky, Janet G., Sakina Shibuya, Lisa Kolovich, and Suhaib Kebhaj. 2016. Trends in Gender Equality and Women’s Advancement. International Monetary Fund Working Paper 16/21. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Svirydzenka, Katsiaryna, and Martin Petri. 2014. Mauritius: The Drivers of Growth—Can the Past be Extended? International Monetary Fund Working Paper 14/134. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Tzannatos, Zafiris. 1999. Women and Labor Market Changes in the Global Economy: Growth Helps, Inequalities Hurt and Public Policy Matters. World Development 27: 551–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- World Bank. 2012. World Development Report: Gender Equality and Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. [Google Scholar]
- World Bank, International Finance Corporation (IFC). 2013. Women, Business, and the Law 2014. Removing Restrictions to Enhance Gender Equality. Washington, DC: World Bank and IFC. [Google Scholar]
- World Bank Group. 2015. Women, Business and the Law 2016: Getting to Equal. Washington, DC: World Bank. [Google Scholar]
1 | The process of structural transformation is characterized by two dimensions: horizontal (across sectors) and vertical (within a sector). Diversification into new higher value-added sectors is the horizontal dimension. Quality upgrading is the vertical dimension and focuses on producing higher quality (and generally higher priced) products within existing sectors (IMF 2014). |
2 | Earlier studies have shown somewhat different results: Barro and Lee (1994) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) find that female secondary education has a negative impact on growth, as low female educational attainment signifies “backwardness” and hence higher growth potential. Klasen (1999) and Lorgelly and Owen (1999), however, suggest that the finding may reflect multicollinearity problems resulting from the inclusion of both female and male education variables in the regression analysis and the disproportionate influence of a few outlier countries. |
3 | See Bandiera and Natraj (2013) for a discussion of panel regressions and the endogenous relationship between gender inequality and growth. |
4 | All regressions are estimated using heteroskedasticity-robust Huber-White standard errors. |
5 | The results hold when real GDP per capita growth is used as an alternative to capture cyclical components. Several measures of income inequality were included in the regressions but did not yield significant results. |
Explanatory Variables: | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Gender Inequality | |||||||||
Gender Inequality Index | 0.703 ** | 0.752 *** | 0.776 *** | 1.156 *** | 1.141 *** | 1.381 *** | 1.078 *** | 0.983 *** | 0.665 ** |
(0.273) | (0.278) | (0.277) | (0.319) | (0.284) | (0.282) | (0.294) | (0.298) | (0.264) | |
-- in LIDC | 1.014 ** | 0.983 ** | 1.113 ** | 0.338 | 0.880 ** | 0.120 | 0.274 | 0.538 | 0.630 |
(0.431) | (0.438) | (0.435) | (0.457) | (0.432) | (0.440) | (0.405) | (0.417) | (0.426) | |
Structural Factors | |||||||||
Log(Population) | −0.707 *** | −0.560 *** | −0.568 *** | −1.059 *** | −0.434 *** | −0.222 | −0.682 *** | −0.450 *** | −0.101 |
(0.133) | (0.135) | (0.136) | (0.156) | (0.146) | (0.145) | (0.138) | (0.148) | (0.147) | |
Lag Human capital index | 0.0460 | 0.0406 | 0.0743 | −0.112 | −0.0729 | 0.0309 | −0.286 ** | −0.285 ** | 0.0887 |
(0.109) | (0.110) | (0.110) | (0.127) | (0.111) | (0.111) | (0.116) | (0.118) | (0.103) | |
Log(Real GDP per capita) | −1.838 *** | −2.371 *** | −1.712 *** | −0.215 | −1.736 *** | −0.970 *** | −1.166 *** | −1.750 *** | −0.971 *** |
(0.294) | (0.289) | (0.308) | (0.310) | (0.297) | (0.311) | (0.296) | (0.301) | (0.328) | |
-- squared | 0.114 *** | 0.140 *** | 0.103 *** | 0.0245 | 0.108 *** | 0.0605 *** | 0.0704 *** | 0.112 *** | 0.0516 *** |
(0.0174) | (0.0172) | (0.0182) | (0.0190) | (0.0179) | (0.0188) | (0.0178) | (0.0182) | (0.0191) | |
Mining as share of GDP | 0.00937 ** | 0.00694 * | 0.0119 *** | 0.0253 *** | 0.00694 * | 0.0119 *** | 0.0221 *** | 0.0266 *** | 0.0236 *** |
(0.00396) | (0.00398) | (0.00416) | (0.00377) | (0.00407) | (0.00407) | (0.00392) | (0.00407) | (0.00472) | |
Policies | |||||||||
1. Institutions | |||||||||
Fraser Institute Sum. Index | −0.116 *** | −0.0700 *** | |||||||
(0.0137) | (0.0178) | ||||||||
Legal Syst.& Property Rights | −0.0358 *** | ||||||||
(0.0102) | |||||||||
2. Openness | |||||||||
Freedom to trade | −0.0646 *** | −0.0219 * | |||||||
(0.00858) | (0.0114) | ||||||||
Globalization Index | −0.0123 *** | ||||||||
(0.00268) | |||||||||
3. Infrastructure | |||||||||
Length of road network | −0.0300 ** | ||||||||
(0.0144) | |||||||||
Log(landlines/1000 workers) | −0.129 *** | −0.110 *** | |||||||
(0.0177) | (0.0180) | ||||||||
Macro/Cyclical Factors | |||||||||
Terms of Trade | 0.00313 *** | 0.00427 *** | |||||||
(0.000347) | (0.000440) | ||||||||
Log(REER) | 0.186 *** | 0.305 *** | |||||||
(0.0519) | (0.0490) | ||||||||
Constant | 11.90 *** | 13.69 *** | 10.78 *** | 5.434 *** | 10.21 *** | 6.928 *** | 8.737 *** | 9.483 *** | 5.712 *** |
(1.201) | (1.209) | (1.273) | (1.209) | (1.232) | (1.284) | (1.223) | (1.263) | (1.436) | |
Observations | 1841 | 1835 | 1836 | 1798 | 1726 | 1726 | 1903 | 1909 | 1583 |
Countries | 100 | 100 | 100 | 105 | 89 | 89 | 100 | 102 | 84 |
R-squared | 0.181 | 0.141 | 0.174 | 0.108 | 0.110 | 0.136 | 0.127 | 0.118 | 0.271 |
Explanatory Variables: | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Gender Inequality | |||||||||
Gender Inequality Index | −0.0552 * | −0.0344 | −0.0867 ** | −0.1000 *** | 0.0283 | 0.0397 | −0.0103 | −0.0932 ** | 0.0404 |
(0.0310) | (0.0315) | (0.0425) | (0.0369) | (0.0305) | (0.0307) | (0.0398) | (0.0369) | (0.0393) | |
-- in LIDC | 0.188 *** | 0.203 *** | 0.212 *** | 0.310 *** | 0.194 *** | 0.158 *** | 0.302 *** | 0.190 ** | 0.268 ** |
−0.0488 | (0.0495) | (0.0709) | (0.0527) | (0.0462) | (0.0476) | (0.0629) | (0.0794) | (0.119) | |
Structural Factors | |||||||||
Log(Population) | −0.0376 ** | −0.0318 ** | −0.0352 | −0.0524 *** | −0.0309 ** | −0.0269 * | −0.0568 *** | −0.0466 ** | −0.0424 * |
(0.0150) | (0.0154) | (0.0224) | (0.0179) | (0.0157) | (0.0158) | (0.0196) | (0.0221) | (0.0240) | |
Lag Human capital index | 0.0350 *** | 0.0346 *** | 0.0271 | 0.0376 *** | 0.0219 * | 0.0281 ** | 0.0254 * | 0.0509 *** | 0.0320 ** |
(0.0121) | (0.0122) | (0.0171) | (0.0145) | (0.0120) | (0.0121) | (0.0154) | (0.0153) | (0.0152) | |
Log(Real GDP per capita) | −0.215 *** | −0.238 *** | −0.225 *** | −0.233 *** | −0.221 *** | −0.192 *** | −0.340 *** | −0.132 ** | −0.208 *** |
(0.0336) | (0.0353) | (0.0431) | (0.0360) | (0.0319) | (0.0339) | (0.0407) | (0.0543) | (0.0707) | |
-- squared | 0.0103 *** | 0.0112 *** | 0.0108 *** | 0.0107 *** | 0.00985 *** | 0.00809 *** | 0.0179 *** | 0.00578 * | 0.0121 *** |
(0.00199) | (0.00209) | (0.00262) | (0.00220) | (0.00192) | (0.00205) | (0.00254) | (0.00302) | (0.00398) | |
Mining as share of GDP | 0.000214 | 0.000283 | −0.00216 *** | −0.000943 ** | 0.00355 *** | 0.00381 *** | −0.000152 | −0.00367 *** | −0.00519 *** |
(0.000449) | (0.000474) | (0.000583) | (0.000430) | (0.000427) | (0.000434) | (0.000461) | (0.000638) | (0.000741) | |
Policies | |||||||||
1. Institutions | |||||||||
Fraser Institute Sum. Index | −0.00961 *** | −0.00816 *** | |||||||
(0.00155) | (0.00191) | ||||||||
2. Openness | |||||||||
Freedom to trade | −0.00224 ** | ||||||||
(0.000976) | |||||||||
Average Tariff Rates | 0.0290 *** | 0.0647 *** | |||||||
(0.0108) | (0.0111) | ||||||||
Globalization Index | −0.00105 *** | ||||||||
(0.000307) | |||||||||
3. Infrastructure/Investment | |||||||||
Length of road network | −0.00464 *** | ||||||||
(0.00153) | |||||||||
Log(Landlines/1000 workers) | −0.00716 *** | −0.00452 * | |||||||
(0.00193) | (0.00234) | ||||||||
Investment per worker | −3.79 × 10−6 *** | −5.94 × 10−6 *** | |||||||
(7.98 × 10−7) | (7.84 × 10−7) | ||||||||
4. Financial Development | |||||||||
Financial reform index | −0.0760 *** | −0.0293 ** | |||||||
(0.0126) | (0.0128) | ||||||||
Constant | 1.386 *** | 1.440 *** | 1.435 *** | 1.550 *** | 1.325 *** | 1.221 *** | 1.895 *** | 1.101 *** | 1.322 *** |
(0.137) | (0.146) | (0.174) | (0.141) | (0.132) | (0.140) | (0.170) | (0.232) | (0.307) | |
Observations | 1880 | 1875 | 1410 | 1839 | 1752 | 1752 | 1783 | 1128 | 1027 |
Countries | 102 | 102 | 100 | 107 | 90 | 90 | 108 | 75 | 67 |
R-squared | 0.165 | 0.146 | 0.108 | 0.209 | 0.221 | 0.223 | 0.190 | 0.167 | 0.220 |
Explanatory Variables: | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Gender Inequality | |||||||||
Female labor force participation rate | 0.473 | 0.970 ** | 0.758 | 1.762 *** | 0.995 ** | 0.859 * | 1.562 *** | 1.478 *** | −0.0324 |
(0.472) | (0.466) | (0.468) | (0.532) | (0.457) | (0.462) | (0.478) | (0.467) | (0.423) | |
- in LIDC | −2.748 *** | −3.458 *** | −2.935 *** | −3.146 *** | −3.400 *** | −3.111 *** | −2.609 *** | −2.185 *** | −2.092 ** |
(0.844) | (0.867) | (0.851) | (0.888) | (0.980) | (1.004) | (0.833) | (0.811) | (1.066) | |
Secondary enrollment ratio | −0.00603 | 0.0555 | 0.0444 | −0.580* | −0.374 | −0.328 | −0.333 | −0.279 | 0.316 |
(0.281) | (0.284) | (0.283) | (0.315) | (0.270) | (0.270) | (0.291) | (0.282) | (0.247) | |
- in LIDC | −0.986 ** | −0.987 ** | −1.034 ** | 0.119 | −0.195 | −0.167 | −0.0318 | −1.012 ** | −1.590 *** |
(0.480) | (0.490) | (0.484) | (0.446) | (0.456) | (0.456) | (0.461) | (0.424) | (0.590) | |
Women in parliament | −0.00265 | −0.00212 | −0.00271 | −0.00525 * | −0.00250 | −0.00292 | −0.00337 | −0.000692 | 0.00444 |
(0.00278) | (0.00282) | (0.00292) | (0.00315) | (0.00283) | (0.00283) | (0.00293) | (0.00315) | (0.00277) | |
- in LIDC | 0.00691 | 0.00482 | 0.00606 | 0.00452 | 0.00752 | 0.00800 * | 0.00418 | 0.00650 | 0.00578 |
(0.00482) | (0.00487) | (0.00493) | (0.00517) | (0.00461) | (0.00459) | (0.00487) | (0.00484) | (0.00471) | |
Maternal mortality ratio | 0.00142 ** | 0.00156 ** | 0.00151 ** | 0.00154 * | 0.00130 * | 0.00104 | 0.00145 ** | 0.00152 ** | 0.00169 *** |
(0.000695) | (0.000700) | (0.000700) | (0.000800) | (0.000676) | (0.000692) | (0.000719) | (0.000699) | (0.000629) | |
- in LIDC | −0.000415 | −0.000884 | −0.000411 | −0.00141 * | −0.000186 | −1.73 × 10−5 | −0.00129 * | −0.000668 | −0.00111 |
(0.000735) | (0.000755) | (0.000741) | (0.000830) | (0.000727) | (0.000733) | (0.000750) | (0.000733) | (0.000672) | |
Adolescent fertility rate | 0.000586 | 0.000761 | −0.000966 | 0.00377 | 0.00172 | 0.00231 | 0.00318 | 0.00267 | 0.00341 |
(0.00271) | (0.00274) | (0.00277) | (0.00309) | (0.00266) | (0.00265) | (0.00284) | (0.00288) | (0.00254) | |
- in LIDC | −0.00143 | 0.00138 | −0.000821 | 0.00640 | 0.00476 | 0.00393 | 0.00702 * | 0.00436 | 0.0122 ** |
(0.00409) | (0.00419) | (0.00411) | (0.00403) | (0.00457) | (0.00461) | (0.00396) | (0.00375) | (0.00535) | |
Structural Factors | |||||||||
Log(Population) | −0.0711 | 0.171 | 0.181 | −0.742 *** | 0.329 | 0.340 | −0.305 | 0.239 | 0.667 *** |
(0.234) | (0.237) | (0.236) | (0.271) | (0.239) | (0.238) | (0.240) | (0.247) | (0.238) | |
Lag Human capital index | −0.358 ** | −0.310 ** | −0.392 ** | −0.244 | −0.313 ** | −0.288 * | −0.483 *** | −0.419 *** | −0.387 *** |
(0.155) | (0.158) | (0.157) | (0.185) | (0.152) | (0.152) | (0.162) | (0.158) | (0.139) | |
Log(Real GDP per capita) | −2.059 *** | −2.261 *** | −2.051 *** | 1.137 * | −1.698 *** | −1.626 *** | 0.248 | −0.766 | −0.848 |
(0.609) | (0.624) | (0.622) | (0.595) | (0.608) | (0.610) | (0.586) | (0.563) | (0.617) | |
- squared | 0.125 *** | 0.131 *** | 0.120 *** | −0.0578 | 0.106 *** | 0.101 *** | −0.0136 | 0.0550 | 0.0495 |
(0.0356) | (0.0365) | (0.0363) | (0.0354) | (0.0357) | (0.0358) | (0.0348) | (0.0335) | (0.0362) | |
Mining as share of GDP | 0.0114 ** | 0.00874 | 0.0151 ** | 0.0122 ** | 0.0142 ** | 0.0151 *** | 0.0143 *** | 0.0191 *** | 0.0390 *** |
(0.00566) | (0.00573) | (0.00607) | (0.00557) | (0.00562) | (0.00565) | (0.00549) | (0.00587) | (0.00629) | |
Policies | |||||||||
1. Institutions | |||||||||
Fraser Institute Sum. Index | −0.115 *** | −0.124 *** | |||||||
(0.0221) | (0.0245) | ||||||||
Legal Syst. &Property Rights | −0.0437 *** | ||||||||
(0.0169) | |||||||||
2. Openness | |||||||||
Freedom to trade | −0.0516 *** | −0.00345 | |||||||
(0.0149) | (0.0168) | ||||||||
Globalization Index | −0.0114 *** | ||||||||
(0.00368) | |||||||||
3. Infrastructure | |||||||||
Length of road network | −0.0276 | ||||||||
(0.0188) | |||||||||
Log(landlines) per 1000 workers | −0.0499 * | −0.0532 ** | |||||||
(0.0271) | (0.0261) | ||||||||
4. Macro/Cyclical factors | |||||||||
Terms of Trade | 0.00287 *** | 0.00485 *** | |||||||
(0.000536) | (0.000607) | ||||||||
Log(REER) | −0.00341 | 0.236 *** | |||||||
(0.0798) | (0.0759) | ||||||||
Constant | 12.64 *** | 12.50 *** | 11.78 *** | −0.198 | 8.799 *** | 8.703 *** | 2.426 | 4.838 * | 3.450 |
(2.540) | (2.640) | (2.583) | (2.488) | (2.590) | (2.588) | (2.484) | (2.498) | (2.704) | |
Observations | 1033 | 1034 | 1032 | 954 | 989 | 989 | 1083 | 1084 | 927 |
Countries | 96 | 97 | 96 | 101 | 86 | 86 | 96 | 98 | 81 |
R-squared | 0.203 | 0.162 | 0.194 | 0.133 | 0.174 | 0.175 | 0.149 | 0.168 | 0.354 |
Explanatory Variables: | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Gender Inequality | |||||||||
Female labor force participation rate | 0.0160 | 0.0562 | 0.0665 | −0.0181 | 0.0776 * | 0.0624 | 0.0613 | 0.0580 | 0.0127 |
(0.0449) | (0.0446) | (0.0642) | (0.0505) | (0.0469) | (0.0474) | (0.0543) | (0.0681) | (0.0704) | |
- in LIDC | 0.0695 | 0.0358 | −0.292 ** | −0.00734 | 0.0568 | 0.0749 | 0.0384 | −0.421 *** | −0.342 ** |
(0.0810) | (0.0821) | (0.123) | (0.0843) | (0.0924) | (0.0939) | (0.0978) | (0.156) | (0.174) | |
Secondary enrollment ratio | 0.124 *** | 0.133 *** | 0.0947 *** | 0.119 *** | 0.110 *** | 0.117 *** | 0.0922 *** | 0.0751 ** | 0.0313 |
(0.0263) | (0.0265) | (0.0359) | (0.0293) | (0.0271) | (0.0271) | (0.0315) | (0.0371) | (0.0384) | |
- in LIDC | −0.0407 | −0.0502 | −0.107 * | −0.0965 ** | −0.0696 | −0.0695 | −0.0760 * | −0.0776 | −0.282 *** |
(0.0453) | (0.0458) | (0.0595) | (0.0417) | (0.0439) | (0.0439) | (0.0452) | (0.0740) | (0.105) | |
Women in parliament | −0.000203 | −0.000462 * | −0.000449 | −0.000178 | −0.000573 ** | −0.000619 ** | −0.000456 | −0.000386 | −0.000523 |
(0.000260) | (0.000277) | (0.000352) | (0.000295) | (0.000283) | (0.000284) | (0.000324) | (0.000360) | (0.000379) | |
- in LIDC | −0.000136 | 3.47 × 10−5 | 0.000539 | 7.31 × 10−5 | 6.11 × 10−5 | 0.000167 | 0.000372 | 0.000137 | −0.000579 |
(0.000458) | (0.000470) | (0.000696) | (0.000473) | (0.000439) | (0.000440) | (0.000531) | (0.00102) | (0.00128) | |
Maternal mortality ratio | 0.000162 ** | 0.000171 *** | 6.44 × 10−5 | 6.27 × 10−5 | 0.000203 *** | 0.000174 ** | 0.000117 | 5.40 × 10−5 | 1.97 × 10−7 |
(6.51 × 10−5) | (6.58 × 10−5) | (9.43 × 10−5) | (7.45 × 10−5) | (6.89 × 10−5) | (7.02 × 10−5) | (7.95 × 10−5) | (9.70 × 10−5) | (9.69 × 10−5) | |
- in LIDC | −8.27 × 10−5 | −7.99 × 10−5 | 4.73 × 10−5 | 7.38 × 10−5 | −0.000136 * | −0.000115 | 3.04 × 10−5 | −1.43 × 10−6 | 7.79 × 10−6 |
(6.94 × 10−5) | (7.02 × 10−5) | (1.00 × 10−4) | (7.79 × 10−5) | (7.44 × 10−5) | (7.52 × 10−5) | (8.34 × 10−5) | (0.000105) | (0.000122) | |
Adolescent fertility rate | 0.000925 *** | 0.00101 *** | 0.000931 ** | 0.000769 *** | 0.000327 | 0.000428 | 0.000535 * | 0.000401 | 0.000758 |
(0.000258) | (0.000264) | (0.000373) | (0.000290) | (0.000270) | (0.000270) | (0.000305) | (0.000474) | (0.000488) | |
- in LIDC | 0.000974 ** | 0.000993 ** | 0.00119 ** | 0.00110 *** | 0.00163 *** | 0.00153 *** | 0.00132 *** | 0.00181 *** | −0.000633 |
(0.000387) | (0.000391) | (0.000523) | (0.000378) | (0.000443) | (0.000450) | (0.000421) | (0.000655) | (0.00104) | |
Structural Factors | |||||||||
Log(Population) | −0.0116 | −0.00569 | 0.0546 | 0.0336 | −0.00484 | −0.00776 | 0.0438 | −0.0281 | −0.00629 |
(0.0224) | (0.0227) | (0.0334) | (0.0259) | (0.0244) | (0.0243) | (0.0286) | (0.0396) | (0.0422) | |
Lag Human capital index | 0.0183 | 0.0191 | 0.0146 | 0.0234 | 0.0199 | 0.0230 | 0.0158 | 0.0479 ** | 0.0459 * |
(0.0148) | (0.0150) | (0.0221) | (0.0176) | (0.0157) | (0.0157) | (0.0188) | (0.0239) | (0.0239) | |
Log(Real GDP per capita) | −0.0755 | −0.0619 | −0.196 ** | −0.217 *** | −0.124 ** | −0.115 * | −0.240 *** | 0.0433 | −0.243 |
(0.0585) | (0.0602) | (0.0801) | (0.0566) | (0.0607) | (0.0613) | (0.0691) | (0.129) | (0.152) | |
- squared | 0.00239 | 0.000941 | 0.00921 * | 0.00980 *** | 0.00422 | 0.00368 | 0.0112 *** | −0.00306 | 0.0141 |
(0.00342) | (0.00352) | (0.00476) | (0.00337) | (0.00356) | (0.00360) | (0.00416) | (0.00718) | (0.00859) | |
Mining as share of GDP | 0.000103 | −0.000482 | −0.00373 *** | −9.53 × 10−5 | 0.00241 *** | 0.00252 *** | 0.000476 | −0.00552 *** | −0.00855 *** |
(0.000544) | (0.000587) | (0.000827) | (0.000510) | (0.000554) | (0.000562) | (0.000556) | (0.00123) | (0.00131) | |
Policies | |||||||||
1. Institutions | |||||||||
Fraser Institute Sum. Index | −0.0107 *** | −0.00724 ** | |||||||
(0.00212) | (0.00341) | ||||||||
2. Openness | |||||||||
Freedom to trade | −0.00251 * | ||||||||
(0.00144) | |||||||||
Average Tariff Rates | 0.0636 *** | 0.143 *** | |||||||
(0.0183) | (0.0251) | ||||||||
Globalization Index | −0.00121 *** | ||||||||
(0.000351) | |||||||||
3. Infrastructure/Investment | |||||||||
Length of road network | −0.00474 ** | ||||||||
(0.00190) | |||||||||
Log(landlines) per 1000 workers | −0.00573 ** | −0.00403 | |||||||
(0.00267) | (0.00390) | ||||||||
Investment per worker | −1.67× 10−6 * | −5.39 × 10−6 *** | |||||||
(9.59× 10−7) | (1.41 × 10−6) | ||||||||
4. Financial Development | |||||||||
Financial reform index | −0.115 *** | −0.0630 *** | |||||||
(0.0201) | (0.0226) | ||||||||
Constant | 0.541 ** | 0.451 * | 0.933 *** | 1.109 *** | 0.719 *** | 0.717 *** | 1.124 *** | 0.138 | 1.389 ** |
(0.245) | (0.251) | (0.330) | (0.236) | (0.257) | (0.258) | (0.291) | (0.554) | (0.656) | |
Observations | 1063 | 1062 | 681 | 987 | 1014 | 1014 | 942 | 552 | 485 |
Countries | 98 | 98 | 95 | 103 | 87 | 87 | 104 | 73 | 65 |
R-squared | 0.245 | 0.229 | 0.231 | 0.330 | 0.259 | 0.258 | 0.294 | 0.276 | 0.341 |
Panel A: Dependent Variable: Export Diversification | Panel B: Dependent Variable: Output Diversification | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Explanatory Variables: | (1) | (2) | Explanatory Variables: | (1) | (2) |
GII Index | 5.785 *** | 3.534** | GII Index | 1.778 *** | 0.153 *** |
(1.942) | (1.739) | (0.361) | (0.0387) | ||
Log(Population) | −0.976 *** | −0.252 | Log(Population) | −0.0830 ** | −0.134 *** |
(0.214) | (0.271) | (0.0396) | (0.0230) | ||
Lag Human capital index | 0.0251 | 0.420 *** | Lag Human capital index | 0.131 *** | −0.00844 |
(0.196) | (0.162) | (0.0321) | (0.0116) | ||
Log(GDP per capita) | −1.307 *** | −0.666 * | Log(GDP per capita) | −0.390 *** | −0.222 *** |
(0.337) | (0.343) | (0.0726) | (0.0809) | ||
- squared | 0.0931 *** | 0.0360 * | - squared | 0.0230 *** | 0.0141 *** |
(0.0201) | (0.0196) | (0.00446) | (0.00473) | ||
Mining as share of GDP | 0.0318 *** | 0.0105 | Mining as share of GDP | 0.00129 | −8.56 × 10−5 |
(0.00710) | (0.00659) | (0.00126) | (0.000944) | ||
Fraser Institute Sum. Index | −0.0498 | Fraser Institute Sum. Index | −0.0114 *** | ||
(0.0363) | (0.00169) | ||||
Freedom to trade | −0.0405 *** | Average Tariff Rates | 0.0361 *** | ||
(0.0141) | (0.0105) | ||||
Log(landlines) per 1000 workers | −0.0919 *** | Log(landlines) per 1000 workers | −0.00201 | ||
(0.0281) | (0.00190) | ||||
Terms of Trade | 0.00427 *** | Investment per worker | −5.89 × 10−6 *** | ||
(0.000609) | (1.02 × 10−6) | ||||
Log(REER) | 0.301 *** | Financial reform index | −0.00467 | ||
(0.0588) | (0.0124) | ||||
Constant | 5.515 *** | 3.438 | Constant | 0.923 *** | 1.578 *** |
(2.046) | (2.466) | (0.329) | (0.354) | ||
Observations | 1552 | 1204 | Observations | 1554 | 833 |
p-value of Hansen J statistic | 0.296 | 0.248 | p-value of Hansen J statistic | 0.548 | 0.276 |
Instrument F-test | 13.27 | 12.85 | Instrument F-test | 16.28 | 33.44 |
© 2019 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Kazandjian, R.; Kolovich, L.; Kochhar, K.; Newiak, M. Gender Equality and Economic Diversification. Soc. Sci. 2019, 8, 118. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci8040118
Kazandjian R, Kolovich L, Kochhar K, Newiak M. Gender Equality and Economic Diversification. Social Sciences. 2019; 8(4):118. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci8040118
Chicago/Turabian StyleKazandjian, Romina, Lisa Kolovich, Kalpana Kochhar, and Monique Newiak. 2019. "Gender Equality and Economic Diversification" Social Sciences 8, no. 4: 118. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci8040118
APA StyleKazandjian, R., Kolovich, L., Kochhar, K., & Newiak, M. (2019). Gender Equality and Economic Diversification. Social Sciences, 8(4), 118. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci8040118