Next Article in Journal
Remote Sensing Technology Applications in Forestry and REDD+
Next Article in Special Issue
Refined Systems of National Accounts and Experimental Ecosystem Accounting Versus the Simplified Agroforestry Accounting System: Testing in Andalusian Holm Oak Open Woodlands
Previous Article in Journal
Resprouting Responses Dynamics of Schima superba Following a Severe Ice Storm in Early 2008 in Southern China: A Six-Year Study
Previous Article in Special Issue
Economic Valuation of Conservation of Inholdings in Protected Areas for the Institution of Payments for Ecosystem Services
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Income and Ecosystem Service Comparisons of Refined National and Agroforestry Accounting Frameworks: Application to Holm Oak Open Woodlands in Andalusia, Spain

1
Spanish National Research Council (CSIC), Institute of Public Goods and Policies (IPP), C/Albasanz, 26–28, E-28037 Madrid, Spain
2
Spanish National Research Council (CSIC), Institute of Marine Sciences of Andalusia (ICMAN), Campus Universitario Río San Pedro s/n, E-11519 Pto. Real-Cádiz, Spain
3
The James Hutton Institute, Social, Economic and Geographical Sciences, Craigiebuckler, Aberdeen, AB15 8QH, UK
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Forests 2020, 11(2), 185; https://doi.org/10.3390/f11020185
Submission received: 2 December 2019 / Revised: 23 January 2020 / Accepted: 4 February 2020 / Published: 7 February 2020
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Environmental Valuation and Sustainable Management of Forests)

Abstract

:
There is growing consensus regarding the implementation of a new statistical framework for environmental-economic accounting to improve ecosystem related policies. As the standard System of National Accounts (SNA) fails to measure the economic contribution of ecosystems to the total income of individuals, governments recognize the need to expand the standard SNA through the ongoing System of Environmental Economic Accounting (SEEA). Based on the authors’ own data, this study focuses on linking 15 economic activities and 12 ecosystem services for a holm oak (Quercus ilex L.) open woodlands (HOW) ecosystem type in Andalusia, Spain. We emphasize that overcoming the challenges of multiple use is preferable to measuring single ecosystem products for improving habitat conservation policies. The objectives of this paper are to measure and compare the environmental assets, ecosystem services, and incomes at basic and social prices by applying a refined version of the standard System of National Accounts (rSNA) and the authors’ Agroforestry Accounting System (AAS), respectively, to HOW. Considering intermediate products and consumptions of HOW farmer and government activities, we find that the rSNA ecosystem services and environmental incomes at basic prices are 123.3 €/ha and −28.0 €/ha, respectively, while those of the AAS at social prices are 442.2 €/ha and 250.8 €/ha. Given advances in non-market valuation techniques, we show that an expanded definition of economic activities can be applied to measure the contribution to total income of managed natural areas taking into account the multiple uses of the ecosystem type. However, HOW sustainability continues to be a challenging issue that requires ecological threshold indicators to be identified, not only because of the economic implications but also because they provide vital information on which to base policy implementation.

1. Introduction

Since 2010, national and international government institutions responsible for producing economic statistics on environmental governance and economic development have been pointing to the need to incorporate the contribution of nature to the income and capital of nations, although to date, these concerns have brought about advances as regards environmental refinement in the application of the statistical office standard System of National Accounts (SNA) [1,2,3,4,5,6,7,8,9,10,11]. One of the main challenges complicating the extension of the System of National Accounts (SNA) to explicitly incorporate the environment as an economic production factor is the consistency of the inclusion of values for products with and without market prices, when extending the SNA to estimate the real contributions of nature to the national product and social total income, as well as to evaluate the depletion and degradation of nature through government policy implementation. Another of the challenges regards the limits of environmental valuations in situations of ‘critical’ (threshold) amounts of renewable biophysical environmental assets.
In the SNA the net value added (NVASNA) of the economic activities does not include natural growth (NG) in the own-account gross capital formation (GCF) as a final product, and omits the environmental work in progress used (WPeu) from the intermediate consumption (IC). These omissions lead to a NVASNA bias associated with the timing of their measurement, which is avoided in this study by refining the standard System of National Accounts (rSNA), which includes their measurement in the NVArSNA.
The coordinated response of the governmental statistical offices to the demand for extending the indicator of SNA net value added (NVASNA), involves the development of the satellite System of Environmental Economic Accounting—Experimental Ecosystem Accounting (SEEA-EEA) [12,13] (currently in progress), with the aim of explicitly measuring the contributions of ecosystems services and environmental assets to the national product and income [14]. Until now, the guidelines in the SEEA-EEA process have focused on the conceptualization of the economic variables of ecosystem services and environmental assets, based on the consumer preferences evidenced in the transactions observed in formal markets and other simulated transactions (using stated or revealed preferences methods). Nevertheless, “the SEEA-EEA (…) provides the first framing, from a national accounting perspective, for the integration of information on ecosystem services and ecosystem assets. This framing is (...) a general understanding of the logic and motivation for the valuation of ecosystem services. It is recognized, however, that the precise description of the relationships between ecosystem assets, ecosystem services and the associated production, consumption and balance sheet [capital account] information in the standard national accounts [SNA] is subject to ongoing discussion. (…) a more precise and commonly agreed framing is required to support discussion and exchange on this issue” [15] (p. 11). This incipient development of the structure of SEEA-EEA accounts linked to the SNA makes it difficult to meet institutional demands for its implementation by national governments. The brief description of the sequence of SEE-AEEA and SNA accounts compared in [16] does not permit a detailed discussion on what its future development might be. The most recent draft dealing with the design of the SEEA-EEA Model C proposes the ecosystem as an institutional sector composed of public products without registering manufactured costs [16].
With respect to the SEEA-EEA, our Agroforestry Accounting System (AAS) incorporates the government institutional sector, and considers the ecosystem as a production factor and not as an institutional sector [17]. The variable that is the backbone of the conceptual design of the AAS is the environmental income at social price.
The three methodologies, the SNA, SEEA EEA, and AAS, follow the same principle for valuing the final products of the economic activities according to the observed transaction price in formal or simulated markets. The SNA can be applied to any economic and spatial unit, although it is only currently applied by governments at scales larger than corporate scale, usually at regional territorial scale and more generally at a national scale. The SEEA-EEA is a system of accounts which is not currently normalized since it is still under development. The novelty of the SEEA-EEA is that its design is expected to be applicable for any given scale, ecosystem type, and ecosystem services of individual products from each type of ecosystem. The AAS can be applied to any economic unit, special unit, and type of ecosystem. In this study, we have limited the application to the rSNA and our extended AAS methodology integrates rSNA.
This study focuses on the comparison of the results for rSNA and AAS environmental incomes measured in the holm oak open woodlands (HOW) of the region of Andalusian-Spain (for detailed descriptions of institutional, physical and yielding characteristics of Spanish and Andalusian HOW see Supplementary Materials Text S1, Tables S1 and S2 and [18]). The rSNA net value added (NVArSNA) modified the NVASNA by uncovering natural growth (NG) and environmental work in progress used (WPeu). In the AAS and rSNA methodologies, the changes in the environmental assets are explicitly incorporated in the environmental income estimates for the economic activities valued in the Andalusian HOW, except forest carbon activity, which is omitted in the rSNA. The HOW economic activities measured using the AAS and rSNA, produce 12 and 8 environmental incomes respectively.
The AAS and rSNA methodologies were applied to the measurement of environmental income at regional scale (Andalucia), measuring that of forests and other forest lands (including natural grasslands) at producer price [17], cork oak (Quercus suber L.) open woodlands at social price [19], and that of holm oak dehesa case studies (farm scale) at social price [20]. This study focuses on a comparison of the applications of the AAS and rSNA to estimate gross and net value added, ecosystem services, changes in environmental assets, total income, and environmental incomes at basic and social prices in the Andalusian HOW at regional scale. The individual economic activities valued are those which are privately-owned by farmers—namely, timber, cork, firewood, nuts, grazing (by game species and livestock), conservation forestry, landowner residential services, and private amenities—along with those which are publicly-owned by government in the form of collective ownership—namely, fire services, water supply, mushrooms, forest carbon, free-access recreation, landscape conservation, and threatened wild biodiversity preservation (see activities conceptualization in Supplementary Text S2). The residential, conservation forestry and fire service economic activities do not use products and services from the environmental assets production factors.
The concept of social price refers in this study to the incorporation (with the valuation at producer prices) of the ordinary own non-commercial intermediate consumption of services: amenity auto-consumption (SSncooa) and donation (SSncood) imputed to the HOW amenity and landscape activities. These SSncooa/d come from the non-commercial intermediate product of services generated by amenity auto-consumption (ISSnca) and donation (ISSncd) associated with the HOW hunting and livestock activities omitted in this study.
The AAS and rSN,A applied to the HOW, coincide with regard to the estimated physical quantities for the economic activities, except that the rSNA omits the forest carbon activity. They differ in terms of prices of the ordinary final products without market prices (private amenities, public recreation service, landscape service, and threatened wild biodiversity service), the valuation of the NVArSNA at basic price and the NVAAAS at social price.
The term environmental income has been employed previously by other authors without measuring the changes in environmental assets in the context of family-scale subsistence economies as a synonym of resource rent in [21] (p. 53), and also assimilated to the gross value added in the absence of opportunity costs of self-employed labor and either null or token employment of manufactured capital [22] (p. 41). Our concept of environmental income refers to the ‘gifts’ of nature that accrue from ecosystem services and adjusted change in environmental asset, integrated consistently into the estimate of social total income of the HOW accruing from the individual activities valued. The valuation of the ordinary environmental net operating margin (NOMeo), conditioned to the priority of remuneration for labor cost and ordinary manufactured net operating margin, allows the consistent integration of the environmental incomes (EI) measured by rSNA (EIrSNA) in the AAS (EIAAS.). As with the total income (TI), the environmental income comprises a residual term of the production account, the NOMeo, and another residual term of the environmental asset account; namely, the environmental asset revaluation (EAr) for the period. In order to overcome the shortcomings of the official SNA, the measurement of these two environmental income components is key when applying the rSNA and extended AAS accounting frameworks.
The measurement of total income (TI) and its factorial distribution follows an order of priority which conditions the remuneration of the three conventional production factors, namely labor, manufactured capital, and environmental asset. The order of priority for remunerations of the production factors in the first possible transaction of a total product consumption (TPc) of an activity is assumed to be: ordinary labor cost (LCo) first, ordinary manufactured net operating margin (NOMmo) second, and ordinary environmental net operating margin (NOMeo) third. The residual remuneration of the NOMeo of nature-based activities in the last position implies that the values cannot be negative. The government voluntarily renounces the remuneration of the ordinary manufactured net operating margin (NOMmoG) of the immobilized manufactured capital in the public activities. From these pre-conditions it can be deduced that the ecosystem services cannot contain negative values (ES ≥ 0), given the positive values for products of environmental work in progress used (WPeu). Consequently, the rSNA ordinary manufactured net operating margin (NOMmorSNA) of the private amenity activity and public activities can only present values equal to or less than zero. We assume that public consumers with free access to recreational services and gathering of wild products do not incur manufactured costs.
Among the conceptual advances of the AAS with respect to the rSNA is the fact that the valuation of individual products is presented at social price, when they are affected by the ordinary own non-commercial intermediate consumption of services of private amenity auto-consumption (SSncooa) and donation (SSncood) by HOW activities which are used as inputs to the private amenity and landscape services activities. In our HOW, the rSNA application is made possible thanks to the availability of our own data on full-cycle biological natural growth of the holm oaks and other tree species associated with the predominant holm oaks at tiles scale. However, our slight modification in the rSNA does not affect the value of the final products consumption recorded by the SNA, although it does affect the durable products accumulated in the production process due to the incorporation of natural growth for the period, and it also affects the net value added for the period due to the incorporation of woody products extracted of timber and firewood (WPeu) in the intermediate consumption. This study’s two most significant practical innovations are the measurement of the theoretical concept of capital gain (omitted in the SNA), to be added to the net value added, thus obtaining the social total income in the rSNA and the environmental income estimate linked to ecosystem services and adjusted change in environmental net worth (CNWead).
The applied contribution is to compare rSNA and AAS, in order to show that the former does not record the totality of the economic value of the activities measured and that it omits others. This is the case for the forest carbon activity, as the other 14 activities compared are the same, after our refinement of the standard SNA. The results confirm that the rSNA, by conceptual definition, cannot measure ecosystem services and environmental assets of the products without market prices. The comparison demonstrates that the scientific knowledge exists to avoid the failure of the market to measure the economic contribution of nature to the total income of the period, and we present the results of our AAS compared with the rSNA for the same variables and the same type of ecosystem, in this study, the holm oak open woodlands of Andalusia.
The physical sustainability of the HOW is forecasted based on scheduled future natural/induced regeneration. The biological cycles are as prescribed by forestry legislation on the management of Quercus genus species in Andalusia and felling of holm oaks is only permitted where there is a government authorized land use change. Commercial harvesting rotations are not regulated in the case of conifers and broadleaf timber producing species (eucalyptus and poplar mainly) and management plans for these species include stand persistence without land use change, except where unforeseen destruction occurs (e.g., catastrophic forest fires).
Although the landowners are not obliged to replant the trees, we assume that the scheduled future conservation silviculture applied will renew the current area (tiles) of woodland in Andalusia where holm oak woodland predominates [17,23].
The environmental incomes from the total products valued by the AAS at social price represent the scheduled sustainable economic contributions of management by farmers and government of the environmental assets of the Andalusian HOW. A valuation of the environmental assets at the closing of the period is assumed to correspond to the forecast regeneration of the trees in the current area over the complete biological/commercial cycle, along with the absence of any loss of currently threatened wild biological species. Under these conditions, the ecological sustainability of future management of the HOW is integrated into the expected results for the future resource rents.
The AAS and rSNA applications are based on information from land use tiles of the third National Forest Inventory for Andalusia and the Forest Map of Spain [24], showing a predominance of holm oak open woodlands (HOW). The HOW predominate in 22,281 tiles of the Forest Map of Spain (FMS), which covers an area of 1,408,170 hectares (see Supplementary Text S1, Tables S1 and S2 and [18]).
The physical data on estimated flows and stocks are for the year 2010. We have omitted the hunting and livestock activities from those valued in the holm oak open woodlands (HOW) as regional scale information was not available. For explanatory purposes we have included the SSncooc/a/d, where c is government compensation, a is private landowner amenity auto-consumption, and d is public landowner donation for the omitted hunting and livestock activities, which we assume to have been used by the HOW amenity and landscape activities valued.
In this application, we do not take into account the existence of a contractual right/liability of the owner for improving/maintaining the threshold of a given natural asset at the closing of the period. Thus, no loan/debt is generated for the increase/loss of natural assets derived from the economic activities and hence the net worth of the HOW does not comprise financial assets.
There are both private and public owners of the land, with different economic rationales. We assume that the economic rationale of the private owners includes auto-consumption of private amenities. It is accepted that the production function of the private amenity and landscape activities uses the ordinary own intermediate consumption of services (SSoo). They are composed of ordinary own commercial intermediate consumption of services consumption of services compensation (SSncooc), amenity auto-consumption (SSncooa), and donation (SSncood). The government fire service activity and the private landowner residential and forestry conservation activities supply commercial intermediate product of services (ISSc). The omitted hunting and livestock activities produce non-commercial intermediate products of services compensation (ISSncc), amenity auto-consumption (ISSnca), and donation (ISSncd). The latter is originated from the public landowner activities. In the HOW, these three ISSnc are generated by the hunting and livestock activities.
The government is the owner and manager in representation of the collective public activities. In the HOW, the public activities are those which are regulated and managed by the government, providing free consumption of the final products to both active and passive consumers. The economic rationale of the government implies registering ordinary own non-commercial intermediate consumption of services compensations (SSncooc) and donations (SSncood) in the public activities that use them, in this study, they are used by the landscape activity. The government is able to accept voluntary negative values in recurrent periods for the ordinary manufactured net operating margin (NOMmo) of a public activity. The main logic for the conservation of a unique biological variety in danger of extinction, based on the concept of valuing the existence of a unique genetic variety which is not industrially reproducible, is a governmental precautionary behavior. However, the omission of current consumer preferences is not complete because democratic governments must consider the tolerable social cost of avoiding the nature variety irreversible loss. Nevertheless, there is a general consensus on the diverse rationales for the integrated conservationist management of the HOW among the economic actors, as reflected in the following quote: “From a production perspective, always effected in a way that focuses on restoring the balance between environment and business [sustainable management] (square brackets are not in the original text), allowing a profitability which facilitates reinvestment in the environment (...), actively organizing the maintenance of the natural scenario in which we carry out our agroforestry activity, with the certainty of achieving the economic return for our labor” [25] (p. 10). Although, in principle, all the actors accept this conservationist perspective, controversy arises among the owners, the government and the consumers when attempting to put into practice their perceptions on the concepts of economic profitability and environmental asset conservation. We are faced with numerous subjective interpretations when attempting to apply sustainable management of renewable natural resources in a way that is coherent with ecological and economic sciences.
Section 2 summarizes the AAS and rSNA accounting frameworks applied to holm oak open woodlands. Section 3 describes and compares the main environmental economic results obtained from the application of the two accounting frameworks to the Andalusia HOW. Section 4 discuss the key findings and policy implications of applying the extended AAS to overcoming the standard SNA nature hidden contribution to total income in this HOW application. Section 5 concludes with the major results, findings, and policy challenges.

2. Accounting Frameworks Applied to Holm Oak Open Woodlands

2.1. Total Income Accounting Framework Applied to Holm Oak Open Woodlands

The System of National Accounts (SNA) definitions of products, costs, and capital offer the mainstream structure concepts of the production and capital accounts, which allows us to estimate the net value added and the capital gain that integrate the coherent definition of the total income of individual products (see Appendix A on glossary of selected accounting economic variables used in this HOW study). However, in practice, the SNA applied by nations is limited to the measurement of a narrow net value added (NVASNA). The SNA measures the total product (TPSNA) without market price at production cost, in this case lacking conceptual consistency with the principle of valuation at transaction price, since it impedes the existence of a positive ordinary net operating margin (NOM).
The AAS and rSNA methodologies adapted to this HOW application are briefly described (for details see [26,27,28] and the Supplementary Texts S3 and S4). We conceptualize the accounting registers developed in the HOW applications, which allow us to estimate the net value added (NVA), the capital gain (CG), the ecosystem services (ES), total income (TI), labor cost (LC), manufactured capital income (CIm), and environmental income (EI). In the below general conceptual description of these variables it is not necessary to make the distinctions of the accounting methodologies and prices (Figure 1).
To date, the notable advances achieved in the techniques for valuing the final products consumption without market price have not been incorporated into the standard System of National Accounts applied by nations in their estimations of gross domestic product (GDP), which, as we will see, is still an incomplete measure of the social total income for the period, generated within the territory of the different nations [5,6].
The satellite Economic Accountsfor agriculture (including livestock and hunting activities) and forestry (EAA/EAF) of the SNA explicitly accept the concept of total income even though measuring it is not their purpose: “Income can be defined as the maximum amount which the beneficiaries can consume over a given period without reducing the volume of their assets. It can also be defined as the total of the consumption and change in value of assets held over a given period, all else being equal, as income represents what could have been consumed” (italics in original text) [6] (p. 87).
The measurement of total income is the principle which governs the organization of the records for the whole accounting system of an economic unit, which should abide by the economic principle that the real capital values at the opening and closing of the period in which the total income produced in the territorial unit is measured remain the same.
Measuring the total income requires the type of production and capital (balance sheet) accounts described in the AAS methodology (see details in Supplementary Texts S3 and S4, [17,18]). The production account gives the net value added (NVA) and its distribution among the production factors of labor (LC), manufactured capital operating income(NOMm), and environmental assets operating income (NOMe) (Figure 1). The latter incorporate the investment environmental net operating margin (NOMei), which is natural growth (NG) less carbon activity emission (consumption of environmental fixed asset: CFCe) (1)
NOMei = NG − CFCe
The capital account gives the capital revaluation (Cr). Following specific accounting adjustments applied to avoid double counting of the natural growth (NG) in HOW applications, the Cr allows us to estimate the capital gain (CG) (see Supplementary Text S3 and [17,18]). In accordance with the factorial distribution of the NVA, the CG is divided into manufactured capital (CGm) and environmental asset (EAg) of each individual total product (Figure 1). Thus, having estimated at the closing of the period the real values registered and the residual values of the production and capital accounts, we estimate the NVA and the CG, which together give the social total income (TI) of the HOW for the period and its factorial distribution among remunerations for labor cost (LC), manufactured capital income (CIm), and environmental income (EI) (Figure 1).
The procedures for estimating the CGm and the EAg are the same. Here, we describe the EAg as it has more novel aspects of environmental asset account in the period. The environmental asset at the closing of the previous period is taken to be the same as the environmental asset at the opening (EAo) of the current period. Environmental asset entries (EAe) and withdrawals (EAw) occur during the period. Among other EAe, is that of natural growth (NG) for the period valued at environmental price discounted at the closing of the period. As regards the EAw, the work in progress used (WPeu) valued at environmental price (equivalent to environmental intermediate consumption). At the end of the period, the closing environmental asset (EAc) is estimated, discounting the indefinite flow of resource rents, assuming all else remains constant, except for the expected variations in biological productivity which are modeled in advance [17]. The revaluation of the environmental asset (EAr) is the residual variable (balancing item) in the capital account. The EAr (2) incorporates the change in the environmental asset in the period (CEA) (3)
EAr = CEA + EAw − EAe
CEA = EAc − EAo
The instrumental environmental asset adjustments (EAad) in HOW applications incorporate the expected opening period natural growth valued (NG/(1+r)) and carbon final product consumption (FPcca/(1+r)) both valued at environmental prices (4). These adjustments avoid the double counting of NG/(1+r) embedded in natural growth (NG) valued at the period closing and FPcca/(1+r) embedded in carbon final consumption (FPcca) valued at the period closing.
EAad = NG/(1+r) + FPcca/(1+r)
Figure 1 and the above CEA, EAr, EAg, and EAad accounting identities from the production and capital accounts provide the elements which correspond to be able to measure the environmental income (EI). The EI represents the total contribution of nature (ecosystems) to the total income (TI) of the HOW. The EI is the core variable which gives the values of the ecosystem services (ES) and the changes in the environmental assets for the period (CEA). In the case of some products, these CEA must be adjusted to avoid double counting, these CEA adjustments leading to the new variable of adjusted change in environmental net worth (CNWead) according to WPeu. Once the CNWead has been measured, the EI (5) can be presented in its ecosystem service (ES) (6) and CNWead (7) components.
EI = ES + CNWead
ES = WPeu + NOMeo
CNWead = NOMei + EAg − WPeu

2.2. Prices of Environmental Assets and Products

The environmental timber, cork, and firewood assets at the opening of the period and total products consumption are valued pending their production process stage at their environmental, stumpage, and farm gate prices. The prices of the stocks of timber, cork, and firewood produced are derived from the current value of the physical quantities times their discounted environmental price at the opening of the period. The products consumption are valued based on the willingness-to-pay of the economic agents, depending on the stage they are at prior to their consumption as a final product.
The environmental price of a harvested product corresponds to the unitary resource rent. The harvested stumpage price of a product represents the transaction price before the product is harvested, and the farm gate price is the harvested price at the farm gate.
Commercial intermediate services (ISSc) without market prices are valued at production costs (e.g., conservation forestry and fire services). Commercial intermediate products with formal markets are valued at their imputed market prices (e.g., grazing and residential service).
Embedded in the value of the total product (TP) at social price are the individual values of its total production costs (TC) and the net operating margin (NOM). The social price is measured in this HOW as the total product at basic price less the ordinary own non-commercial intermediate consumption of services amenity auto-consumption (SSncooa) and donation (SSncood). These SSncoa/d, which come from the omitted hunting and livestock activities, are valued according to the ordinary manufactured net operating margin loss (opportunity cost) voluntarily accepted by the farmers.
In this HOW application, the activities valued do not incorporate non-commercial intermediate product of services compensation (ISSncc), but they do include ordinary own non-commercial intermediate consumption of services compensation (SSncooc), which is used by the amenity and landscape activities, and which comes from the ISSncc of the omitted activities of hunting and livestock. Therefore, the basic price in this HOW study is the producer price less SSncooc.
The fact that products are valued at producer, basic, and social prices does not influence the aggregate estimate for the considered HOW activities as a whole (if hunting and livestock activities were included). However, the different types of prices do influence the estimates of ecosystem services and the gross value added of the farmer and government HOW activities valued, and those of individual activities where input of SSncooc/a/d is involved.
The revised System of National Accounts (rSNA) applied to the HOW estimates environmental economic variables at both producer and basic prices. In the Agroforestry Accounting System (ASS), ecosystem services and incomes are valued at producer, basic, and social prices. The reason for this difference is that the AAS considers the SSncooa/d accruing from the HOW hunting and livestock activities omitted.
The HOW maps of tile geo-referenced results of total environmental income shows values at producer price. In this case, the embedded amenity environmental income is overvalued with respect to its social prices due to the omission of the SSncooa.

2.3. Integration of the rSNA in the AAS Applied to Holm Oak Open Woodlands

We are interested in linking the net value added at social prices in the AAS (NVAsp,AAS) with the respective rSNA at basic prices (NVAbp,rSNA). This linkage is achieved in this HOW application through the following criteria: (i) subtracting ordinary own non-commercial intermediate consumption of services from the farmer amenity auto-consumption (SSncooaAAS) and government donation (SSncoodAAS); (ii) adding the difference from the price of the final product of private amenity auto-consumption (ΔFPaaAAS) derived from farmers’ willingness-to-pay to the rSNA valued at the manufactured production cost, the final product of water supply (ΔFPwaAAS) derived from the revealed (hedonic) environmental market price to the water supply used by the industry and service sectors valued by the rSNA at manufactured production cost, non-commercial (in this HOW application, consumption of public goods and services without market prices are recreational service, landscape conservation service, and existence of the threatened wild biodiversity service) final product consumption of government goods and services (ΔFPncG,AAS) valued at revealed marginal consumer willingness-to-pay to the cost price of the rSNA, carbon final product consumption (FPcaAAS); and (iii) subtracting the carbon consumption from environmental fixed asset (CFCecaAAS) (8)
NVAsp,AAS = NVAbp,rSNA − SSncooaAAS − SSncoodAAS +ΔFPaaAAS +ΔFPwaAAS + ΔFPncGAAS + FPcaAAS − CFCecaAAS
Figure 1 and the above equations show that the rSNA and the AAS contain consistent integrated accounting structures which allow homogeneous comparisons of their ecosystem service, incomes, environmental asset values, as well as any other environmental economic indicator of the ecosystem type.

3. Results

The primary data are the authors’ own sources and comes from the RECAMAN project [17]. The authors wish to express our willingness to provide the primary data on which the results of this study are based to any readers who request it. In this study, we consider the methods used in the estimation of the values recorded for the Andalusian holm oak woodlands (HOW) in the production and capital accounts of the rSNA and AAS methodologies compared to be well known (see detailed description in the Supplementary Text S3 and [17]).

3.1. Agroforestry Accounting System Total Income and Capital

The purposes of the production and capital accounts in the AAS methodology are to estimate the net value added (NVA) and the capital gain (Cg) to be able to obtain the social total income (Figure 1). The net operating margin (NOM) and capital revaluation (Cr) are the production and capital accounts balancing items respectively. The NOM is measured by subtracting the labor cost (LC) and consumption of fixed capital from the total product (TP) (Figure 1, Table 1). The capital gain (Cg) is measured by subtracting the capital adjustment (Cad) from the capital revaluation (Cr) according to the accounting register convention to avoid double counting (Table 2).
It may seem strange that countries do not know the income of their national territories when the economic statistic most universally used by governments is that known as the gross domestic product (GDP). The GDP is a synonym for the gross value added (GVA) and in fact the income for the national territory, which in practice is estimated by the government offices for statistics through the SNA, is represented by the net domestic product (NDP), which is synonymous with net value added (NVA). We have devised the AAS production account for the purpose of estimating the NVA and excluding the capital gain (CG) in the gross capital formation (GCF). The SNA also excludes capital gain from the GCF, except for that which corresponds to the livestock activity. We need to estimate the CG from the capital account and thus provide a value for the total income of the HOW.

3.1.1. Net Value Added

The ultimate aim guiding the accounting structure of the AAS total production account records is the measurement of the net values added (NVA) classified into ordinary (NVAo) and investment (NVAi) of the individual activities, institutional sectors of farmer and government, and whole cork oak woodlands (HOW) activities, along with the factorial distribution among the labor costs (LC), manufactured net operating margin (NOMm), and environmental net operating margin (NOMe) (Table 1, Tables S3 and S4).
Table 1 and Table S3 show the details of the total product (TP) and total cost (TC) records for the individual activities, which in turn allow us to estimate their respective net operating margins at social price (NOMsp) and their factorial distribution among the operating services of manufactured capital (NOMm) and the environmental asset (NOMe). Table S3 shows the separation of the total cost into ordinary total cost (TCo) and total investment cost (TCi). This classification of the costs allows us to distinguish the origin of the NOMe as total products consumption (NOMeo) and net investment in environmental assets (NOMei). The NOMei is estimated according to the natural growth less the consumption of environmental fixed capital (CFCe). The manufactured investment is represented by own-account gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) and does not generate manufactured investment net operating margin (NOMmi) as it has been valued at production cost. That is, the NOMmi is not applicable. Figure 2 and Figure 3 show the net added values of the individual, farmer, government, and total activities of the HOW separated into labor cost (LC) and net operating margin (NOM).
Table 3 and Table S3 give the variables for the (WPeu) and the ordinary environmental net operating margin (NOMeo), which—added together—give the ecosystem service (ES) estimates. Table 3 and Table S4 provide a detailed description of the components which make up the value of a product consumption, among which are the ecosystem services. Finally, Table 1 and Table S3 show the net value added (NVA) which remunerates the labor cost (LC) and the total capital net operating margin (NOM).
Figure 2 and Figure 3 show the net value added of the individual, farmer, government, and total activities of the HOW separated into labor cost (LC) and net operating margin (NOM). Labor cost only contributes minimally to the total income of the HOW activities valued since the HOW animal activities omitted are those which generate most of the demand for employment.

3.1.2. Capital Gain

Table 2 shows the opening capital for the period of the 15 HOW economic activities valued, separated into manufactured (Cmo) and environmental (EAo). Three of the 15 HOW activities valued do not contribute to the environmental assets. The most important individual environmental assets are the private amenity, stored surface water, grazing, and landscape (Table 2). The Cmo mainly corresponds to the farmer activities and the EAo are divided in similar proportions between farmers and government (Table 3).
The capital account in Table 3, Tables S5 and S6 show the capital revaluation (Cr), distinguishing between the revaluation of manufactured capital (Cmr) and environmental assets (EAr). According with the accounting adjustments (Cad), which avoid double counting due to the ad hoc procedures used in the measurement of the NG, carbon final consumption, and manufactured fixed capital consumption revaluation (CFCmr) we arrive at estimates for the capital gain (GC) and its separation into manufactured (CGm) and environmental (EAg) as shown in Figure 1 and Figure S1 and Table S7.
The HOW maintain a minimal value of environmental work in progress asset (WPe) (Table 2, Table 3, Table S5, and Table S6) due to the dissipation of the resource rent from firewood and scarce representation of the associated species of timber-yielding conifers and cork oaks respectively. Although the resource rent from grazing is tending to decline, it is still the second environmental asset for farmers in terms of value after the amenity (Table 2 and Table 3).
The negative result for the CG of the HOW in the 2010 period is due to the drop in land prices and the manufactured capital of machinery and buildings not forecast at the opening of the period. The volatility of the land price change in the short term is of little relevance given the long-term investment-consumption rationale of the land owners. The variation of annual real accumulative rate of grassland prices of HOW over the period 1994–2010 was more than 3% [29].
The factorial distributions of the total income are consistent with the results of the opening capital, where the environmental assets make up most of the total opening capital and therefore at the closing of the period the environmental income makes up most of the total income of the HOW. In the 2010 period the circumstance arose of the manufactured capital income being negative.

3.1.3. Total and Environmental Incomes

We have described above the structured results for the total production (Table S3) and capital accounts (Table 1, Table 2 and Table 3, Tables S5 and S6) of the holm oak open woodlands (HOW), which allow us to reorganize and simplify the data in the instrumental sequence of accounts which show the estimates of the net values added, ecosystem services, total income, and environmental income. The results for these variables are presented per individual, farmer, government, and total activities in the HOW of Andalusia.
Table 1, Table 3, and Table S7 and Figure 1 and Figure S1 present the simplified sequence of production and capital accounts which allow the estimation of the total income and its factorial distribution as the sum of the NVA and the GC. It is important to note that the simplified structures of the data in Table S7 and Figure S1 are derived from the complete primary data of Tables S3 and S5.
Table S4 shows, in detail, the measurement of the ecosystem services (ES) valued at social prices based on separating the estimates for net value added of the total products consumption (TPc) and own-account gross capital formation (GCF) for the period of the individual HOW activities. Only the TPc contains the ecosystem services (ES) embedded in its two possible components of intermediate consumption of environmental work in progress used (WPeu) and ordinary operating income of the environmental asset represented by the ordinary environmental net operating margin (NOMeo).
The production account (Table 1, Table S3, and Table S4) and capital account (Table 2, Table 3, Table S5, and Table S6) allow a simplified sequence of identities of the total income measurements. Figure S1 show the sequence of identities which permit the total income to be estimated as the sum of the net value added at social price (NVAsp) and the capital gain (CG).
The environmental income is presented in Figure 1 and Figure S1 as the sum of the operating margin (NOMe) and environmental asset gain (EAg) components. By reorganizing the elements which integrate the NOMe and the EAg we get the identity of the environmental income (EI) which links ecosystem services (ES) and adjusted change of environmental net worth (CNWead) (Table S7 and Figure 4, Figure 5 and Figure 6). Figure 4 shows the individual and aggregate values for the AAS ecosystem services and Figure 5 shows the change in environmental net worth adjusted according to WPeu. Figure 6 shows the aggregate value of individual ES and CNWead at social prices, estimated by individual activities, farmer, government, and the HOW activities as a whole.
The briefly described sequences of accounts are repeated in the application of the rSNA to the holm oak open woodlands of Andalusia (Tables S8, S9, and Table A1 on Appendix B).

3.1.4. Geo-Referenced Results

The ecosystem services and the environmental and total incomes at producer prices for the Andalusian HOW activities valued by the AAS methodology are presented in the maps of Figure 7 and Figure S2, geo-referenced for Andalusia at the scale of the tiles of the Forest Map of Spain (FMS). The AAS estimates at producer price in the HOW overvalue the ES and the EI of the amenity activity. At tile scale we, think it is unwise to present the data at social price for the amenity activity given the uncertainty of having imputed the SSncoo according to the ISSnc of the hunting and livestock activities in 16 private and 6 public HOW farm (dehesa) case studies respectively. Figures S3 and S4 present the ecosystem services and the environmental income of the individual products consumption and the total for the HOW of Andalusia.

3.2. Agroforestry Accounting System Versus Refined System of National Accounts

Comparisons of incomes and capital under the AAS and the rSNA reveal that the results for the two approaches coincide for activities with market price and that there are large differences between the results for activities without market price as regards the private and public amenity products. The rSNA only include valuations at producer and basic prices. Here, we only compare the estimates at basic price in the rSNA and at social price in the AAS.
The advantage of producer prices is that they can be observed directly and indirectly in formal and simulated markets respectively. The Agroforestry Accounting System (AAS) estimates the non-commercial final product consumption (FPnccAAS) without market prices according to consumer willingness to pay, whereas the refined System of National Accounts values them at production cost price. The disadvantage of producer prices is that they give biased valuations, which normally undervalue the operating margins of the activities which produce own ordinary non-commercial intermediate services (ISSnc) and in contrast overvalue the operating margins of the activities which demand the own ordinary non-commercial intermediate consumption of services (SSncoo).
The basic prices partially correct the bias in the valuations by incorporating the intermediate services of compensations (ISSncc) and their respective counterpart of ordinary own intermediate consumptions (SSncooc). Total correction of the valuation biases is achieved by applying the social price. In this study of HOW, we have added the valuations imputed at basic prices and social prices to the results at producer prices. Due to a lack of representative statistical basic and social price valuations, any conclusions with regard to the results at basic and social prices for the only two individual activities affected—namely, amenity and landscape—should be drawn with caution (see Supplementary Text S4). Furthermore, having estimated the willingness to pay for landscape and threatened biodiversity activities as a value additional to their total costs, whatever the type of cost, the ecosystem services of these activities will not vary when the type of prices changed. It can be observed in Table 4 and Table S10 that the price comparisons within the same accounting methodologies present unitary indices, indicating the absence of variation with type of price applied. Given these results, we lean towards presenting the results at producer prices in this incomplete study of the HOW activities in Andalusia. However, for illustrative purposes, we comment on some of the variations in the results for ecosystem incomes and services of the amenity activity, the farmer, and the HOW activities as a whole.
The HOW ecosystem services and the gross values added at producer prices and social prices for the farmers and the total for the activities vary due to the omission of the livestock and hunting activities (see Table 4 and Table S10). The variation in ecosystem services (ES), depending on the type of price applied, is slightly greater for the amenity activity than for the farmer activities as a whole due to the greater weight of the amenity in the ES and because the rest of the farmer activities are not affected by the inclusion of the SSncoo.
There are notable variations in the valuations of farmer ES and gross added values which indicate that, in the presence of auto-consumption of amenities by the owners, the social price more reliably reflects the individual and aggregate economic valuations derived from the economic rationales of the owners.
The estimates of ecosystem services for government activities in this HOW study do not vary depending on the type of price applied, although gross added values for landscape and the aggregate total for the government activities do vary.
As regards HOW activities as a whole, comparisons of ES and GVA evaluations reveal substantial overvaluations when estimating at producer prices in comparison to social prices (Table 4 and Table S10).
In the HOW activities valued using the rSNA, the ES and GVA estimates are 28% and 37% respectively of the respective values in the AAS (Table 4 and Table S10).
Figure 8 shows that amenity, carbon, and landscape are the ecosystem services which present the greatest differences in the comparisons between the rSNA at basic price and the AAS at social price. Figure 9 reveals an important loss in environmental income for the amenity, caused by the fall in the price of land in 2010. The rest of the activities show almost zero or positive environmental incomes.

4. Discussion

4.1. We Cannot Consume the Ecosystem Services but Rather their Ordinary Final Product

In this study, as regards the economic analysis of ecosystem services we have referred exclusively to the renewable products appropriated by farmers and the government. It is accepted that the economic production functions can only employ inputs (intermediate consumptions) and cost of environmental asset use (natural) being their physical contribution sufficient for their inclusion [17,30]. Capital use cost is defined in this case as the sum of the fixed capital consumption and the normal income from capital invested in the ordinary final production. Consequently, the economic analysis of the ecosystem services goes beyond their economic value and from our perspective, the final product consumption is at the center of the analysis of the contribution of nature to the value of the nature based products consumption.
The production functions of an ordinary final product in the SNA ignore the zero price natural inputs but in contrast, admit the residual values, regardless of sign, for net mixed income and net operating surplus in a consistent manner. Thus, we can consider that it is consistent with the SNA methodology to take into account the zero value natural intermediate consumptions so as to make the physical quantities of the production factors consistent with their final products consumption. The fact that the ecosystem service is an income from the gifted natural resource (environmental asset) means that its residual economic value will be greater than or equal to zero (since the farmers and government do not incur manufactured production costs in their appropriation).
The SEEA-EEA implicitly accept that products without manufactured costs can be integrated in the economic activities since “the production boundary is expanded relative to the SNA reflecting that the supply of goods and services by ecosystems is considered additional production” [12] (p. 88). Here, in order for the additional products to be valued consistently with respect to those of the SNA, the ecosystem institutional sector must only refer to government public products without manufactured costs.
The AAS maintains the dependency on the nature based ordinary final products, even where the resource rent is zero, since people enjoy the consumption of these products without knowing the remunerations of the production factors which contribute to their market or simulated price. In other words, we cannot consume the ecosystem service of an economic activity, but we can consume the ordinary final product to which it contributes physically and/or economically. It is inconsistent from the perspective of consumption of an ordinary product to conclude that “if no [resource] rent is earned [embedded], the concept of [net] value added will represent no more than that which could be earned in alternative employment, and will as such not reflect any dependency on the natural resource” [22] (p. 41). The zero value of the resource rent does not nullify the ecological dependence, which makes it possible to obtain a manufactured net value added embedded in the value of the product consumption, the existence of which is only viable due to the physical consumption of the environmental intermediate input supplied by the ecosystem. This would be the case of grazing, if it is considered as an environmental input consumed by the HOW game species which, even though it has a zero transaction price. This gives rise to the existence of a resource rent for market transactions of game captures which, in the case of the HOW, allows us to match the resource rent for game captures to the value of the grazing consumption, and to the net value added due to the absence of manufactured costs.
The supply of stored water with commercial economic use is another example where the resource rent coincides with the value of the product in the HOW due to the absence of manufactured costs.
In the case of harvesting free access wild products, the net mixed income must be estimated and the factorial distribution of the net mixed income must be derived from the local markets and the motivation of the picker. In the HOW, the recreational mushroom pickers do not incur intermediate consumptions or cost for manufactured capital use, and it is assumed that they do not incur opportunity costs for the time employed on the visit; therefore, the values of the ordinary product, the ecosystem service, and the net value added coincide.
In all the examples described, there is a constant in the ecosystem service estimates for an individual product which consists of starting from the first possible transaction value of the ordinary product. This criterion is followed by the estimates of intermediate consumptions and the capital use cost, and finally the ecosystem service is estimated as a residual value. All types of relationship are possible among the values of the product, the ecosystem service resource rent and the net value added, but all equivalence must be consistent with the concept of total income. In short, the existence of an ecosystem institutional sector is an instrumental construction, the justification for which lies more in political convention than a scientific necessity derived from the production function.

4.2. Ecosystem Service and Income Valuations: Producer versus Social Prices

In this study, the AAS methodology is applied to fifteen economic activities (hunting, livestock, and agriculture activities are omitted) at regional scale in holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia in 2010, with the novelty of comparing producer prices (market and simulated) and social prices. The results reveal notable overvaluations at producer prices in comparison to social prices of the net/gross added values of the private amenity and landscape economic activities, as well as of the aggregate farmer, government, and total HOW activities. The ecosystem services and the environmental income of the private amenity, along with their aggregate values for farmers and total for the HOW are affected. The results for the ecosystem services and the environmental incomes of the individual activities of the government are not affected by the change in the type of price used in the valuations.
The comparison of the results for the valuations of ecosystem services and incomes at producer price in the rSNA reveal notable undervaluation compared to the AAS estimates at social price. The differences revealed in the comparisons of environmental assets estimated by the AAS and rSNA are due to the valuation at production cost of the final products consumption without market prices in the rSNA and at simulated revealed/declared price in the AAS, as well as to the omission of the carbon activity in the rSNA.

4.3. Lack of Investment in Conservation Forestry in Holm Oak Woodlands

The commercial products of the HOW do not generally provide competitive monetary profits at producer (market) prices; the justification for the market price of the HOW can only be found in the auto-consumption of amenities (recreation) by non-industrial owners. In other words, the private family owners pay themselves the monetary opportunity cost of the production of amenity services auto-consumed exclusively in their properties, when they incur in voluntarily accepted monetary opportunity costs. The public administration also recognizes this economic value of the dehesa owner’s amenities. Spanish land law establishes that to buy or expropriate a rural property it is possible to pay up to a maximum of twice what it would be worth, if only the profits from its commercial exploitation are considered, since the legislators recognize that the other half of its market price corresponds to the benefit from the non-commercial flow of private amenities of the owner.
It is unusual for owners to invest in order to benefit the consumption of future generations without receiving government compensations, given that competitive profitability results are mainly due to the amenities, and these are not affected in the short and medium term by the current rate of degradation of the HOW taking into account the historical variations in the price of land [29]. It is worth noting the modest investment in conservation forestry by a group of large private dehesa operations [20]. The private owner prefers to invest in land and livestock, which contribute in the short to medium term to increasing the available monetary profitability [29,31,32]. Plantations do not provide monetary benefits for the generation of the owner who undertakes the plantation. The high level of uncertainty associated with the generation of future profits from the plantation is the main factor underlying the uncertainty of the gain in net worth in the present for the future yield. However, the future owner who harvests the products of the historical plantations will be the beneficiary of the largest ordinary environmental operating margins, as the historical costs of the conservation forestry will have been amortized. In other words, the conservation of the HOW can be considered a public service, which is represented in this study by the landscape activity. In this context, the words of the editor of the influential publication ‘Our Common Future’ are of relevance with respect to the need for government to have consistent information on sustainable management and contributions of natural resources to the total income of the HOW when drawing up their policies: “Politics that disregard science and knowledge will not stand the test of time. Indeed, there is no other basis for sound political decisions than the best available scientific evidence. This is especially true in the fields of resource management and environmental protection” [33] (p. 457).

4.4. Does the SEEA-EEA Provide Concepts for Measuring Environmental Income?

From our perspective of the conceptualization of ecosystem accounting, it is necessary to admit the nature-based government activities, both direct and indirect. It makes little sense that an economic rationale should be admissible in the case of farmer activities but not the government public activities affected in their management and regulations by manufactured costs. The SEEA-EEA criterion which refers to the fact that “the production boundary is expanded relative to the SNA reflecting that the supply of goods and services by ecosystems is considered additional production” [12] (p. 88) is consistent from the perspective of including an ecosystem institutional sector only for public products consumption, without regulations and without government costs. In return, a debatable limitation is incurred; namely, the exclusion of the government sector which, in the case of the HOW, is an ecosystem service provider of similar importance to the farmers. Furthermore, it renders unnecessary the inclusion of a non-human institutional sector which provides free ordinary economic products to humans, independently of the farmers [16].
Our response to the question that provides the heading to this section is that we cannot know whether the SEEA-EEA in their current incipient stage of development will include standard guidelines for the nature-based government activities as a whole. If they were not included, the SEEA-EEA would not be able to measure the environmental income of ecosystems of the type valued at a national level which are produced with government manufactured costs.
The debate concerning the conceptual design of ecosystem accounting has so far centered on the valuations of ecosystem services and their respective environmental assets derived from the prices of transactions observed in formal or simulated markets based on consumer preferences. Although a detailed development of the SEEA-EEA accounting structure is not available, the reference of [16] (Table 6, p. 33) allows us to outline a provisional interpretation of the concept of extending the economic activities with respect to the SNA. These authors take into consideration the institutional sector of corporations (e.g., timber) and add the ecosystem public services produced without manufactured costs (e.g., air filtration). Should we understand, therefore, that the SNA valuation of public goods and services of nature-based government services is maintained at production cost and therefore the value of their ecosystem services is zero. This interpretation does not appear to be coherent, and we understand from what the authors state in the above cited reference that they are referring to an example of the application of the SEEA-EEA to two specific products, which cannot be generalized to embrace public products with manufactured production costs. It would also not make sense to present the values for products of the corporations and only the ecosystem services for the public products with and without manufactured production costs.
Since the purpose of the SEEA-EEA is to explicitly specify the valuations of the ecosystem services of ordinary individual products and their respective environmental assets, it can be concluded that the ultimate aim of the SEEA-EEA is the estimation of the environmental incomes of the individual economic activities valued for the ecosystem types of the spatial unit considered.
To date, the SEEA-EEA does not explicitly mention the environmental income of the ecosystems, but gives the measurements separately for the ecosystem services (ES) and the change in environmental asset (CEA) of the individual product. These two variables added together give the value of the environmental income, and depending on the specific accounting conventions of the environmental production and balance accounts, the CEA is adjusted in the case of certain individual products in order to give the adjusted change in environmental net worth (CNWead) according to the environmental work in progress used (WPeu), as we have shown in Section 2 and Supplementary Text S3. Thus, we arrive at the general expression of the environmental income (EI) as the sum of the ES and the CNWead of the individual product. All the information that we require to measure the environmental income is provided by the variables ES and EAg proposed by the authors of SEEA-EEA discussion papers ([16] Table 6, p.33, [34] Section 4.1, pp. 20–23). Other authors also implicitly estimate the environmental income, the value of the environmental assets depending on the discounted benefits (ecosystem services) and the capital gain (change in environmental asset) [35,36].
We can simplify the definition of the concept of environmental income as the value of the ecosystem service of a stationary state nature-based activity, given that in this situation the value of the CEA/CNWead is zero. Beyond the stationary state of the ecosystem activity, the EI represents the maximum possible consumption of the ES of the individual ecosystem product which we can permit without reducing its value at the opening of the period.
It seems strange that no SEEA-EEA applications have so far been produced by other authors which include measurements of ecosystem services for one or various ecosystem types and the respective changes in the environmental assets of the products incorporated in a single indicator such as the environmental income of the ecosystems and which is integrated in the standard SNA at national/regional scale. In [18], a simplified AAS application is presented comparing the results with our refined version of the SEEA-EEA sequence of accounts proposed by [16] (Table 6, p. 33). The application in [18] is based on the data from the production and balance accounts in this HOW study to develop the format of the sequences in [16], the purpose of which is to compare the refined rSNA, rSEEA-EEA, and simplified sAAS systems.
The AAS and rSNA applications in this study reveal that the measurement of environmental incomes in the HOW may be derived directly based on the total products that are generated by the activities valued in the HOW territory of Andalusia by the institutional sectors of the farmers and the government, the latter including the ecosystem sector of the SEEA-EEA.
The consistency of the comparisons of the AAS and rSNA results based on the theoretical concept of total income shows that the SNA can be extended with the ultimate aim of estimating the environmental income, (i) modifying the inconsistent application of the production cost in the valuation of products without market prices, substituting it for the marginal price of the simulated demand of active and passive consumers; and (ii) extending the measurement of society total income by incorporating the capital gain in the net value added (operating income).

4.5. Valuing the Ecosystem Service as a Residual Value

In the SEEA-EEA, independent estimates (not linked to the total income accounts) of ecosystem services and changes in the environmental assets risk incurring bias as regards remunerations of the manufactured incomes generated in the type of ecosystem valued. The fact that the ecosystem service is a residual value together with other operating incomes of a consumed product means that prior estimation is necessary of the priority remunerations for manufactured incomes of the individual ecosystem product valued. Ecosystem service estimates using non-residual procedures are common, and in these cases the situation may arise where the arbitrarily assigned value of the ecosystem service of a consumed product exceeds the value of its net value added, which would be a conceptually inconsistent result. For example, [37] estimate that if family-scale shepherds in Iteimia (Tunisia) with free access to grazing attributed themselves a remuneration for their self-employed work equal to 81% of that received by a local forestry worker. This implies that the ecosystem service of grazing would be dissipated. If the shepherds in Itemia were willing to work as employees, earning 60% of the current earnings of forest workers, the ecosystem service of grazing would be 0.07 €/UF o 36.95 €/ha. Other authors estimate the grazing resource rent as the energy substitute of the market price of barley, which would mean paying the self-employed wage rate at 38% of the forestry employee wage rate of 0.37 €/h at the time of the Iteimia study.

4.6. Policy Implications

In a world where the property rights over global goods and damages tend to be regulated, the divide as regards free public goods is diminishing. In other words, the economic accounts for global society should incorporate public products and costs appropriated directly or indirectly by the government, without market price, and produced within the national territory in the period, valuing them at simulated marginal prices derived from the active and passive consumer demand globally. However, the government institutions specialized in the regulations of the System of National Accounts (SNA) oppose the extension of the economic activities and the substitution of valuations of public and private products without market price at production cost for the simulated marginal value according to consumer demand. This situation has ultimately led to the public debate which has given rise to the satellite proposal in the process of the System of Environmental Economic Accounting-Experimental Ecosystem Accounting (SEEA-EEA) [12,13]. This subsidiarity of the SEEA-EEA with respect to the SNA can be avoided by extending the SNA with the ultimate goal of measuring the total income. The economic accounts of the global society make the existence of a satellite SEEA-EEA unnecessary as the former directly provides consistent measurements of the environmental income of the ecosystem types which exist in the national territory and the planet as a whole. In the absence of global compensations among governments for appropriated environmental products and assets of the ecosystems, the design and application of environmental accounts for ecosystem types, such as the HOW studied here, can be applied at national scale and multinational regional scales as the European Union.
Public consumers demand that farmers and governments maintain/improve the offer of public goods and services. This demand will continue increasing, although we will continue to see a process of internalization through the market for public goods and services in which the rights of economic use will change to a private property regime. In this double process of growth of government and market supply of nature-based products, there are technical and institutional factors which determine the local division of economic activities between corporations and government. The government will continue to take exclusive responsibility in cases where consumer exclusion is highly costly or where consumer exclusion is impossible due to the nature of the product; hence, such products will continue to be consumed freely by citizens [38]. In these circumstances, the government—in representation of the public consumers—compensates the owners for the unwanted loss of profit involved in meeting the demands of the public consumers, previously agreed with the government.
The payment of compensation should be linked to the existence of sustainable management practices with regard to renewable natural resources. Continual management which is often necessary for grazing land in the Mediterranean (scrub control, pruning, periodical sowing, etc.) is one of the necessary conditions for the conservation of the HOW cultural landscape. From this perspective, should payment be extended to owners where loss of profit occurs through any cultural practice favoring the many nature-based products such as game species, firewood from thinning/pruning, apiculture products, and free-access products such as wild mushrooms and asparagus? Government compensations with the ultimate goal of HOW conservation should be based on the concept of cultural landscape, for example, as defined by the [39], and payment to the owner should be legitimized having previously determined the consumers’ willingness to pay a tax for the services of cultural landscape conservation to a degree assumed bio-physically sustainable in the long term.
The government could use the landscape tax to finance the loss of profit not accepted by the owners of the land and livestock for HOW activities which produce intermediate services used as inputs in the production of additional public service provision. Thus, the thinning/pruning undertaken as part of landscape management should be compensated given the public benefits associated with cultural landscape conservation. Honey production should also be compensated for the intermediate services which it produces in the landscape, but only for the loss of profit not accepted by the hive owner. Compensation could be paid to owners where wild mushroom and asparagus picking takes place, on the condition that a plan agreed with the government is put in place which is proved to encourage future production for commercial or recreational picking.
According to the local institutional agreements reached, the owners may receive compensation without having to make additional investment for allowing mushroom/asparagus pickers access to the farm, although in such cases there would be no loss of commercial profit to the owner but there could be a loss of private amenity service for the non-industrial owner.
An illustrative example of the complexity involved in implementing agreed compensation policies is that of the exclusion from compensations of most of the areas of woody grazing in Spain. Compensations under the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) of the European Union continue to suffer from its philosophy based around livestock and crops, without conditioning these compensations to the sustainability of the management practices employed for renewable natural resources on the farms. This commercial principle in the CAP of dealing with the final agricultural and livestock products results in the intermediate outputs of managed wild grazing (fruit, leaves, and twigs) being ignored, as is the case of holm oak open woodland (HOW), where the fruit (acorns) and leaves/twigs from regeneration, pruning, etc. are consumed by game species, cattle, and other wild animals. This situation of ‘commodity tragedy’ under the CAP means that silvopastoral landscape grazing does not form part of the CAP, except indirectly through compensations for extensive husbandry. Grazing is also invisible in the net value added estimated in the government economic accounts for agriculture and forestry [6].
In a recent report analyzing the limitations of CAP direct payments for areas of woody pasture, the authors consider that the current guidelines of the CAP, which under certain circumstances recognize the right of HOW to compensation for livestock grazing, present limitations which should be mitigated by generalizing the compensations paid for woody grazing. The justification for this recommendation is that such a policy would clearly have favorable social, economic, and environmental effects [40].
The design of the CAP still does not explicitly include the payment of compensations for non-commercial intermediate products of the HOW which contribute to public goods and services consumed freely by European citizens. It would seem that the compensations under the CAP which indirectly affect the production of grazing in the HOW do not fulfill the criteria of equity and mitigation of the ‘free rider’ behavior of the active and passive consumers of HOW public products, while at the same time the standard of living of owners and employees is negatively impacted. The paradox of this decline in the commercial products of their farms is that it is taking place at the same time as the public products derived from the economic activities in the HOW are increasingly valued by public consumers.

5. Conclusions

The first conclusion which can be drawn from the results given in this article is that the valuations of ecosystem services and gross values added vary in those activities affected by the change in the type of valuation from producer prices to social price. The second conclusion is that the omission of the valuations of corporation activities producing non-commercial intermediate services (ISSnc) used by activities which are valued as own non-commercial intermediate consumption (SSncoo) also leads to variations in the aggregate values added of the farmer and government activities.
A general policy conclusion is that the challenge to be addressed by the government, in the name of current society and especially of future generations, is to overcome the current limitations in the functioning of market forces which make the investment by non-industrial private owners profitable, mainly through auto-consumption of amenities, without long term investment in woodland regeneration taking place, along with the policy of government compensations for extensive husbandry set apart from the public environmental income in silvopastoral landscapes, so that the aforementioned future generations are able to inherit the cultural and biological environmental assets of the HOW in good condition. Therefore, it is the government that must take care of landscape conservation with the purpose of avoiding the deterioration and/or complete disappearance of the natural and cultural variety of the HOW in all its different aspects, whether biophysical, anthropological, built historical patrimony, and testimonial uses of traditional skills which are attributed as being bearers of heritage values recognized by global society. In this case, the reference to ‘global society’ goes beyond Spanish society and should include at least the European Union member countries.
For this task, it is necessary to make available the best scientific knowledge for decision making to governments, consumers, and landowners. A methodology such as the Agroforestry Accounting System can contribute to informing governments on the ultimate goal of implementing policies with greater efficiency and equity in terms of preserving threatened nature and associated human culture without failing to meet the needs of current generations or deteriorating the non-reproducible environmental assets of our planet.

Supplementary Materials

The following are available online at https://www.mdpi.com/1999-4907/11/2/185/s1, Text S1: Background to holm oak open woodlands in West and South-West Spain, Text S2: Economic activities reconsidered, Text S3: Accounting methods applied to holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia, Text S4: Imputed own non-commercial intermediate consumption of services of holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia, Table S1: Tiles with predominant holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia, Table S2: Tiles with predominant holm oak open woodlands sizes characteristic in Andalusia, Table S3: Agroforestry Accounting System total production account at social prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha), Table S4: Agroforestry Accounting System ordinary and investment production accounts at social prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha), Table S5: Agroforestry Accounting System capital account for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha), Table S6: Agroforestry Accounting System produced and expected work in progress balance account for holm oak open woodland in Andalusia (2010: €/ha), Table S7: Agroforestry Accounting System simplified accounts sequence of total income at social prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha), Table S8: Refined System of National Accounts ordinary and investment production accounts at basic prices applied to holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha), Table S9: Refined System of National Accounts simplified accounts sequence of total income at basic prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha), Table S10: Agroforestry Accounting System and refined System of Nationals Accounts measurements at producer, basic and social prices of ecosystems services and incomes for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha), Figure S1: Agroforestry Accounting System simplified accounts sequence of total income factorial distribution at social prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia-(2010: €/ha), Figure S2: Agroforestry Accounting System total income at producer prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha), Figure S3: Map of Agroforestry Accounting System ecosystem services at producer prices by products and total for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia, Figure S4: Agroforestry Accounting System environmental income at producer prices per activity and total for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, P.C.; Data curation, P.C., A.Á., and B.M.; Formal analysis, P.C., A.Á., and B.M.; Funding acquisition, P.C.; Methodology, P.C.; Project administration, P.C.; Supervision, P.C.; Visualization, P.C. and A.Á.; Writing—original draft, P.C.; Writing—review and editing, P.C., A.Á., J.L.O., P.O., B.M., and A.C. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This study was funded by Agency for Water and Environment of the Regional Government of Andalusia, Contract NET 165602; Spanish National Research Council (CSIC), grant number ref. 201810E036; and European Union, call H2020-SC5-2018-1 (grant no. 817527).

Acknowledgments

The authors thank the Agency for Water and Environment of the Regional Government of Andalusia for the financial and field work support for the REnta y CApital de los Montes de ANdalucía (RECAMAN) project (Contract NET 165602), the Valoraciones de servicios y activos de AMenidades privadas de fincas SILvopastorales (VAMSIL) project of CSIC (ref. 201810E036) and the Mapping and Assessment for Integrated ecosystem Accounting (MAIA) project of EU call H2020-SC5-2018-1 (grant no. 817527). We acknowledge the contributions of Eloy Almazán and Begoña Álvarez-Farizo and other colleagues in the framework of the RECAMAN project to the methods and results presented in this study. We thank Daniel Jordan for helping us to review the English writing and the two reviewers for suggesting substantial improvements of the original version of this study.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Glossary of selected ecosystem accounting acronyms, concepts and definitions applied to the holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia, Spain.
CEA. Change in environmental asset: Difference between closing less opening environmental assets in the accounting period.
CFC. Consumption of fixed capital: Depreciation of the total opening capital embedded in total product in the accounting period.
CFCe. Consumption of environmental fixed capital (asset): Carbon environmental asset emission embedded in investment of environmental net operating margin valued at market price in the accounting period.
CFCm. Manufactured consumption of fixed capital: Depreciation of the manufactured fixed capital embedded in total product valued at replacement cost in the accounting period.
CG. Capital gain: Capital revaluation adjusted according specific convention to avoid double counting for the production account registers of carbon sequestration, woody product natural growth and consumption of manufactured fixed capital in the accounting period.
CGm. Manufactured capital gain: Manufactured fixed capital revaluation less manufactured fixed capital adjustments to avoid double counting according to consumption of manufactured fixed capital and the change in replacement prices of the manufactured fixed capital consumption in the accounting period.
CIm. Manufactured capital income: Remuneration received by the farmer for the services of the manufactured capital used in the accounting period.
CNWe. Change in environmental net worth: Depicts the difference between the environmental own-account gross capital formation and consumption of environmental fixed capital, adding the environmental asset gain.
CNWead. Adjusted change in environmental net worth: Adjustment to avoid double counting of the environmental work in progress used to show the ecosystem service as a component of the environmental income in the accounting period.
Cr. Capital revaluation: Change in values of the closing and withdrawals of environmental assets due to discounting effects and unanticipated price variation in the accounting period.
EAad. Environmental assets adjustments: Instrumental environmental asset gain adjustments to avoid double counting of opening natural growth and carbon sequestration embedded in theirs closing accumulated values in the accounting period.
EAg. Environmental asset gain: Expected (discount effect) and unexpected (extraordinary destructions) environmental asset revaluation (EAr) and accounting instrumental adjustment (EAad) at the closing of current period.
EAr. Environmental asset revaluation: Revaluation of the discounted expected future indefinite ecosystem services extractions and change in asset prices at the closing of the accounting period which were unanticipated at the opening.
EI. Environmental income: Economic contributions of nature in the accounting period embedded in current and future total product consumption. In ecosystem accounting terminology, environmental income is the environmental net operating margin plus environmental asset gain. This accounting identity of environmental income is equivalent to the ecosystem service plus (environmental work in progress used-adjusted) change in environmental net worth in the current period.
ES. Ecosystem services: The economic ‘gift’ contribution of nature embedded in the total product consumption in the accounting period. This definition is equivalent to the resource rent concept.
FPc. Final product consumption: Goods and services produced that are not accumulated as production factors of future total product consumption in the accounting period in the ecosystem type.
GVA. Gross value added: Operating gross income derived from the production factor services of human labor and capital user cost embedded in the total product in the accounting period. Operating income is also known as gross domestic product when referred to an economic sector, a region or a nation.
IC. Intermediate consumption: Raw materials (including environmental work in progress used) and services contributing as input (working capital) to generate the total product during the accounting period.
ICm. Manufactured intermediate consumption: Manufactured raw materials, services and working capital used during the accounting period to obtain the total product.
IRM. Intermediate product of raw materials: Goods (tangible items) produced in a spatial unit and/or ecosystem type and used as own working capital (re-employed) in the same period to produce another good or service in the same ecosystem type and/or spatial unit.
ISS. Intermediate product of services: Services (intangible items) produced in an ecosystem type and or spatial unit and used as own working capital (re-employed) in the same period to produce another good or service in the same ecosystem type and/or spatial unit.
ISSc. Commercial intermediate product of services: Intermediate product of services produced by manufactured commercial activities valued at market prices or production cost.
ISSncc. Non-commercial intermediate product of services: Intermediate product of services produced without market prices, valued in accordance with government compensation for farmer willingness to accept hunting and livestock ordinary monetary losses (as opportunity cost) in an ecosystem type and/or spatial unit during the current period and re-employed in the same period to produce another good or service in the same ecosystem type and/or spatial unit.
LC. Labor cost: Employee compensation for labor in the accounting period for the tasks derived from the economic activities, under the responsibility of the famer or the government activities funded by public expenditures.
NG. Natural growth: Accumulation of environmental work in progress during the current period valued at discounted environmental price (resource rent price) times physical growth (yield) expected to be extracted in future periods.
NOM. Net operating margin: Capital operating income embedded in total products in the accounting period.
NOMe. Environmental net operating margin: Environmental asset operating income embedded in total products in the accounting period.
NOMei. Investment environmental net operating margin: Environmental asset operating income embedded in the net natural growth measured as the natural growth less carbon emission in the accounting period.
NOMeo. Ordinary environmental net operating margin: Environmental asset operating income embedded in total product consumption in the accounting period.
NOMm. Manufactured net operating margin: Manufactured capital operating income embedded in total product consumption in the accounting period.
NOMmo. Ordinary manufactured net operating margin: Manufactured capital operating income embedded in total product consumption in the accounting period.
NVA. Net valued added: Operating net income derived from the production factors services of human labor and capital embedded in the total product in the accounting period. Operating income is also known as net domestic product when referred to an economic sector, a region or a nation.
SSncoo. Ordinary own non-commercial intermediate consumption of services: Private amenity activity intermediate consumption of services as amenity auto- consumption (SSncooa) and landscape activity intermediate consumption of services as compensation (SSncooc) and donation (SSncood) embedded in the total product consumption in the accounting period.
TI. Total income: Maximum possible total product consumption in the ecosystem type and/or spatial unit in the accounting period that leads to the closing total capital being the same as it was at the opening, in real terms, all else being unchanged.
TP. Total product: Goods and services produced by the economic activities in the ecosystem type and or spatial unit valued at observed or simulated transaction prices in the accounting period. Total product contains the intermediate product and the final product.
TPc. Total product consumption: Good or service produced in an ecosystem type and or spatial unit and destined for direct or indirect consumption by people in the accounting period, valued at observed and/or transaction prices. Total product consumption contains the intermediate product and the final product consumption.
WPeu. Environmental work in progress used: Woody unfinished environmental goods inventoried at the opening of the accounting period, which are environmental asset withdrawals used as environmental intermediate consumption embedded in the generation of total product consumption in the accounting period.

Appendix B

Table A1. Refined System of National Accounts total production account at basic prices applied to holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Table A1. Refined System of National Accounts total production account at basic prices applied to holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
ClassTimberCorkFirewoodNutsGrazingCon. ForestryResidentialAmenityFarmerFire ServicesRecreationMushroomsCarbonLandscapeBiodiversityWaterGovernmentHOW *
12345678∑1–89101112131415∑9–15∑1–15
1. Total product (TPbp)0.42.21.80.133.94.514.714.772.241.38.918.0n.a77.06.376.2227.8300.0
 1.1 Intermediate product (IPbp) 33.92.814.7 51.338.1 n.a 38.189.4
 1.2 Final product (FPpp)0.42.21.80.1 1.7 14.720.93.28.918.0n.a77.06.376.2189.7210.5
  1.2.1 Final product consumption (FPcpp)0.30.71.50.1 14.717.2 8.118.0n.a76.45.276.2189.3201.1
  1.2.2 Gross capital formation (GCF)0.11.50.3 1.7 3.63.20.80.1n.a0.71.1 5.89.4
   1.2.2.1 Manufactured (GCFm) 1.7 1.73.20.80.1n.a0.71.1 5.87.5
   1.2.2.2 Natural growth (NG)0.11.50.3 1.9 n.a 1.9
2. Intermediate consumption (ICbp)0.60.60.40.10.61.60.814.719.312.43.20.1n.a72.31.8 89.8109.1
 2.1 Manufactured intermediate consumption (ICm)0.40.00.20.10.61.60.814.718.312.43.20.1n.a72.31.8 89.8108.1
  2.1.1 Bought (ICmb)0.40.00.20.10.61.60.8 3.712.41.60.1n.a1.91.8 17.921.5
  2.1.2 Own (ICmobp) 14.714.7 1.6 n.a70.40.0 71.986.6
 2.2 Environmental work in progress used (WPeu)0.20.60.2 1.0 n.a 1.0
3. Consumption of fixed capital (CFC)0.0 0.00.01.10.15.6 6.82.81.60.0n.a0.70.6 5.712.6
 3.1 Manufactured (CFCm)0.0 0.00.01.10.15.6 6.82.81.60.0n.a0.70.6 5.712.6
 3.2 Environmental (CFCe) n.a
4. Net value added (NVAbp) (TPbp-ICbp-CFC)−0.21.61.4−0.132.32.98.3 46.026.24.117.9n.a4.03.876.2132.3178.3
 4.1. Labor cost (LC)2.50.10.30.93.42.83.1 13.126.14.10.1n.a4.03.8 38.251.3
 4.2. Net operating margin (NOMbp)−2.71.51.1−0.928.90.05.1 32.90.00.017.8n.a0.00.076.294.1127.0
  4.2.1 Manufactured (NOMmbp)−2.90.00.8−0.90.60.05.1 2.70.0n.an.an.an.an.a 0.12.8
  4.2.2 Environmental (NOMebp)0.11.50.3 28.3 n.a30.2 n.a17.8n.an.an.a76.294.0124.2
   4.2.2.1 Ordinary (NOMeo) 28.3 28.3 17.8n.a 76.294.4122.3
   4.2.2.2 Investment (NOMei)0.11.50.3 1.9 n.a 1.9
* HOW is holm oak open woodlands. n.a is not applicable in refined System of National Accounts (rSNA) methodology. Source: Own elaboration from primary data of RECAMAN project [17].

References

  1. European Commission. Our Life Insurance, Our Natural Capital: An EU Biodiversity Strategy to 2020; Committee on the Environment, Public Health and Food Safety: Brussels, Belgium, 2011; p. 17. Available online: http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52011DC0244&from=EN (accessed on 23 January 2018).
  2. European Commission. Report on Phase 1 of the Knowledge Innovation Project on an Integrated System of Natural Capital and Ecosystem Services Accounting in the EU (KIP-INCA Phase 1 Report); European Commission, European Environment Agency: Copenhagen, Denmark, 2016; p. 106. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/nature/capital_accounting/pdf/KIP_INCA_final_report_phase-1.pdf (accessed on 11 July 2019).
  3. Edens, B.; Hein, L. Towards a consistent approach for ecosystem accounting. Ecol. Econ. 2013, 90, 41–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. EFTEC. Developing UK Natural Capital Accounts: Woodland Ecosystem Accounts; Economics for the Environment Consultancy Ltd., Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (Defra): London, UK, 2015; p. 97. Available online: http://sciencesearch.defra.gov.uk/Default.aspx?Menu=Menu&Module=More&Location=None&Completed=0&ProjectID=18909 (accessed on 14 September 2017).
  5. European Commission; International Monetary Fund; Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development; United Nations; World Bank. System of National Accounts 2008 (SNA 2008); European Communities, International Monetary Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, United Nations, World Bank: New York, NY, USA, 2009; p. 722. Available online: http://unstats.un.org/unsd/nationalaccount/docs/SNA2008.pdf (accessed on 27 September 2017).
  6. European Communities. Manual on the Economic Accounts for Agriculture and Forestry EEA/EAF 97 (Rev. 1.1); EC, EUROSTAT: Luxembourg, Luxembourg, 2000; p. 172. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/documents/3859598/5854389/KS-27-00-782-EN.PDF/e79eb663-b744-46c1-b41e-0902be421beb (accessed on 14 September 2017).
  7. FAO. System of Environmental-Economic Accounting for Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries; Statistics, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations: New York, NY, USA, 2017; p. 138. Available online: http://www.fao.org/economic/ess/environment/methodology/en/ (accessed on 14 May 2019).
  8. Masiero, M.; Pettenella, D.; Boscolo, M.; Barua, S.K.; Animon, I.; Matta, J.R. Valuing Forest Ecosystem Services: A Training Manual for Planners and Project Developers; Forestry Working Paper 11; Licence: CC BY-NC-SA 3.0 IGO; FAO: Rome, Italy, 2019; p. 216. [Google Scholar]
  9. Obst, C.; Hein, L.; Edens, B. National Accounting and the Valuation of Ecosystem, Assets and Their Services. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2016, 64, 1–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Senado. Informe de la Ponencia de Estudio Sobre la Protección del Ecosistema de la Dehesa; Boletín Oficial de las Cortes Generales: Madrid, Spain, 2010; p. 27. Available online: http://www.senado.es/legis9/publicaciones/pdf/senado/bocg/I0553.PDF (accessed on 25 October 2019).
  11. United Nations. The Future We Want: Outcome Document Adopted at Rio + 20; United Nations: Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 2012; p. 49. Available online: http://www.un.org/disabilities/documents/rio20_outcome_document_complete.pdf (accessed on 2 October 2018).
  12. United Nations. Technical Recommendations in Support of the System of Environmental-Economic Accounting 2012–Experimental Ecosystem Accounting; United Nations: New York, NY, USA, 2017; Available online: https://seea.un.org/sites/seea.un.org/files/technical_recommendations_in_support_of_the_seea_eea_final_white_cover.pdf (accessed on 17 December 2018).
  13. United Nations, European Commission, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, World Bank Group. System of Environmental Economic Accounting 2012—Experimental Ecosystem Accounting [SEEA-EEA]; United Nations: New York, NY, USA, 2014; p. 198. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/documents/3859598/6925551/KS-05-14-103-EN-N.pdf (accessed on 14 September 2017).
  14. Hein, L.; Bagstad, K.J.; Obst, C.; Edens, B.; Schenau, S.; Castillo, G.; Soulard, F.; Brown, C.; Driver, A.; Bordt, M.; et al. Global progress in natural capital accounting. Science 2020, 367, 514–515. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  15. Atkinson, G.; Obst, C. Prices for Ecosystem Accounting; World Bank, Wealth Accounting and Valuation of Ecosystem Services: Washington, DC, USA, 2017; p. 38. Available online: https://www.wavespartnership.org/sites/waves/files/kc/Prices%20for%20ecosystem%20accounting.pdf (accessed on 2 October 2018).
  16. Van de Ven, P.; Obst, C.; Edens, B. Discussion Paper 5.3: Accounting Treatments When Integrating Ecosystem Accounts in the SNA; SEEA EEA Revision. Version Date: 22 November 2019. Expert Consultation. Working Group 5: Valuation and Accounting Treatments; Department of Economic and Social Affairs Statistics Division/United Nations: New York, NY, USA, 2019; p. 19. Available online: https://seea.un.org/sites/seea.un.org/files/documents/EEA/dp5.3_accounting_treatments_22nov2019.pdf (accessed on 20 January 2020).
  17. Campos, P.; Caparrós, A.; Oviedo, J.L.; Ovando, P.; Álvarez-Farizo, B.; Díaz-Balteiro, L.; Carranza, J.; Beguería, S.; Díaz, M.; Herruzo, A.C.; et al. Bridging the gap between national and ecosystem accounting application in Andalusian forests, Spain. Ecol. Econ. 2019, 157, 218–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Campos, P.; Oviedo, J.L.; Ovando, P.; Álvarez, A.; Mesa, B.; Caparrós, A. Agroforestry Accounting System for Measuring Environmental Incomes at Social Prices: Application to Holm Oak Open Woodlands in Andalusia-Spain; Instituto de Políticas y Bienes Públicos (IPP) CSIC: Madrid, Spain, 2019; p. 117. Available online: https://ipp.csic.es/sites/default/files/content/workpaper/2019/2019_06_ippwp_campos.pdf (accessed on 20 January 2020).
  19. Campos, P.; Caparrós, A.; Oviedo, J.L.; Ovando, P.; Álvarez, A.; Mesa, B. Measuring Environmental Incomes: System of National Accounts and Agroforestry Accounting System Applied to Cork Oak Open Woodlands in Andalusia, Spain; Instituto de Políticas y Bienes Públicos (IPP) CSIC: Madrid, Spain, 2019; p. 74. Available online: http://ipp.csic.es/sites/default/files/content/workpaper/2019/2019_04_ippwp_campos.pdf (accessed on 1 October 2019).
  20. Campos, P.; Álvarez, A.; Mesa, B.; Oviedo, J.L.; Ovando, P.; Caparrós, A. Uncovering the Hidden Ecosystem Services Embedded in Environmental Incomes: Testing Experimental Extended Accounts in Dehesas of Holm Oak Woodlands, Andalusia-Spain; Instituto de Políticas y Bienes Públicos (IPP) CSIC: Madrid, Spain, 2019; p. 91. Available online: http://ipp.csic.es/sites/default/files/content/workpaper/2019/2019_03_IPPwp_Campos.pdf (accessed on 1 October 2019).
  21. Cavendish, W. Quantitative methods for estimating the economic value of resource use to rural households. In Uncovering the Hidden Harvest-Valuation Methods for Woodland & Forest Resources; Cambell, B.M., Luckert, M.K., Eds.; Earthscan: London, UK, 2002; pp. 17–65. [Google Scholar]
  22. Sjaastad, E.; Angelsen, A.; Vedeld, P.; Bojö, J. What is environmental income? Ecol. Econ. 2005, 55, 37–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Montero, G.; Pasalodos-Tato, M.; López-Senespleda, E.; Ruiz-Peinado, R.; Bravo-Oviedo, A.; Madrigal, G.; Onrubia, R. Modelos de selvicultura y producción de madera, frutos y fijación de carbono de los sistemas forestales de Andalucía. In Economía y selviculturas de los montes de Andalucía; Campos, P., Díaz-Balteiro, L., Eds.; Memorias Científicas de RECAMAN; Memoria 1.2; Editorial CSIC: Madrid, Spain, 2015; Volume 1, pp. 153–396. Available online: http://libros.csic.es/product_info.php?products_id=987 (accessed on 27 April 2018).
  24. DGCN. Mapa Forestal de España 1:50.000. Ministerio de Medio Ambiente, Dirección General de Conservación de la Naturaleza: Madrid, Spain, 2008. Available online: https://www.miteco.gob.es/es/biodiversidad/servicios/banco-datos-naturaleza/informacion-disponible/mfe50.aspx (accessed on 11 July 2019).
  25. García, J.L.; Prólogo, I. Esperanza en la dehesa. In Manual para la Gestión Sostenible de las Dehesas Andaluzas; Alejano, R., Domingo, J.M., Fernández, M., Eds.; Foro para la defensa y conservación de la dehesa “Encinal”, Universidad de Huelva: Huelva, Spain, 2011; pp. 9–10. [Google Scholar]
  26. Campos, P.; Ovando, P.; Mesa, B.; Oviedo, J.L. Environmental income of livestock grazing on privately owned silvopastoral farms in Andalusia, Spain. J. Land. Degrad. Dev. 2016, 29, 250–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Caparrós, A.; Oviedo, J.L.; Álvarez, A.; Campos, P. Simulated Exchange Values and Ecosystem Accounting: Theory and Application to Recreation. Ecol. Econ. 2017, 139, 140–149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Caparrós, A.; Campos, P.; Montero, G. An operative framework for total Hicksian income measurement: Application to a multiple use forest. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2003, 26, 173–198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Ovando, P.; Campos, P.; Oviedo, J.L.; Caparrós, A. Ecosystem accounting for measuring total income in private and public agroforestry farms. For. Policy Econ. 2016, 71, 43–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Campos, P.; Oviedo, J.L.; Álvarez, A.; Mesa, B.; Caparrós, A. The role of non-commercial intermediate services in the valuations of ecosystem services: Application to cork oak farms in Andalusia, Spain. Ecosyst. Serv. 2019, 39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Oviedo, J.L.; Huntsinger, L.; Campos, P. Contribution of Amenities to Landowner Income: Case of Spanish and Californian Hardwood Rangelands. Ecol. Manag. 2017, 70, 518–528. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Ovando, P.; Campos, P.; Mesa, B.; Álvarez, A.; Fernández, C.; Oviedo, J.L.; Caparrós, A.; Álvarez-Farizo, B. Renta y capital de estudios de caso de fincas agroforestales de Andalucía. In Renta Total y Capital de las Fincas Agroforestales de Andalucía; Campos, P., Ovando, P., Eds.; Memorias científicas de RECAMAN; Memoria 4.2; Editorial CSIC: Madrid, Spain, 2015; Volume 4, pp. 156–445. Available online: http://libros.csic.es/product_info.php?products_id=990 (accessed on 27 April 2018).
  33. Brundtland, G.H. Editorial: The Scientific Underpinning of Policy. Science 1997, 277, 457. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Fenichel, E.P.; Obst, C. A Framework for the Valuation of Ecosystem Assets (Draft). Working Group 5: Valuation and Accounting Treatments; Discussion Paper 5.2; Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Statistics Division of United Nations: New York, NY, USA, 2019; p. 35. Available online: https://seea.un.org/sites/seea.un.org/files/documents/EEA/discussion_paper_5.2_valuation_ecosystem_assets_for_erg_aug_2019.pdf (accessed on 6 February 2020).
  35. Fenichel, E.P.; Abbott, J.K.; Bayham, J.; Boone, W.; Haacker, E.M.K.; Pfeiffer, L. Measuring the value of groundwater and other forms of natural capital. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2016, 113, 2382–2387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  36. Narita, D.; Lemenih, M.; Shimoda, Y.; Ayana, A.N. Economic accounting of ethiopian forests: A natural capital approach. For. Policy Econ. 2018, 97, 189–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Campos, P.; Daly, H.; Oviedo, J.L.; Ovando, P.; Chebil, A. Accounting for single and aggregated forest incomes: Application to public cork oak forests of Jerez in Spain and Iteimia in Tunisia. Ecol. Econ. 2008, 65, 76–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Mäler, K.; Aniyar, S.; Jansson, Å. Accounting for ecosystem services as a way to understand the requirements for sustainable development. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2008, 105, 9501–9506. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  39. Council of Europe. European Landscape Convention; European Treaty Series: Florence, Italy, 2000; p. 4. Available online: http://www.convenzioneeuropeapaesaggio.beniculturali.it/uploads/Council%20of%20Europe%20-%20European%20Landscape%20Convention.pdf (accessed on 27 September 2017).
  40. Ruiz, J.; Beaufoy, G.; Jiménez, R.; Majadas, J.; Sánchez, P.; Mantecas, C.; Lanchas, C.; Busqué, J.; Ferrer, V.; San Vicente, J.; et al. Informe Sobre la Elegibilidad para pagos Directos de la PAC de los Pastos Leñosos Españoles. Plataforma por la Ganadería Extensiva y el Pastoralismo; Fundación Entretantos: Valladolid, Spain, 2015; p. 225. Available online: http://www.ganaderiaextensiva.org/InformeElegibilidadPastos.pdf (accessed on 31 October 2019).
Figure 1. Total income accounting identities applied in holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia, Spain.
Figure 1. Total income accounting identities applied in holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia, Spain.
Forests 11 00185 g001
Figure 2. Agroforestry Accounting System farmer net value added at social prices of holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Figure 2. Agroforestry Accounting System farmer net value added at social prices of holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Forests 11 00185 g002
Figure 3. Agroforestry Accounting System total net value added at social prices of holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Figure 3. Agroforestry Accounting System total net value added at social prices of holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Forests 11 00185 g003
Figure 4. Agroforestry Accounting System ecosystem services at social prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Figure 4. Agroforestry Accounting System ecosystem services at social prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Forests 11 00185 g004
Figure 5. Agroforestry Accounting System adjusted change in environmental net worth for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Figure 5. Agroforestry Accounting System adjusted change in environmental net worth for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Forests 11 00185 g005
Figure 6. Agroforestry Accounting System ecosystem services change in environmental net worth adjusted according to WPeu and environmental incomes at social prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Figure 6. Agroforestry Accounting System ecosystem services change in environmental net worth adjusted according to WPeu and environmental incomes at social prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Forests 11 00185 g006
Figure 7. Agroforestry Accounting System total environmental income at producer prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia. Source: Eloy Almazán based on the [24].
Figure 7. Agroforestry Accounting System total environmental income at producer prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia. Source: Eloy Almazán based on the [24].
Forests 11 00185 g007
Figure 8. AAS and rSNA ecosystem services at social and basic prices comparison for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Figure 8. AAS and rSNA ecosystem services at social and basic prices comparison for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Forests 11 00185 g008
Figure 9. Comparison of AAS and rSNA environmental income at social and basic prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Figure 9. Comparison of AAS and rSNA environmental income at social and basic prices for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha).
Forests 11 00185 g009
Table 1. Agroforestry Accounting System total production account at social prices applied to holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha)
Table 1. Agroforestry Accounting System total production account at social prices applied to holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha)
Class.TimberCorkFirewoodNutsGrazingCon. forestryResidentialAmenityFarmerFire ServicesRecreationMushroomsCarbonLandscapeBiodiversityWaterGovernmentHOW *
12345678∑1–89101112131415∑9–15∑1–15
1. Total product (TPsp)0.42.21.80.133.94.514.7342.7400.241.331.818.041.8110.812.289.7345.7745.9
1.1 Intermediate product (IPsp) 33.92.814.7 51.338.1 38.189.4
1.2 Final product (FPpp)0.42.21.80.1 1.7 342.7348.93.231.818.041.8110.812.289.7307.5656.5
1.2.1 Final product consumption (FPcpp)0.30.71.50.1 342.7345.3 31.018.041.8110.211.289.7301.7647.0
1.2.2 Gross capital formation (GCF)0.11.50.3 1.7 3.63.20.80.1 0.71.1 5.89.4
1.2.2.1 Manufactured (GCFm) 1.7 1.73.20.80.1 0.71.1 5.87.5
1.2.2.2 Natural growth (NG)0.11.50.3 1.9 1.9
2. Intermediate consumption (ICsp)0.60.60.40.10.61.60.8137.9142.612.43.20.1 74.41.8 91.9234.5
2.1 Manufactured intermediate consumption (ICm)0.40.00.20.10.61.60.8137.9141.612.43.20.1 74.41.8 91.9233.5
2.1.1 Bought (ICmb)0.40.00.20.10.61.60.8 3.712.41.60.1 1.91.8 17.921.5
2.1.2 Own (ICmosp) 137.9137.9 1.6 72.50.0 74.0211.9
2.2 Environmental work in progress used (WPeu)0.20.60.2 1.0 1.0
3. Consumption of fixed capital (CFC)0.0 0.00.01.10.15.6 6.82.81.60.013.20.70.6 19.025.8
3.1 Manufactured (CFCm)0.0 0.00.01.10.15.6 6.82.81.60.0 0.70.6 5.712.6
3.2 Environmental (CFCe) 13.2 13.213.2
4. Net value added (NVAsp)−0.21.61.4−0.132.32.98.3204.8250.826.227.017.928.635.79.889.7234.8485.6
4.1. Labor cost (LC)2.50.10.30.93.42.83.1 13.126.14.10.1 4.03.8 38.251.3
4.2. Net operating margin (NOMsp)−2.71.51.1−0.928.90.05.1204.8237.70.022.917.828.631.75.989.7196.6434.3
4.2.1 Manufactured (NOMmsp)−2.90.00.8−0.90.60.05.1 2.70.01.30.0 0.20.2 1.74.4
4.2.2 Environmental (NOMesp)0.11.50.3 28.3 204.8235.0 21.617.828.631.55.889.7194.9429.9
4.2.2.1 Ordinary (NOMeo) 28.3 204.8233.1 21.617.841.831.55.889.7208.1441.2
4.2.2.2 Investment (NOMei)0.11.50.3 1.9 13.2 13.211.3
* HOW: holm oak open woodlands. Source: Own elaboration from RECAMAN project primary data [17].
Table 2. Agroforestry Accounting System opening capital of holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha)
Table 2. Agroforestry Accounting System opening capital of holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha)
ClassEnvironmental AssetManufactured CapitalOpening Capital
FarmerGovernmentTotalFarmerGovernmentTotalFarmerGovernmentTotal
Timber10.3 10.30.7 0.711.1 11.1
Cork38.1 38.11.0 1.039.1 39.1
Firewood210.8 210.80.1 0.1210.9 210.9
Nuts0.3 0.30.0 0.00.3 0.3
Grazing1051.0 1051.018.5 18.51069.5 1069.5
Grass and browse727.7 727.718.5 18.5746.1 746.1
Acorn74.0 74.0 74.0 74.0
Game grazing249.3 249.3 249.3 249.3
Con.forestry 10.0 10.010.0 10.0
Residential 455.1 455.1455.1 455.1
Amenity3521.6 3521.6 3521.6 3521.6
Fire services 44.644.6 44.644.6
Recreation 892.9892.9 40.540.5 933.3933.3
Mushrooms 591.0591.0 1.21.2 592.2592.2
Carbon 346.5346.5 346.5346.5
Landscape 1056.11056.1 2.72.7 1058.81058.8
Biodiversity 198.0198.0 3.83.8 201.8201.8
Water 1467.91467.9 1467.91467.9
Total4832.24552.49384.6485.492.9578.25317.64645.29962.8
Table 3. Agroforestry Accounting System total capital account of holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha)
Table 3. Agroforestry Accounting System total capital account of holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010: €/ha)
Class1. Opening Capital2. Capital Entry3. Capital Withdrawal4. Revaluation5. Closing Capital
2.1 Bought2.2 Own2.3 Other2.4 Total3.1 Used3.2 Sales3.2 Destructions3.3. Reclassifications3.4 Other3.5 Total
(Co)(Ceb)(Ceoo)(Ceot)(Ce)(Cwu)(Cws)(Cwd)(Cwrc)(Cwot)(Cw)(Cr) (Cc)
1. Environmental asset9384.6 1.941.843.71.0 42.413.256.7−136.69235.0
 1.1 Farmer4832.2 1.9 1.91.0 1.9 2.9−150.44680.9
  1.1.1 Timber10.3 0.1 0.10.2 0.1 0.30.710.9
  1.1.2 Cork38.1 1.5 1.50.6 1.4 2.02.740.3
  1.1.3 Firewood210.8 0.3 0.30.2 0.3 0.59.3219.8
  1.1.4 Nuts0.3 0.00.3
  1.1.5 Grazing1051.0 2.01053.0
   1.1.5.1 Grass and browse727.7 727.7
   1.1.5.2 Acorn74.0 2.076.0
   1.1.5.3 Game grazing249.3 249.3
  1.1.6 Amenity3521.6 −165.13356.6
 1.2 Government4552.4 41.841.8 40.613.253.813.84554.1
  1.2.1 Recreation892.9 892.9
  1.1.2 Mushrooms591.0 591.0
  1.1.3 Carbon346.5 41.841.8 40.613.253.813.8348.3
  1.1.4 Landscape1056.1 1056.1
  1.1.5 Biodiversity198.0 198.0
  1.1.6 Water1467.9 1467.9
2. Manufactured578.20.47.5 7.9 0.0 0.0−34.4551.8
 2.1 Farmer485.4 1.7 1.7 −27.9459.3
  2.1.1 Plantations10.2 1.7 1.7 −0.211.8
  2.1.2 Constructions475.2 −27.7447.5
 2.2 Government92.80.45.8 6.2 0.0 0.0−6.692.5
  2.1.1 Plantations 0.0 0.0 0.00.0
  2.1.2 Constructions75.6 4.1 4.1 −5.074.8
  2.1.3 Equipment2.80.4 0.4 0.0 0.0−0.13.1
  2.1.4 Others14.4 1.7 1.7 −1.414.6
Total (1 + 2)9962.80.49.441.851.71.0 0.042.413.256.7−171.09786.8
Table 4. Agroforestry Accounting System and refined standard System of National Accounts ecosystem services and gross value-added index comparisons for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010).
Table 4. Agroforestry Accounting System and refined standard System of National Accounts ecosystem services and gross value-added index comparisons for holm oak open woodlands in Andalusia (2010).
ClassTimberCorkFirewoodNutsGrazingConserv. ForestryResidentialAmenityFarmerFire ServicesRecreationMushroomsCarbonLandscapeBiodiversityWaterGovernmentHolm Oak Open Woodlands
12345678∑1–89101112131415∑9–15∑1–15
Ecosystem services
ESpp,AAS/ESsp,AAS1.01.01.00.01.0 1.61.5 1.01.01.01.01.01.01.01.3
ESbp,AAS/ESsp,AAS1.01.01.00.01.0 1.61.5 1.01.01.01.01.01.01.01.3
ESbp,rSNA/ESsp,AAS1.01.01.00.01.0 n.a0.1 n.a1.0n.an.an.a0.90.50.3
ESpp,rSNA/ESpb,rSNA1.01.01.00.01.0 n.a1.0 n.a1.0n.an.an.a1.01.01.0
Gross value added
GVApp,AAS/GVAsp, AAS1.01.01.01.01.01.01.01.61.51.01.01.01.01.91.01.01.11.3
GVAbp,AAS /GVAsp,AAS1.01.01.01.01.01.01.01.61.51.01.01.01.01.11.01.01.01.2
GVAbp,rSNA/GVAsp,AAS1.01.01.01.01.01.01.00.00.21.00.21.0n.a0.10.40.90.50.4
GVApp,rSNA/GVAbp,rSNA1.01.01.01.01.01.01.00.01.01.01.01.0n.a1.01.01.01.01.0
sp—social prices; bp—basic prices; pp—producer prices. n.a is not applicable in rSNA methodology.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Campos, P.; Álvarez, A.; Oviedo, J.L.; Ovando, P.; Mesa, B.; Caparrós, A. Income and Ecosystem Service Comparisons of Refined National and Agroforestry Accounting Frameworks: Application to Holm Oak Open Woodlands in Andalusia, Spain. Forests 2020, 11, 185. https://doi.org/10.3390/f11020185

AMA Style

Campos P, Álvarez A, Oviedo JL, Ovando P, Mesa B, Caparrós A. Income and Ecosystem Service Comparisons of Refined National and Agroforestry Accounting Frameworks: Application to Holm Oak Open Woodlands in Andalusia, Spain. Forests. 2020; 11(2):185. https://doi.org/10.3390/f11020185

Chicago/Turabian Style

Campos, Pablo, Alejandro Álvarez, José L. Oviedo, Paola Ovando, Bruno Mesa, and Alejandro Caparrós. 2020. "Income and Ecosystem Service Comparisons of Refined National and Agroforestry Accounting Frameworks: Application to Holm Oak Open Woodlands in Andalusia, Spain" Forests 11, no. 2: 185. https://doi.org/10.3390/f11020185

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop