Next Article in Journal
Influence of Background Voltage Distortion on Operation of Passive Harmonic Compensation Devices
Previous Article in Journal
Numerical Simulation on Two-Phase Ejector with Non-Condensable Gas
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Governance of Greenwashing Behaviors: A Perspective of Heterogeneous Firm Types

1
School of Management Science and Engineering, Nanjing University of Information Science & Technology, Nanjing 210044, China
2
Institute of Climate Economy and Low-Carbon Industry, Nanjing University of Information Science & Technology, Nanjing 210044, China
3
School of Finance, Central University of Finance and Economics, Beijing 100081, China
4
School of Applied Technology, Nanjing University of Information Science & Technology, Nanjing 210044, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2024, 17(6), 1340; https://doi.org/10.3390/en17061340
Submission received: 11 January 2024 / Revised: 28 February 2024 / Accepted: 1 March 2024 / Published: 11 March 2024
(This article belongs to the Section B: Energy and Environment)

Abstract

:
Corporate greenwashing in response to carbon neutrality strategies has received substantial academic attention. Distinct from previous studies, this paper establishes a differential game model incorporating both green and brown enterprise types. The model compares greenness and total profits under two government scenarios: subsidies for green enterprises and the regulation of brown enterprises. It further analyzes the mechanism behind brown enterprise greenwashing formation. The results show that subsidies alone encourage brown enterprises to engage in greenwashing. However, government regulation inhibits such behaviors, with the inhibition effect positively correlated to regulatory intensity. Consumers’ green perception of enterprises also significantly drives brown enterprise greenwashing degrees. Higher green enterprise perception coefficients reduce greenwashing, while higher brown enterprise perception coefficients increase it. Differential game and simulation analyses reveal that greenwashing governance should consider both direct policy effects on brown enterprises and indirect subsidy effects on green enterprises.

1. Introduction

Carbon neutrality has become an important global initiative in response to climate change and energy transformation. In China, the 20th National Congress of the Communist Party further emphasized actively yet prudently promoting ‘dual-carbon’ targets, presenting new requirements for corporate environmental practices. From a purchase decision perspective, as environmental issues become more prominent, public awareness has grown, and stakeholders have strengthened environmental considerations [1]. Consumers desire green products and experience spillover effects from pro-environmental behaviors, increasing a willingness to pay green premiums [2]. On the production side, green consumer preferences may compel producers and suppliers to enhance product greenness [3]. For instance, energy companies face increasing stakeholder pressure to provide sustainable and clean energy products [4]. With ESG investment growth, companies now emphasize ESG performance to build responsible green development reputations favored by markets and consumers.
However, when actively implementing carbon neutrality and responding to purchase decisions, some enterprises have engaged in ‘greenwashing’, exaggerating ESG efforts and contributions, especially regarding environmental protection, through false or misleading information [5]. Such behaviors damage corporate reputations and stock performance while negatively impacting consumer purchases, creating a ‘lemon market’ problem [6]. Examples such as Volkswagen, Northern Pharmaceutical, Coca-Cola, Nike, and Allbirds highlight the urgent need for governance.
Current research on governing corporate greenwashing as a critical environmental policy issue has attracted substantial academic attention. The relevant literature focuses on:
  • Green behavior game research. Domestic and foreign scholars have expanded green technology innovation research to green supply chain management, examining how chains can provide green products meeting environmental and sustainability needs [7]. Game models are increasingly applied in green supply chain research, with evolutionary games used to simulate collaborative emission-reduction stability trends [8] and explore emerging corporate green behaviors [9]. However, evolutionary games use static frameworks without considering corporate operational continuity. Some scholars have since studied green supply chain issues under a dynamic framework using differential game models [10]. Ma used a differential game for manufacturing-retailer technological investment and cooperation strategy decisions [11].
  • Greenwashing motivation analysis. Different perspectives have been used to study motivations. From a neoclassical economics view, enterprises are profit-seeking, maximizing self-interest and minimizing costs. Thus, greenwashing is a rational corporate strategy development choice influenced by competitive pressures and opportunities [12]. Environmental policy requirements [13] and consumer demand [3] have become important greenwashing drivers. From an information economics view, consumers have limited green market cognition, causing information asymmetry [14]. Imperfect regulations enable greenwashing through certification loopholes [15]. A stakeholder view categorizes motivations as external market/non-market factors (consumers, policies, etc.) [16,17] and internal factors such as age, size, debt, performance, and values [18]. Stakeholder activism also motivates greenwashing [19].
  • Greenwashing governance research. Environmental certifications and reductions provide constraints, but governance relies on government actions [20,21]. As corporate behaviors, experts apply market failure, natural monopoly, and information asymmetry theories to study greenwashing market rules. Governments can regulate to maintain stability. Under ideal conditions, enterprises adopt environmental philosophies within policy goals [22]. Research shows that green credit governance effectively deters greenwashing [13], while central inspections reduce misconduct, indicating that standardized central governance is needed [23]. Some current research focusing on addressing greenwashing emphasizes the effects of third-party certification [24]. Certification standards and systems have provided recognized benchmarks for green market competition and corporate sustainability to some innovative extent, but apparently, such labels and certifications have little effect on the market order under conditions of market competition and regulatory absence [25]. Therefore, strictly regulating certification systems, strengthening supervision and publicity, and increasing monitoring channels will be key to enhancing the authority and credibility of green certifications and strengthening consumer awareness and governance of corporate greenwashing [26].
Media oversight also plays an important role in eliminating greenwashing companies. Media coverage as a form of external supervision can have an inhibitory effect on greenwashing behaviors [27]. However, current governance of greenwashing remains “joint” governance rather than “collaborative” governance. When cooperation between the government and media is strengthened, corporate hidden behaviors will be inhibited, improving the effectiveness of greenwashing governance and achieving “synergy” [28].
The above literature indicates that establishing government regulatory systems is critical for greenwashing governance. However, even in developed countries with relatively strong environmental awareness like the United States, monitoring involves uncertain enforcement [16]. Such non-binding guidelines are insufficient to protect consumers from greenwashing harm [29]. In China, punitive regulations provide policy support to curb illegal greenwashing, yet industries still exaggerate or mislead in online green marketing claims. Thus, governance may require considering regulatory intensity, and monitoring should be supplemented with other approaches.
In summary, existing research has conducted beneficial greenwashing governance exploration, laying the foundation for this study. Using a Stackelberg differential game model, this paper examines greenwashing governance from a green supply chain perspective, incorporating corporate heterogeneity and government governance modes. First, internal greenwashing motivations are important. Different stakeholder pressures [30], political relationships [31] and environmental awareness [32] determine green strategy preferences. Thus, this paper divides enterprises into green firms that do not greenwash and brown firms that may greenwash for profit. Second, different government approaches such as subsidies and regulations are incorporated into the model.
Marginal innovations versus the existing literature include: (1) Unlike models with a single enterprise type [33,34], this paper incorporates heterogeneity, as policies targeting one type may also impact others’ greenwashing, informing anti-greenwashing policies. (2) Most research uses static frameworks [35,36], while this paper introduces a differential game model studying greenwashing formation, adding upstream suppliers for practical governance insights. (3) Whereas studies conclude that subsidies benefit low-carbon enterprises, encouraging their use [37], this research finds that subsidies alone may increase brown enterprise greenwashing.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 outlines the modeling assumptions. Section 3 analyzes and discusses the equilibrium results from modeling three periods. Section 4 simulates the equilibrium results of different decision models through numerical simulation and discusses the factors influencing green drift. Finally, Section 5 concludes the paper and offers policy recommendations.

2. Model Assumptions

First, the following assumptions are made for the model:
Assumption 1.
Considering corporate heterogeneity, this paper studies a green supply chain with one manufacturer (green enterprise U) and one retailer (brown enterprise D). Manufacturer U provides green products on a wholesale basis to retailer D. Retailer D sells both U’s green products and its own non-green brands with lower greenness. Consumer purchases are influenced by factors including price, green perception, and brand reputation.
Assumption 2.
U’s greenness level for its products is g U ( t ) , t [ 0 , ) , g D ( t ) g U ( t ) , and U’s wholesale price is P . D’s greenness level is g D . D’s sale price for its own brand is P D ( t ) = α g D ( t ) , and for U’s green product it is P U ( t ) = β g U ( t ) . Fixed costs for U and D are unchanged. With green R&D investment as the focus, other costs such as equipment and labor are not yet considered. Thus, marginal costs are C U = c U g U ( t ) , C D = c D g D ( t ) .
Assumption 3.
D’s greenwashing variable is based on the nature and form of greenwashing. Some companies invest in green marketing to be perceived as environmentally friendly despite limited environmental performance. They advertise to improve purchase intentions and brand attitudes [38]. “Greenwashing” refers to misleading consumers about a company’s environmental practices or a product’s benefits [16]. There are two forms: making green claims and executing greenwashing. Most literature examines making claims, while executing greenwashing is less studied [39]. D can influence green perceptions and reputation via promotions [40]. Since making claims is prevalent, this paper introduces false advertising intensity as the greenwashing variable measuring the degree of greenwashing. D controls its false green promotion level A ( t ) , with costs 1 2 ρ A ( t ) 2 [41].
Assumption 4.
D’s false promotion positively impacts its brand reputation [40]. Brand image (reputation) dynamics are denoted by G ( t ) , with dynamics [42]:
G ( t ) · = θ A ( t ) δ G ( t ) ,       G ( 0 ) = G 0 > 0
where G ( t ) denotes the brand reputation of green products at time t, and θ > 0 is a positive parameter measuring the impact of D’s degree of greenwashing on the brand image; δ > 0 is the decay rate of the brand image.
Assumption 5.
Consumers’ choices are influenced by their green perception of the product. Green perception is positively correlated with green value and marketing [43]. Consumers’ green perceptions for the two enterprises are: S U ( t ) = k 1 g U ( t ) , where k are positive parameters measuring consumers’ own green perception coefficients for the products.
Assumption 6.
Demand Q negatively depends on price P ( t ) and the environmental reputation (green reputation) G ( t ) of the competing enterprise, and it positively depends on its own environmental reputation (green reputation) G ( t ) . It is also influenced by competition between U’s product and D’s own brand. The demand functions for U and D take the following linear forms [41]:
Q U ( g U , A , G , P U ) = γ [ S U ( t ) S D ( t ) ] G ( t ) P U ( t )
Q D ( g U , A , G , P U ) = φ [ S D ( t ) S U ( t ) ] + G ( t ) P D ( t )
where γ , φ are the competition coefficients between the two commodities.
Based on the above assumptions, the objective functions of the green enterprise and brown enterprise are:
max g U π U = 0 e r t P C U Q U d t
max A , g D π D = 0 e r t P D C D P Q D 1 2 ρ A 2 d t

3. Model Construction and Solution

3.1. Benchmark Model under Free Competition (Model B)

The benchmark model considers the situation without government regulation, where the market only has a green enterprise and a brown enterprise as decision makers, both aiming to maximize their own profits. The objective functions of the two enterprises are:
max g U π U = 0 e r t P C U Q U d t
max A , g D π D = 0 e r t P D C D P Q D 1 2 ρ A 2 d t
Proposition 1.
  • The optimal greenness trajectory of the brown enterprise is g D B = ( 1 k 2 ) k 1 γ + α φ 2 β ( α     k 1 γ ) ( β     c d ) e r t k 1 + α ( P   α k 1 ) + ( 1   +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 ) , the optimal greenness trajectory of the green enterprise is g D B = ( 1 k 1 ) α k 1 γ + ( P α k 1 γ ) 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1   c d ) e r t + ( 1   k 1 γ +   k 2 ) α k 2 γ φ 2 θ k 1 ;
  • The degree of greenwashing by the brown enterprise is A B = ( P   k 1 γ ) φ + α ( θ k 1   c d ) + θ 2 β 2 ( α     k 1 γ ) + P   α k 1 β   k 2 φ 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 ) ;
  • The optimal trajectory of the brand reputation of the brown enterprise is G B = [ G 0 θ δ A ] e δ t + θ δ A ;
  • The optimal profit value function of the green enterprise is V D B ( G ) = m 1 B G 2 - m 2 B G + m 3 B , V U B ( G ) = t 1 B G 2 - t 2 B G + t 3 B , where m B , t B in proof.
Proof 1.
The Hamiltonian function of Enterprise D is:
r V D ( G ) = max A , g D ( P D C D P ) Q D 1 2 ρ A 2 + V D ( θ A δ G )
Taking the partial derivatives of A and g D , respectively, in the above equation and setting them to 0 yields:
A = θ V D     g D k 2 φ ( P   α g D   +   c D g D ) ρ
g D ( t ) = G     g U k 1 φ 2 ( α     A k 2 φ ) + P 2 ( α     c D )
The Hamiltonian function of Enterprise U is:
r V U ( G ) = max g U ( P C U ) Q U + V U ( θ A δ G )
Substituting the above two equations into the Hamiltonian function of Enterprise U, taking the partial derivative of g U and setting it to 0 yields:
g U ( t ) = P 2 c U G   +   γ A   g D k 2 2 ( β     k 1 γ )
Combining g U , g D and A yields:
g U = P   3 k 1 2 ( β   k 2 φ ) k 1 + α V U + ( 1   +   k 2 ) φ + G 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 )
g D = ( 1 k 1 ) α φ V U + α V D + ( P α k 1 γ ) G + k 2 β   k 2 φ
A = ( P   k 1 γ ) φ + α V D + θ 2 β ( α     k 1 γ ) + P α k 2 γ β   k 2 φ
Substitute A , g U and g D back into the Hamiltonian functions of Enterprise U and Enterprise D:
r V D ( G ) = φ α V U + G + ( α + 1 ) φ V D + θ α     k 1 γ + P θ k 1 φ V U + V D + G 2 β G V D + β k 1 + ( 1 P ) ( φ G ) ( 1 k 2 ) V U + α φ V D 2 β ( α     k 1 γ ) ( β     c D )
r V U ( G ) = β V U + ( 1   k 1 γ ) φ + α V D α   + P   k 1 γ + ( P   α k 1 ) V U β   k 2 φ + α k 1 + ( 1 P ) β 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 ) + ( 1 γ ) V U V D β ( 1 P ) ( P α k 1 γ )
Let: V D B ( G ) = m 1 B G 2 - m 2 B G + m 3 B , V U B ( G ) = t 1 B G 2 - t 2 B G + t 3 B .
Substituting into the Hamiltonian equations and solving by the undetermined coefficients method yields:
m 1 B = P   k 1   k 2 ( P α k 1 γ ) θ k 1 + ( 1   k 1 γ +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 β   k 2 φ ) m 2 B = ( 1 γ ) α + k 1 γ β ( 1 P ) ( P α k 1 γ ) m 3 B = ( P   k 1 γ ) φ + 2 α β + θ 2 β ( α     k 1 γ + φ 2 ) t 1 B = α κ 1 + ( 1   k 1 γ +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 ) + φ α + ( k 1 γ + 1 ) φ + θ β ( 1 P ) ( φ 2 β ) t 2 B = β + ( 1   k 1 γ ) φ α φ 2   k 1 γ + P   α k 1 β t 3 B = 0
Substituting back into A , g U and g D yields the optimal decision functions of Enterprise U and Enterprise D:
g U = ( 1 k 2 ) k 1 γ + α φ 2 β ( α     k 1 γ ) ( β     c D ) e r t k 1 + α ( P   α k 1 ) + ( 1   +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 )
g D = ( 1 k 1 ) α k 1 γ + ( P α k 1 γ ) 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1   c D ) e r t + ( 1   k 1 γ +   k 2 ) α k 2 γ φ 2 θ k 1
A = ( P   k 1 γ ) φ + α ( θ k 1   c D ) + θ 2 β 2 ( α     k 1 γ ) + P   α k 1 β   k 2 φ 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 )
The optimal value functions of Enterprise U and Enterprise D can be expressed as:
V D ( G ) = P   k 1   k 2 ( P α k 1 γ ) θ k 1 + ( 1   k 1 γ +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 β   k 2 φ ) G 2 - ( 1 γ ) α + k 1 γ β ( 1 P ) ( P α k 1 γ ) G + ( P   k 1 γ ) φ + 2 α β + θ 2 β ( α     k 1 γ + φ 2 )
V U ( G ) = [ α k 1 + ( 1   k 1 γ +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 ) + φ α + ( k 1 γ + 1 ) φ + θ β ( 1 P ) ( φ 2 β ) ] G 2 [ β + ( 1   k 1 γ ) φ α φ 2   k 1 γ + P   α k 1 β ] G
The optimal trajectory of the green supply chain reputation is:
G ( t ) = [ G 0 θ δ A ] e δ t + θ δ A
Through the above process, the conclusion in Proposition 1 can be proved. □

3.2. Government Subsidy Model for Green Enterprises (Model S)

In the government subsidy model for green enterprises, the government provides a subsidy S to enterprises assessed as green factories and publicizes the list of green factories, i.e., providing cost-free promotion AG to green enterprises. The green perception of consumers for the upstream enterprise is S U S ( t ) = k 1 g U ( t ) A G . The objective functions of the two enterprises are:
max g U π U = 0 e r t P C U Q U + S d t
max A , g D π D = 0 e r t P D C D P Q D 1 2 ρ A 2 d t
Proposition 2.
  • The optimal greenness trajectory of the brown enterprise is g D S = ( 1 k 2 ) k 1 A G γ + α φ 2 β ( α     k 1 A G γ ) ( β     c d ) e r t k 1 + α ( P   α k 1 A G ) + ( 1   +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 A G ) , the optimal greenness trajectory of the green enterprise is g D S = ( 1 k 1 ) α k 1 A G γ + ( P α k 1 A G γ ) 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 A G   c d ) e r t + ( 1   k 1 A G γ +   k 2 ) α k 2 γ φ 2 θ k 1 A G ;
  • The degree of greenwashing by the brown enterprise is A S = ( P   k 1 A G γ ) φ + α ( θ k 1 A G   c d ) + θ 2 β 2 ( α     k 1 A G γ ) + P   α k 1 A G β   k 2 φ 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 A G ) ;
  • The optimal trajectory of the brand reputation of the brown enterprise is G S = [ G 0 θ δ A ] e δ t + θ δ A ;
  • The optimal profit value function of the green enterprise is V D S ( G ) = m 1 S G 2 - m 2 S G + m 3 S , V U S ( G ) = t 1 S G 2 - t 2 S G + t 3 S .
Proof 2.
The Hamiltonian function of Enterprise D is:
r V D ( G ) = max A , g D ( P D C D P ) Q D 1 2 ρ A 2 + V D ( θ A δ G )
Taking the partial derivatives of A and g D , respectively, and setting them to 0 yields:
A = θ V D     g D k 2 φ ( P   α g D   +   c D g D ) ρ
g D ( t ) = G     A G g U k 1 φ 2 ( α     A k 2 φ ) + P 2 ( α     c D )
The Hamiltonian function of Enterprise U is:
r V U ( G ) = max g U ( P C U ) Q U + S + V U ( θ A δ G )
Substituting the above two equations into the Hamiltonian function of Enterprise U, taking the partial derivative of g U and setting it to 0 yields:
g U ( t ) = P 2 c U G   +   γ A   g D k 2 2 ( β   A G k 1 γ )
Following the same steps as in Section 3.1, the optimal decision functions of Enterprise U and Enterprise D are:
g U = ( 1 k 2 ) A G k 1 γ + α φ 2 β ( α     k 1 A G γ ) ( β     c D ) e r t k 1 + α ( P   α k 1 A G ) + ( 1   +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 θ k 1 A G )
g D = ( 1 k 1 ) α A G k 1 γ + ( P α A G k 1 γ ) 2 ( φ 2 θ A G k 1   c D ) e r t + ( 1   A G k 1 γ +   k 2 ) α k 2 γ φ 2 θ k 1
A = ( P   A G k 1 γ ) φ + α ( θ A G k 1   c D ) + θ 2 β 2 ( α     A G k 1 γ ) + P   α A G k 1 β   k 2 φ 2 ( φ 2 θ A G k 1 )
The optimal value functions of Enterprise U and Enterprise D can be expressed as:
m 1 S = P   k 1 A G   k 2 ( P α A G k 1 γ ) θ A G k 1 + ( 1   A G k 1 γ +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 β   k 2 φ ) m 2 S = ( 1 γ ) α + k 1 γ β ( 1 P ) ( P α k 1 γ ) m 3 S = ( P   A G k 1 γ ) φ + 2 α β + θ 2 β ( α     A G k 1 γ + φ 2 ) t 1 S = α A G k 1 + ( 1   A G k 1 γ +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 θ A G k 1 ) + φ α + ( A G k 1 γ + 1 ) φ + θ β ( 1 P ) ( φ 2 β ) t 2 S = β + ( 1   A G k 1 γ ) φ α φ 2   A G k 1 γ + P   A G α k 1 β t 3 S = S
V D ( G ) = P   k 1 A G   k 2 ( P α A G k 1 γ ) θ A G k 1 + ( 1   A G k 1 γ +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 β   k 2 φ ) G 2 - ( 1 γ ) α + A G k 1 γ β ( 1 P ) ( P α A G k 1 γ ) G + ( P   A G k 1 γ ) φ + 2 α β + θ 2 β ( α     A G k 1 γ + φ 2 )
V U ( G ) = [ α A G k 1 + ( 1   A G k 1 γ +   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 θ A G k 1 ) + φ α + ( A G k 1 γ + 1 ) φ + θ β ( 1 P ) ( φ 2 β ) ] G 2 [ β + ( 1   A G k 1 γ ) φ α φ 2   A G k 1 γ + P   A G α k 1 β ] G + S
The optimal trajectory of the green supply chain reputation is:
G ( t ) = [ G 0 θ δ A ] e δ t + θ δ A
Through the above process, the conclusion in Proposition 2 can be proved. □

3.3. Government Regulation Model for Brown Enterprises (Model R)

In the government regulation model for brown enterprises, enterprises are legally required to disclose environmental information. The government as regulator randomly inspects brown enterprises with probability p, discloses any misconduct, and imposes fines C p if greenwashing is found. In this stage, consumers’ green perception of the brown enterprise’s own brand is S D R ( t ) = ( 1 p ) k 2 g D ( t ) A ( t ) . The brand reputation dynamics for the brown enterprise D are G ( t ) = [ θ p ] A ( t ) δ G ( t ) . The objective functions of the two enterprises are:
max g U π U = 0 e r t P C U Q U d t
max A , g D π D = 0 e r t P D C D P Q D 1 2 ρ A 2 C p d t
Proposition 3.
  • The optimal greenness trajectory of the brown enterprise is g D R = ( 1 ( 1 p )   k 2 ) k 1 γ + α φ 2 β ( α     k 1 γ ) ( β     c D ) e r t - k 1 + α ( P   α k 1 ) + ( 1   +   ( 1 p )   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 [ θ p ] k 1 ) , the optimal greenness trajectory of the green enterprise is g D R = ( 1 k 1 ) α k 1 γ + ( P α k 1 γ ) 2 ( φ 2 ( θ p ) k 1 c D ) e r t + ( 1   k 1 γ + ( 1 p ) k 2 ) α ( 1 p )   k 2 γ φ 2 ( θ p ) k 1 ;
  • The degree of greenwashing by the brown enterprise is A R = ( P   k 1 γ ) φ + α ( ( θ p ) k 1 c d ) + θ p 2 β 2 ( α     k 1 γ ) + P   α k 1 β   ( 1 p )   k 2 φ 2 ( φ 2 ( θ p ) k 1 ) ;
  • The optimal trajectory of the brand reputation of the brown enterprise is G S = [ G 0 θ p δ A ] e δ t + θ p δ A ;
  • The optimal profit value function of the green enterprise is V D R ( G ) = m 1 R G 2 - m 2 R G + m 3 R , V U R ( G ) = t 1 R G 2 - t 2 R G + t 3 R .
Proof 3.
The Hamiltonian function of Enterprise D is:
r V D ( G ) = max A , g D ( P D C D P ) Q D 1 2 ρ A 2 p C p + V D ( θ A δ G )
Taking the partial derivatives of A and g D in the above equation, respectively, and setting them to 0 yields:
A = [ θ p ] V D + g D k 2 φ ( p 1 ) ( P α g D + c D g D ) ρ
g D ( t ) = G     g U k 1 φ 2 ( α     A k 2 φ ( p 1 ) ) + P 2 ( α     c D )
The Hamiltonian function of Enterprise U is:
r V U ( G ) = max g U ( P C U ) Q U + V U ( ( θ p ) A δ G )
Substituting the above two equations into the Hamiltonian function of Enterprise U, taking the partial derivative of g U and setting it to 0 yields:
g U ( t ) = P 2 c U G   +   ( 1 p ) γ A   g D k 2 2 ( β   k 1 γ )
Following the same steps as in Section 3.1, the optimal decision functions of Enterprise U and Enterprise D are:
g U = ( 1 ( 1 p )   k 2 ) k 1 γ + α φ 2 β ( α     k 1 γ ) ( β     c D ) e r t - k 1 + α ( P   α k 1 ) + ( 1   +   ( 1 p )   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 [ θ p ] k 1 )
g D = ( 1 k 1 ) α k 1 γ + ( P α k 1 γ ) 2 ( φ 2 [ θ p ] k 1 c D ) e r t + ( 1   k 1 γ + ( 1 p ) k 2 ) α ( 1 p )   k 2 γ φ 2 [ θ p ] k 1
A = ( P   k 1 γ ) φ + α ( [ θ p ] k 1 c d ) + [ θ p ] 2 β 2 ( α     k 1 γ ) + P   α k 1 β   ( 1 p )   k 2 φ 2 ( φ 2 [ θ p ] k 1 )
The optimal value functions of Enterprise U and Enterprise D can be expressed as:
m 1 R = P   k 1 ( 1 p )   k 2 ( P α k 1 γ ) ( θ p ) k 1 + ( 1   k 1 γ +   ( 1 p ) k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 β ( 1 p )   k 2 φ ) m 2 R = ( 1 γ ) α + k 1 γ β ( 1 P ) ( P α k 1 γ ) m 3 R = ( P   k 1 γ ) φ + 2 α β + ( θ p ) 2 β ( α     k 1 γ + φ 2 ) p C p t 1 R = α k 1 + ( 1   k 1 γ + ( 1 p )   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 ( θ p ) k 1 ) + φ α + ( k 1 γ + 1 ) φ + ( θ p ) β ( 1 P ) ( φ 2 β ) t 2 R = β + ( 1   k 1 γ ) φ α φ 2   k 1 γ + P   α k 1 β t 3 R = 0
V D ( G ) = P   k 1 ( 1 p )   k 2 ( P α k 1 γ ) ( θ p ) k 1 + ( 1   k 1 γ +   ( 1 p ) k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 β ( 1 p )   k 2 φ ) G 2 - ( 1 γ ) α + k 1 γ β ( 1 P ) ( P α k 1 γ ) G + ( P   k 1 γ ) φ + 2 α β + ( θ p ) 2 β ( α     k 1 γ + φ 2 ) p C p
V U ( G ) = [ α k 1 + ( 1   k 1 γ + ( 1 p )   k 2 ) φ 2 ( φ 2 ( θ p ) k 1 ) + φ α + ( k 1 γ + 1 ) φ + ( θ p ) β ( 1 P ) ( φ 2 β ) ] G 2 [ β + ( 1   k 1 γ ) φ α φ 2   k 1 γ + P   α k 1 β ] G
The optimal trajectory of the green supply chain reputation is:
G ( t ) = [ G 0 θ p ( A ) δ A ] e δ t + θ p ( A ) δ A
Through the above process, the conclusion in Proposition 3 can be proved. □

3.4. Model Comparison

This section compares the product greenness, degree of greenwashing by the brown enterprise, and total profits of enterprises under the three decision models, and obtains the following conclusions:
Corollary 1.
Given A G 1 ,   p < 1 , the product greenness and degree of greenwashing by brown enterprises under the three models satisfy: g u 2 ( t ) > g u 3 ( t ) > g u 1 ( t ) , g d 3 ( t ) > g d 2 ( t ) > g d 1 ( t ) , A 2 > A 1 > A 3 . It follows that:
Under the benchmark model without government intervention, allowing the disruptive effects of greenwashing behaviors represents the worst state with the lowest greenness, and the degree of greenwashing chosen by the brown enterprise is highest to maximize profits. Under the government subsidy model, subsidies and publicity for green enterprises lead to higher greenness for the green enterprise compared to the benchmark model, but the greenness of the brown enterprise does not improve, and it increases greenwashing to compete with the green enterprise. Under the government regulation model without subsidies for green enterprises but with monitoring and penalties for brown enterprises, the greenness levels of both enterprises are higher than the benchmark model due to the positive impact of greenwashing costs, and the degree of greenwashing is lower due to the negative impact of costs.
Corollary 2.
The total profit relationships under the three models are: When C p > Δ 1 , V D 1 ( t ) > V D 2 ( t ) > V D 3 ( t ) ; When C p < Δ 1 , V D 1 ( t ) > V D 3 ( t ) > V D 2 ( t ) ; When S > Δ 2 , V U 1 ( t ) < V U 2 ( t ) < V U 3 ( t ) . Δ 1 = 1 p [ ( m 1 R m 1 S ) G 2 + ( m 2 S m 2 R ) G + ( P   k 1 γ ) φ + 2 α β + ( θ p ) 2 β ( α     k 1 γ + φ 2 ) m 3 S ] , Δ 2 = ( t 1 R t 1 S ) G 2 + ( t 2 S t 2 R ) G .
For the brown enterprise, total profit under the subsidy model is lower than under the benchmark model. Total profit under the regulation model is also lower than under the benchmark when there is no penalty cost. When the penalty cost is zero, profit under regulation is higher than under the subsidy model. As the penalty cost increases, profit under regulation gradually decreases to the level of the subsidy model. In contrast, total profit for the green enterprise is higher under both the subsidy and regulation models compared to the benchmark. The critical value of profit under the subsidy model is mainly affected by the positive impact of subsidies: the greater the subsidy, the greater the total profit.
In a previous study, Sun [44] divided enterprises into advantaged and disadvantaged groups and developed two game models exploring the evolution of green cleaning and innovation strategies, considering government penalties and subsidies. Sun also analyzed the evolutionary stabilization strategies (ESSs) of the models and the evolution process for both enterprise groups. The study found that penalties effectively deterred “greenwashing” by both firm types, while subsidies did not inhibit disadvantaged enterprises.
This paper builds on previous research using a dynamic game model considering long-term enterprise operations. The model confirms earlier findings and provides insights into decision-making over time. Additionally, incorporating consumer perceptions of green products on demand offers valuable information for consumer-oriented policies.

4. Simulation and Analysis of Influencing Factors

Next, numerical simulations model the equilibrium results under different decision models to analyze the product greenness and optimal profit functions of enterprises. The parameter values are set as: P = 0.8 , α = 0.8 , β = 0.7 , κ 1 = 0.3 , κ 2 = 0.15 , φ = 0.7 , γ = 0.9 ,   c U = 0.7 , c D = 0.5 , θ = 0.6 , δ = 0.4 , A G = 1.5 , p = 0.5 .

4.1. Policy Comparison

According to the numerical simulation, the degree of greenwashing by the brown enterprise at each stage is:
A 1 = 1.70 ,   A 2 = 2.10 ,   A 3 = 0.13
Based on A 3 < A 1 < A 2 , under carbon neutrality, effective punitive policies significantly reduce the degree of greenwashing by brown enterprises compared to subsidy policies and the free market, where brown enterprises expand greenwashing to compete for demand. The greenness levels of both enterprises follow the same ranking. For greenwashing governance, subsidy policies do not reduce greenwashing behaviors of brown enterprises, but rather cause greater greenwashing efforts. In contrast, government punitive mechanisms effectively reduce false promotions by brown enterprises, achieving the purpose of greenwashing governance.
The optimal trajectories of product greenness under the three models are shown in Figure 1, Figure 2 and Figure 3, respectively. Initially, g D < g U and, as time increases, g U and g D both decrease with the difference reducing. This shows that downstream greenwashing adversely affects upstream green enterprises. This leads to unhealthy market competition, eventually resulting in the lemon market problem.
Figure 4 shows that as the government regulatory intensity increases, the degree of enterprise greenwashing gradually decreases. With the increase of government supervision, the degree of “greenwashing” of enterprises has gradually decreased. It can be seen that when the government conducts supervision, greenwashing enterprises will reduce their greenwashing behavior under the pressure of supervision, and when the government’s perceived supervision is increased, enterprises will gradually choose not to greenwashing. It shows that government supervision is an effective means to control enterprise greenwashing behavior.

4.2. The Impact of Consumer Green Perception on “Greenwashing”

Under the government regulation scenario, Figure 5 shows the influence of consumers’ perception coefficients for different enterprise types on the degree of greenwashing. The figure shows that when the consumers’ perception coefficient for green enterprises is relatively small, brown enterprises engage in some greenwashing. As the perception coefficient for green enterprises increases, the degree of greenwashing by brown enterprises gradually decreases. When the consumers’ perception coefficient for brown enterprises is relatively low, the degree of greenwashing is also small. As the perception coefficient for brown enterprises increases, the degree of greenwashing increases.

5. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations

A Stackelberg differential game model is established incorporating both green and brown enterprise types. The model compares greenness and total profits under two government scenarios: subsidies for green enterprises and regulation of brown enterprises. It further analyzes the mechanism behind brown enterprise greenwashing formation. Through a sensitivity analysis of the model parameters under different scenarios, the inhibitory effects of government policies on corporate greenwashing are investigated. The results show that: (1) Given the assumptions, when the government subsidizes green enterprises and regulates brown enterprises, compared to free market competition, green enterprises improve product greenness for higher profits, while the limited greenness improvement for regulated brown enterprises results in lower profits. (2) With government subsidies for only green enterprises, brown enterprises increase greenwashing to compensate for decreased total profits. Under government regulation, brown enterprises curb greenwashing behaviors. (3) In the regulatory model, the degree of brown enterprise greenwashing depends on the intensity of government oversight. As the regulatory intensity rises, this model outperforms the free competition model. Consumer green perception also affects brown enterprise greenwashing, with higher green enterprise perception coefficients reducing greenwashing, while higher brown enterprise perception coefficients increase greenwashing.
Based on the differential game analysis, policy recommendations for greenwashing governance include:
(1) Consider both the direct effects of policies targeting brown enterprises and indirect effects of green enterprise subsidies, such as appropriately reducing manufacturer subsidies to decrease fiscal burden and greenwashing.
(2) Use a combination of subsidies and regulation, as the model shows that joint deployment effectively improves supply chain greenness. Regulation can focus on monitoring green advertising and improving techniques, such as establishing a green advertising case law database and national real-time online monitoring system.
(3) Encourage consumer participation by sharing information and conducting joint anti-greenwashing activities through websites introducing green product knowledge. This can alleviate information asymmetry in the green product market, improve consumer perception of green enterprises, and strengthen awareness of greenwashing.

Author Contributions

H.Z.: Conceptualization, writing—original draft. Y.Z.: Methodology, data curation, writing—original draft. K.W.: Methodology, software, writing—review & editing. D.S.: Investigation, validation. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported by the National Social Science Fund in China (no. 19BGL185), The Major Project of Philosophy and Social Science of Jiangsu Province (2023SJZD025), the Clean Energy Branch of Huaneng International Power Jiangsu Energy Development Co., LTD. [no. HN-49A0-202100016-PWQT00015; HN-49A0-202100016-PWQT00019], and the Ministry of Education Humanities and Social Sciences Fund (19YJC630138).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Data are contained within the article.

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Thomas A. Gavin, Cornell University, for his help in editing this paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Kakadellis, S.; Woods, J.; Harris, Z.M. Friend or foe: Stakeholder attitudes towards biodegradable plastic packaging in food waste anaerobic digestion. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2021, 169, 105529. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Li, F.; Zhang, K.; Hao, A.; Yin, C.; Wu, G. Environmental Behavior Spillover or Public Information Induction: Consumers’ Intention to Pay a Premium for Rice Grown with Green Manure as Crop Fertilizer. Foods 2021, 10, 1285. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Wang, Y.; Hou, G. A duopoly game with heterogeneous green supply chains in optimal price and market stability with consumer green preference. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 255, 120161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Vollero, A.; Palazzo, M.; Siano, A.; Elving, W.J.L. Avoiding the greenwashing trap: Between CSR communication and stakeholder engagement. Int. J. Innov. Sustain. Dev. 2016, 10, 120–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Fernandes, J.; Segev, S.; Leopold, J.K. When consumers learn to spot deception in advertising: Testing a literacy intervention to combat greenwashing. Int. J. Advert. 2020, 39, 1115–1149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Ioannou, I.; Kassinis, G.; Papagiannakis, G. The Impact of Perceived Greenwashing on Customer Satisfaction and the Contingent Role of Capability Reputation. J. Bus. Ethics 2023, 185, 333–347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Cai, J.; Sun, H.; Shang, J.; Hegde, G.G. Information structure selection in a green supply chain: Impacts of wholesale price and greenness level. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2023, 306, 34–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Liu, Z.; Qian, Q.; Hu, B.; Shang, W.-L.; Li, L.; Zhao, Y.; Zhao, Z.; Han, C. Government regulation to promote coordinated emission reduction among enterprises in the green supply chain based on evolutionary game analysis. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2022, 182, 106290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Chen, M.-H.; Wei, H.; Wei, M.; Huang, H.; Su, C.-H. Modeling a green supply chain in the hotel industry: An evolutionary game theory approach. Int. J. Hosp. Manag. 2021, 92, 102716. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Liu, Z.; Huang, Y.-Q.; Shang, W.-L.; Zhao, Y.-J.; Yang, Z.-L.; Zhao, Z. Precooling energy and carbon emission reduction technology investment model in a fresh food cold chain based on a differential game. Appl. Energy 2022, 326, 119945. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Ma, S.; He, Y.; Gu, R.; Li, S. Sustainable supply chain management considering technology investments and government intervention. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2021, 149, 102290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. He, Q.; Wang, Z.; Wang, G.; Xie, J.; Chen, Z. The Dark Side of Environmental Sustainability in Projects: Unraveling Greenwashing Behaviors. Proj. Manag. J. 2021, 53, 349–366. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Zhang, D. Green financial system regulation shock and greenwashing behaviors: Evidence from Chinese firms. Energy Econ. 2022, 111, 106064. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Hung, C.-Z.; Chang, T.-W. Have I purchased the right product? Consumer behavior under corporate greenwash behavior. J. Consum. Behav. 2023, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Demirel, P.; Iatridis, K.; Kesidou, E. The impact of regulatory complexity upon self-regulation: Evidence from the adoption and certification of environmental management systems. J. Environ. Manag. 2018, 207, 80–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Delmas, M.A.; Burbano, V.C. The Drivers of Greenwashing. Calif. Manag. Rev. 2011, 54, 64–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Lyon, T.P.; Maxwell, J.W. Greenwash: Corporate Environmental Disclosure under Threat of Audit. J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 2011, 20, 3–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Zhang, D. Environmental regulation, green innovation, and export product quality: What is the role of greenwashing? Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 2022, 83, 102311. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Lee, M.T.; Raschke, R.L. Stakeholder legitimacy in firm greening and financial performance: What about greenwashing temptations? J. Bus. Res. 2023, 155, 113393. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Liu, C.; Song, Y.; Wang, W.; Shi, X. The governance of manufacturers’ greenwashing behaviors: A tripartite evolutionary game analysis of electric vehicles. Appl. Energy 2023, 333, 120498. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Smith, V.L.; Font, X. Volunteer tourism, greenwashing and understanding responsible marketing using market signalling theory. J. Sustain. Tour. 2014, 22, 942–963. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Makhloufi, L.; Laghouag, A.A.; Meirun, T.; Belaid, F. Impact of green entrepreneurship orientation on environmental performance: The natural resource-based view and environmental policy perspective. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2022, 31, 425–444. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Huang, H.; Xing, X.; He, Y.; Gu, X. Combating greenwashers in emerging markets: A game-theoretical exploration of firms, customers and government regulations. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2020, 140, 101976. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Kassinis, G.I.; Kay, A.A.; Papagiannakis, G.; Vlachos, P.A. Stigma as Moral Insurance: How Stigma Buffers Firms from the Market Consequences of Greenwashing. J. Manag. Stud. 2022, 59, 2154–2190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Hamilton, S.F.; Zilberman, D. Green markets, eco-certification, and equilibrium fraud. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2006, 52, 627–644. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Harbaugh, R.; Maxwell, J.W.; Roussillon, B. Label Confusion: The Groucho Effect of Uncertain Standards. Manag. Sci. 2011, 57, 1512–1527. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Li, W.; Li, W.; Seppänen, V.; Koivumäki, T. Effects of greenwashing on financial performance: Moderation through local environmental regulation and media coverage. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2023, 32, 820–841. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Wang, W.; Sun, Z.; Zhu, W.; Ma, L.; Dong, Y.; Sun, X.; Wu, F. How does multi-agent govern corporate greenwashing? A stakeholder engagement perspective from “common” to “collaborative” governance. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ. Manag. 2023, 30, 291–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Glachant, M. Non-binding voluntary agreements. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2007, 54, 32–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Qi, G.; Zeng, S.; Tam, C.; Yin, H.; Zou, H. Stakeholders’ Influences on Corporate Green Innovation Strategy: A Case Study of Manufacturing Firms in China. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ. Manag. 2013, 20, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Zhang, C.; Zhou, B.; Tian, X. Political connections and green innovation: The role of a corporate entrepreneurship strategy in state-owned enterprises. J. Bus. Res. 2022, 146, 375–384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Rui, Z.; Lu, Y. Stakeholder pressure, corporate environmental ethics and green innovation. Asian J. Technol. Innov. 2021, 29, 70–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. He, Q.; Wang, Z.; Wang, G.; Zuo, J.; Wu, G.; Liu, B. To be green or not to be: How environmental regulations shape contractor greenwashing behaviors in construction projects. Sustain. Cities Soc. 2020, 63, 102462. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Zhang, D. Do heterogenous subsides work differently on environmental innovation? A mechanism exploration approach. Energy Econ. 2022, 114, 106233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Huang, Y.; Xie, X.; Zhou, H. The “isomorphic” behavior of enterprise greenwashing. Chin. J. Popul. Resour. Environ. 2020, 30, 139–150. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  36. Zhang, T.; Qin, H.; Xu, W. Environmental Regulation, Greenwashing Behaviour, and Green Governance of High-Pollution Enterprises in China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 12539. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Zhu, Q.; Xia, X.; Wang, Y. Research on competition between low carbon and common product manufacturers under government subsidies. J. Syst. Eng. 2014, 29, 640–651. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Nyilasy, G.; Gangadharbatla, H.; Paladino, A. Perceived Greenwashing: The Interactive Effects of Green Advertising and Corporate Environmental Performance on Consumer Reactions. J. Bus. Ethics 2014, 125, 693–707. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. de Freitas Netto, S.V.; Sobral, M.F.F.; Ribeiro, A.R.B.; Soares, G.R.d.L. Concepts and forms of greenwashing: A systematic review. Environ. Sci. Eur. 2020, 32, 19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Chenavaz, R.Y.; Eynan, A. Advertising, goodwill, and the Veblen effect. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2021, 289, 676–682. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Jørgensen, S.; Taboubi, S.; Zaccour, G. Retail promotions with negative brand image effects: Is cooperation possible? Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2003, 150, 395–405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. André, F.J.; Sokri, A.; Zaccour, G. Public Disclosure Programs vs. traditional approaches for environmental regulation: Green goodwill and the policies of the firm. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2011, 212, 199–212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Szabo, S.; Webster, J. Perceived Greenwashing: The Effects of Green Marketing on Environmental and Product Perceptions. Bus. Ethics 2021, 171, 719–739. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Sun, Z.; Zhang, W. Do government regulations prevent greenwashing? An evolutionary game analysis of heterogeneous enterprises. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 231, 1489–1502. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Optimal greenness trajectory under free competition model.
Figure 1. Optimal greenness trajectory under free competition model.
Energies 17 01340 g001
Figure 2. Optimal greenness trajectory under government subsidy model.
Figure 2. Optimal greenness trajectory under government subsidy model.
Energies 17 01340 g002
Figure 3. Optimal greenness trajectory under regulation model.
Figure 3. Optimal greenness trajectory under regulation model.
Energies 17 01340 g003
Figure 4. Impact of regulatory intensity on enterprise greenwashing under regulation model.
Figure 4. Impact of regulatory intensity on enterprise greenwashing under regulation model.
Energies 17 01340 g004
Figure 5. Impact of consumer green perception on greenwashing.
Figure 5. Impact of consumer green perception on greenwashing.
Energies 17 01340 g005
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zhang, Y.; Zhang, H.; Wu, K.; Shen, D. Governance of Greenwashing Behaviors: A Perspective of Heterogeneous Firm Types. Energies 2024, 17, 1340. https://doi.org/10.3390/en17061340

AMA Style

Zhang Y, Zhang H, Wu K, Shen D. Governance of Greenwashing Behaviors: A Perspective of Heterogeneous Firm Types. Energies. 2024; 17(6):1340. https://doi.org/10.3390/en17061340

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zhang, Yi, Huiming Zhang, Kai Wu, and Danyun Shen. 2024. "Governance of Greenwashing Behaviors: A Perspective of Heterogeneous Firm Types" Energies 17, no. 6: 1340. https://doi.org/10.3390/en17061340

APA Style

Zhang, Y., Zhang, H., Wu, K., & Shen, D. (2024). Governance of Greenwashing Behaviors: A Perspective of Heterogeneous Firm Types. Energies, 17(6), 1340. https://doi.org/10.3390/en17061340

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop