Next Article in Journal
The Extraction of Torreya grandis Growing Areas Using a Spatial–Spectral Fused Attention Network and Multitemporal Sentinel-2 Images: A Case Study of the Kuaiji Mountain Region
Previous Article in Journal
Enhancing Autonomous Orchard Navigation: A Real-Time Convolutional Neural Network-Based Obstacle Classification System for Distinguishing ‘Real’ and ‘Fake’ Obstacles in Agricultural Robotics
Previous Article in Special Issue
Research on the Spatial Correlation Network and Driving Mechanism of Agricultural Green Development in China
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Key Determinants of the Economic Viability of Family Farms: Evidence from Serbia

by
Aleksandar Miljatović
*,
Mirela Tomaš Simin
and
Veljko Vukoje
Faculty of Agriculture, University of Novi Sad, 21000 Novi Sad, Serbia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Agriculture 2025, 15(8), 828; https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture15080828
Submission received: 12 March 2025 / Revised: 2 April 2025 / Accepted: 5 April 2025 / Published: 10 April 2025
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Productivity and Efficiency of Agricultural and Livestock Systems)

Abstract

:
Ensuring a fair income for farmers, as one of the key objectives of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), focuses on the economic dimension of sustainable agricultural development. Achieving the economic viability of farms is often prioritized in developing countries, as the economic dimension is crucial for farm survival in the long term. This paper aims to assess the economic viability of farms and examine the impact of various factors on their viability. The study focuses on family farms that were part of the Serbian Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) sample over a seven-year period from 2015 to 2021. Farm economic viability is evaluated using the opportunity cost approach. The results show that the highest proportion of economically viable farms was found in field crop farming, while grazing livestock farms were the least economically viable due to the extensive farming methods they typically employ. Among the determinants of farm viability, the most important was the asset turnover ratio, which positively influenced the economic viability of all types of farming. The results obtained may help farm managers identify the primary obstacles to achieving optimal long-term performance. Moreover, agricultural policymakers could improve existing measures and introduce new ones to strengthen the overall economic viability of farms.

1. Introduction

The concept of sustainable agriculture is a key component of every major strategic document worldwide. The second of the seventeen Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) in the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development is to end hunger, achieve food security and improved nutrition, and promote sustainable agriculture [1]. Additionally, the Farm to Fork strategy, as part of the European Green Deal, aims to accelerate the transition to a sustainable food system [2]. Achieving sustainability is not an easy process. Wiśniewska [3] (p. 120) claims that assessing sustainable development is a “complicated, long-term process, considered in an infinite time horizon”. The sustainable development is commonly understood through three main pillars: (1) economic, (2) environmental and (3) social. From the farm’s perspective, sustainable agriculture can be understood as producing high-quality goods and services under the economic pillar, managing natural resources responsibly under the environmental pillar, and enhancing rural dynamics under the social pillar [4].
In developing countries, the focus is primarily on the economic dimension of sustainable development. The main reason is that they have not yet reached an adequate level of economic viability, preventing them from fully addressing the environmental and social dimensions. Farms, as the key entities in agriculture, cannot sustain themselves in the long term if they are not economically viable [5], meaning they must be able to provide a fair income for farmers. Fair income is one of the ten key objectives of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), and most European countries incorporated this goal into their agricultural strategic plans for the period of 2023–2027. This is one of the reasons why numerous authors have recently focused their research on analyzing income viability, fair income in agriculture, and the economic viability of farms [6,7,8,9,10,11,12].
In the literature, two closely related terms are often mentioned in the context of the economic dimension of sustainable agricultural development: economic viability and economic sustainability. Economic viability of farms refers to their ability to generate sufficient net income from farm operations to cover the opportunity costs of their own factors of production. Economic sustainability, on the other hand, refers to the total disposable income, which includes income from both farm operations and off-farm sources. This makes economic sustainability a measure of the long-term viability of the farm [13]. In the European studies, the focus is primarily on the economic viability of farms. The main reason is the lack of data on farm household income as a whole in the Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) system [8], which serves as the main database for this type of research. In the USA and Canada, the focus is more on economic sustainability, as researchers use specially designed questionnaires for data collection. This approach is known in the literature as a household welfare measure [14].
The economic viability of farms refers to an analytical concept that encompasses both viable farm incomes and adequate returns to factors of production [15]. The fair income for farmers is undoubtedly a prerequisite for the economic viability of farms, as it represents the return to one of the key factors of production—labour. In addition to labour, it is crucial to analyze the returns to the other two factors of production (capital and land) in order to evaluate the overall economic viability of farms. This is known as an opportunity cost approach, which is based on ensuring an adequate standard of living for farm employees. The main question is what defines an adequate standard of living, or in other words, what makes the viability threshold. In the case of short-term viability, the threshold is the reference wage that family members or unpaid labour could earn by working off the farm. In long-term viability, the threshold is defined as a reference income that accounts for the total opportunity costs of all factors of production (labour, capital, and land) used on the farm. This makes long-term viability the measure of overall economic viability.
The opportunity cost of labour quantifies the best alternative wages that could be earned by the unpaid labour, including the owner or farm manager, family members, and other unpaid workers. It represents the reference wage that serves as the viability threshold in calculating short-term economic viability. There are varying opinions in the literature regarding the most appropriate measure for the best alternative wage. The most common approaches are the following:
  • The minimum wage;
  • The average wage in agriculture; and
  • The average wage in the national economy.
The use of the minimum wage as a reference can be justified by the fact that agricultural activities often involve elderly and low-qualified workers, who typically face challenges when searching for employment in other, higher-paying sectors [15,16,17]. The average wage in agriculture can also serve as a possible reference wage, considering that farmers typically have a low opportunity cost and working in agriculture is often the best alternative to working at their own farm [18]. The average wage is calculated by dividing total labour cost by the paid labour input, then taking the average value for a specific region or country [7,19,20]. The main shortcoming of the aforementioned two approaches is that they may discriminate against agricultural workers and set a very low threshold, which is likely insufficient to ensure an adequate standard of living for the farm manager and family members—a key requirement for achieving economic viability. Hence, the third approach uses the average wage in the national economy, aiming to address the deficiencies of the first two. The average wage in the national economy definitely ensures the best possible alternative wage for unpaid labour [10,11,14,21], without any limitations related to age or qualifications of the farmer. This is particularly relevant because many farmers are highly skilled and qualified for sectors other than agriculture, yet they continue farming for various reasons.
The opportunity cost of capital refers to the best alternative use of the capital invested in agricultural production. In the literature, two main approaches for determining the best alternative are highlighted. According to the first approach, average interest rates calculated based on long-term bonds are used [10,22,23,24]. In the second approach, a reference rate of return of 5% is applied [7,15,16,17], which is typical for countries with underdeveloped financial markets.
When calculating the opportunity cost of capital, an important consideration is how to account for the value of agricultural land. The opportunity cost of land can be evaluated either together with the opportunity cost of capital or separately. In the latter case, the opportunity cost of capital is calculated excluding the land value and focusing instead on the opportunity cost of non-land capital. As a result, the opportunity cost of land is evaluated separately, representing the best alternative use of land allocated to agricultural production. The best alternative use is to rent out the land and earn income through land rent. The question is what rate of return should be used, and the answer would be the rate that is appropriate for the specific region. Hence, the land rent should be calculated based on the average rent for the region where the specific farm is located [6,7,12].
In addition to farm viability analysis, it is equally important to explore the determinants of economic viability. By analyzing the main internal and external factors, it can be concluded what the primary obstacles are to achieving the highest possible level of economic viability on a farm. According to the literature, these factors can be categorized into the following groups: basic farm characteristics, socio-demographic characteristics of farm manager, economic characteristics of the farm, risk management, and agricultural policy measures.
The economic size of a farm is usually measured based on total income value, total utilized agricultural area, standard output value, etc. Farm size is a very important factor that generally has a positive impact on farm viability, as larger and more powerful farms tend to achieve higher levels of economic viability [6,19,24]. The share of rented land, as one of the basic characteristics of the farm, could have either a negative or positive impact on farm viability. It is believed that a lower share of rented or higher share of owned land provides security to the farm manager, allowing for greater certainty in planning and organizing the production process, including the sowing structure and other activities [25,26]. On the other hand, Barnes et al. [16] state that a higher share of rented land can help a farm achieve an optimal size, which in turn leads to an increased productivity. There are different opinions on the impact of the share of paid labour on a farm’s economic viability, with motivation being the key influencing factor. The higher share of unpaid labour (family members’ work) reduces labour costs, which can positively affect farm viability [9]. Furthermore, their vested interest in the farm’s success drives better performance and business development. Conversely, a higher share of paid labour can positively impact farm performance, as paid workers may be more efficient due to the financial benefits they obtained through the salaries [22].
One of the most commonly used socio-demographic factors is the farmer’s age. The age of a farm manager often has a negative impact on farm performance, as older farmers are typically less inclined to accept and adapt to market changes, innovations, or take on unnecessary business risks [27]. Younger farmers, on the other hand, tend to embrace new technologies and innovations that can enhance farm performance and, consequently, the level of farm viability [28]. The asset turnover ratio is the key economic characteristic of the farm. This factor positively impacts farm performance, meaning that farms with faster asset turnover tend to have a higher level of economic viability [6,22].
In terms of risk management, income diversification should be considered. First, a distinction should be made between agricultural and farm diversification [16]. Agricultural diversification refers to the proportion of the value of a single production line in relation to the total value of agricultural production. On the other hand, farm diversification includes other gainful activities, such as contracting work, agritourism, processing agricultural products, etc. The share of income from other gainful activities in total income represents farm diversification. The impact of diversification on farm viability can be both positive and negative. Some authors claim that diversification has a positive impact because a more diversified production helps reduce the risk of failure [9,29]. Conversely, the negative impact of diversification can be attributed to the fact that farmers engaged in multiple activities may have less time to focus on improving farm performance [30].
In addition to the previously mentioned internal factor, it is also important to consider the impact of the subsidy level. It is a policy instrument beyond the control of farm managers, making it an external factor influencing farm viability. A higher share of subsidies in total income can impact economic viability either positively or negatively [9]. The positive impact is linked to the fact that incentives provide stability and certainty in planning future production [31,32,33], while the negative impact indicates the inefficiency of subsidies, which is particularly recognized in smaller farms [34].
Family farms are the predominant business entities engaged in agricultural production globally [35,36], including most European countries [37,38]. In the Republic of Serbia, family farms represent approximately 99% of the total number of agricultural entities and occupy about 82% of the total agricultural areas. Their role is crucial in improving living standards in rural areas, where agriculture remains the leading industry. The main characteristic of family farms is that they typically rely on their own factors of production (land, labour, and capital), making them implicit costs for the farm. This is why an opportunity cost approach [8,14] is commonly used to determine whether investing their own factors of production in agriculture is economically justified, or to assess the overall economic viability of family farms.
The ability of family farms to achieve a high level of economic viability is lower compared to larger farms [19]. Larger farms are in a better position to secure adequate financing for production, diversify potential risks, and make better use of available resources overall. They are certainly fewer in number, but their share of total agricultural production is quite significant [12]. Nevertheless, given their number and overall importance for rural development, family farms remain at the heart of the European agricultural model [11].
The issue of economic viability of family farms in the Republic of Serbia (RS) has not been sufficiently explored, primarily due to the lack of production, economic, and financial data necessary for such an analysis. The introduction of the Farm Accountancy Data Network in 2011 marked the beginning of efforts to address this issue. Nevertheless, conducting a comprehensive analysis of economic viability was not possible in the beginning due to the small number of farms in early years. In recent years, this database includes a sufficient number of farms to ensure representativeness and enable high-quality and reliable research studies. For this reason, a scientifically grounded study became necessary to address the key research question concerning the level of economic viability of family farms in RS and the dominant factors influencing their viability. The paper aims to assess the economic viability level of family farms and to examine the impact of various internal and external factors on their economic viability over the seven-year period from 2015 to 2021.
The structure of the paper is as follows: after the introduction, which provides a concise summary of the theoretical background, the next section describes the materials used and the research methodology applied. The main section presents the empirical findings, followed by the discussion. In the final section, the key conclusions and limitations of the research are outlined.

2. Materials and Methods

The analysis was based on data from farms in the Republic of Serbia (RS) that were part of the FADN sample from 2015 to 2021. Specifically, it concerns family farms that were included in the FADN database throughout the entire seven-year period. The total number of analyzed farms, after eliminating observations with extreme values and missing data, was 527.
Farms were divided according to type of farming (TF) into the following: (1) specialist field crops, (2) specialist permanent crops (vineyards and fruits), (3) specialist milk, (4) specialist grazing livestock (other than milk—cattle, sheep and goats), and (5) mixed. These are the dominant types of farming in RS, accounting for approximately 96% of all commercial farms, i.e., those with a standard output (SO) value exceeding EUR 4000 [39]. Compared to the official TF8 classification based on European Union (EU) regulations [40], the specialist horticulture and granivores types of farming were excluded. The main reason for this, aside from the low share, is the specific nature of the production process [41], which gives these types of farming an advantage over others with a significantly lower asset turnover ratio.
The economic viability of farms is assessed using the opportunity cost approach. The focus is on long-term economic viability (LTEV), as it represents the only true measure of economic viability that accounts for the opportunity costs of the three crucial factors of production in agriculture: labour, capital, and land. The formula for calculating the economic viability of farms is as follows:
L T E V = F N I T O C
where FNI is the value of farm net income and TOC is total opportunity costs.
Economically viable farms have an LTEV coefficient equal to or greater than 1, indicating their ability to efficiently utilize their own resources. In other words, these farms generate higher income from agricultural production than they would by allocating their factors of production to alternative uses. Conversely, farms with an LTEV coefficient lower than 1 are unable to generate sufficient net income to cover the opportunity costs of their own factors of production or incur net loss.
Total opportunity costs represent the sum of the opportunity cost of labour, opportunity cost of non-land capital, and opportunity cost of land. The opportunity cost of labour is the product of reference wage and unpaid labour input. The reference wage is the average gross wage in the national economy for the specific region (administrative district), taking into account potential regional differences. The average wage, as the best possible alternative, is used to avoid discriminating against agricultural workers and to establish a reference value that ensures an adequate standard of living for farmers. The gross value is used because the wages paid in FADN is also calculated as gross values.
The opportunity cost of non-land capital is the product of total equity (excluding the value of agricultural land) and the 5% rate of return [17,42]. The Republic of Serbia does not have a well-developed financial market, which is why an average annual return on long-term bonds could not be used [22,24]. The agricultural land is specific in comparison with other farm assets, which is why the opportunity cost of land is separately estimated as the product of the farm’s own land and the average land rental fees for the specific region [6].
The economic viability of farms was also examined in the context of various factors that may influence it. The focus is on the most important internal and external variables identified in the previous literature review: (1) economic size (ES), (2) share of rented land (SRL), (3) share of paid labour (SPL), (4) farmer’s age (AGE), (5) asset turnover ratio (ATR), (6) agricultural diversification (DIV), and (7) subsidy level (SUB). The factors and the formulas used for their calculations are presented in Table 1.
The impact of the previously mentioned factors (independent variables) on economic viability (dependent variable) was analyzed using panel regression analysis. Panel data models combine cross-sectional and time series data [43], a combination used in this research, which is why this model is suitable for analyzing factors that may influence farm viability. In its general form, the linear regression model for panel data can be expressed through the following function:
Y i t = β i t + k = 2 K β k i t X k i t + u i t , i = 1 , , N ; t = 1 , , T ; k = 1 , K
where Y i t is the value of the dependent variable for the i unit of observation in period t; X k i t is the value of the k independent variable for the i unit of observation in period t; β k i t represents the value of unknown regression parameters that are variable by observation unit i and period t; u i t is the random error, which has an arithmetic mean equal to one and a constant common variance for each i and t.
Before selecting the final specification of the model, the stationarity of a time series should be determined using unit root tests. Only stationary time series can be included in panel regression analysis, while non-stationary series must be transformed before inclusion. The presence of a unit root in the time series was tested using augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) test.
To select the final specification of the model, it is essential to test for the presence of individual and time effects. In the fixed effects model specification, an F-test was applied to test for individual and time effects, while in the random effects specification, the Breusch–Pagan LM test was used. The nature of potential individual (and time) effects was determined using the Hausman test, which enabled the choice between the fixed and random effects model specification.
The next step in the analysis is to check for multicollinearity using the Variance Inflation Factor (VIF) test and the Tolerance (TOL) test, which represents the reciprocal of VIF. Next, the basic assumptions of the model need to be examined, including testing for autocorrelation, heteroskedasticity, and cross-sectional dependence. Autocorrelation was tested using the Wooldridge test, where the null hypothesis stated the absence of first-order autocorrelation. Heteroskedasticity occurs when the random error in the model is correlated with one or more independent variables. It was tested by applying the White test. Cross-sectional dependence can lead to biased and inconsistent results when evaluating classical models, making it essential to test for its presence using the Pesaran CD test. Finally, if any of the three assumptions mentioned above are violated, the initial model must be transformed.
Based on the selected variables that may affect farm viability, the model can be specified as follows:
L T E V i t = β i t + β 1 E S + β 2 S R L + β 3 S P L + β 4 A G E + β 5 A T R + β 6 D I V + β 7 S U B + u i t
where i is the unit of observation—the farm (i = 1, 2, …, 527); t is each year (t = 1, 2, …, 7); u is the random error.

3. Results and Discussion

3.1. Analysis of the Farm Economic Viability

The long-term economic viability (LTEV) indicator, as a measure of overall farm viability, showed positive values throughout the observed period. The average coefficient exceeds one across all types of farming, indicating that farms can cover the opportunity costs of production factors from their net income (Table 2). As expected, the obtained results differ among various types of farming. The LTEV indicator is highest for field crop farms (2.91), and lowest for grazing livestock farms (1.03). Overall, livestock farms exhibit lower average coefficients of economic viability compared to crop production farms. This corresponds to findings in a Czech study [7].
The median values of the observed indicator are expectedly lower, reflecting the significantly reduced level of economic viability among farms in the Republic of Serbia. The situation is particularly problematic in milk, mixed, and grazing livestock farms, where the median coefficient value is below one. The most endangered are definitely grazing livestock farms, which is in line with Hlouškova et al. [12]. They not only exhibit the lowest average and median economic viability coefficients, but they also consistently recorded a share of economically viable farms below 50% (Figure 1). In all observed years, the share of economically viable grazing livestock farms was the lowest, except in 2016, when mixed farms took on this role. Although, there are a noticeable number of farms with very promising prospects, the obtained results clearly indicate that the majority of grazing livestock farms face serious challenges in achieving economic viability. On the other hand, field crop farms generally recorded the highest share of economic viability, with the exception of 2015 and 2017. They were followed by permanent crop farms, which also exhibit the second-highest average economic viability coefficient among the remaining types of farming.
In order to accurately assess the economic viability of farms and the vulnerability of those that are not economically viable, the farms were divided into two categories: (1) economically viable—farms with an LTEV coefficient equal to or greater than one, and (2) economically non-viable—farms with an LTEV coefficient less than one (Table 3). The proportion of economically viable farms is favourable, with 54.38% of the total observed farms being economically viable. The recorded LTEV coefficient of 4.15 in this category of farms is also beneficial, indicating promising prospects for the farms in general. The highest percentage of economically viable farms is recorded in field crop farming (61.30%), closely followed by permanent crop farming (60.71%). These two types of farming also achieve the highest LTEV coefficients within the category of economically viable farms.
On the other hand, the share of economically non-viable farms was 45.62%, with an average LTEV coefficient of −0.09. The negative value of the LTEV coefficient is highly concerning, indicating that farms achieving net loss dominate in this group. Grazing livestock farming recorded the lowest share of economically viable farms (38.78%), as expected. In the category of economically non-viable grazing livestock farms, the average LTEV coefficient is also extremely low, at just 0.04. This indicates that grazing livestock farms are the most endangered, as they are the farthest from the viability threshold among all observed types of farming. Grazing livestock farms are generally extensive farms, often located in areas with natural constraints. These farms are usually managed by elderly farmers who have never worked outside of agriculture. The reason is primarily that they are not capable of doing anything else due to their low qualifications. However, an equally important factor is the agricultural tradition they maintain. The emotional connection to the work they do is undoubtedly a key reason preventing them from leaving agriculture, even though they may not achieve the best economic viability outcomes. Nevertheless, the continuation of their activity is crucial for the development of the remote rural areas [12] where these farms are dominant.

3.2. Exploring the Factors Affecting Farm Economic Viability

In order to examine the relationship between variables in the model, the Pearson correlation coefficient is applied. Due to the extensive data, the results are presented in the appendix (Table A1, Appendix A). The results indicate that the observed variables can be used in panel regression analysis, as only insignificant or weak correlations are recorded. A strong relationship is noticed only between the economic viability coefficient and economic size in milk farms, with a correlation coefficient of 0.7030. However, this result suggests a potential reverse causality [44], meaning that the dependent variable (LTEV) might influence the independent variable (ES) in the model. According to the reviewed literature, no research analyzes the impact of the economic viability coefficient on the economic size of farms. The opposite influence of economic size on the farm viability is often observed in the analysis [6,19,24] and is considered relevant.
Before conducting the panel regression analysis, the stationarity of the time series is assessed using the augmented Dickey–Fuller unit root test. The null hypothesis assumes that the time series have a unit root. Since the p value is less than 0.05 in all types of farming (Table 4), the null hypothesis is rejected. Accordingly, the alterative hypothesis, which assumes stationarity, is accepted.
The first step in panel regression analysis is to select the appropriate model among the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS), fixed effects model, and random effects model. The OLS model is unbiased and efficient when individual and/or time effects do not exist, making it essential to test for their presence. The existence of individual and time effects was tested using the F-test for fixed specification of the model. The results confirmed the presence of individual effects in all types of farming, as the p value is less than 0.05 (Table 5). On the other hand, the presence of time effects is recorded only in field crop and permanent crop farms (p < 0.05).
In the random effects model specification, the existence of individual and time effects was examined using the Breusch–Pagan LM test. Based on the test results, individual effects are found in all types of farming, since the p value is less than 0.05 (Table 6). Conversely, the presence of time effects is confirmed only in field crop and permanent crop farms (p < 0.05).
The confirmed presence of individual (and time) effects in all types of farming clearly indicates that OLS is not an adequate model to use. Therefore, it is necessary to use a model with individual and time effects for field crop and permanent crop farms, and a model with individual effects for milk, grazing livestock, and mixed farms. The next step in selecting the final specification of the model is to determine the nature of the effects, i.e., to choose between the model with fixed and random effects. For this purpose, the Hausman test was applied, with the null hypothesis assuming the appropriateness of the random effects model. Since the p value is less than 0.05 in all types of farming except milk farms, the null hypothesis is rejected (Table 7), indicating that for field crop, permanent crop, grazing livestock, and mixed types of farming, the fixed effects model should be used. The exception is milk farms, where the null hypothesis is accepted (p > 0.05), suggesting that the random effects model specification is more appropriate.
After selecting the model specification, it is necessary to examine the basic assumptions for applying panel regression analysis. Regarding this, it is crucial to access the presence of multicollinearity. The test results indicate that the VIF values do not exceed 5, and the TOL values are not lower than 0.2 (Table 8). This clearly confirms that there is no harmful multicollinearity in the observed models.
Finally, the models were tested for the presence of autocorrelation, heteroskedasticity and cross-sectional dependence (Table 9). The presence of autocorrelation was tested using the Wooldridge test, and the results confirm the existence of first-order autocorrelation in the models of permanent crop, milk, and mixed farms (p < 0.05). In the models of field crop and grazing livestock farms, the null hypothesis is accepted (p > 0.05), indicating the absence of first-order autocorrelation. The existence of heteroskedasticity was tested using the White test. Since the p value is less than 0.05 in all types of farming, the null hypothesis is rejected, indicating that heteroskedasticity is present in the models of all types of farming. Finally, the Pesaran CD test was applied to test for the presence of cross-sectional dependence in the models. The results indicate that there is interdependence in the models of field crop, milk, and mixed farms (p < 0.05), while in the models of permanent crop and grazing livestock farms, cross-sectional dependence is not confirmed (p > 0.05).
Considering that at least one basic assumption is violated, an alternative specification of the panel regression model with corrected standard errors (PCSE) was used in the research (the tested OLS, fixed effects model, and random effects model, as necessary steps in panel regression analysis, are presented in the appendix (Table A2, Table A3 and Table A4, Appendix A)). As far as the results of the previous tests have shown, the fixed effects model specification is the most reliable for use in all types of farming, except for milk farms. Following this, the results of the alternative panel model with fixed individual (and time) effects for field crop, permanent crop, grazing livestock, and mixed farms are presented in Table 10. In milk farms, on the other hand, an alternative panel model with random individual effects was applied.
According to the F-test/Wald chi2 results, all models are statistically significant (p < 0.01). Relatively low values of the coefficient of determination, particularly in field crop and permanent crop types of farming (12.80% and 16.21%), are to be expected. Crop production is highly influenced by climatic conditions, soil fertility, and irrigation, none of which are included in this study. Unlike crop production, livestock production is managed under more controlled conditions, which is why the coefficient of determination values are significantly higher here.
The research results indicate that economic size has a statistically significant positive impact on economic viability in all types of farming, except for permanent crops (Table 10). This is expected, as larger farms are better equipped with machinery and other technical resources. They also have larger land and livestock capacities, as well as newer and more modern buildings for storing finished crop products and housing livestock. That is precisely why these farms are generally characterized by higher labour productivity and production efficiency, enabling them to generate higher incomes and, consequently, achieve a greater level of economic viability [6,12,24,25,45,46]. Conversely, economic size does not have a statistically significant impact on the economic viability of permanent crop farms, which is in line with the findings of Ziętara and Sobierajewska [23] based on research of fruit farms in selected Eastern and Western European countries.
Unlike economic size, the share of rented land and share of paid labour significantly impact economic viability only in one specific type of farming. The share of rented land has a statistically significant negative impact on the economic viability of mixed farms. A higher share of rented land increases the level of uncertainty in the organization and planning of production, particularly in crop farms [25]. They cannot make long-term production plans or plant perennial crops, which directly impacts livestock production as well. For this very reason, mixed farms, which are involved in both crop and livestock production, are most negatively affected by a high share of rented land. Vira et al. [26] go even further and claim that a high share of rented land can lead producers to quit agriculture, particularly in the case of small-scale agricultural producers. The share of paid labour, similarly, has a statistically significant positive impact only in permanent crop farms. These farms are highly dependent on paid labour, as the nature of the business requires the engagement of a large number of workers during specific, short time intervals. This, of course, cannot be accomplished solely with unpaid labour input. Therefore, the motivation of paid labour [22] and job quality play a crucial role, directly influencing the results achieved in permanent crop farming. Paid labourers are specialized in the tasks they perform [47] and, as a rule, achieve higher labour productivity compared to unpaid labour, which typically consists of family members [48,49]. Finally, employing paid labour also entails higher labour costs, but at the same time, it enables farms to generate significantly higher incomes, ultimately leading to a higher level of economic viability.
The farmer’s age has a statistically significant negative impact on the economic viability only of mixed farms, at the 5% level. The negative impact of the farmer’s age is expected, considering that older farm managers are usually less willing to innovate and make significant changes to the production process. They generally have less energy, find it more difficult to adapt to new technology, and are less willing to increase the intensity of agricultural land use [50,51]. Unlike older farmers, younger farm managers are well educated and adapt more quickly and easily to market changes [27]. They consistently stay informed about the latest legal regulations [33], agricultural competitions and generally keep up to date with important information relevant to agricultural production.
The asset turnover ratio is the only variable that has a statistically significant impact on the economic viability of all types of farming. It has a positive and highly statistically significant impact at the 1% level, except in the model for milk farms, where the level of significance is 5%. The results indicate that farms with a higher asset turnover ratio achieve higher economic viability coefficients, which is consistent with research conducted by numerous authors [22,45,52,53]. A faster turnover of assets logically indicates a shorter production cycle, meaning a higher intensity of production. The higher intensity is very important for better capacity utilization, which provides more efficient production. This is, certainly, related to the generation of higher incomes, which consequently leads to a greater level of economic viability of farms. Hence, farm managers should aim to further reduce the production cycle wherever possible, by using fast-growing crops and livestock units with the best genetic potential.
Further, agricultural diversification has a statistically significant negative impact on the economic viability of field crop farms at the 1% level. Employees on diversified farms must invest significantly more time and effort in performing various tasks on the farm [30]. Unlike them, workers on specialized farms can achieve better results as they are trained for just one or a small group of specific tasks. Accordingly, greater farm diversification could lead to a decrease in efficiency or labour productivity [48] and, ultimately, a reduction in economic viability level. This is particularly characteristic of farms engaged in crop production [54], as is the case with field crop farms. These farms often lack adequate mechanization and other necessary equipment, as well as sufficient labour input to efficiently perform the various tasks required for diverse crop cultivation.
Finally, the subsidy level does not emerge as a variable with a statistically significant impact on the economic viability of farms. It is important to emphasize that only current operations related to production are included here, while subsidies on investments are not. By investing in assets, farms enable more efficient resource utilization, which positively impacts their development opportunities [55]. The effect of subsidies, on the other hand, is insignificant, primarily due to the nature of the subsidy schemes in RS. As direct payments are dominant in income support, this could influence the lack of motivation among farmers to improve farm performance [56]. The insignificant effect of subsidies on farm viability is also recognized in Scottish farms [16], which imply the long-term resilience of farms in relation to public support. Slijper et al. [9] take it a step further, arguing that farms receiving more direct payments have a lower probability of being economically viable in the long term. The main reason is that a higher share of subsidies in total income could indicate subsidy inefficiency. Obviously, the current support program in RS does not provide adequate gains for farmers. Direct subsidies, which dominate the subsidy structure, primarily serve as income support, disregarding support for improving farm performance. In line with this, there is a need for agricultural policymakers to focus more on the product quality and efficiency of resource use in order to fully realize the effects of subsidies.

4. Conclusions

Assessing the economic viability of farms is a highly relevant analysis, given the essential role of the economic pillar in the sustainable development of agriculture, especially in developing countries. An opportunity cost approach is frequently used to measure the economic viability of farms in Europe, offering a way to evaluate the returns to production factors employed in agriculture (labour, land, and capital). The primary objective is to ensure that employees in agriculture can meet their basic living needs or maintain an adequate standard of living. In the long term, the returns to other two factors (land and capital) are also evaluated, making it a comprehensive economic viability analysis.
Our findings indicate that 54.38% of the observed farms in the Republic of Serbia are economically viable. These farms are viable in the long term, meaning that they are capable of earning an adequate return to the factors of production available to them, with an emphasis on ensuring a sufficient living standard for the unpaid labour input (including the farm manager, family members, and other unpaid workers). The proportion of economically viable farms varies according to the type of farming. Field crop and permanent crop types of farming exhibit the highest percentage of economically viable farms and the largest economic viability coefficients, meaning that these types generate the highest return rates among all observed farms. On the other hand, milk, mixed, and especially grazing livestock farms achieve significantly lower results, indicating that these are the least viable types of farming in RS.
The grazing livestock farms, as obviously the most endangered type of farming, are largely extensive farms and primarily located in remote rural areas. These extensive farms are typically managed by elderly farmers with low qualifications who have been engaged in agricultural production for an extended period. Such farmers are not willing to leave agriculture, even if they do not achieve the best results. The reasons they remain in agricultural production are numerous, but the most significant are the difficulty of finding employment outside their own farm due to low qualifications and the very limited opportunities in these areas for anything other than agriculture.
In terms of the determinants of farm economic viability, based on the conducted panel regression analysis, two factors stand out in particular: the asset turnover ratio and economic size. The asset turnover ratio has a positive impact on the economic viability of all types of farming, as expected. Namely, a faster asset turnover is characteristic of more intensive production with shorter production cycles, which consequently contributes to generating higher incomes. Economic size also positively impacts the economic viability of all types of farming, except for permanent crop farms. Farms with access to significant capacities such as land, mechanization, buildings, etc., have greater potential to generate higher incomes and achieve a higher level of economic viability.
For this very reason, farm managers should focus more on using fast-growing crops and livestock units with the best genetic potential. Additionally, investing in new, high-performance equipment could simplify the production process, address the issue of agricultural labour deficiency, and ultimately lead to more productive and economically viable farms. For this purpose, farm managers could utilize available European and domestic funds, which offer favourable conditions. Besides farm managers, the comprehensive analysis of farm economic viability can also be valuable to policymakers responsible for agricultural measures. Obviously, the current subsidy program, which relies on direct subsidies, has proven to be inefficient, which is why the focus should be more toward product quality and resource-use efficiency.
The study makes a significant contribution to the field of agricultural productivity in Western Balkan countries, as there is no existing research that offers such a comprehensive analysis of the economic viability of family farms, with a particular focus on the factors that affect their viability. The research, of course, has certain limitations that should be taken into account when interpreting the obtained results. First, the analysis is based on data from farms in the Republic of Serbia, so a recommendation for future research could be to conduct a similar analysis for a few European Union countries or for a specific region in Europe (e.g., Eastern European or Western Balkan countries). In that case, a potential challenge could be the lack of adequate original data required for the analysis. Secondly, the paper does not cover all potential factors that may have influence the economic viability of farms, as the available FADN database lacks sufficient socio-demographic, environmental, and off-farm income data. A potential solution to this problem could lie in the announced conversion of the FADN into the FSDN (Farm Sustainability Data Network), which will include numerous new data from the aforementioned fields. Thus, the inclusion of a significantly broader range of indicators could be possible, which may certainly be the focus of future research studies.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, A.M. and V.V.; methodology, A.M.; software, A.M.; validation, A.M., M.T.S. and V.V.; formal analysis, A.M. and V.V.; investigation, A.M. and V.V.; resources, A.M., M.T.S. and V.V.; data curation, A.M. and V.V.; writing—original draft preparation, A.M.; writing—review and editing, M.T.S. and V.V.; visualization, A.M.; supervision, M.T.S. and V.V.; project administration, A.M. and M.T.S.; funding acquisition, M.T.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the Science Fund of the Republic of Serbia, grant number: 10843, project title: Farm Economic Viability in the context of Sustainable Agricultural Development—ViaFarm.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in this study are included in the article. Further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest. The funders had no role in the design of the study; in the collection, analyses, or interpretation of data; in the writing of the manuscript; or in the decision to publish the results.

Appendix A

Table A1. Correlation matrix results.
Table A1. Correlation matrix results.
VariableLTEVESSRLSPLAGEATRDIVSUB
Field crops
LTEV1
ES0.35901
SRL0.15900.34901
SPL0.0090−0.05400.03901
AGE−0.1150−0.1580−0.24100.01601
ATR0.21300.11200.27600.1030−0.16301
DIV0.05500.07000.08500.0630−0.02400.07801
SUB−0.1750−0.3240−0.2560−0.04100.0790−0.2220−0.08601
Permanent crops
LTEV1
ES0.26101
SRL0.09400.12201
SPL−0.0380−0.01300.20101
AGE−0.0510−0.21300.0530−0.04001
ATR0.32700.01600.0220−0.01100.11801
DIV−0.0580−0.0900−0.00700.0010−0.12700.03601
SUB−0.11800.0510−0.0460−0.0500−0.0890−0.1160−0.01001
Milk
LTEV1
ES0.70301
SRL0.18300.31401
SPL0.03100.0110−0.20801
AGE−0.1720−0.2020−0.06100.06201
ATR0.22800.30000.4470−0.1190−0.13001
DIV0.07600.06900.04700.03100.0490−0.20601
SUB−0.0130−0.0650−0.13700.13200.0850−0.2600−0.14301
Grazing livestock
LTEV1
ES0.36301
SRL0.17000.41801
SPL−0.0360−0.02200.21801
AGE−0.0130−0.0450−0.09100.21401
ATR0.35600.25400.34900.0150−0.01001
DIV−0.1250−0.08100.05700.0420−0.1200−0.06101
SUB0.03100.0540−0.0790−0.02100.2070−0.1500−0.13501
Mixed
LTEV1
ES0.20001
SRL−0.00100.43101
SPL−0.1050−0.1120−0.11301
AGE−0.0990−0.2650−0.0330−0.01001
ATR0.56800.05800.1200−0.0730−0.07301
DIV−0.19900.31900.4060−0.05500.1570−0.20801
SUB−0.20800.02700.07200.1660−0.1130−0.23700.14301
Source: author’s calculation.
Table A2. Results of the pooled OLS regression model.
Table A2. Results of the pooled OLS regression model.
VariableField CropsPermanent CropsMilkGrazing LivestockMixed
Constant1.4040 *1.4766−1.2151 **0.15510.2017
(0.7540)(1.0113)(0.6003)(0.6592)(0.3679)
ES4.2407 ***5.8750 ***9.9406 ***5.3480 ***2.7295 ***
(0.3108)(1.2962)(0.4180)(0.9159)(0.4523)
SRL−0.38601.0483−0.5143 *−0.3347−0.8195 ***
(0.4381)(0.8045)(0.2627)(0.3665)(0.2718)
SPL0.1955−1.75320.2002−0.3255−0.3533
(0.5086)(1.7179)(0.4461)(1.0083)(0.2738)
AGE−0.0185 *−0.0190−0.0085−0.00300.0024
(0.0110)(0.0165)(0.0068)(0.0086)(0.0058)
ATR1.7460 ***3.5105 ***0.6409 ***2.1862 ***3.1759 ***
(0.2426)(0.5555)(0.3028)(0.3592)(0.2371)
DIV0.4839−1.33731.1376 ***−1.0149−0.6678 ***
(0.6294)(1.2021)(0.6049)(0.6346)(0.2515)
SUB−6.7769−6.6001 *2.3118 *0.9416−1.7684
(5.1089)(3.3614)(1.2969)(0.8955)(1.2849)
N1778336721392462
F-test48.7130 ***11.0993 ***102.4460 ***15.3304 ***41.7632 ***
R20.16150.19150.50140.21840.3917
Notes: standard errors are presented in parenthesis. *** level of significance 1%; ** level of significance 5%; * level of significance 10%. Source: author’s calculation.
Table A3. Results of fixed effects panel regression analysis.
Table A3. Results of fixed effects panel regression analysis.
VariableField CropsPermanent CropsMilkGrazing LivestockMixed
Constant−1.26362.35210.0741 ***−2.83541.2159
(1.9608)(3.8176)(1.6646)(2.0674)(0.9938)
ES4.5639 ***−1.325411.6161 **6.5013 ***5.1540 ***
(0.6850)(1.4996)(0.9943)(1.5112)(1.0378)
SRL−2.6308 *4.44580.5266−0.2021−0.6390
(1.4513)(3.1604)(0.7454)(0.8945)(0.5115)
SPL−0.92845.14370.5169−0.49620.0163
(0.9044)(3.3262)(1.0506)(1.1286)(0.7068)
AGE0.0607 *−0.0306−0.02180.0091−0.0367 **
(0.0345)(0.0704)(0.0298)(0.0365)(0.0167)
ATR4.1708 ***4.0056 ***1.0240 **6.2728 ***3.9857 ***
(0.4210)(0.5978)(0.4711)(0.4812)(0.3149)
DIV−2.8316 ***−1.0874−0.79070.1170−0.1882
(0.9267)(2.1306)(0.7554)(0.7837)(0.5993)
SUB−4.5810−3.01510.43510.6202−0.8482
(4.6660)(3.1509)(1.6206)(0.8610)(1.2973)
N1778336721392462
F-test31.8084 ***7.7679 ***267595 ***29.3718 ***39.8959 ***
R20.12800.16210.23460.38460.4179
Notes: standard errors are presented in parenthesis. *** level of significance 1%; ** level of significance 5%; * level of significance 10%. Source: author’s calculation.
Table A4. Results of random effects panel regression analysis.
Table A4. Results of random effects panel regression analysis.
VariableField CropsPermanent CropsMilkGrazing LivestockMixed
Constant0.95422.3774−0.6175−1.11050.1120
(1.1350)(1.4778)(0.8358)(1.0384)(0.5746)
ES4.5513 ***1.696410.5597 ***5.7484 ***3.5009 ***
(0.4451)(1.3698)(0.6446)(1.2415)(0.6840)
SRL−1.01751.5712−0.3663−0.9603 *−0.8759 **
(0.7081)(1.2403)(0.4070)(0.5662)(0.3832)
SPL−0.38110.31650.4472−0.4106−0.2396
(0.6817)(2.2998)(0.6799)(1.0556)(0.4425)
AGE0.0007−0.0286−0.0073−0.0004−0.0053
(0.0178)(0.0253)(0.0120)(0.0157)(0.0095)
ATR2.9606 ***3.8230 ***0.7686 ***4.8244 ***3.8140 ***
(0.3176)(0.5586)(0.3753)(0.4253)(0.2721)
DIV1.4734 *−1.2198−0.0022−0.4068−0.5326
(0.7672)(1.5475)(0.6661)(0.7194)(0.3856)
SUB−5.4417−3.96350.94530.5697−0.6561
(4.5420)(3.1074)(1.4373)(0.8392)(1.2217)
N1778336721392462
Wald chi2257.8950 ***57.0445 ***344.1950 ***172.9750 ***298.4570 ***
R20.12720.14820.32560.31060.3966
Notes: standard errors are presented in parenthesis. *** level of significance 1%; ** level of significance 5%; * level of significance 10%. Source: author’s calculation.

References

  1. United Nations. Transforming Our World: The 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development (A/RES/70/1); UN General Assembly: New York, NY, USA, 2015; Available online: https://sdgs.un.org/2030agenda (accessed on 8 January 2025).
  2. European Commission. Farm to Fork Strategy. 2020. Available online: https://food.ec.europa.eu/horizontal-topics/farm-fork-strategy_en (accessed on 8 January 2025).
  3. Wiśniewska, J. Economic Sustainability of Agriculture–Conceptions and Indicators. Acta Sci. Polonorum. Oeconomia 2011, 10, 119–137. [Google Scholar]
  4. Latruffe, L.; Diazabakana, A.; Bockstaller, C.; Desjeux, Y.; Finn, J.; Kelly, E.; Ryan, M.; Uthes, S. Measurement of Sustainability in Agriculture: A Review of Indicators. Stud. Agric. Econ. 2016, 118, 123–130. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Ryan, M.; Hennessy, T.; Buckley, C.; Dillon, E.J.; Donnellan, T.; Hanrahan, K.; Moran, B. Developing farm-level sustainability indicators for Ireland using the Teagasc National Farm Survey. Ir. J. Agric. Food Res. 2016, 55, 112–125. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Coppola, A.; Scardera, A.; Amato, M.; Verneau, F. Income Levels and Farm Economic Viability in Italian Farms: An Analysis of FADN Data. Sustainability 2020, 12, 4898. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Hlavsa, T.; Spicka, J.; Stolbova, M.; Hlouskova, Z. Statistical analysis of economic viability of farms operating in Czech areas facing natural constraints. Agric. Econ. 2020, 66, 193–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Poczta-Wajda, A. Economic viability of family farms in Europe—A literature review. Ann. PAAAE 2020, 22, 161–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Slijper, T. The Resilience of European Farm: A Qualitative and Quantitative Assessment. Ph.D. Thesis, Wageningen University and Research, Wageningen, The Netherlands, 15 December 2021. [Google Scholar]
  10. Špička, J.; Dereník, P. How opportunity costs change the view on the viability of farms? Empirical evidence from the EU. Agric. Econ. 2021, 67, 41–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Wilczyński, A.; Kołoszycz, E. Economic Resilience of EU Dairy Farms: An Evaluation of Economic Viability. Agriculture 2021, 11, 510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Hloušková, Z.; Lekešová, M.; Prajerová, A.; Doucha, T. Assessing the Economic Viability of Agricultural Holdings with the Inclusion of Opportunity Costs. Sustainability 2022, 14, 15087. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Spicka, J.; Hlavsa, T.; Soukupova, K.; Stolbova, M. Approaches to estimation the farm-level economic viability and sustainability in agriculture: A literature review. Agric. Econ. 2019, 65, 289–297. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. O’Donoghue, C.; Devisme, S.; Ryan, M.; Conneely, R.; Gillespie, P.; Vrolijk, H. Farm Economic Sustainability in the European Union: A Pilot Study. Stud. Agric. Econ. 2016, 118, 163–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Loughrey, J.; O’Donoghue, C.; Conneely, R. Alternative measures of Family Farm Viability–Incorporating gap measures. J. Rural Stud. 2022, 89, 257–274. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Barnes, A.P.; Hansson, H.; Manevska-Tasevska, G.; Shrestha, S.S.; Thomson, S.G. The influence of diversification on long-term viability of the agricultural sector. Land Use Policy 2015, 49, 404–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Hennessy, T.; Moran, B. The Viability of the Irish Farming Sector in 2015. Teagasc, 2015. Available online: https://www.teagasc.ie/publications/2016/the-viability-of-the-irish-farming-sector-in-2015.php (accessed on 17 January 2025).
  18. Davidova, S.; Gorton, M.; Ratinger, T.; Zawalinska, K.; Iraizoz, B. Farm productivity and profitability: A comparative analysis of selected new and existing EU Member States. Comp. Econ. Stud. 2005, 47, 652–674. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Nurmet, M.; Omel, R. Economic viability by farm size of Estonian family farms. Probl. Agric. Econ. 2020, 362, 14–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Skarżyńska, A.; Abramczuk, Ł.; Goławska, M. Wages for paid labor, farmers’ own labor payment, and production efficiency in the case of Polish farms classified by types of farming. Probl. Agric. Econ. 2022, 370, 22–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Wąs, A.; Sulewski, P.; Majewski, E. Methodical and practical aspects of the parity income in the Polish agriculture. Probl. Agric. Econ. 2019, 359, 3–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Vrolijk, H.C.J.; De Bont, C.J.A.M.; Blokland, P.W.; Soboh, R.A.M.E. Farm Viability in the European Union: Assessment of the Impact of Changes in Farm Payments; Report 2010-011; LEI-Wageningen UR: Den Haag, The Netherlands, 2010; Available online: https://research.wur.nl/en/publications/farm-viability-in-the-european-union-assessment-of-the-impact-of- (accessed on 27 January 2025).
  23. Ziętara, W.; Sobierajewska, J. Competitiveness of the Polish fruit farms. Probl. Agric. Econ. 2017, 350, 101–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Kołoszycz, E. Economic viability of dairy farms in selected European Union countries. Ann. PAAAE 2020, 22, 129–139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Alexandri, C.; Pauna, B.; Saman, C. The determinants of viability for field crop farms in Romania. In Proceedings of the 8th International Conference ESPERA “The Crisis After the Crisis. When and How the New Normal Will Be”, Bucharest, Romania, 9–10 December 2021. [Google Scholar]
  26. Viira, A.H.; Põder, A.; Värnik, R. The factors affecting the motivation to exit farming–Evidence from Estonia. Food Econ.–Acta Agric. Scand C 2009, 6, 156–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Aggelopoulos, S.; Samathrakis, V.; Theocharopoulos, A. Modelling Determinants of the Financial Viability of Farms. Res. J. Agric. Biol. Sci. 2007, 3, 896–901. [Google Scholar]
  28. Ezcurra, R.; Iráizoz, B.; Pascual, P.; Rapún, M. Agricultural productivity in the European regions: Trends and explanatory factors. Eur. Urban Reg. Stud. 2011, 18, 113–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Salvioni, C.; Henke, R.; Vanni, F. The impact of non-agricultural diversification on financial performance: Evidence from family farms in Italy. Sustainability 2020, 12, 486. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Košařová, J.; Pokrivčák, J. Assessing the efficiency of diversified farms in Slovakia using DEA metafrontier approach. J. Cent. Eur. Agric. 2023, 24, 929–941. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Coppola, A.; Scardera, A.; Tosco, D. Economic profitability and long-term viability in Italian agriculture. Politica Agric. Internazionale 2013, 1, 71–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Slavickiene, A.; Savickiene, J. The evaluation of small and medium farms’ economic viability in the new EU countries. Econ. Bus. 2014, 8, 843–855. [Google Scholar]
  33. Vassalos, M.; Karanikolas, P.; Li, Y. Investigating the Impact of Farm Characteristics, Socioeconomic Characteristics and of the Single Farm Payment on the Viability of Farms: The Case of Greece. In Proceedings of the Agricultural & Applied Economics Association and Western Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, San Francisco, CA, USA, 26–28 July 2015. [Google Scholar]
  34. Alexandri, C.; Saman, C.; Pauna, B. Exploring the relationship between farm productivity and the CAP subsidies for the NMS. Rom. J. Econ. Forecast. 2021, 24, 124–140. [Google Scholar]
  35. Graeub, B.E.; Chappell, M.J.; Wittman, H.; Ledermann, S.; Kerr, R.B.; Gemmill-Herren, B. The State of Family Farms in the World. World Dev. 2016, 87, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Lowder, S.K.; Skoet, J.; Raney, T. The number, size, and distribution of farms, smallholder farms, and family farms worldwide. World Dev. 2016, 87, 16–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Davidova, S.M.; Fredriksson, L.; Gorton, M.; Mishev, P.; Petrovici, D.A. Subsistence farming, incomes, and agricultural livelihoods in the new member states of the European Union. Environ. Plan. C Gov. Policy 2012, 30, 209–227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Guiomar, N.; Godinho, S.; Pinto-Correia, T.; Almeida, M.; Bartolini, F.; Bezák, P.; Biró, M.; Bjørkhaug, H.; Bojnec, Š.; Brunori, G.; et al. Typology and distribution of small farms in Europe: Towards a better picture. Land Use Policy 2018, 75, 784–798. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Statistical Office of the Republic of Serbia. Census of Agriculture 2023; Database, 2023. Available online: https://data.stat.gov.rs/Home/Result/1300020106?languageCode=sr-Cyrl (accessed on 13 January 2025).
  40. European Commission. DG AGRI. Definitions of Variables Used in FADN Standard Results, RI/CC 1750; European Commission: Brussels, Belgium, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  41. Coppola, A.; Amato, M.; Vistocco, D.; Verneau, F. Measuring the economic sustainability of Italian farms using FADN data. Agric. Econ. 2022, 68, 327–337. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Frawley, J.P.; Commins, P. The Changing Structure of Irish Farming: Trends and Prospects; Teagasc: Dublin, Ireland, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  43. Gujarati, D.N.; Porter, D.C. Basic Econometrics, 5th ed.; McGraw-Hill/Irwin: New York, NY, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  44. Vuković, B.; Tica, T.; Jakšić, D. Sustainable Growth Rate Analysis in Eastern European Companies. Sustainability 2022, 14, 10731. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Baležentis, T.; Galnaitytė, A.; Kriščiukaitienė, I.; Namiotko, V.; Novickytė, L.; Streimikiene, D.; Melnikiene, R. Decomposing dynamics in the farm profitability: An application of index decomposition analysis to Lithuanian FADN sample. Sustainability 2019, 11, 2861. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Náglová, Z.; Rudinskaya, T. Factors influencing technical efficiency in the EU dairy farms. Agriculture 2021, 11, 1114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Latruffe, L.; Davidova, S.; Balcombe, K. Application of a double bootstrap to investigation of determinants of technical efficiency of farms in Central Europe. J. Prod. Anal. 2008, 29, 183–191. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Karagiannis, G.; Sarris, A. Measuring and explaining scale efficiency with the parametric approach: The case of Greek tobacco growers. Agric. Econ. 2005, 33, 441–451. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Barnes, A.P.; Revoredo-Giha, C.; Sauer, J.; Elliott, J.; Jones, G. A Report on Technical Efficiency at the Farm Level 1989 to 2008; Final Report to Defra: London, UK, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  50. Adelaja, A.; Sullivan, K.; Lake, M.B. Agricultural viability at the urban fringe. In Proceedings of the International Conference on Emerging Issues Along Urban/Rural Interfaces: Linking Science and Society, Atlanta, GA, USA, 13–16 March 2005. [Google Scholar]
  51. Brown, P.; Daigneault, A.; Dawson, J. Age, values, farming objectives, past management decisions, and future intentions in New Zealand agriculture. J. Environ. Manag. 2019, 231, 110–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Argilés, J.M. Accounting information and the prediction of farm non-viability. Eur. Account. Rev. 2001, 10, 73–105. [Google Scholar]
  53. Zorn, A.; Esteves, M.; Baur, I.; Lips, M. Financial Ratios as Indicators of Economic Sustainability: A Quantitative Analysis for Swiss Dairy Farms. Sustainability 2018, 10, 2942. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Kurdyś-Kujawska, A.; Strzelecka, A.; Zawadzka, D. The Impact of Crop Diversification on the Economic Efficiency of Small Farms in Poland. Agriculture 2021, 11, 250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Czubak, W.; Pawłowski, K.P. The Impact of Agricultural Investments on the Economic Efficiency of Production Factors: An Empirical Study of the Wielkopolska Voivodeship. Agriculture 2024, 14, 2217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Milić, D.; Novaković, T.; Tekić, D.; Matkovski, B.; Ðokić, D.; Zekić, S. Economic Sustainability of the Milk and Dairy Supply Chain: Evidence from Serbia. Sustainability 2023, 15, 15234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Share of economically viable farms during the period of 2015–2021. Source: author’s calculation.
Figure 1. Share of economically viable farms during the period of 2015–2021. Source: author’s calculation.
Agriculture 15 00828 g001
Table 1. Overview of variables used in analysis.
Table 1. Overview of variables used in analysis.
VariableSymbolUnit of MeasureFormula
Economic sizeESstandard output S O y 1 = i = 1 n v ¯ y i × u y i
Share of rented landSRLratio R e n t e d   u t i l i z e d   a g r i c u l t u r a l   a r e a   ( h a ) T o t a l   u t i l i z e d   a g r i c u l t u r a l   a r e a   ( h a )
Share of paid labourSPLratio P a i d   l a b o u r   i n p u t   ( h ) L a b o u r   i n p u t   ( h )
Farmer’s ageAGEyearsAge of farm manager
Asset turnover ratioATRratio T o t a l   o u t p u t T o t a l   a s s e t s
Agricultural diversificationDIVHerfindahl–Hirschman index H H I 2 = 1 i = 1 n s i 2
Subsidy levelSUBratio T o t a l   s u b s i d i e s e x c l u d i n g   o n   i n v e s t m e n t s T o t a l   i n c o m e   v a l u e
1  S O y is the value of standard output in a year y; n is number of primary and secondary products in a year y; v ¯ y i is the standard output coefficient for product i in a year y; u y i is the area under specific crop i in crop production or number of livestock units i in livestock production in a year y. 2  s i is the share of the production value of product i in the total production value. The HHI value ranges from 0, indicating specialized farms that generate income from a single type of production, to 1, representing farms with a more diversified production structure. Source: author’s illustration.
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of the LTEV indicator for various types of farming.
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of the LTEV indicator for various types of farming.
Descriptive StatisticsField CropsPermanent CropsMilk Grazing LivestockMixed
Mean2.912.491.601.031.30
Median1.591.440.960.680.85
Lower Quartile0.370.490.500.160.36
Upper Quartile4.163.391.751.401.82
Standard Deviation5.353.882.442.031.53
n254481035666
T77777
N1778336721392462
Source: author’s calculation.
Table 3. Categories of farms according to economic viability by type of farming.
Table 3. Categories of farms according to economic viability by type of farming.
Type of FarmingEconomically Viable FarmsEconomically Non-Viable Farms
Share (%)LTEV (coeff)Share (%)LTEV (coeff)
Field crops61.305.1038.70−0.56
Permanent crops60.714.2439.29−0.21
Milk48.132.8251.870.47
Grazing livestock38.782.5961.220.04
Mixed46.102.4753.900.31
Total54.384.1545.62−0.09
Source: author’s calculation.
Table 4. Results of unit root testing using the augmented Dickey–Fuller test.
Table 4. Results of unit root testing using the augmented Dickey–Fuller test.
VariableField CropsPermanent CropsMilkGrazing LivestockMixed
LTEV−28.4780 **−11.8690 **−12.3940 **−12.7450 **−11.8770 **
ES−13.2360 **−9.3900 **−8.2226 **−7.7807 **−7.3642 **
SRL−12.4620 **−5.4845 **−7.7664 **−5.9092 **−6.3826 **
SPL−15.6160 **−6.9364 **−8.2554 **−8.8595 **−6.3601 **
AGE−12.6830 **−5.8132 **−7.5461 **−5.7282 **−6.2066 **
ATR−16.1000 **−14.3120 **−10.659 **−9.0439 **−10.9890 **
DIV−18.5690 **−8.1598 **−14.2950 **−8.9922 **−6.2619 **
SUB−34.3600 **−17.6560 **−14.5420 **−11.6130 **−12.1800 **
Notes: ** level of significance 5%.
Table 5. Results of testing for the presence of individual and time effects for fixed effects model specification.
Table 5. Results of testing for the presence of individual and time effects for fixed effects model specification.
F-TestField CropsPermanent CropsMilkGrazing LivestockMixed
Test Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p Value
Individual effect5.660.00004.550.00006.120.00009.850.00007.460.0000
Time effect11.510.00004.500.00020.340.91561.130.34461.120.3504
Source: author’s calculation.
Table 6. Results of testing for the presence of individual and time effects for random effects model specification.
Table 6. Results of testing for the presence of individual and time effects for random effects model specification.
Breusch–
Pagan LM Test
Field CropsPermanent CropsMilkGrazing LivestockMixed
Test Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p Value
Individual effect758.810.000072.660.0000361.400.0000245.160.0000276.870.0000
Time effect231.240.000011.360.00081.810.17850.010.93710.070.7940
Source: author’s calculation.
Table 7. Results of the Hausman test for panel regression model specification.
Table 7. Results of the Hausman test for panel regression model specification.
TestField CropsPermanent CropsMilkGrazing LivestockMixed
Test Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p Value
Hausman test38.040.000035.600.000010.190.178045.250.000016.760.0190
Source: author’s calculation.
Table 8. Results of testing for the presence of multicollinearity.
Table 8. Results of testing for the presence of multicollinearity.
VariableField CropsPermanent CropsMilkGrazing LivestockMixed
VIF1/VIFVIF1/VIFVIF1/VIFVIF1/VIFVIF1/VIF
ES1.240.811.090.921.220.821.280.781.430.70
SRL1.280.781.070.931.390.721.450.691.430.70
SPL1.020.981.050.951.070.931.140.881.050.95
AGE1.080.931.110.901.060.941.140.881.190.84
ATR1.140.881.030.971.510.661.200.831.170.86
DIV1.020.981.040.971.140.881.050.951.440.69
SUB1.180.841.030.971.140.881.100.911.130.88
Source: author’s calculation.
Table 9. Autocorrelation, heteroskedasticity, and cross-sectional dependence test results.
Table 9. Autocorrelation, heteroskedasticity, and cross-sectional dependence test results.
TestField CropsPermanent CropsMilkGrazing LivestockMixed
Test Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p ValueTest Statistic p Value
Wooldridge test 10.900.34184.170.0422186.360.00002.440.118924.390.0000
White test65.390.000050.360.0000347.000.000057.590.000043.000.0000
Pesaran CD test39.110.00001.850.064721.510.0000−0.290.77046.670.0000
1 In milk type of farming, the Breusch–Godfrey/Wooldridge test was used to assess the presence of first-order autocorrelation, as the classical Wooldridge test is not applicable to the random effects model. Source: author’s calculation.
Table 10. Results of the evaluation of the transformed regression model.
Table 10. Results of the evaluation of the transformed regression model.
VariableField CropsPermanent CropsMilkGrazing LivestockMixed
Constant−1.26362.3521−0.6175−2.8354 ***1.2159
(3.4474)(1.7650)(0.6240)(1.0529)(1.1316)
ES4.5639 **−1.325410.5597 ***6.5013 ***5.1540 ***
(2.2582)(2.3708)(1.5051)(1.8623)(1.5541)
SRL−2.63084.4458−0.3663−0.2021−0.6390 *
(2.4846)(5.0377)(0.3406)(1.0940)(0.3628)
SPL−0.92845.1437 *0.4472−0.49620.0163
(0.9078)(2.7556)(0.5458)(0.4894)(0.7220)
AGE0.0607−0.0306−0.00730.0091−0.0367 **
(0.0615)(0.0316)(0.0105)(0.0105)(0.0177)
ATR4.1708 ***4.0056 ***0.7686 **6.2728 ***3.9857 ***
(0.7137)(1.0000)(0.3905)(0.6777)(0.3387)
DIV−2.8316 ***−1.0874−0.00220.1170−0.1882
(0.8533)(1.9319)(0.5877)(0.8666)(0.5671)
SUB−4.5810−3.01510.94530.6202−0.8482
(6.2941)(1.9005)(1.0682)(0.6254)(1.1021)
N1778336721392462
F-test/Wald chi213.9421 ***3.1201 ***114.3600 ***23.0068 ***68.8806 ***
R20.12800.16210.32560.38460.4179
Notes: standard errors are presented in parenthesis. *** level of significance 1%; ** level of significance 5%; * level of significance 10%. Source: author’s calculation.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Miljatović, A.; Tomaš Simin, M.; Vukoje, V. Key Determinants of the Economic Viability of Family Farms: Evidence from Serbia. Agriculture 2025, 15, 828. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture15080828

AMA Style

Miljatović A, Tomaš Simin M, Vukoje V. Key Determinants of the Economic Viability of Family Farms: Evidence from Serbia. Agriculture. 2025; 15(8):828. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture15080828

Chicago/Turabian Style

Miljatović, Aleksandar, Mirela Tomaš Simin, and Veljko Vukoje. 2025. "Key Determinants of the Economic Viability of Family Farms: Evidence from Serbia" Agriculture 15, no. 8: 828. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture15080828

APA Style

Miljatović, A., Tomaš Simin, M., & Vukoje, V. (2025). Key Determinants of the Economic Viability of Family Farms: Evidence from Serbia. Agriculture, 15(8), 828. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture15080828

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop