Next Article in Journal
Reinventing a Rural Area: A Case Study into Cultural Festivals in Oldambt, The Netherlands
Next Article in Special Issue
Examining the Potential of Marine Renewable Energy: A Net Energy Perspective
Previous Article in Journal
A Study of GNSS-IR Soil Moisture Inversion Algorithms Integrating Robust Estimation with Machine Learning
Previous Article in Special Issue
Climate and Energy Crises from the Perspective of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change: Trade-Offs between Systemic Transition and Societal Collapse?
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Peaking Dynamics of the Production Cycle of a Nonrenewable Resource

1
Global Sustainability Institute, Anglia Ruskin University, Cambridge CB1 1PT, UK
2
Consiglio Nazionale delle Ricerche (CNR), Istituto di Chimica dei Composti Organo Metallici (ICCOM), Area della Ricerca di Firenze, Via Madonna del Piano 10, 50019 Sesto Fiorentino, Italy
3
Consorzio Interuniversitario Nazionale per la Scienza e la Tecnologia dei Materiali (INSTM), 50121 Florence, Italy
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(8), 6920; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15086920
Submission received: 19 February 2023 / Revised: 8 April 2023 / Accepted: 10 April 2023 / Published: 20 April 2023

Abstract

:
We use a system dynamics model to analyse the cycle of production of a nonrenewable natural resource, with a specific interest in crude oil. This subject has been empirically studied for a long time. However, modelling studies able to correlate the peaking with the parameters of the system have been very rare, and only recently proposed. In the present paper, we examine the timing of the peaking mainly as a function of the energy return for energy invested (EROI). The model provides approximate formulas for evaluating the peak time and “rules of thumb” that are useful for understanding the peaking phenomenon in the exploitation of natural resources. It shows that the peaking of the production curve occurs at a time that is inversely proportional to the EROI of the process at the start of the cycle.

1. Introduction

The idea that the production of a nonrenewable resource follows a “bell-shaped” curve was first proposed by Marion King Hubbert in 1956 for crude oil in the continental United States [1]. The term “peak oil” became fashionable in the early 2000s to indicate the peak of the global oil production curve. The mainstream debate lost interest in the concept of peak oil when some of the early predictions of the peak date turned out to have been misplaced [2].
Bell-shaped curves were later observed for crude oil in several productive regions [3], and the same kind of curve was observed for other fossil fuels (e.g., coal), for mineral resources [4], and for theoretically renewable resources that were exploited faster than they could re-form by natural processes (for instance, whale oil) [5,6,7].
In qualitative terms, the bell-shaped curve is easily understandable considering the differential costs of the extraction (or production) of a nonrenewable resource. Because the cheaper resources are produced first, the cost or production tend to gradually increase, reducing profits. The consequence is a reduction in investments that generates a decline in production. Hence, peaking necessarily appears at some moment.
The concept of peak oil generated a widespread debate, with some authors discounting it as an arbitrary concept [7], while, for others, it represented a watershed that would lead to profound changes in human civilization [8]. Given this attitude, it was believed that determining the peak date in advance was of the utmost importance. Various approaches were used for this purpose, mainly based on fitting the historical data with various mathematical curves [9] or using such methods as “Hubbert Linearization” [10]. These approaches were found to be inaccurate, and the mainstream debate lost interest in peak oil when some of the early predictions of the peak date turned out to have been misplaced [11].
In time, some models based on system dynamics were proposed for the production cycle [2,12,13]. These models are based on measurable parameters, and particularly the one called “Energy Return for Energy Invested” (EROI or EROEI) [14]. The EROI is the ratio of the energy produced by a plant or system over its lifetime to the energy needed to build, supply, maintain, and eventually dismantle the producing plant(s).
The EROI of crude oil has been discussed in depth by Hall, Murphy, and coworkers [8,9,10]. They show the gradual reduction in the EROI of crude oil production as extraction has proceeded over the past decades. It is this reduction that reduces monetary profits and causes a decline in investments.
Nevertheless, these models lacked the capability to determine a fundamental element of the system, the one that had been the objective of many past studies: the timing of the production peak. Therefore, in the present paper, we develop an approximate solution of the differential equations of the resource extraction model, and we use it to determine how the EROI and other parameters affect the timing of the peak. The main result is that the time to peak for a nonrenewable resource extracted in free-market conditions is inversely proportional to the value of the EROI at the start of the production cycle. We apply this model to a real-world “toy system” that shows the main elements of the dynamical model [11].
This study may be used as an alternative method to the empirical ones to estimate the peaking data of a real-world system, but we believe that its main value is to provide a better understanding of the peaking phenomenon in terms of its causes and the parameters that influence it.

2. Methods

The term “complex systems” refers to systems out of thermodynamic equilibrium, typically described as “complex adaptative systems” (CASs) [12] when they are dominated by feedback effects. These systems can be modelled using the technique called “system dynamics” [13], where the elements of the systems under study are described in terms of “stocks” or “levels” linked to each other by “flows” of matter, energy, or other entities. When a flow rate depends on the size of a stock that it connects to, the resulting interaction is called “feedback.” Typically, CASs tend to attain a steady-state condition, defined as homeostasis (or “homeorhesis” when the system oscillates around a fixed set of parameters).
The system dynamics approach can be applied to model the production of a nonrenewable resource, such as crude oil, by the following assumptions:
  • The resource is defined as an initial fixed stock. In the case of crude oil, it is the ensemble of the extractable resources (“URR” (ultimate recoverable resources));
  • The extraction and processing of the resource transform it into a stock called “capital” that aggregates all the economic entities created by the process. The flow from the resource stock to the capital stock is called “production”;
  • The resource stock is depleted proportionally to the size of the capital stock;
  • The capital stock grows in proportion to the amount of the remaining resources, and to the amount of available capital;
  • The capital stock is depleted at a rate proportional to the size of the stock (“depreciation”).
These assumptions can be quantified using system dynamics. In developing the model, we chose the simplest possible assumptions: we assumed that the flows are linearly proportional to the stocks they are connected to, and that there are no other factors affecting them. Other assumptions are possible, but we found that the ones we chose generate a model that is able to reproduce the data from historical cases in a quantitative manner [6,14]. The model is shown in Figure 1, using the graphic conventions of system dynamics (that is, with stocks drawn as boxes and flows as arrows). Note how the model is drawn in such a way as to emphasize that the flows have a “downward” direction, in analogy with the flow of a liquid in a gravitational field. This is just a graphic convention; it does not affect the model itself. Note that the model shown in the figure assumes the possibility of a regeneration of the resource stock, but this does not occur for nonrenewable resources.
The equations underlying the graphic representation of Figure 1 are shown below. We term the two stocks as “Resources” and “Capital” (R and C), and we label the flow constants as kn.
dR/dt = k1R − k2RC
dC/dt = ηk2RC − k3C
In the equations, η (eta) is the efficiency of the transformation of the resource into useful energy to be accumulated in the capital stock. It is a dimensionless number that can go from 0 to 1 if the two stocks are measured using the same units. As written, the model is equivalent to the Lotka–Volterra one [15]. If, instead, the resource is not renewable, then we can assume that k1 = 0, and the first equations (Equations (1)) of the system become as follows:
dR/dt = −k2RC
This set was termed the “single cycle Lotka-Volterra” (SCLV) model in [16]. It reproduces a “bell-shaped” curve, also known as the “Hubbert Curve.” An example of the results of the model is shown in Figure 2.
The model also generates the behaviour of the two stocks of the system, Capital and Resources. The qualitative behaviour of this system is shown in Figure 3.
In the model, the EROI can be defined as the ratio of the energy produced (that is, the flow of energy into the C stock or −ηk2RC) divided by the energy expended (“invested”) by the capital stock (that is, the flow out of the C stock (−k3C)). The result is as follows:
EROI = ηk2R/k3
The EROI value is proportional to the size of the resource stock and declines with time. By setting to zero the first derivative of Equation (2) and comparing to Equation (4), it can be proven that the capital stock peaks and starts declining when the EROI is equal to one [16]. We can write EROIc = 1, with the “c” subscript referring to the capital peak.
Regarding the production curve, the available data are normally much more common than those for the capital curve, and so there is a special interest in determining how the EROI affects peaking. We write the EROI at the peak as EROIp. It can be approximately determined considering that the peak occurs when about half of the URR has been extracted. Hence, Rp = ½R(0) and EROIp = ½ηk2Rp/k3. Alternatively, the EROIp can be determined by setting to zero the second derivative of Equation (3) and combining the result with Equation (4). As discussed in [16], the result is that EROIp = k2Cp/k3 + 1, where, again, the “p” subscript indicates the values of the variables at the production peak. Because all the factors in this expression are larger than zero, it follows that the EROI at the production peak is larger than one. This result tells us that the production peaks earlier than the capital accumulation. This is a behaviour that agrees with the historical data.
These expressions correlate some of the parameters of the model to each other, but they do not tell us anything about the time variable. To estimate the peaking time, we need explicit time-dependent forms of the equations of the model, but such equations do not exist in a general form. Nevertheless, it is possible to simplify the model to obtain approximate expressions.
Let us start by noting that the production curve starts growing earlier than the capital curve, and so it is reasonable to assume that the capital stock (C) is small during the early stages of the cycle. In this case, the term −k3C can be neglected. This assumption is equivalent to assuming that the growth of the stocks is exponential during the early stages of the cycle. In this case, the equations of the model are as follows:
dR/dt = −k2RC
dC/dt = ηk2RC
This system has an analytical solution. First, it must be that C = η (R0 − R), with the “0” subscript indicating the value of the variables at the start of the cycle. Therefore:
dR/dt = −k2η R (R0 − R)
This is the well-known logistic equation, which has the integrated solution as a function of time:
R = R0/(1 + exp(R0k2η(t − t0)))
When t = t0, the exponential is equal to 1 and we have R = ½R0. This means that half of the resource has been extracted. The equation tp = t0 corresponds to the peak time from the start of the exploitation cycle. This can be demonstrated by taking the second derivative of the equation for R and setting it to zero, noting that the peak corresponds to the flex of the resource curve. This interpretation implies that the production curve is symmetric, which is a reasonable approximation in many historical cases. This equality has been extensively used in early studies on oil production to estimate the data of the peak [17]. Finally, note that for R = R0, we have t = −∞.
In the real world, t cannot be −∞, and so we can define a time (ts (“t-start”)) that we take as the start of the cycle. We can take t0 = 0; therefore, the “time to peak” (TtP) is −ts. The remaining resources at t = ts are defined as Rs.
We may now write Equation (6) as follows:
Rs = R0/(1 + exp(R0k2ηts))
From this equation, we can determine the value of the ts if we know the value of the Rs/R0 that we call “F”, which can be calculated from the historical data. It follows that:
exp(R0k2ηts) = 1/F − 1
and
R0k2ηts = ln(1/F − 1)
TtP = ts = ln(1/F − 1)/(R0k2η)
Or, also, from Equation (4):
TtP = ts = ln(1/F − 1)/(k3 EROI0)
Note how the time to peak is inversely proportional to the initial EROI of the system.
We can also examine another time-dependent element generated by the model for which an analytical solution is not directly available. This is the spacing between the production peak and the peak of the capital stock. Historical data describing the latter are not often available, but when they are, the presence of the two peaks is strong evidence of the SCLV mechanism at work. We start by expressing the values of the R stock at the two peaks. Here, “p” stands for “peak production” and “c” stands for “peak capital.” To simplify, we assume η = 1:
Rp = k3/k2 + Cp
Rc = k3/k2
The difference we call ΔRpc is equal to Cp. Because the two peaks are close to each other, we can discretize the first equation of the SCLV model and write ΔRpc/Δt = k2RpCp. Substituting, we have the following:
Δt =1/k2Rp
There follows that the time distance between the two peaks is inversely proportional to k2. Taking into account that EROI = ηk2R/k3, and that the peak occurs at approximately Rp = ½ R(0), it follows that:
Δt = µ/(EROIp · k3/k2Rp)
or
Δt = 2µ/(EROI0 · k3)
We note that the two curves are closer to each other the larger the EROI at the start of the production cycle and the faster the depreciation takes place.

3. Results

3.1. The Mousetrap Experiment

To evaluate the usefulness of the approximations developed in the previous section, we used the parameters of a real system that can be simulated using the equations reported here: the “mousetrap experiment” [11]. In this system, mousetraps loaded with wooden balls play the role of stocks of mechanical energy, while the flying balls are the result of the release of this energy that triggers more release; hence, the “capital” stock is measured by the number of flying balls at any given time. This system shows the same feedback elements as real-world systems, such as petroleum extraction, nuclear chain reactions, epidemic disease diffusion, and others. For the purposes of the present paper, it has the advantage that it is a repeatable laboratory system with parameters that are fully known.
In Figure 4, we show the measured trajectories of the main parameters of the mousetrap system in an average of three experimental tests that we ran.
By fitting the data with the SD model, we obtained the following values for the system’s parameters:
  • k2 = 0.0604 (s−1*nballs−1);
  • η = 2;
  • k3 = 3.31 (s−1);
  • R0 = 50.7 (n traps);
  • C0 = 0.6 (n balls);
  • TtP = 1.2 s (time to production peak);
  • TtC = 1.5 s (time to capital peak);
  • 2 × 0.0604/3.31 = 0.036.
Note that the efficiency factor (µ) is larger than one. This is because the system is described in terms of “proxy” parameters (traps and balls) rather than the actual values of the energy involved.
The complete characterization of this system includes the determination of the EROI at various important points in the cycle. Note, first, that here we do not have the possibility of determining the actual elastic energy of the loaded traps, nor the kinetic energy of the flying balls. The “EROI” is a measure of the yield of the system, and, in this case, the relative yield is the ratio of the (number of balls released)/(number of balls spent). Because each flying ball releases two new balls, this ratio has to be corrected by a factor of 2. This is the η factor in the model.
To check that the above interpretation is correct, we first measure the EROI yield at the peak capital (EROIc). We determined earlier on that this ratio must be equal to 1 if the two stocks are measured in the same units. Now, using the values obtained in the fitting, and noting that the number of untriggered traps at the peak capital is equal to ca. 26, we have EROIc = 2 × 0.06 × 26/3.31 = 0.95, which is approximately correct.
We can now estimate the EROI0 (the EROI at the start of the cycle). Using the same formula as before, we find that the EROI0 = 1.82. Correctly, it is larger than one; otherwise, the chain reaction could not have started. We may also estimate the EROIp (the EROI at the peak of the production curve). From the formula EROIp = k2Cp/k3 + 1, using Cp = 11, we have EROIp = 1.02, which is larger than the EROIc, as it should be.
The “time to peak” (TtP) can be calculated according to the approximate formulas developed in the previous section. We said that TtP ~ ln(1/F − 1)/(R0k2η). F can be estimated by noting that the experiment starts with 50 traps, each loaded with 2 balls. At the start, one extra ball is dropped on the trap array—which corresponds to one-half of an additional trap. So, Rs/R0 is 50/50.5 = 0.99. The result is TtP = 0.77 s, which is correct in terms of the order of magnitude, but smaller than the actual value of TtP = 1.15 s.
Finally, we can calculate the time difference between peak capital and peak production from the following formula: Δt = 1/k2Rp. With Rp = 27 and k2 = 0.0604, we have Δt = 0.6 s. Again, this value can be considered correct as an order of magnitude, but it is double the actual value, which is about 0.3 s.
In conclusion, the model provides approximate results but is correct as orders of magnitude.

3.2. Model Comparison

To evaluate the degree of approximation of the formulas proposed in the present study, we performed simulations using the full SCLV model solved by iterative approximations and compared with the approximate model.
In Figure 5, we show the results for the peak time as a function of 1/k2.
The approximation is good only for relatively large values of k, but the proportionality of the TtP (time to peak) to 1/k2 is evident. This approximation remains valid if we express the time to peak as a function of the value of the EROI at the start of the cycle (EROI0), as shown in Figure 6.
Finally, we tested the dependency of the time distance between the production peak and capital peak. The results are shown in Figure 7, and they confirm that the peaks become closer together for larger values of the initial EROI of the system. Note, though, that the discrepancy of the full model with the approximate model is large for low EROIs, which is consistent with the results obtained with the mousetrap experiment, where the EROI is relatively small.

4. Conclusions

Models are a popular way to understand and manage complex realities. They can be used in basically two ways: one way is to interpret data, and the other is to predict the future. Both are subjected to uncertainties, given the many uncertainties in data and the effects of human factors, such as political decisions, financial effects, and technological factors. However, predicting the future is a difficult task, and there are many cases of failed predictions. Regarding the subject of this study, predicting the future of mineral production has turned out to be difficult. A large number of studies have attempted to provide an answer, and the range of dates proposed is wide, spanning at least a couple of decades. Models failed to predict the rapid growth of nonconventional oil production in the United States, which changed the whole world’s trends and postponed the peak by at least a decade.
What models can do, however, is interpret the past, and the past is always a guide to the future. One shortcoming of many studies on resource production is the lack of a model that interprets the reasons why the exploitation cycle follows a specific path in relation to the physical parameters of the system, such as its energy yield in the case of the extraction of fossil fuels. In this light, the use of the SCLV model to describe the peaking of the production of a nonrenewable resource highlights a fundamental element of the overexploitation phenomenon. We were able to model some parameters that, to the best of our knowledge, were never reported in previous studies on these kinds of biophysical models. The model we developed is necessarily approximate, but it can be used to determine some “rules of thumb” for understanding the peaking phenomenon in the exploitation of natural resources.
The present paper is limited to the examination of a “toy” model as a test bed for the formulas and concepts that we developed. This approach was chosen as a first demonstration that the model can be useful to examine a real-world system. The usability of the model for predictive purposes is still to be tested and examined. Generally speaking, no model can be more accurate than the data that are input, and so extrapolating trends from a limited database is always risky. Our model is no exception to this rule, and it is affected by uncertainties in the historical data, and by all the factors that make predictions difficult when we deal with systems that are influenced by political decisions. For these reasons, we do not claim that our method is better than the simpler ones used so far in peak-oil studies (e.g., “Hubbert Linearization”). Instead, we believe that the main innovative element of the present study, and its fundamental purpose, is the demonstration of the influence of the input parameters on the production cycle length and intensity. In particular, we demonstrate that the duration of the production cycle is inversely proportional to the initial EROI (energy return for energy invested) of the exploitation process. In other words, for the same amount of available resources, systems providing larger initial energy or economic returns are more rapidly overexploited and depleted.
Further research is in progress to examine the historical exploitation cycles of natural resources, including metal ores and rare-earth elements.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, U.B. and A.L.; methodology, U.B.; software, I.P.; validation, U.B. and I.P.; formal analysis, A.L.; resources, I.P.; data curation, U.B. and I.P.; writing—original draft preparation, U.B.; writing—review and editing, I.P and A.L.; supervision, U.B. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Abbreviations

AbbreviationExplanation
CCapital stock
CASComplex adaptive system
EROIEnergy return for energy invested
EROI0EROI at the beginning of the production cycle
EROIpEROI at the production peak
EROIcEROI at the peak of the capital stock
RResource stock
SCLVSingle-cycle Lotka–Volterra
TtPTime to peak
URRUltimate recovery resources

References

  1. Hubbert, M.K. Nuclear Energy and the Fossil Fuels. In Proceedings of the Spring Meeting of the Southern District, San Antonio, TX, USA, 7–9 March 1956; Shell Development Company: San Antonio, TX, USA, 1956. [Google Scholar]
  2. Schneider-Mayerson, M. Peak Oil: Apocalyptic Environmentalism and Libertarian Political Culture; University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  3. Brandt, A.R. Testing Hubbert. Energy Policy 2007, 35, 3074–3088. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Bardi, U. Peak oil, 20 years later: Failed prediction or useful insight? Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2019, 48, 257–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Prior, T.; Giurco, D.; Mudd, G.; Mason, L.; Behrisch, J. Resource depletion, peak minerals and the implications for sustainable resource management. Glob. Environ. Change 2012, 22, 577–587. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Perissi, I.; Bardi, U.; Asmar, T.; Lavacchi, A. Dynamic patterns of overexploitation in fisheries. Ecol. Model. 2017, 359, 285–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  7. Bardi, U. Extracted: How the Quest for Mineral Resources is Plundering the Planet; Chelsea Green: New York, NY, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  8. Murphy, D.D.J.; Hall, C.A.S.C. Energy return on investment, peak oil, and the end of economic growth. Ann. N. Y. Acad. Sci. 2011, 1219, 52–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  9. Murphy, D.J. The implications of the declining energy return on investment of oil production. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. Lond. A Math. Phys. Eng. Sci. 2013, 372, 20130126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  10. Hall, C.A.S.; Lambert, J.G.; Balogh, S.B. EROI of different fuels and the implications for society. Energy Policy 2014, 64, 141–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Bardi, U.; Perissi, I. Revisiting the Mousetrap Experiment: Not Just About Nuclear Chain Reactions. arXiv 2021, arXiv:2110.15215. [Google Scholar]
  12. Mobus, G.E.; Kalton, M.C. Principles of System Science; Springer: New York, NY, USA; Heidelberg, Germany; Dordrecht, The Netherlands; London, UK, 2015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Bruckmann, G. Elements of the system dynamics method. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 1982, 21, 85–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Bardi, U.; Lavacchi, A. A Simple Interpretation of Hubbert’s Model of Resource Exploitation. Energies 2009, 2, 646–661. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Tyutyunov, Y.; Titova, L. From Lotka-Volterra to Arditi-Ginzburg: 90 Years of Evolving Trophic Functions. Biol. Bull. Rev. 2020, 10, 167–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Bardi, U.; Perissi, I.; Lavacchi, A. The Role of Energy Return on Energy Invested (EROEI) in Complex Adaptive Systems. Systems, 2021; in press. [Google Scholar]
  17. Deffeyes, K. Hubbert’s Peak, The Impending World Oil Shortage; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. An interpretation of the two-stock model of the extraction of a mineral resource according to the conventions of system dynamics. The rectangles indicate stocks, while the double-edged connectors indicate flows. Single arrows indicate the effect of the parameters drawn using Vensim™ software. k1, k2, and k3 represent, respectively, the regeneration rate, production rate, and depreciation rate, and they are deeply explained in [6,14]. Figure drawn using Vensim ©.
Figure 1. An interpretation of the two-stock model of the extraction of a mineral resource according to the conventions of system dynamics. The rectangles indicate stocks, while the double-edged connectors indicate flows. Single arrows indicate the effect of the parameters drawn using Vensim™ software. k1, k2, and k3 represent, respectively, the regeneration rate, production rate, and depreciation rate, and they are deeply explained in [6,14]. Figure drawn using Vensim ©.
Sustainability 15 06920 g001
Figure 2. A qualitative illustration of the typical bell-shaped “Hubbert curve” simulated using the SCLV model. The vertical scale is the production of a nonrenewable resource in arbitrary units. The horizontal scale is also in arbitrary time units. This curve may represent the smoothed case of the production of crude oil in a large producing region [1]. It has also been observed for the production of other resources, such as for fisheries [5].
Figure 2. A qualitative illustration of the typical bell-shaped “Hubbert curve” simulated using the SCLV model. The vertical scale is the production of a nonrenewable resource in arbitrary units. The horizontal scale is also in arbitrary time units. This curve may represent the smoothed case of the production of crude oil in a large producing region [1]. It has also been observed for the production of other resources, such as for fisheries [5].
Sustainability 15 06920 g002
Figure 3. Qualitative behaviour of the parameters of the SCLV model. The X-scale is in arbitrary time units, while the Y-scale is in arbitrary energy units. The meanings of the terms are explained in the text.
Figure 3. Qualitative behaviour of the parameters of the SCLV model. The X-scale is in arbitrary time units, while the Y-scale is in arbitrary energy units. The meanings of the terms are explained in the text.
Sustainability 15 06920 g003
Figure 4. Results of the “mousetrap experiment” according to the EROI model. he data shown are the result of averaging three experimental runs. “Untriggered Traps” are the resources, “Flying Balls” are the capital, and the production is the number of flying balls generated per unit time (Figure 3).
Figure 4. Results of the “mousetrap experiment” according to the EROI model. he data shown are the result of averaging three experimental runs. “Untriggered Traps” are the resources, “Flying Balls” are the capital, and the production is the number of flying balls generated per unit time (Figure 3).
Sustainability 15 06920 g004
Figure 5. Comparison of the results of a full-model calculation and the logistic approximation.
Figure 5. Comparison of the results of a full-model calculation and the logistic approximation.
Sustainability 15 06920 g005
Figure 6. The values of the timing of the peak (TtP) as a function of the system EROI at the start, according to the model calculation and logistic approximation. The parameters are those for the “mousetrap” model described before. The results are consistent with those obtained in the previous section. The EROI0 in the mousetrap experiment was 1.8, the experimentally observed TtP was 1.2 s, while the calculated peak using the logistic approximation was 0.8 s. These results are approximately reproduced by the calculations.
Figure 6. The values of the timing of the peak (TtP) as a function of the system EROI at the start, according to the model calculation and logistic approximation. The parameters are those for the “mousetrap” model described before. The results are consistent with those obtained in the previous section. The EROI0 in the mousetrap experiment was 1.8, the experimentally observed TtP was 1.2 s, while the calculated peak using the logistic approximation was 0.8 s. These results are approximately reproduced by the calculations.
Sustainability 15 06920 g006
Figure 7. The effect of the variable initial EROI on the distance between peak production and peak capital. The parameters of the model are the same as those for the “mousetrap” model described in the text. The “Full model” data were calculated by solving the differential equations of the model by iterative methods. The “approximate” model describes a model in which the production peak time was calculated using the approximation described in the text, and the capital peak from solving the equations by iterative calculations. The actual distance of the two peaks is ca. 0.2 s for EROI(0) = 1.8.
Figure 7. The effect of the variable initial EROI on the distance between peak production and peak capital. The parameters of the model are the same as those for the “mousetrap” model described in the text. The “Full model” data were calculated by solving the differential equations of the model by iterative methods. The “approximate” model describes a model in which the production peak time was calculated using the approximation described in the text, and the capital peak from solving the equations by iterative calculations. The actual distance of the two peaks is ca. 0.2 s for EROI(0) = 1.8.
Sustainability 15 06920 g007
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Perissi, I.; Lavacchi, A.; Bardi, U. Peaking Dynamics of the Production Cycle of a Nonrenewable Resource. Sustainability 2023, 15, 6920. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15086920

AMA Style

Perissi I, Lavacchi A, Bardi U. Peaking Dynamics of the Production Cycle of a Nonrenewable Resource. Sustainability. 2023; 15(8):6920. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15086920

Chicago/Turabian Style

Perissi, Ilaria, Alessandro Lavacchi, and Ugo Bardi. 2023. "Peaking Dynamics of the Production Cycle of a Nonrenewable Resource" Sustainability 15, no. 8: 6920. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15086920

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop