Next Article in Journal
Optimizing the Transient Performance of Thermoelectric Generator with PCM by Taguchi Method
Next Article in Special Issue
Developing an Integrated Energy–Economy Model Framework for Islands
Previous Article in Journal
Dynamic Prediction of Natural Gas Calorific Value Based on Deep Learning
Previous Article in Special Issue
Coal or Biomass? Case Study of Consumption Behaviour of Households in the Czech Republic
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Review

Exploring Energy Trading Markets in Smart Grid and Microgrid Systems and Their Implications for Sustainability in Smart Cities

1
Smart Cities Research Center (Ci2-IPT), 2300-313 Tomar, Portugal
2
Institute for Systems Engineering and Computers at Coimbra (INESC Coimbra), 3030-290 Coimbra, Portugal
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2023, 16(2), 801; https://doi.org/10.3390/en16020801
Submission received: 27 November 2022 / Revised: 28 December 2022 / Accepted: 7 January 2023 / Published: 10 January 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Sustainable Development, Energy Economics and Economic Analysis)

Abstract

:
Smart cities are aimed at connecting urban infrastructures to enhance the efficiency of their operation and services while taking sustainability goals into consideration. As a result of the intermittency associated with renewable generation, smart city systems such as smart grids and microgrids may not be able to ensure the security of supply. This can be mitigated by allowing these systems to trade surplus energy with other neighboring systems through local energy markets based on peer-to-peer schemes. Such an approach can play an important role on achieving sustainability due to the positive impacts at the economic, social, and environmental level. Therefore, this work explores the design of local energy markets to help determine how they are relevant to smart grid and microgrid applications and what their contributions are to sustainability in smart cities. Essentially, this is achieved by performing a literature review to address key characteristics related to the design of local energy markets while considering their relationship with urban sustainability. In addition, the concept of game theory and its potential to evaluate market designs are also introduced and discussed. Finally, the suitability of centralized, decentralized, and distributed market designs for each dimension of sustainability is estimated based on their design characteristics.

1. Introduction

Information and communication technologies (ICTs) provided the opportunity for cities to become digital, connected, structured, and in a way, more efficient and smarter. This paved the way for the introduction of a smart and sustainable urban environment, i.e., smart city, capable of improving the quality of life of its citizens and enhancing the efficiency of its operation and services through ICTs [1]. The commonly accepted definition of sustainable development defined by the United Nations in the Brundtland Report is applied to the concept of the smart city with an emphasis on an equilibrium among the dimensions of economic, social, and environmental sustainability [2,3]. Hence, this aspect of urban sustainability needs to be considered and embedded in the definition and various domains and subdomains of smart cities. The key indicators of a smart city vary widely in the literature, but generally include smart economy, smart people, smart governance, smart mobility, smart environment, and smart living [4,5]. These indicators are enabled by the smart infrastructure, which is the main domain of smart cities and serves as the foundation that supports the various subdomains. Smart grids (SGs) and microgrids (MGs) are an important part of the smart infrastructure, allowing cities to effectively meet their energy and transportation needs while taking into consideration various aspects at the economic, technical, social, and environmental level [6].
An MG is seen by the US Department of Energy as a smart and small-scale electrical power system incorporated with controllable loads, energy storage system (ESS), and microgeneration units such as renewable energy sources (RES) [7], being capable of operating in both grid-connected and islanded modes when allowed by the national regulatory agency (NRA). The ability to connect with the public grid at the point of common coupling (PCC) and successfully operate in both modes is mainly granted by the various control and protection devices that guarantee a safe, reliable, and optimal operation under all circumstances [7,8]. The mitigation of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions is an important benefit of MGs due to the extensive use of RES, but this type of system has also been developed as an effective way of solving the power supply crisis in remote and isolated locations [9,10]. In general, single MGs are usually only applied at a small scale or at the individual or community level, while SGs encompass a more complex system at a much larger scale. Groups of interconnected MGs can also be seen as an SG [11].
Certain RES such as photovoltaic (PV) panels and wind turbines are considered non-dispatchable, variable, and heavily dependent on weather conditions [12]. As a result of this intermittency, it is increasingly difficult to ensure a reliable balance between power generation and consumption. In particularly, prosumers (i.e., individual consumers able to produce and share electricity) and certain systems such as MGs operating in a cluster of interconnected MGs may not be able to ensure the continuous supply of critical and essential loads during islanded operation mode (i.e., when the MG cluster is operating disconnected from the public grid), because they mostly rely on RES and ESS. This can be mitigated by allowing MGs to cooperate and trade energy with other neighboring MGs, as well as with any other peers (i.e., producers, prosumers, and consumers) in the same distribution grid [8]. A local energy market (LEM) based on a peer-to-peer (P2P) scheme facilitates this energy trading and provides benefits to both participants and utilities [12].
Recently, the ability to transact energy in a P2P manner has been a topic of interest among researchers, especially in the field of SGs and MGs. Because of this, many works in the literature have addressed the implementation of LEMs to enable P2P energy trading in a wide variety of applications [13]. Although, the practical implementation of P2P energy trading and collaboration between systems in SG and MG applications is still in the early stages. Some works in the literature have focused on providing a brief review of existing P2P energy trading projects [14,15], while others have provided an extensive overview of various aspects associated with the operation of energy trading markets and their design [16,17,18,19,20,21,22]. Many works are also strongly focused on the control and energy management of SGs or MG clusters [8,23]. However, these works have not addressed the potential of P2P energy trading and distinct market designs for achieving a level of sustainability in the context of smart cities. Therefore, the contents of this work aim to address key aspects related to the design and evaluation of LEMs for P2P energy trading as well as their relationship with urban sustainability in the smart city context. This is performed through a review of the most relevant works in the literature with the goal of contributing a potential answer to the research question: How can LEMs for P2P energy trading be enabled in SG and MG systems and what are the implications of different market designs for sustainability in smart city ecosystems? In order to tighten this literature gap, it is important to provide a comprehensive overview of the most important aspects of P2P energy trading in SG and MG systems, and at the same time, address the benefits and potential shortcomings of LEMs for sustainability and regulatory challenges brought by market decentralization and distributed ledger technology (DLT) such as blockchain technology. In addition, game theory is introduced and discussed due to its potential to effectively evaluate market designs and analyze decision-making behaviors of market players. Game-theoretic approaches can play a key role in SG and MG applications, allowing us to obtain fair and optimal outcomes in highly competitive market settings with distinct player goals and preferences.
This paper is organized as follows: Section 2 provides details on the systematic methodology used to perform the literature review. Section 3 introduces the concept of LEMs for P2P energy trading and its relationship with MGs while addressing potential barriers and value propositions of MG projects. Section 4 and Section 5 present a comprehensive comparison between the different market designs and trading platforms, including the use of blockchain technology. Section 6 addresses the importance of game theory and its role on SG and MG applications to provide adaptability and enable an effective and fair P2P energy trading among market participants. Section 7 presents a panoply of economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal or political implications associated with LEMs for P2P energy trading. Section 8 discusses the relative suitability of energy market designs for each dimension of sustainability and addresses the scalability and replicability of SG and MG projects. Finally, Section 9 presents the main conclusions based on the various aspects addressed throughout the paper.

2. Method

Literature Review Methodology

The key aspects related to the implementation of LEMs for P2P energy trading in SGs and MG systems, as well as their implications for sustainability in the topic of smart city ecosystems, have been addressed based on a literature review. Figure 1 shows the percentage of documents that address these aspects. The sources were identified through an article title, abstract, and keyword search using the Scopus database and through a secondary search using Google Scholar to identify potential commercial reports and other documents. The search performed for this work prioritized relevant documents published in recent years (i.e., after the year 2016 with special attention to publications from 2019 to 2022). Figure 2 provides details on the systematic methodology used to identify, select, and categorize English literature publications (i.e., journal articles, conference papers, book chapters, commercial reports, and working papers). After the removal of duplicate sources through a deduplication process, an abstract screening process was performed for the remaining set of documents in accordance with the following screening criteria:
  • Sources in English language;
  • Sources proposing centralized, decentralized, or distributed/hybrid market designs for LEMs and P2P energy trading;
  • Sources proposing centralized or decentralized trading platforms to enable P2P energy trading;
  • Sources addressing advantages and/or disadvantages of each market design and trading platform, as well as sources providing empirical evidence for comparison;
  • Sources addressing the use and benefits of game-theoretic approaches in P2P energy trading applications;
  • Sources proposing cooperative and/or non-cooperative game-theoretic models to improve transactions in SG and MG systems;
  • Sources addressing economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal benefits and/or shortcomings of LEMs and P2P energy trading;
  • Sources addressing the potential of LEMs and P2P energy trading for sustainability in the topic of smart and sustainable cities.
Then, the selection of potential documents to be used in this work was performed by undergoing a full-text analysis. This methodology allowed us to categorize the key aspects of LEMs into three main topics or categories:
  • Characteristics of energy market designs and trading platforms (Section 4 and Section 5);
  • Evaluation and modelling of energy markets through game theory (Section 6);
  • Implications of energy markets for sustainability (Section 7).

3. Background to LEMs and MGs

The concept of P2P is not entirely new and has been used in a wide variety of applications, ranging from computer networks to energy management. In the context of MG systems, P2P energy trading allows each individual MG to share its resources and trade energy with other neighboring peers (i.e., other MGs or any producer and prosumer) in order to ensure the security of supply. Depending on the installed capacity and location, certain peers may be able to support and supply the loads of neighboring peers with deficit energy by exchanging their excess energy [8,14]. A LEM can facilitate this energy trade among individual MGs and offer transparency to each transaction between sellers and buyers. This can be particularly important for the concept of smart city to achieve a complete connection among the distinct city entities by allowing them to interact and share their resources with each other [24]. Implementing a LEM can provide numerous benefits to both the participant and the power system, being considered by IRENA as one of the 30 innovative solutions to enhance power system flexibility, grant increased access to renewable energy, empower consumers, and allow for a higher availability and more cost-effective use of RES [25].
A well-known and successful implementation of a LEM is the real-world case of the Brooklyn MG part of the TransActive Grid project, which uses blockchain technology to allow local P2P energy trading among the participants without relying on a central entity to manage the transactions [12,14]. Besides this case, several regional and national projects have been developed for P2P energy trading with some of the most relevant ones being Piclo in the United Kingdom, Vandebron in the Netherlands, and Yeloha and Masaic in the United States [14,15]. In a smaller scale, other projects have been developed for P2P energy trading in MG systems, including PeerEnergyCloud in Germany and TransActive Grid in the United States. The PeerEnergyCloud project was developed using a cloud-based trading platform for the local transaction of excess energy within a MG [12,14].
As represented in Figure 3, the market design, trading platform, and physical infrastructure are some of the key aspects of P2P energy trading in LEMs. In any of the designs, each upper layer is responsible for the control of the lower layer. The use of game theory, namely cooperative and non-cooperative games, is also an important aspect to consider when designing a P2P energy market to model the decision-making behaviors among market participants, being reflected in the sheer number of publications proposing game-theoretic approaches [16,17,18,19,20,21,22]. The energy trading platform is part of the virtual layer and contains an information system that interacts with the energy management system [12].
This work is only focused on the aspects associated with the virtual layer and does not address the physical layer of LEMs, although it is worth mentioning that the physical layer mainly includes the physical infrastructure responsible for the power flow and data communication between peers or devices. Depending on the communication requirements and type of network (e.g., WAN, NAN, and HAN), the communication between the trading platform and smart meters and devices can be achieved through various communication protocols and standards using wired technologies (e.g., DSL, PLC, and optic fiber) or wireless technologies (e.g., Wi-Fi, WiMax, ZigBee, Bluetooth, and Cellular 3G/4G/5G) [26]. Many works have been specifically proposed for SGs and MG systems, but even the ones proposed for other applications such as electric vehicles (EV) and battery energy storage systems (BESS) can be effectively integrated into MG applications.
Table 1 presents relevant works available in the literature which propose market design models, trading platforms, and game-theoretic approaches for P2P energy trading in LEMs.

3.1. Relationship between LEMs and MGs

LEMs can be seen as local energy communities, which are considered and treated as legal entities consisted of local system operators, generators, and consumers. Such communities aggregate DERs in a local area, allowing us to mitigate forecast errors of renewable energy generation and turn community members into active market players [63]. This is facilitated through consumer-centric schemes for P2P energy trading to enable the concept of P2P economy also known as sharing economy [64]. The active engagement from community members can lead to the provision of ancillary services to DSOs and reduction of additional costs associated with grid usage and expansion, extending the charging network for EVs in MGs and facilitating the transition to smarter, cleaner, and more flexible grid systems [63,65].
There is a close relationship between the concept of local energy community and the concept of MG or SG. According to [65], the definitions of local energy community available in the literature do not concern technology, unlike the definitions of MG. The concept of local energy community focuses solely on the community as space, as stakeholder, and as shared interest. It mainly concerns the area affected, who develops and runs the project, and who benefits from the project in socio-economic terms. MGs can be owned by a utility or any other private or public company, but in certain cases, the community can act as a stakeholder by implementing and operating an MG itself. In either case, the local energy community is electrically served by the MG, independently of the ownership [65].
MGs interact with the LEM or community as well as with the upper wholesale market layer in order to provide various ancillary services to both DSOs and TSOs [66]. These services can include black start capability, congestion management, reactive power and voltage control support, harmonics compensation, frequency regulation, load following, and spinning, non-spinning, and replacement reserves [67]. Depending on local or regional regulation, SGs and MGs can provide increased flexibility to TSOs as they can be treated as effective means of grid expansion. This has the potential to increase reliability and effectively extend the power supply to remote and isolated locations [66,68].

3.2. Barriers Associated with MGs

While MGs can provide various benefits and services to facilitate the implementation of LEMs [66], there are technical, social, institutional, economic, and regulatory challenges that constitute potential barriers to their widespread adoption [69,70].
Technical challenges may involve developments in control of MGs with meshed topology, improvements in islanding detection techniques, changes in fault currents by location and operation mode, lack of grounding systems for DC MGs, and difficulties in implementing controllers for plug-and-play capabilities and in managing, exchanging, and processing large amounts of data [64,69]. The islanded operation of MGs is associated with some challenges which may include the ability of DERs to locally change power output according to the frequency and voltage of the MG or the capability of grid-forming power inverters to provide synthetic inertia and regulation of frequency and voltage [71]. Another potential technical barrier can be related to the lack of conformity with communication protocols and standards or the inappropriate design of energy resources, energy market, infrastructure, and various systems, which can diminish the overall efficiency, reliability, and lifespan of SGs and MGs [69,70]. In particularly, user privacy and cybersecurity has received a lot of attention to ensure the privacy of users and the integrity and security of data [64]. The availability of secure and anonymous data is important to estimate grid constraints, determine the need for consumer-centric services, and guarantee a healthy growth of competition among market players in local flexibility markets [64,72].
Social challenges often include the ability of community members to be persuaded in being actively engaged in MG projects during the planning stage and accept the integration of various RES and smart devices, as well as the lack of qualified and experienced community members with adequate knowledge regarding energy management or system maintenance [69,70]. Moreover, other social challenges can be related to the identification of potential triggers for behavioral changes via incentives and the lack of mutual agreements or cooperation among all involved parties (e.g., community members, investors, or system planners and developers) [64,69,70]. The lack of engagement in MG projects and market activities is often a result of the lack of interest on the part of consumers or the lack of understanding and willingness to understand [64].
Institutional challenges are generally related to inertia in changing the structure of power systems and difficulties in decision-making and coordination among stakeholders. These challenges also encompass some economic barriers associated with lack of incentives, financial capacity, or capital to make significant high-risk investments in MG projects and uncertainty regarding future revenues and hidden costs [69,70]. From an economic perspective, it is important to overcome the challenge of defining common frameworks for profitable business models and identifying, evaluating, and comparing new or existing business models applicable to SGs and MGs from on-going project demonstrations [64].
Regulatory challenges include the assurance of user privacy and cybersecurity, lack of incentive for community members to provide flexibility, and uncertain contractual agreements between market players [69,73]. In certain cases, the existence of ineffective initiatives or lack of proper policy and frameworks may discourage stakeholders and players, preventing them from being interested in MG projects. This constitutes a potential barrier to the development of mechanisms and schemes (e.g., feed-in tariffs, net metering, net billing, and tax incentives), which are needed to promote and facilitate the integration of RES and trade of excess energy between community members in a SG or MG [70]. According to [64], some of the regulatory challenges in SGs and MGs can be associated with the provision of incentives for smart metering data, demand response (DR), and commercial arrangements, as well as the need to provide clear rules and set responsibilities regarding competition, ownership, and technical and financial conditions [64]. Regulation also plays a key role on allowing the use of blockchain technology for automated transactions between parties and increasing its potential in existing SG and MG applications [64].
Several European projects have been developing approaches to address some of these challenges. The proposed projects are mainly focused on upgrading the existing architecture (e.g., SmartNet and IDE4L projects) or based on introducing essential changes to the architecture through decentralized systems with local autonomy in the optimal management of resources (e.g., Web of Cells and LINK-Solution projects) [72].

3.3. Value Proposition of MGs

MG projects can support the implementation of LEMs and provide a panoply of services or value propositions to all involved market players [66,74]. This should be addressed to help understand the diversity of business models available for MG projects. Table 2 presents the importance ranking of value propositions offered by MGs to projects located in the United States, Canada, Germany, Denmark, Mozambique, India, South Korea, China, Singapore, and Japan [74,75].

4. Energy Market Design

The implementation and operation of P2P energy trading in LEMs requires a market design capable of dealing with the increased penetration of RES and effectively enable participants to share their resources with other peers in the same network. Depending on how they are structured, these energy market designs can be categorized as centralized, decentralized, and distributed markets [16,17,18,19,20,21,22], as briefly represented in Figure 4. Table 3 presents a comparison among centralized, decentralized, and distributed market designs, summarizing the main characteristics and the most noticeable advantages and disadvantages of each design.

4.1. Centralized Market Designs

A centralized market design relies on pool market trading and involves a central entity to manage and coordinate the energy transactions between the participants [16,17], as represented in Figure 4A. The central entity is responsible for making decisions regarding prices and for directly managing the amount of energy exported and imported based on data collected from each peer [16,19,20].
Some works available in the literature have addressed the implementation of centralized market designs, mainly focusing on the optimization and reduction of energy costs. Alam et al. in [27] proposed a near-optimal cost algorithm, called “Energy Cost Optimization via Trade” (ECO-Trade), for the optimization of the energy trade and to avoid unfair cost distribution in a centralized market design by coordinating the P2P energy trade in smart homes with demand-side management (DSM) system. In [28], two centralized market designs, called “Flexi User” and “Pool Hub”, are proposed for P2P energy trading in a LEM incorporated with BESS to achieve energy cost savings. Long et al. in [29] proposed a two-stage aggregated control for P2P energy trading in community MGs by simply using one-way communication links and measurements at the PCC. The energy resources of each individual prosumer were controlled and managed using a central entity or third-party entity known as the energy sharing coordinator (ESC), being able to reduce the energy bills and costs of the community.

4.1.1. Advantages of Centralized Markets

This market design allows the central entity to maximize the social welfare of the entire P2P energy market and increase the overall market efficiency [21,78,79]. The study in [22] found that decentralized energy markets result in a small welfare loss of around 4.25% when compared to centralized energy markets, which can be a significant difference considering the annual trade volume occurring in large-scale markets. There is also less uncertainty of power generation and consumption patterns with a centralized market design, given the increased direct control of the central entity over the device operation of peers [16,21,80].
Ahlqvist et al. in [81] addresses and discusses wholesale electricity markets, providing a detailed comparison of the main advantages and disadvantages of adopting centralized and decentralized market designs. In wholesale electricity markets, a centralized design can ensure the technical and economic feasibility of the day-ahead dispatch by relying on the central entity to manage and coordinate electricity production. This coordination and decision making is achieved by taking into consideration several network aspects such as power plant location, costs, and ramp rates, which are submitted to the central entity as part of the bid [81]. Because centralized electricity markets use marginal or uniform pricing based on the variable costs of the marginal generation unit or power plant, they can set a clear and well-defined market price for all transactions at a specified location [78,81]. These well-defined market prices are only possible if there are no uplift payments or other form of compensation to help finance start-up and no-load costs, which often provide producers an incentive to exaggerate or overstate their variable costs [81]. Due to increased coordination, these markets can also help providing various grid services and delivery of high-quality energy [19].

4.1.2. Disadvantages of Centralized Markets

A centralized market design raises a few autonomy and privacy concerns because of the amount of data each peer sends to the central entity and its ability to directly influence their decisions and outcomes of deals [16]. Privacy can become a concern for market participants because sensitive information regarding personal preferences, load properties, and daily habits can easily be disclosed during the bidding processes [80]. In addition, the existence of a single central entity to manage the entire market makes it unable to scale and vulnerable to a single-point failure [78].
Another disadvantage of the centralized market design is the high computational and communication burden [17], especially in P2P energy markets with many distributed energy resources (DERs) and peers participating simultaneously in the energy trade [16,21,66]. This large number of market assets is likely to cause severe problems related to data collection and communication faults for the central entity, reducing the scalability of the centralized network [80]. More specifically, the presence of various dynamic costs, as well as network and production constraints in the bidding process, prevents the separation of the market clearing of adjacent supply periods in the optimization of day-ahead dispatch. This contributes to a significant increase of the computational burden required for a fast and transparent market clearing procedure free of faults, especially if the day-ahead market needs to be cleared within a short time frame (i.e., from 5 min to 1 h). For large-scale markets, the scalability of the network can be substantially reduced as the clearing procedure becomes more complex and challenging to perform in short time frames [80,81]. This constitutes a challenge to attain an optimal dispatch within such a short time frame in the day-ahead market, thus having to rely on approximations determined by an opaque iterative procedure which reduces market transparency and forces participants to place their trust on the central entity [81].
The response to grid events such as uncertain generation from RES, power outages, and network disturbances is usually slow in day-ahead markets with a centralized market design. This is a result of producers or prosumers being forced to wait for the real-time or hour-ahead market in order to correct or adjust their day-ahead dispatch [78,81]. Centralized markets are often rigid and offer low day-ahead dispatch flexibility, making intra-day market trading a difficult task for producers with day-ahead unit commitment and tailored-made contracts. In certain cases, penalties can be issued to prevent producers from revising and optimally adjusting their day-ahead dispatch. This inflexibility is also reflected in the ability to develop new bidding strategies to properly integrate ESS and DR programs, which require high costs and long periods of time [81].

4.2. Decentralized Market Designs

A decentralized market design discards the central entity and allows energy to be directly traded between the participants through bilateral trading [16,17], as represented in Figure 4B. Because there is no central entity to manage and coordinate the transactions, this market design is operated in a less organized and structured manner with lower market efficiency [16,19,20]. According to the literature, decentralized market designs are often considered as pure and full P2P networks.
There have been several works being proposed in the literature regarding decentralized market designs, being mostly focused on satisfying the preferences of participants and on maximizing social welfare. Sorin et al. in [30] introduced a P2P market structure based on a multi-bilateral economic dispatch (MBED) formulation in a fully decentralized manner. This allowed for a more pro-active participant behavior and enabled multi-bilateral trading with product differentiation in respect to participant preferences while maximizing social welfare. Morstyn et al. in [31] presented a new scalable decentralized market design for P2P energy trading using forward and real-time bilateral contract networks to satisfy full substitutability conditions and obtain a stable outcome. Khorasany et al. in [32] proposed a fully decentralized market design for P2P energy markets with high penetration of DERs. By using bilateral trading with product differentiation, the proposed design respected the preferences of participants and enabled them to trade energy while maximizing the social welfare and reducing the amount of data exchanged in the system. Antal et al. in [33] presented a blockchain-based decentralized market to enable prosumers to trade their energy profile flexibility in a fully P2P manner. The results of this decentralized market showed complete self-consumption of renewable energy generated in a small-scale urban MG, which facilitated the P2P transactions of DSM among prosumers. Khorasany et al. in [34] proposed an energy trading optimization framework for a decentralized market containing smart buildings with BESS and aggregated EVs. This framework was focused on maximizing social welfare through P2P energy cooperation among participants. Hu et al. in [35] relied on game theory to develop a decentralized energy trading framework for an oceanic islanded MG. This framework was able to maximize the revenue of the aggregator and minimize the energy costs for each participant.

4.2.1. Advantages of Decentralized Markets

This type of market provides a high level of autonomy and privacy for participants, because no data is sent to a central entity and each peer is directly responsible for their own decisions and has control over the outcomes of deals [79]. The absence of a central entity increases reliability as it eliminates problems associated with single-point failures [16,17]. This also offers high scalability, flexibility, and plug-and-play capability to the network, allowing peers to easily enter or leave the energy trading market if they so desire [16,21]. The fewer number of communication links compared to centralized energy markets is an important factor that contributes to the increased scalability [30].
As addressed by [81] in the context of wholesale electricity markets, a decentralized market design provides a more transparent and straightforward way to facilitate hedging and simplify market clearing, which can also increase the scalability of the network. This is achieved by performing a decoupling of supply periods in the day-ahead market. Market prices received by producers and paid by consumers are dependent on the respective zonal spot prices, being advantageous for investments and facilitating the hedge of profits for prosumers and optimal dispatch based on estimates [78,81].

4.2.2. Disadvantages of Decentralized Markets

The lack of a central entity to optimally manage and control each transaction deteriorates the social welfare of the P2P energy market and reduces its efficiency [21,22,78,79]. The reduction of social welfare is a result of producers and prosumers avoiding losses due to non-convexities by offering their electricity at a price higher than their marginal cost [78,81]. Moreover, the management of a decentralized market network is known to be relatively complex due to several hidden constraints (e.g., participant interests and device operation) that are difficult for the distribution system operator (DSO) to visualize and predict, which also contributes to the low overall efficiency of the market [16].
Decentralized market designs often rely on block orders, which can increase the complexity of the bidding process due to the large number of different block types or combinations of supply hours [81,82], although this complexity can be mitigated by applying block type restrictions on block orders [82]. While the increased complexity can be a drawback, block orders also provide additional flexibility in intra-day markets, allowing producers to increase their generation output during a certain period by simply selling more for that period in the intra-day market [78,81]. In addition, continuous intra-day trading in decentralized markets may suffer from problems related to the lack of full consideration for grid transmission constraints due to the fast and overwhelming market clearing process. Such problems cause zonal pricing inefficiencies in large networks, favoring fast traders rather than network owners. There is an incentive for automated high-frequency trading in continuous intra-day trading, resulting in a problematic large number of orders needed to be clearer in a short time frame [81]. This type of energy market can also induce a level of competition among participants, but without a central entity to coordinate the energy trade, it may be unable to provide or guarantee the delivery of high-quality energy to the consumers [19].

4.3. Distributed Market Designs

A distributed market design can be seen as a combination of the centralized and decentralized market designs, in which various central entities, in this case called coordinators or agents, are used to coordinate the transactions but participants can trade energy with each other without their direct influence [16,17], as represented in Figure 4C. The role of central entities or coordinators in a distributed market design is relatively limited compared to their role in centralized market designs because they cannot manage the amount of energy each peer exports or imports [16,19,20].
The works available in the literature encompassing distributed market designs are mainly focused on the development of pricing mechanisms to enable and facilitate P2P energy trading in SGs and MG systems. For instance, Long et al. in [36] proposed three distinct pricing mechanisms for P2P energy trading in a community MG to increase income for producers and reduce energy costs for consumers. These pricing mechanisms included bill sharing, mid-market rate, and auction-based pricing with specified detailed business models, energy trading prices, and individual participant energy costs. Liu et al. in [37] proposed a P2P energy trading model with price-based DR for MGs. This was achieved by using an equivalent cost model based on the energy consumption flexibility of prosumers and a dynamic internal pricing model based on the supply and demand ratio of PV energy traded. Furthermore, Nunna and Srinivasan in [38] proposed an agent-based transactive energy management framework for distribution systems with multiple MGs, enabling each MG to buy or sell energy in the internal auction-based market. In the context of social welfare in distributed market designs, Kang et al. in [39] proposed a P2P energy trading model to enable local electricity trading among plug-in hybrid electric vehicles (PHEVs) in SGs. This was achieved by using an iterative double-auction mechanism to determine the price and amount of electricity traded and thus maximize social welfare. Concerns associated with the security and privacy of the PHEVs are also considered in the proposed model, showing a relative improvement of the protection level. Wang et al. in [40] presented a model for a distributed energy trading market using game theory to study the cooperative benefits between several EV charging stations and integrated energy systems. This model was able to reduce energy costs for the integrated energy systems and increase profits for the EV charging stations by considering individual participant interests and various uncertainties associated with market prices, renewable energy generation, and DR. Khorasany et al. in [41] proposed a hybrid energy trading scheme for distributed energy trading markets, in which market participants could transact in different LEMs, neighborhood areas, or even transact with the grid. Each LEM relied on a central entity known as the community manager (CM) to facilitate the process of energy trading and negotiate with the other CMs for energy trading between distinct markets. Finally, Yao et al. in [85] proposed a strategy for distributed energy trading markets to determine the optimal trading decisions of competitive prosumers and enable successful transactions between them using prospect theory and adaptive learning process.

4.3.1. Advantages of Distributed Markets

Like decentralized designs, a distributed market design can enable a certain level of autonomy and privacy for participants by limiting the amount of data sent to the central entities and by not directly controlling the operation of devices. This allows peers to autonomously maximize their own individual benefits [16,70]. Distributed market designs can also provide increased network scalability for the ICT infrastructures and easier integration in existing infrastructure [17,20]. According to [40], distributed or hybrid market designs can provide a level of network scalability higher than centralized market design because the number of market participants is decreased as they are divided into groups or communities, which reduces the overall computational and communication requirement.
The existence of various coordinators encourages or promotes the development of these various groups or cooperative communities of like-minded peers with common interests and preferences, which form around each coordinator and contain their own market clearing price [19,40]. This could be referred to as an organized prosumer group, in which a group of prosumers share and combine their resources as denoted in [19]. Each coordinator can be a non-profit entity that interacts with the DSO and solely focused on serving and benefiting the members of its community by increasing the social welfare and optimizing prices for sellers and buyers [84]. Distributed market designs can also take into consideration network constraints to avoid congestion in distribution branches. As suggested in [40], this can be achieved by introducing a network utilization charge to integrate operating conditions of the network into each energy transaction and generate a local price signal based on the network constraints. Like centralized designs, a distributed energy market can also help providing various grid services and delivery of high-quality energy [19].

4.3.2. Disadvantages of Distributed Markets

The pricing mechanisms used in distributed market designs can be relatively complex due to the existence of multiple simultaneous markets and may require further development to be effective for P2P energy trading [16,17]. Moreover, this type of market design encompasses a challenge related to the high difficulty in integrating and managing data sets from the various prosumer groups or communities [17,19,20].

5. Energy Trading Platform

LEMs require an effective energy trading platform to successfully allow all the participants to trade energy with each other, as well as with retail and wholesale markets. In this context, participants are likely to be encouraged to first trade energy locally with each other before transacting with the wholesale and retail markets individually or in a community group [16]. The wholesale market operates to maintain the supply–demand balance and involves lower price energy transactions among large entities such as power generation companies, independent system operators (ISOs), distribution companies, and large consumers. On the other hand, the retail market involves higher price energy transactions between distribution companies and small consumers with energy purchased from the wholesale market or excess renewable energy from prosumers [86].
The market design mainly dictates how the general market architecture is structured or organized, whereas the trading platform is the interface that houses the necessary market mechanisms and enables the P2P transactions based on gathered data and information. The energy trading platforms also need to ensure that participants follow the market regulations and pay any fees associated with the use of the power distribution grid. An effective and reliable information system is required for the operation of the energy trading platform and provide access to the energy market, enabling participants to connect and transact energy with each other within a day or in near real time. As shown in Figure 3, the information system allocates two important mechanisms, namely the market mechanism and pricing mechanism [12]. Essentially, the market mechanism performs an allocation of traded energy by matching the buy and sell orders of the participants in different market stages, including day-ahead and intraday markets. The pricing mechanism allocates supply and demand with their respective market clearing prices while including applicable taxes and fees on the final traded energy price. Then, an energy management system is responsible for managing the amount of traded energy from sellers to buyers with a bidding strategy based on real-time supply and demand data of each market participant [12].
Blockchain has been a highly popular technology to meet the requirements of the information system and develop a decentralized platform for energy trading [87,88,89]. Essentially, it involves an incorruptible and secure digital ledger that contains interconnected blocks to permanently record every financial transaction in a fully decentralized manner, as briefly represented in Figure 5A. The use of DLTs such as blockchain technology provides high level of transparency and redundancy because every node or peer contains a copy of the ledger and thus anyone in the network can access it to verify the validity of each transaction, which can be verified and validated through consensus mechanisms such as proof-of-work (PoW) and proof-of-stake (PoS) [90,91]. Depending on the rights to access the network and on the authorization to verify and validate transactions, blockchain can be classified as private or public and as permissioned or permissionless [91,92].
A wide variety of benefits can be provided to energy trading markets in SG and MG applications. Most of these benefits come from the ability to enable smart contracts. Smart contracts rely on computer code that is stored in the blockchain to automatically execute the contract if a set of conditions are met between the two parties, as briefly shown in Figure 5B. In general, traditional contracts are slow (i.e., 1 to 3 days), manual, expensive, and require a third-party entity and physical signature. In contrast, smart contracts are fast (i.e., few seconds or minutes), automatic, cheap, and only require a digital signature [87,93].
According to the literature, several trading platforms have been proposed for successful P2P energy trading and can be divided into centralized and decentralized trading platforms [16,21]. Most of the energy trading platforms being proposed in the literature follow decentralized approaches and only a handful of works have opted for a centralized approach. The business model of energy trading platforms is similar to that of e-commerce or blockchain-based exchange platforms, and thus may share some of their characteristics [87]. Blockchain-based exchanges for cryptocurrency and tokens have been used as the basis for the development of energy trading platforms [94,95]. In particularly, a decentralized exchange operating on a public blockchain ecosystem was used in [94] to enable the transaction of energy by swapping specific tokens between VPPs. Blockchain technology has also been used in combination with game theory in [77] to create a centralized trading platform for interconnected MGs, which relied on Nash bargaining to guarantee fair agreements through the DSO. Other than blockchain technology, more recent and less mature DLTs such as direct acyclic graph (DAG) have also been suggested to enable energy trading [96,97], which included a DAG-based network for interconnected smart homes in [96].
Other projects such as the SOGNO platform aim at delivering a variety of management services to achieve network stability and security through a modular system for grid automation. This platform is a reference architecture selected by the Linux Foundation Energy (LFE), which improves distribution system monitoring and enables market interactions for DSOs to ensure an optimal operation when dealing with the high penetration of intermittent generation from RES [98]. The SOGNO reference architecture has been used as tool by the Platone project to integrate blockchain technology in market models with a potential for local energy trading [99].

5.1. Centralized Trading Platforms

Centralized or third-party trading platforms have not received much attention from authors. This trend may be due to the lack of trust, autonomy, and privacy associated with centralized or third-party platforms which are governed by an individual or company with the goal of creating a profit [77,94]. It is easier for centralized trading platforms to accept regulation and government approval due to the existence of a single central or third-party entity [12,88]. However, these platforms may be associated with high transaction and service fees due to the use of intermediaries [88].
Zhang et al. in [42] presented a centralized trading platform called “Elecbay” to enable P2P energy trading in a grid-connected MG through a four-layer system architecture. The Elecbay software platform allowed the participants to place orders based on their forecast of energy generation and consumption with different periods reserved for bidding, exchange, and settlement processes. Zepter et al. in [43] introduced the Smart elecTricity Exchange Platform (STEP) to provide an interface between wholesale electricity markets and communities of prosumers. The STEP allowed both prosumers and consumers to take profit from higher sell prices and lower buy prices instead of the prices from the wholesale market and the grid. In addition, Alvaro-Hermana et al. in [44] proposed an energy trading platform that used an aggregator of EVs as central entity to determine the optimal P2P energy prices, interconnecting EVs with an excess of energy and EVs with a deficit of energy in their batteries.

5.2. Decentralized Trading Platforms

Decentralized trading platforms have gained a lot of attention from authors, especially in the field of SGs and MG systems. Without a doubt, most works available in the literature rely on blockchain technology to develop effective decentralized trading platforms for P2P energy trading through smart contracts [94]. One advantage of decentralized trading platform for market participants may be the relatively low transaction and service fees because it avoids multiple layers of fees by allowing direct buyer and seller interaction without intermediary services [88]. However, decentralized trading platforms may be prone to face several regulatory challenges in the way they accept regulation and operate accordingly [88,89]. This is because most of the market control is redirected to the users and there is no central or third-party entity to ensure that market participants comply with regulations. The regulatory challenges are aggravated when dealing with blockchain technology in P2P energy trading applications due to a panoply of factors that play a key role in the operation of energy markets [88,95]. These factors give rise to certain concerns or questions such as whether excess energy should solely be used for ancillary services of the grid or traded for profit of a specific market participant [95].
An Australian blockchain-based platform called “Power Ledger” has recently emerged to provide a scalable and adaptable ecosystem for trading renewable energy, flexibility grid services, and environmental commodities (e.g., renewable energy certificates and carbon credits) in new energy markets. It uses a dual blockchain token system and allows users to trade their energy generated from PV systems with others, maximizing the profit and the benefits of integrating RES in communities [100]. In Germany, a platform called “Lition” is being developed to directly connect end users to renewable energy providers and producers using blockchain and enable P2P energy trading through smart contracts [101]. Other blockchain-based decentralized trading platforms using Ethereum are also proposed in [45,46] to enable smart contracts and ensure secure decentralized transactions of renewable energy within MGs in real time. Recently, Hassan et al. in [47] developed a blockchain-based energy auction called “DEAL” for MG systems to guarantee the privacy and security of participants when they buy or sell renewable energy. Esmat et al. in [48] developed a decentralized P2P energy trading platform called “DeTrade” to enhance economic efficiency and provide transaction privacy and security. This energy trading platform consisted of a market layer called “DeMarket” with uniform pricing mechanism and a permissioned blockchain layer with smart contracts. The authors also developed a decentralized market clearing method called “DACO” to enable the maximization of social welfare. Leeuwen et al. in [49] proposed a blockchain-based energy trading platform to optimize energy flows in a MG and implement a bilateral trading mechanism. The results showed that the costs and amount of the import energy are reduced for the MG community, but the social welfare also decreases with the implementation of the energy trading mechanism. Finally, Suthar and Pindoriya in [50] presented a blockchain-based energy trading platform to enable P2P energy trading with smart contracts and increase the use and security of renewable energy generation while providing transparency and energy affordability and self-sufficiency.

6. Game Theory

Game theory is considered a powerful and well-established mathematical tool to analyze decision-making behaviors in competitive settings and successfully solve complex problems associated with data security and privacy issues [102,103]. It has been extensively used to model the rational behavior of individuals and address energy management in a wide variety of data applications and signal processing techniques, being able to be effectively integrated with the domains of machine learning and the internet of things (IoT). Moreover, game theory enables the integration and development of frameworks for pricing mechanisms and incentive designs [104,105,106]. In electricity markets, game theory is often used to compare market equilibrium outcomes for the analysis and evaluation of market designs [81]. Players, in this case producers and prosumers, have an incentive to charge a price for electricity higher than the marginal cost to avoid potential losses due to non-convexities. Thus, game-theoretic models can be developed to evaluate these competitive markets by solving for the Nash equilibrium, in which all players simultaneously maximize their profits while having no incentive to deviate from this outcome [81]. The use of game theory, namely non-cooperative game, has also been widely applied in SG applications to study and model the behavior among groups of multiple MGs [107].
According to recent trends, most works being presented in the literature usually follow a cooperative or non-cooperative game theoretic approach, focusing on P2P energy trading among participants in a single MG and among interconnected MGs located in the same network [108]. Some of the most relevant works are summarized and listed in Table 4. A basic definition is given for the most common types of cooperative and non-cooperative games used in the literature works for P2P energy trading in SG and MG systems, as shown in Figure 6.

6.1. Cooperative Game Theory

Cooperative game theory has been proven to be effective in dealing with energy management in P2P transactions and can be used to encourage the peers to cooperate in energy trading. It enables players to form groups (i.e., coalitions) in order to make more informed decisions and maximize the benefits. The outcome is mainly characterized by the joint actions of the coalition [8,108].
Tushar et al. in [51] proposed a P2P energy trading scheme using canonical coalition game (CCG), allowing prosumers to trade their energy within the coalition they formed and with other coalitions. This scheme has proven to be consumer-centric and able to endorse prosumer participation in P2P energy trading. Regarding MG systems, Du et al. in [52] used cooperative game theory to develop a coalitional model for the cooperation among multiple grid-connected MGs, achieving optimal local operation and guaranteeing a fair cost share among MGs and the economic stability of the entire coalition. Mei et al. in [53] proposed an energy trading algorithm using coalitional game to identify incentives for coalitional operation and facilitate local energy trading among neighboring MGs in the same network. The results from the algorithm showed an increase of expected individual MG utility and efficiency in the network. Regarding SGs, Tushar et al. in [54] proposed a motivational psychology framework to design P2P energy trading in a SG using coalitional game, which focused on increasing user participation in the market and reducing energy costs.
Other methods using coalitional game theory in SG applications are proposed in [55], which focused on minimizing energy costs and distributing the cost savings among the participants of the coalition according to the Shapley value. Zhou et al. in [56] used coalitional game to develop an energy trading model capable of improving the efficiency of interconnected MGs by maximizing the profit of the entire cluster. In this mode, the fair allocation of both total and individual MG gains was also done according to the Shapley value. Shapley value defines the solution of cooperative games that distributes the total gains and costs among all the players cooperatively participating in the coalition according to the contribution of each individual player. This means that each player has an incentive to collaborate in the coalition and players can gain at least as much as they would have if they acted non-cooperatively or alone. Essayeh et al. in [109] used coalitional game to optimize energy trading inside the coalition and reduce power losses during the exchange of energy in a network of interconnected MGs. Saad et al. in [110] used coalitional game to study cooperative strategies between interconnected MGs and enable them to form coalitions for coordinated energy trading. The MGs within the coalitions were able to cooperate and self-adapt to environmental changes, resulting in an overall reduction of power loss costs. Moreover, Huang et al. in [111] proposed a mechanism for P2P energy trading optimization and customer motivation in a MG using coalitional game. The proposed mechanism has potential to motivate customers to participate in P2P energy trading, reduce energy costs, and help grid operators with economic and social decision-making. Several works in the literature have proven that coalitional game can be effective at maximizing the mutual outcome for all the players in the coalition. On the other hand, Wang and Huang in [112] relied on bargaining game to study the interactions among interconnected MGs and develop a bargain-based energy trading and fair benefit sharing. This allowed the development of an incentive mechanism that was able to increase profits and reduce the total operation costs of the participating MGs. More specifically, the proposed mechanism achieved cost reduction up to around 13% in the case of interconnected MGs when compared to the scenario without cooperation. Bargaining game aims at dividing the potential benefits among the bargaining players [117,118]. Even though bargaining game has a large potential to ensure a fair division of benefits in LEMs for P2P energy trading, it has not received much attention from authors when compared to coalitional game.

6.2. Non-Cooperative Game Theory

Non-cooperative game theory can also be used to address complex P2P energy trading, although without coordination among the peers. Non-cooperative game theory is mostly used in strategic decision-making processes involving conflicting players and when it is impossible to combine the strategies of players or establish agreements between them. The outcome is only characterized by the actions and payoff of each individual player [8,108].
One of the approaches proposed by Kim et al. in [57] used non-cooperative game theory for energy trading among self-interested customers to maximize their profits by determining their energy trading and load scheduling with EVs. In the context of MGs, Liu et al. in [58] used non-cooperative game theory to enable distributed control and energy trading among multiple MGs in an electricity market environment. More specifically, differential game was used to effectively coordinate the benefits of each MG. Because of multiple conflicting beneficiaries associated with the MGs, a cooperative game would not be viable and the task of establishing agreements among them would be difficult to achieve in this case. Differential game studies problems of conflict in systems driven by differential equations controlled by several players involved in the game [58]. Paudel et al. [59] proposed a relatively diverse game-theoretic iterative pricing mechanism to enable P2P energy trading in a community MG. More specifically, non-cooperative game was used for the price competition, evolutionary game for the seller selection, and Stackelberg game for the buyer and seller interaction. Evolutionary game allows us to model the dynamics of changes in the strategies of an evolving population that engages in strategic interactions, being useful to study the dynamics of buyers and select potential sellers in energy trading markets [59]. Stackelberg game mainly involves a set of actions selected by the leader being followed by another set of actions selected by the followers [117,118]. Li et al. in [60] proposed two-stage stochastic game-theoretic model to deal with energy supply and demand uncertainty in a cluster of interconnected MGs and minimize the risk of overbidding for renewable energy. Essentially, stochastic game is seen as a probabilistic transition of one or more players that is repeatedly played in a sequence of stages with different payoffs from actions selected by players in each stage [117,118]. Kou et al. in [61] presented a non-cooperative game-theoretic approach using Stackelberg game to model the interactions between the utility and MG systems and provide support on energy price decisions during load restoration. Moreover, Belgana et al. in [62] used Stackelberg game to develop an analytic model capable of finding the optimal strategies that simultaneously lead to profit maximization and carbon emissions minimization. Lee et al. in [113] proposed a distributed mechanism for energy trading among interconnected MGs using Stackelberg game, which was able to achieve a unique equilibrium solution for the maximization of the payoff of all the MGs participating in the market. Wu et al. in [114] used Stackelberg game to propose a decentralized pool strategy for a MG. This strategy was able to create a fair and competitive market environment for all participants.
Other game-theoretic approaches using non-cooperative games have been proposed in [115,116]. These included a reverse auction model for a single MG and a contribution-based energy trading mechanism for interconnected MGs in a competitive market environment. When analyzing the literature, it is noticeable that non-cooperative game theory, namely Stackelberg game, appears to be the predominant choice to study and develop LEMs for P2P energy trading in SG and MG systems.

6.3. Potential of Game Theory in Energy Trading

The selection of game theory over other tools to address energy transactions and design energy markets is mainly because game theory is proven to be effective in analyzing decision-making behaviors, allowing us to properly justify, in a mathematical way, the strategic interactions among multiple independent players in a highly competitive environment and help predicting the outcome for their interactions. The heterogenous and dynamic nature of SGs and MG systems motivates the adoption of game-theoretic approaches due to the existence of various players with distinct goals or preferences, which often seek to maximize their own profits [119]. This calls for advanced techniques and approaches that can provide a robust and analytic framework to look for a fair and optimal outcome in collaborative and competitive scenarios by analyzing individual player strategies [105,119]. Such approaches can stimulate interaction between MGs and be successfully applied to the energy management domain in networks containing EVs, energy services, and buildings at the residential, commercial, and industrial level [105]. More importantly, game theory enables the easy integration of pricing mechanisms and incentive designs that can adapt to the heterogenous and dynamic nature of SGs and MG systems by modelling the behaviors of players [119]. This has the potential to establish social trust between players and encourage them to combine strategies and adopt cooperative behaviors with each other to obtain a fair and sustainable outcome [104,105].
In the context of smart cities, it is important to not overlook sustainable urban development because factors may change significantly when considering sustainability in the design of game-theoretic approaches. More specifically, economic, social, and environmental sustainability needs to be taken into consideration when modelling player behaviors to obtain a sustainable outcome. For this to be effective in practical applications, there also needs to be a way to ensure that these entities are motivated to participate in the energy trading market [51]. The introduction of an incentive and penalty mechanisms can strengthen the cooperative behavior in the P2P energy trading market and impose desired behaviors of the various entities, enabling them to contribute to the coalition value increase or penalizing them for choosing to defect [106]. This can be achieved through attractive energy trading prices practiced in the P2P market to encourage the players to participate, as proposed by Tushar et al. in [51].
There are a few limitations and challenges associated with the adoption of game-theoretic approaches for energy trading [119]. The practical deployment of a game-theoretic model can be difficult to implement when the optimization process is dependent on human behavior and other unpredictable variables (e.g., uncertain generation from RES). Furthermore, the performance of game-theoretic models in applications that involve large amounts of data is heavily dependent on the effectiveness of the communication infrastructure and its ability to manage network congestion [105]. This may constitute a potential problem because most of the players transacting energy are human users and there is also a high penetration of variable RES, which may result in unpredictable behavior driven by personal interests and uncertain renewable energy generation. In game theory, the assumption that players are rational in order to maximize their utility is not guaranteed in real-world scenarios when the game involves human entities, in which the decision-making process is heavily affected by personal interests and emotions [106].
Fortunately, several smart city technologies and various SG and MG systems driven by ICTs (e.g., automated energy management systems, smart meters, and smart appliances) enable the access to real-time information regarding energy consumption and provide the tools to optimize or reduce it, allowing human users to make more rational and informed decisions [120]. Furthermore, these smart technologies and infrastructures perform an active and constant optimization of the energy systems in buildings by relying exclusively on automated systems to optimize energy consumption and estimate energy needs [120,121]. Taking this level of automation into consideration, part of the problem of game theory being dependent on human behavior and variable RES can be mitigated or even eliminated in the context of smart cities as most of the human behavior is avoided with the use of automated systems.

7. Implications of P2P Energy Trading for Sustainability

The business models should enable most of the benefits provided by community-wide services which can be practiced in LEMs to improve the level of sustainability. In general, business models revolve around the provisions of flexibility services directly or indirectly by community members. These flexibility services may lead to communal cost savings related to the energy purchased from wholesale markets [122]. Flexibility service providers should be able to access and participate in all energy markets to increase the effectiveness of services and the heathy growth of market competition [64]. Moreover, the aggregation of DR allows communities to consume energy during lower energy prices when the access to market price signals is enabled. In few cases, the business model can be focused on allowing communities to generate a form of revenue by participating in mechanisms which provide flexibility services [64,122]. The islanded operation of MGs due to power system outages can also be made technically and economically possible by relying on flexibility services provided by LEMs [122].
Although communities may be interested in developing small-scale networks (e.g., MGs) to interconnect a group of community members and allow them to provide flexibility services and trade energy in a P2P manner, this constitutes a potential challenge for NRAs. The challenge is to ensure the benefits of MGs for power systems and local communities while making sure they are compatible with grid regulation principles [122].
A continuous exchange of energy under a consumer-centric P2P market scheme is also important to facilitate the transition of cities to a state of urban sustainability. Depending on the design of the energy market, this can help increase the effectiveness of intermittent RES in urban environments and ensure energy access and self-sufficiency of cities. The consumer-centric premise of P2P markets creates the sense that citizens are actively contributing to and benefiting from this transition to a more sustainable development [20,123].
A smart city ecosystem is likely to rely on LEMs with distributed market designs as this hybrid model allows for various city districts and neighborhoods consisting of smart buildings and homes, MG systems, and EV aggregators to form groups or communities [19,24]. Such design structure operates in a similar way to a system of systems approach, in which these prosumer groups and communities can interact with different DSOs and provide benefits to their citizens by dynamically managing and balancing their energy needs in accordance with a common goal [8,19]. In a sense, each district and neighborhood of the smart city ecosystem encompasses a single part of the larger system of systems, benefiting from optimal energy transactions within their own communal marketplace as well as with marketplaces of other communities. While this is a possible direction for smart cities to enable energy interactions among distinct entities, the requirements for the operation of LEMs in urban environments are not yet clear and further developments are required in this context [24]. In both developing and developed regions, the direct and indirect benefit and value of LEMs for P2P energy trading goes beyond the monetization of surplus energy and reduction of carbon emissions from the increased use of on-site renewable generation [124]. In particularly, several benefits can be provided at the economic, social, and environmental level with the proper implementation of LEMs [125,126,127]. This makes P2P energy trading a tool capable of supporting those living in energy poverty and helping citizens shape society towards attaining broader sustainability goals [128].
Even though LEMs for P2P energy trading can provide various benefits to increase the overall level of urban sustainability, their implementation is also associated with some shortcomings that can negatively impact market participants as well as non-participating entities. As summarized in Table 5, these positive and negative impacts on sustainability can be categorized in accordance with economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal dimensions. Based on this, Figure 7 shows a brief representation of various benefits provided by P2P energy trading and their relationship with the main indicators of a smart city denoted in [4,5].

7.1. Economic Impacts

Economic impacts of P2P energy trading denote effects and changes on energy prices and taxes paid by both participants and non-participants, grid costs for utilities, as well as any effects on the return of investment made in renewable generation. The initial investment costs and operation costs necessary for the development, implementation, and operation of an effective LEM for P2P energy trading can be significantly high due to the high requirements in smart meters, ICT infrastructure, RES, and BESS [129], although P2P energy trading can decrease energy prices for participants as they buy cheaper energy from other peers instead of purchasing energy from the grid at a higher cost. The decrease in energy prices can also be associated with donations or discounts offered by participants to friends, relatives, organizations, or even individuals at risk of energy poverty. While some of the study participants interviewed in [128] valued the ability to make donations to low-income households living under energy poverty, others described how the existence of formal support mechanisms in P2P energy markets are better suited to support vulnerable populations in benefiting from P2P energy trading. The criticism of making donations towards energy poverty revolve around the notion that it makes low-income households highly dependent on the altruism of others. Leaving vulnerable populations at the mercy of charity donations can have negative consequences and further aggravate energy poverty, especially when P2P energy markets involve a conflict of interests between maximization of profit and contributions to energy poverty [128]. Nevertheless, this can be mitigated through the implementation of mechanisms and policies that ensure engagement opportunity and continuous education for vulnerable populations while providing a layer of transparency on where and how donations are being spent [128].
Taxes and fees may not be applied at all or may not be as high, as the amount of energy purchased from the grid is reduced. The results presented in [130] showed that P2P energy trading was able to decrease expenses and increase income of participants while remaining within the operating limits of the network. On the other hand, energy prices, taxes, and other fees may increase for non-participants as utilities attempt to recover losses of revenue [126]. Depending on the business model of utilities, the loss of revenues due to increased P2P energy trading can be substantial for small utility companies with less diverse business models. According to [131], the P2P energy trading policy in China can benefit PV generation with an increase in revenues of around 6% to 11% and end-use cost savings of 6% to 12%, but the utility company can suffer a significant decrease in revenues of 32% to 55%. The government can see a decrease in subsidy costs of around 6% [131]. In contrast, the Lition energy trading platform is reporting a 30% increase in the revenues of power plants [132]. However, this significant increase is most likely because customers can select the preferred regional energy providers to buy renewable energy from in a P2P manner based on their sale offers. This can be a solution to strengthen the role of utilities in P2P energy trading and improve their margins. Fortunately, there is an opportunity for utilities to participate in P2P energy trading with competitive prices and treat it as an effective alternative to additional generation capacity and grid reinforcements that often result in high investment costs.
P2P energy trading can also lead to cost savings related to demand shifting as changes in the energy consumption of participants are induced due to energy price fluctuation or volatility associated with intermittent generation from RES [126]. However, the simultaneous price negotiations to match different preferences of consumers can make energy prices sub-optimal and more difficult to compare, resulting in less optimal trade deals for participants [20,126]. Grid costs in terms of operation, transmission, and distribution are reduced for participants due to a locally concentrated trade of energy with less grid usage and lower energy prices, but non-participants may have to pay a higher energy price as utilities charge more to cover operation, transmission, and distribution costs [125,126]. P2P energy trading can also increase the amount of income in exported renewable energy as participants are able to sell their excess energy to other peers at a higher price when compared to the price of energy sold to the grid. Although, the return on investment made in RES and ESS may be negatively affected if participants have a low sales revenue [126]. P2P energy trading is not just economically advantageous for individuals, but also for communities as demonstrated in a few studies in the literature [17,25]. In particularly, Long et al. in [29] showed through a case study that P2P energy trading can lead to a substantial energy cost reduction of around 30% for communities and around 12.4% for individual consumers, as well as an increase of annual income for individual prosumers.
When comparing centralized, decentralized, and distributed market designs, the adoption of a centralized or distributed energy market seems to be the most suitable options from an economic point of view, being considered more cost-efficient than decentralized designs. As addressed in Section 3, centralized market designs can ensure the economic feasibility of the day-ahead dispatch and set well-defined market prices for all transactions by using marginal or uniform pricing if uplift payments or other form of compensation is avoided. This also means that producers participating in a competitive market do not have an incentive to exaggerate or overstate their variable costs [81]. With a distributed market design, the non-profit community coordinators are focused on serving and benefiting their members by providing optimal pricing for sellers and buyers [84]. On the other hand, decentralized market designs can facilitate the hedge of profits for prosumers as market prices are dependent on zonal spot prices [78,81].

7.2. Social Impacts

Social impacts are hard to define and quantify, especially in the context of energy trading. This type of impacts usually encompasses effects and changes on the well-being of communities and individuals in terms of awareness and knowledge or effects on the way distinct communities and individuals interact and connect with each other. P2P energy trading can provide opportunities of training and employment as participants gain skills to reduce their own energy consumption and improve energy sales revenues. New job opportunities related to the operation, administration, and maintenance services of the P2P energy trading market can also be created [126]. This generates a sense of employment security, which alongside the additional revenue from selling excess renewable energy, helps reduce financial stress and improve the overall mental well-being of participants.
In addition, empowerment is developed as participants gain awareness and knowledge regarding energy efficiency and improve their decision-making skills to examine deals and obtain a better outcome [20,126]. According to [128], the study participants mentioned the ability of P2P energy trading to enable users to obtain different levels of awareness and understanding of several energy-related aspects, which increases their sense of individual and communal responsibility towards sustainability concepts and commitment to reduce energy consumption. They also described how P2P energy markets and various technologies can support users with economic, technical, and psychological change to facilitate their engagement in the decarbonization process while granting them greater control over energy demand and supply. However, the level of awareness and knowledge can be reduced with the use of automated energy trading processes that rely on, for example, smart contracts enabled by blockchain technology [20,128]. This has the potential to cause a sense of disconnection between users and energy concerns [128].
Participants are encouraged and motivated to improve their building energy efficiency with the goal of maximizing the amount of excess renewable energy available for trading with other peers. These energy efficiency improvements can help improve both physical health and mental well-being in the long run due to improved housing condition in terms of thermal comfort, indoor air quality, noise insulation, and natural lighting [133]. Certain energy efficiency measures can decrease hazardous particles and prevent the formation of damp and mold in buildings, reducing the vulnerability of children and the elderly to asthma, pneumonia, lung cancer, and other chronic respiratory diseases [133]. However, on a less positive note, energy trading requires several ICTs and data for the market operation and to allow participants make better and more informed decisions [125]. This can put some low-income households and certain populations that lack digital skills and economic power at a disadvantage and restrict their access to affordable energy as utilities increase prices and fees, which intensifies energy poverty and inequality among populations [20,129].
P2P energy trading can also increase the social trust among participants due to the increased transparency in each transaction provided by DLTs [20,91], allowing them to easily expose potential fraudulent deals [129]. Although social welfare can usually be maximized, the adoption of a centralized market design also reduces the level of transparency and force participants to place their trust on the central entity or coordinator [81]. The autonomy and privacy of participants can also be potentially enabled with P2P energy trading as it allows participants to be responsible for their own decisions and gain control over deals [79], especially if a blockchain-based trading platform is integrated in the LEM [47]. This level of autonomy and privacy can only be guaranteed through a decentralized market design. As addressed in Section 3, relying on a centralized market design may raise a few autonomy and privacy concerns because the central entity can directly influence the decisions of peers and sensitive data is sent to the central entity or coordinator for the bidding process [16,80]. The study participants interviewed in [128] voiced their concerns regarding the untested nature and novelty of P2P energy markets, which were commonly understood to be unable to offer the same level of supply security and billing accuracy as traditional electricity markets. Nonetheless, the study participants also mentioned that trust could be improved if users knew who they are trading with as well as where their energy is coming from and how sustainable it is. In respect to user privacy, this would need to be implemented in a way that guarantees the protection of sensible user data while concealing the identity of specific individuals [128].
Community attachment and cooperation can increase as the level of direct connection and dependence between participants improves, providing a sense of reinsurance and cohesion among households and organizations [126,128]. These contributions to the local community support and help building new types of social relationships, especially within communities or groups of like-minded market participants with the ability to set common goals and interests for P2P energy trading [128]. Such can be achieved with distributed market designs as each group or cooperative community has its own market clearing price based on the preferences of its participants [40]. This can increase social welfare by granting each participant a sense of communal cooperation and freedom of choice with additional options in terms of different marketplaces for energy trading (e.g., transactions with the utility grid and neighboring communities or within the local community) [40,84]. Moreover, participants can build a positive reputation for their energy transactions and become proud of their actions and contributions to the community and environment, especially when participants are allowed to make donations towards the alleviation of energy poverty. Unfortunately, some negative and non-cooperative interactions are bound to occur between certain participants such as competitors and rival organizations, which can decrease market efficiency and deteriorate social welfare [126]. Regarding social welfare in LEMs, it has been highlighted in [135] that social welfare can be maximized in both centralized and decentralized market designs with an optimal block bid size or length in the number of quarter hours. Moreover, adopting a simultaneous market clearing procedure in decentralized market designs instead of a sequential one can result in higher social welfare [135].
A potential shortcoming of P2P energy trading is that it can cause discrimination against specific individuals by imposing certain restrictions or features that limit the choice of which participants are allowed to enter the market and with whom they can trade. According to [134], it may be possible to maintain this type of restrictions and features (e.g., records of energy transactions and previous trading partners), and at the same time, prevent a priori selection of specific trading partners. The author suggests that the selection of trading partners could be restricted to only general group characteristics (e.g., direct and local communities) in order to reduce discrimination against specific individuals [134].
It is recommended that projects define and allocate a specific budget for the recruitment of experts and local partners to support customer engagement initiatives, which can be a portion ranging from 5% to 10% of the overall project recruitment budget or up to 30% if training activities are needed to conduct engagement work with potential customers [64]. To help overcome initial engagement barriers of developing a project to establish MGs and LEMs, customer involvement and participation should be facilitated by building trust and local relationships, giving users a voice, and considering their interests and goals as one of the main targets of the projects and various partner interventions [64,128]. Although the interest of some customers in energy-related projects may be already driven by environmental values, other benefits such as economic and social values also play a major role on ensuring customer engagement. This is dependent on the level of energy poverty, living conditions of populations, and local energy prices. Thus, it is important to adapt the project scope and goals to the target population and location while enabling constant communication with customers in a clear and non-intrusive way (e.g., through surveys, workshops, personal visits, and phone calls or messages) to keep them well-informed and aware of shortcomings and unforeseen events. Furthermore, communication between partners and similar projects can also be important to combine different areas of expertise and overcome common challenges [64].

7.3. Environmental Impacts

Environmental impacts denote effects and changes on the environment in terms of natural resource consumption and GHG emissions from the use of fossil fuels. The RES integration is encouraged by enabling participants to sell excess renewable energy at more favorable prices and by taking advantage of renewable generation from other peers [125,126,127]. P2P energy trading can decrease the amount of imported energy from the grid as participants are more motivated to reduce energy consumption through energy efficiency and generate excess renewable energy on-site to sell to other peers [126]. However, energy consumption may increase due to the desire of consuming the excess energy during low price periods. The study in [29] revealed an increase of around 10% to 30% in self-consumption of PV energy and an increase of around 20% in the level of self-sufficiency of individuals and communities. Emissions of GHG and local air pollution can be mitigated due to the increased use of EVs and improved energy efficiency that motivates participants to invest in RES [126]. This further alleviates the dependency on fossil fuels for power generation and their importation. However, P2P energy trading requires many smart devices, ICT equipment, ESS, and RES such as PV systems [20], which negatively impact the environment due to increased extraction and consumption of natural resources [25,129].
The integration of RES and trade of renewable energy is easier in LEM with decentralized market design by taking advantage of the increased flexibility provided by the intra-day market. This allows producers and prosumers to optimize their dispatch and exchange energy based on the variability of renewable generation [81]. On the contrary, a centralized market design can be highly inflexible, being difficult for producers and prosumers to perform a continuous adjustment of their dispatch in the intra-day market in accordance with the forecast of renewable generation [78,81]. Cadre in [135] determined that a LEM with decentralized market design under a high share of local RES can be as efficient as a centralized LEM. The author also concluded that the existence of imperfect information has a limited impact on the level of efficiency of decentralized market designs. Renewable energy is also facilitated through a LEM with distributed market design. This hybrid model has been used to stimulate and maintain local supply–demand balance by allowing like-minded producers and prosumers to pool their resources in internal local markets inside communities under a cooperative game theory approach [17,19]. This has the potential to mitigate the uncertainty of demand and variability of energy generated from community-based RES, which increases the availability of renewable energy and facilitates the integration of RES and EV support within each community [17]. Larger prosumers groups can form or operate as VPPs, further benefiting the community [19].
The environmental impacts associated with the various DLTs are also important to considered when implementing an LEM for P2P energy trading. This is heavily dependent on the technology used to develop the energy trading platform. Most of the environmental impact is related to the amount of power required to operate and maintain the network [91,136]. In particularly, the oldest blockchain technologies with the highest level of maturity and security that rely on the PoW consensus mechanism can be relatively energy intensive when compared to most recent and less secure ones [91,97].

7.4. Technical Impacts

Technical impacts of P2P energy trading in LEMs mostly denote effects and changes on the grid operation, energy management, and MG integration. The widespread of DERs in existing power systems, the variability of renewable generation from RES, and the transition of customers to active grid members constitute major challenges currently being faced by traditional electricity markets [125]. This paradigm shift can be sustained with the adoption of LEMs for P2P energy trading. For instance, LEMs market can improve the energy access in isolated MGs as participants use smart appliances and trade energy with other peers when required in order to mitigate the intermittency associated with RES. Congestion in distribution branches and balance between supply and demand can also be locally managed by reducing peak demand as participants trade energy [25,125]. On the other hand, congestion in distribution branches caused by overvoltage, capacity overload, and bi-directional power flows may also increase and become an issue if not properly managed due to the introduction of multiple energy transactions [20,125,129]. Decentralized market designs may not fully consider transmission constraints and optimally represent them ahead of real time. This may neglect network congestion within large zones, meaning that the day-ahead and intra-day dispatch may not be technically feasible due to intra-zone congestion. A centralized market design can be advantageous in areas which may be susceptible to issues related to network congestion [81]. Distributed market designs may also be able to consider network constraints and generate a local price signal based on them to avoid congestion in distribution branches by introducing a network utilization charge for each transaction [40]. In terms of power losses, the use of P2P energy trading may not produce significant changes to the power losses in grid-connected networks. According to the study in [137], P2P energy trading has been shown to only produce changes to the power losses of the network at certain time instants of the day if prosumers possess power dispatch flexibility. However, the variation in power losses throughout the day was considered insignificant for the large-scale distribution grid being studied in [137].
Finally, P2P energy trading also enables participants to provide several ancillary services and flexibility to the grid, allowing utilities to identify distribution needs and alleviate limitations without the costs of grid reinforcement [25,125]. According to [134], the need for P2P energy trading should have the greatest impact and become more attractive for services providers located in areas with high network management requirements since they have relatively high incentives to participate in the market. Thus, the implementation of P2P energy trading in these areas can be an effective way to connect with service providers and take advantage of several technical benefits [134]. As addressed in Section 3, centralized market designs are less flexible than decentralized market designs, making them relatively slow in responding to potential grid events and disturbances. In contrast, decentralized market designs can provide an adequate level of flexibility for the provisions of grid services by enabling producers to optimally adjust their dispatch and by facilitating the integration of ESS and DR programs [78,81].
The implementation of LEMs for P2P energy trading are often characterized as having scalability issues in large-scale applications. Therefore, their deployment in urban environments with many city entities and participants transacting energy simultaneously can be difficult [129], especially in the context of smart cities, which may require highly scalable market designs and trading platforms to extend the coverage area of the market and deal with the computational burden. While a centralized market design significantly reduces the network scalability for large-scale markets [80,81], a decentralized market design can offer high network scalability due to the fewer number of communication links required [30,81]. Moreover, distributed market designs can also provide a moderate level of network scalability for the ICT infrastructures due to participants being divided into groups or communities [17,20,40].
With the use of smart devices and ICTs in the data-intensive operation of LEMs and integration of SG and MG systems, suitable measures for effective data and information protection need to be implemented. These measures should provide robust protection of customer data and information against malicious attacks and unwanted intrusions. Cybersecurity should ensure the resilience and security of the energy infrastructure, which can be particularly important in smart cities due to their high energy and data intensity for the operation of the smart infrastructure and its many services [139].

7.5. Legal Impacts

The future of LEMs and their success is mainly dependent on regulations and policies of countries, which are most likely going to impose certain restrictions to the design and governance of LEMs and how blockchain is used [129]. The widespread adoption of blockchain-based platforms for P2P energy trading will not just significantly impact market participants, but also cause some disruptions on the business and regulatory models of traditional intermediaries such as exchanges, brokers, and price reporting agencies (PRAs) [138]. Legal issues related to differences in legislation between regions may arise, which constitutes an additional regulatory barrier and restricts P2P transactions to a regional or local area within a country. The participation and contracting process in LEMs also needs to be properly regulated to ensure that the market can still deliver high-quality energy services as new participants decide to enter or leave the market [140].
Most countries in the EU lack consensus on the topic of LEMs and do not yet possess well-defined policy and regulation that properly supports the implementation of P2P energy trading [17,141]. Energy trading between individual peers within a community or between distinct communities is a significant departure from the traditional supplier–consumer relationship and, thus it requires special attention from a regulatory perspective [142]. In this case, energy communities should not destabilize the operation of energy markets or jeopardize the protection rights of consumers and the economic viability of the grid [122]. As discussed in [17], the EU Directive 2019/944 on common rules for the internal electricity market allows consumers to form citizen energy communities and perform a local share of energy among them, acting as closed DSOs. Therefore, a local energy community which acts as a DSO is bound to the same rules as other DSOs and should provide consumer protection rights in terms of freedom of choice, enabling consumers to freely choose a supplier and obtain an adequate level of power quality and service [122].
However, this directive only clarifies aspects related to the distribution system operation and responsibility of prosumers, being seen as vague and requiring further clarification regarding regulatory frameworks for LEMs and specification of market design models [17]. Decentralized market designs, in particularly, can pose regulatory challenges if the energy services agreed upon are not delivered. Currently, the reliance on blockchain technology to perform transactions through smart contracts cannot solve this challenge because smart contracts are not appropriately regulated [17]. Centralized market designs can simplify and facilitate regulation due to the presence of central or third-party entity to oversee market operation and communicate with the DSO [141]. For the same reason, a distributed market design may also have the potential to offer increased compatibility with existing regulatory framework [17]. In particularly, the SonnenCommunity project in Germany follows a hybrid or distributed market design for P2P energy trading and, like Piclo and Vanderbron, is one of the projects in which regulation is integrated into its business model by analyzing existing policy and regulatory frameworks [17,143]. This project allows surplus energy generated from PV systems and stored in BESS to be traded among prosumers and consumers within the community. However, it faces a regulatory barrier, which prevents excess energy generation from being injected into the grid [143]. The Community S project located in Portugal focus on creating P2P energy trading communities within the boundaries of the low voltage and medium-voltage distribution grid that serve their members with surplus energy from PV systems [141]. The analysis performed in [141] for the Community S project is meant to circumvent the regulatory barriers imposed by the Portuguese Energy Services Regulatory Authority (ERSE) by optimizing the absorption of surplus energy within the lower voltage levels and avoiding the energy export to the next higher voltage level of the grid. Thus, consumers would benefit from reduced prices for the electricity traded within the P2P market as they would be exempted from paying the totality of network access tariffs, while prosumers would benefit from larger profits for selling electricity in the P2P market as selling it to the distribution grid under the current feed-in tariff scheme in Portugal is unattractive [141].
Current regulation is falling behind the fast development of blockchain technology and emergence of LEM for P2P energy trading [88,129]. The clear ownership of the network in a private blockchain makes this type of blockchain much more desirable for regulators to implement laws and regulations, as well as for the owner to place a set of network restrictions and conditions for all users that comply with regulations [88]. On the other hand, a public blockchain makes it difficult to hold a specific entity accountable for breaches of law and regulation due to the unclear ownership of the open network, being not desirable for the proper implementation of laws and regulations [88]. In contrast to permissionless blockchains, a permissioned blockchain relies on a central entity to place restrictions and gain increased control over what activities the various participating entities can perform in the network, which is ideal for businesses and MGs owned by commercial and industrial organizations [91,92].
Within the current European legal framework, it may be impossible to establish a solution that would fit in all applications of blockchain technology in the liberalization of energy markets [144]. This desperately calls for new and improved regulation that can accompany technological development and assist the widespread of P2P energy trading in SGs and MG systems [144,145]. As proper regulation is implemented, the role of market participants can be changed and seen as additional capacity for the grid as new responsibilities and legal obligations are assigned to producers, prosumers, and consumers [140]. According to [144], legislative proposals of the European commission have set an ambitious vision to protect the most vulnerable consumers while market participants become active and empowered members of the grid. Future regulation needs to carefully address the disruption caused by the emergence of blockchain-enabled applications as energy transactions between market participants become completely direct and transparent. This needs to be done in a way that promotes innovation and ensures all the benefits associated with DLTs. It is also important to allow more services and resources to be accommodated and traded in P2P energy trading markets, making this type of market much more diverse, desirable, and accessible. Although, specific regulatory action over highly diverse markets can be difficult or impossible to prescribe [134].

8. Discussion

The economic, social, and environmental dimensions are seen as the fundamental pillars of sustainability, but the technical and legal dimensions are also required to properly support and enable the development of LEMs for P2P energy trading and allow their techno-economic viability in practical applications [127,129]. Addressing the potential benefits and technical and legal shortcomings of consumer-centric schemes for P2P energy trading is essential to provide a panoply of wider societal improvements and make valuable contributions to the three main pillars of sustainability [127,128]. This importance can be further elevated because the design, implementation, and operation of LEMs is heavily dependent on their technical implications and effects on energy infrastructures and various users of the network, as well as on their compatibility with existing policy and regulatory frameworks.

8.1. Market Design Suitability for Sustainability

The level of suitability of each energy market design for the economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal dimensions of sustainability is represented in Figure 8.
Based on all aspects addressed throughout this work and on the number of contributions provided by each market design minus their threats to sustainability, the level of suitability of each market design for each dimension of sustainability can be as follows:
  • For the economic dimension of sustainability, a centralized or distributed market design may be the most suitable option. Centralized designs can ensure day-ahead dispatch feasibility and set well-defined market prices for the energy transactions by using marginal pricing, while distributed designs can focus on benefiting community members and optimizing prices for sellers and buyers;
  • For the social dimension of sustainability, a decentralized or distributed market design may be the most suitable option. Decentralized designs can offer a high level of transparency, autonomy, and privacy by not relying on a central entity for decision-making and control, while distributed designs can increase social welfare by granting participants a sense of communal cooperation and freedom of choice with additional marketplace options;
  • For the environmental dimension of sustainability, a decentralized market design may be the most suitable as it can provide increased intra-day dispatch flexibility to facilitate the integration of RES and allow the trade of energy based on the variability of renewable generation;
  • For the technical dimension of sustainability, a decentralized market design may be the most suitable as it can provide both high network scalability and dispatch flexibility for the provisions of grid services and integration of ESS and DR programs;
  • For the legal dimension of sustainability, a centralized or distributed market design may be suitable as both designs can simplify and facilitate the integration of policy and regulation while having potential to be compatible with existing regulatory frameworks.

8.2. Project Scalability and Replicability

There have been numerous demonstrations to implement and evaluate the operation of SG and MG systems in real-world applications. However, the results (e.g., potential costs and benefits) obtained from the demonstrations are specific to their context and local conditions, which may not be valid or directly applicable for implementation in other locations and at different scales [146,147]. In order to understand and estimate the impacts of SG and MG applications and ensure their sustainability, a scalability and replicability analysis (SRA) is required [147]. This can be used to perform cost-benefit analyses (CBAs), develop effective business models and market strategies, support policymakers, and help mitigate the challenges associated with scaling-up and replication of results from demonstrations [147,148]. Scalability is defined as the ability of a system to apply technical innovation and increase its size, range, density, or scope, whereas replicability is defined as the ability of a system to duplicate technical innovation in another location or time under different characteristics and conditions [147]. For instance, the scalability of a SG system can denote its ability to be successfully implemented in a larger distribution system with a larger number of consumers and DERs, as well as with a different load density. On the other hand, the replicability of the same system can denote its ability to be successfully duplicated in other locations and network architectures under different reliability levels, boundary conditions, market designs, regulatory schemes, stakeholder perspectives, and economic conditions [147,148].
The methodology used for SRAs generally consists of collecting extensive data regarding demonstrations of SG or MG projects through surveys to access and evaluate several factors of scalability and replicability [147,148,149]. These factors mainly encompass technical aspects in terms of modularity and standardization, economic aspects related to profitability and business model, and regulatory and social acceptance aspects, which allow us to quantify the scalability and replicability status of both new and existing projects [148,149]. SRAs require a set of key performance indicators (KPIs) to quantify the performance of the SG and MG implementation to assess its impacts and attain the intended objective [147,148]. The selected KPIs should be quantifiable to allow projects with the same or similar objectives to be compared under different conditions, serving as a valuable input to improve CBAs [147].
CBAs can be particularly important to determine whether the benefits of SG or MG projects and LEMs outweigh their costs [146]. This can be a valuable tool to assess their impacts and contributions to sustainability in the context of smart cities if the costs and benefits are properly weighted and analyzed from a societal or customer-oriented perspective. However, performing a CBA for SG and MG projects presents some challenges. In particularly, the panoply of diverse technologies, systems, and techniques necessary for the effective communication among devices and operation of SGs and MGs can be broad, requiring the involvement of personnel from many backgrounds with different skillsets. Moreover, the scale and scope of projects can widely differ between projects, ranging from small or isolated networks to large networks expanded through several stages of the power system. LEMs can also include a diverse set of market players and customer classes, including utilities, system operators, producers, consumers, or prosumers [146,147].
In order to promote and enable the large-scale deployment of SG and MG projects, it is necessary to perform high quality and detailed CBAs, tackle computational and communication capacity, promote standard compliance, solve architecture simplification, guarantee data security and confidentiality, develop clear rules and proper regulatory and legal frameworks, and ensure customer and stakeholder acceptance [146,147,148,149,150].

9. Conclusions

The contents of this work have addressed energy market designs, trading platforms, and game-theoretic approaches for P2P energy trading in SG and MG applications. Based on a literature review, several key aspects related to the design and evaluation of LEMs for P2P energy trading were addressed while taking into consideration their relationship with urban sustainability in the topic of smart cities. Therefore, this work started by identifying several works and projects that have addressed the implementation of energy markets for P2P energy trading, focusing on centralized, decentralized, and distributed market designs, as well as on both centralized and decentralized trading platforms. Game theory, namely cooperative and non-cooperative game, is also addressed given its importance in evaluating market designs and model participant behavior, playing a key role on properly enabling SG and MG applications. Upon addressing the structure and characteristics of the different market designs and trading platforms, this work then presented the implications of implementing P2P energy markets on the level of sustainability and categorized their positive and negative impacts in accordance with economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal or political aspects. Finally, the suitability of centralized, decentralized, and distributed market designs for each dimension of sustainability was assessed based on their unique characteristics and contributions to sustainability.
  • The adoption of a centralized market design can offer a higher level of coordination and overall efficiency, whereas a decentralized market design can provide a higher level of reliability and scalability. Distributed or hybrid market designs combine the strengths and benefits of both centralized and decentralized designs, offering a balanced “middle ground” between the two ends of the spectrum. This market design can be particularly important for smart city ecosystems as it allows for various city districts and neighborhoods to form groups or communities and dynamically manage their energy needs in accordance with a common goal. With decentralized and distributed market designs being more common in the literature, a similar trend occurs with trading platforms. Most of the energy trading platforms being proposed in the literature are decentralized and heavily based on blockchain technology.
  • The use of cooperative and non-cooperative game theory has been extensive for market design evaluation and energy trading in SGs and MGs. This is mostly because of the ability to analytically develop pricing mechanisms and incentive designs suitable for SGs and MGs. Based on the literature review, most cooperative approaches use coalitional game, while non-cooperative approaches usually rely on Stackelberg game. Cooperative game has the potential to establish social trust and encourage players to combine strategies for a fair and sustainable outcome. However, it is important to mention that game-theoretic approaches can be data intensive and difficult to implement when the optimization process is dependent on human behavior and uncertain generation from RES. Nevertheless, this problem can be mitigated in smart cities as most of the human behavior can be avoided with automated systems.
  • The implementation of a centralized market design may contribute more to the economic and legal dimensions of sustainability as it ensures dispatch feasibility, sets well-defined market prices, and facilitates the integration of policy and regulation. On the other hand, a decentralized market design can mostly contribute to the social, environmental, and technical dimensions of sustainability due to the high level of transparency, autonomy, privacy, and scalability, as well as the intra-day dispatch flexibility to provide grid services and facilitate the trade of renewable energy. As a balanced solution with a lower number of threats to sustainability, distributed market designs can contribute to the economic, social, and legal dimensions as they optimize pricing, grant a sense of communal cooperation and freedom of choice, and offer compatibility with regulatory frameworks.
  • These conclusions have shown that there is high value in adopting LEMs to increase the level of sustainability and the ability to trade surplus energy in a consumer-centric P2P manner. This can be a promising solution to reduce the reliability problems of MGs and solve various energy security concerns in remote locations. Moreover, the proper implementation of LEMs can help support those living in energy poverty and motivate citizens to help shape society towards a more sustainable development. Nonetheless, specific strategies, regulations, and policies are needed to successfully implement LEMs for P2P energy trading and ensure their positive impacts. Furthermore, detailed CBAs and SRAs are required to properly determine potential contributions to sustainability, develop business models, and evaluate the scalability and replicability of new and existing projects at larger scales, enabling the widespread adoption of SGs and MGs. Future research should also focus on guaranteeing an acceptable level of sustainability associated with P2P energy trading in urban environments while taking into consideration various objectives at the economic, social, and environmental level.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, F.B., Á.G., M.G. and P.C.; methodology, F.B.; validation, Á.G., M.G. and P.C.; formal analysis, F.B.; investigation, F.B.; resources, M.G. and P.C.; writing—original draft preparation, F.B.; writing—review and editing, F.B., Á.G., M.G. and P.C.; visualization, Á.G.; supervision, Á.G., M.G. and P.C.; project administration, Á.G., M.G. and P.C.; funding acquisition, F.B. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was partially supported by the Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology (FCT) under the PhD research grant 2020.07048.BD.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest. The funders had no role in the design of the study; in the collection, analyses, or interpretation of data; in the writing of the manuscript; or in the decision to publish the results.

References

  1. Trindade, E.P.; Hinnig, M.P.F.; Moreira da Costa, E.; Marques, J.S.; Bastos, R.C.; Yigitcanlar, T. Sustainable development of smart cities: A systematic review of the literature. J. Open Innov. Technol. Mark. Complex. 2017, 3, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Terrien, P.; GASSER, B.; RAY, M.; Beaudoux, M.C.; Deleu, H.; Cattan, N.; Hegron, G.; Coutard, O.; Raux, C.; Laigle, L.; et al. Challenges and Prospects for Efficient Sustainable Cities: Climate, Energy and Environment; French Environment & Energy Management Agency (ADEME): Angers, France, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  3. Orchestrating Infrastructure for Sustainable Smart Cities; International Electrotechnical Commission (IEC): Geneva, Switzerland, 2014; Available online: https://www.ceps.eu/wp-content/uploads/2015/01/iecWP-smartcities-LR-en.pdf (accessed on 20 September 2022).
  4. Letaifa, S.B. How to strategize smart cities: Revealing the SMART model. J. Bus. Res. 2015, 68, 1414–1419. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Giffinger, R.; Gudrun, H. Smart cities ranking: An effective instrument for the positioning of the cities? ACE Archit. City Environ. 2010, 4, 7–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Smart Cities and Infrastructure; United Nations Economic and Social Council: Geneva, Switzerland, 2016; Available online: https://unctad.org/system/files/official-document/ecn162016d2_en.pdf (accessed on 20 September 2022).
  7. Ton, D.T.; Smith, M.A. The U.S. Department of Energy’s Microgrid Initiative. Electr. J. 2012, 25, 84–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Bandeiras, F.; Pinheiro, E.; Gomes, M.; Coelho, P.; Fernandes, J. Review of the cooperation and operation of microgrid clusters. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2020, 133, 110311. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Moslehi, K.; Kumar, R. A Reliability Perspective of the Smart Grid. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2010, 1, 57–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Microgrids for Commercial and Industrial Companies Delivering Increased Power Reliability, Lower Energy Costs and Lower Emissions; World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD): Geneva, Switzerland, 2017; Available online: https://docs.wbcsd.org/2017/11/WBCSD_microgrid_INTERACTIVE.pdf (accessed on 21 September 2022).
  11. Yoldaş, Y.; Önen, A.; Muyeen, S.M.; Vasilakos, A.V.; Alan, İ. Enhancing smart grid with microgrids: Challenges and opportunities. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 72, 205–214. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Mengelkamp, E.; Gärttner, J.; Rock, K.; Kessler, S.; Orsini, L.; Weinhardt, C. Designing microgrid energy markets: A case study: The Brooklyn Microgrid. Appl. Energy 2018, 210, 870–880. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Soto, E.A.; Bosman, L.B.; Wollega, E.; Leon-Salas, W.D. Peer-to-peer energy trading: A review of the literature. Appl. Energy 2021, 283, 116268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Zhang, C.; Wu, J.; Long, C.; Cheng, M. Review of Existing Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading Projects. Energy Procedia 2017, 105, 2563–2568. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Park, C.; Yong, T. Comparative review and discussion on P2P electricity trading. Energy Procedia 2017, 128, 3–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Zhou, Y.; Wu, J.; Long, C.; Ming, W. State-of-the-Art Analysis and Perspectives for Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading. Engineering 2020, 6, 739–753. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Bjarghov, S.; Löschenbrand, M.; Saif, A.I.; Pedrero, R.A.; Pfeiffer, C.; Khadem, S.K.; Rabelhofer, M.; Revheim, F.; Farahmand, H. Developments and Challenges in Local Electricity Markets: A Comprehensive Review. IEEE Access 2021, 9, 58910–58943. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Papadaskalopoulos, D.; Ye, Y.; Qiu, D.; Li, J.; Strbac, G. Review of Electricity Market Design Challenges and Recommendations; Imperial College London: London, UK, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  19. Parag, Y.; Sovacool, B.K. Electricity market design for the prosumer era. Nat. Energy 2016, 1, 1–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Sousa, T.; Soares, T.; Pinson, P.; Moret, F.; Baroche, T.; Sorin, E. Peer-to-peer and community-based markets: A comprehensive review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2019, 104, 367–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Tushar, W.; Yuen, C.; Saha, T.K.; Morstyn, T.; Chapman, A.C.; Alam, M.J.E.; Hanif, S.; Poor, H.V. Peer-to-peer energy systems for connected communities: A review of recent advances and emerging challenges. Appl. Energy 2021, 282, 116131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Sioshansi, R.; Oren, S.; O’Neill, R. Chapter 6—The Cost of Anarchy in Self-Commitment-Based Electricity Markets. In Elsevier Global Energy Policy and Economics Series, Competitive Electricity Markets; Sioshansi, F.P., Ed.; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2008; pp. 245–266. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Elmouatamid, A.; Ouladsine, R.; Bakhouya, M.; El Kamoun, N.; Khaidar, M.; Zine-Dine, K. Review of Control and Energy Management Approaches in Micro-Grid Systems. Energies 2021, 14, 168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Karnouskos, S. Demand Side Management via prosumer interactions in a smart city energy marketplace. In Proceedings of the 2011 2nd IEEE PES International Conference and Exhibition on Innovative Smart Grid Technologies, Manchester, UK, 5–7 December 2011; pp. 1–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Peer-to-Peer Electricity Trading: Innovation Landscape Brief; International Renewable Energy Agency (IRENA): Abu Dhabi, United Arab Emirates, 2020; Available online: https://www.irena.org/-/media/Files/IRENA/Agency/Publication/2020/Jul/IRENA_Peer-to-peer_electricity_trading_2020.pdf (accessed on 22 September 2022).
  26. Raza, N.; Akbar, M.; Soofi, A.; Akbar, S. Study of Smart Grid Communication Network Architectures and Technologies. J. Comput. Commun. 2019, 7, 19–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Alam, M.R.; St-Hilaire, M.; Kunz, T. Peer-to-peer energy trading among smart homes. Appl. Energy 2019, 238, 1434–1443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Lüth, A.; Zepter, J.M.; Crespo del Granado, P.; Egging, R. Local electricity market designs for peer-to-peer trading: The role of battery flexibility. Appl. Energy 2018, 229, 1233–1243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Long, C.; Wu, J.; Zhou, Y.; Jenkins, N. Peer-to-peer energy sharing through a two-stage aggregated battery control in a community Microgrid. Appl. Energy 2018, 226, 261–276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Sorin, E.; Bobo, L.; Pinson, P. Consensus-Based Approach to Peer-to-Peer Electricity Markets with Product Differentiation. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2019, 34, 994–1004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Morstyn, T.; Teytelboym, A.; Mcculloch, M.D. Bilateral Contract Networks for Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2019, 10, 2026–2035. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Khorasany, M.; Mishra, Y.; Ledwich, G. A Decentralized Bilateral Energy Trading System for Peer-to-Peer Electricity Markets. IEEE Trans. Ind. Electron. 2020, 67, 4646–4657. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Antal, C.; Cioara, T.; Antal, M.; Mihailescu, V.; Mitrea, D.; Anghel, I.; Salomie, I.; Raveduto, G.; Bertoncini, M.; Croce, V.; et al. Blockchain based decentralized local energy flexibility market. Energy Rep. 2021, 7, 5269–5288. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Lyu, C.; Jia, Y.; Xu, Z. Fully decentralized peer-to-peer energy sharing framework for smart buildings with local battery system and aggregated electric vehicles. Appl. Energy 2021, 299, 117243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Hu, M.; Wang, Y.; Lin, X.; Shi, Y. A Decentralized Periodic Energy Trading Framework for Pelagic Islanded Microgrids. IEEE Trans. Ind. Electron. 2020, 67, 7595–7605. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Long, C.; Wu, J.; Zhang, C.; Thomas, L.; Cheng, M.; Jenkins, N. Peer-to-peer energy trading in a community microgrid. In Proceedings of the 2017 IEEE Power & Energy Society General Meeting, Chicago, IL, USA, 16–20 July 2017. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Liu, N.; Yu, X.; Wang, C.; Li, C.; Ma, L.; Lei, J. Energy-Sharing Model with Price-Based Demand Response for Microgrids of Peer-to-Peer Prosumers. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2017, 32, 3569–3583. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Nunna, H.S.V.S.K.; Srinivasan, D. Multiagent-Based Transactive Energy Framework for Distribution Systems with Smart Microgrids. IEEE Trans. Ind. Inform. 2017, 13, 2241–2250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Kang, J.; Yu, R.; Huang, X.; Maharjan, S.; Zhang, Y.; Hossain, E. Enabling Localized Peer-to-Peer Electricity Trading Among Plug-in Hybrid Electric Vehicles Using Consortium Blockchains. IEEE Trans. Ind. Inform. 2017, 13, 3154–3164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Wang, Y.; Wang, X.; Shao, C.; Gong, N. Distributed energy trading for an integrated energy system and electric vehicle charging stations: A Nash bargaining game approach. Renew. Energy 2020, 155, 513–530. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Khorasany, M.; Mishra, Y.; Ledwich, G. Hybrid trading scheme for peer-to-peer energy trading in transactive energy markets. IET Gener. Transm. Distrib. 2020, 14, 245–253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Zhang, C.; Wu, J.; Zhou, Y.; Cheng, M.; Long, C. Peer-to-Peer energy trading in a Microgrid. Appl. Energy 2018, 220, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Zepter, J.M.; Lüth, A.; Crespo del Granado, P.; Egging, R. Prosumer integration in wholesale electricity markets: Synergies of peer-to-peer trade and residential storage. Energy Build. 2019, 184, 163–176. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Alvaro-Hermana, R.; Fraile-Ardanuy, J.; Zufiria, P.J.; Knapen, L.; Janssens, D. Peer to Peer Energy Trading with Electric Vehicles. IEEE Intell. Transp. Syst. Mag. 2016, 8, 33–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  45. Kang, E.S.; Pee, S.J.; Song, J.G.; Jang, J.W. A Blockchain-Based Energy Trading Platform for Smart Homes in a Microgrid. In Proceedings of the 2018 3rd International Conference on Computer and Communication Systems (ICCCS), Nagoya, Japan, 27–30 April 2018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Sabounchi, M.; Wei, J. Towards resilient networked microgrids: Blockchain-enabled peer-to-peer electricity trading mechanism. In Proceedings of the 2017 IEEE Conference on Energy Internet and Energy System Integration (EI2), Beijing, China, 26–28 November 2017. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Hassan, M.U.; Rehmani, M.H.; Chen, J. DEAL: Differentially Private Auction for Blockchain-Based Microgrids Energy Trading. IEEE Trans. Serv. Comput. 2020, 13, 263–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Esmat, A.; Vos, M.; Ghiassi-Farrokhfal, Y.; Palensky, P.; Epema, D. A novel decentralized platform for peer-to-peer energy trading market with blockchain technology. Appl. Energy 2021, 282, 116123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Leeuwen, G.; AlSkaif, T.; Gibescu, M.; Sark, W. An integrated blockchain-based energy management platform with bilateral trading for microgrid communities. Appl. Energy 2020, 263, 114613. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Suthar, S.; Pindoriya, N.M. Blockchain and Smart Contract based Decentralized Energy Trading Platform. In Proceedings of the 2020 21st National Power Systems Conference (NPSC), Gandhinagar, India, 17–19 December 2020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Tushar, W.; Saha, T.K.; Yuen, C.; Liddell, P.; Bean, R.; Poor, H.V. Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading with Sustainable User Participation: A Game Theoretic Approach. IEEE Access 2018, 6, 62932–62943. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Du, Y.; Li, F.; Kou, X.; Pei, W. Coordinating multi-microgrid operation within distribution system: A cooperative game approach. In Proceedings of the 2017 IEEE Power & Energy Society General Meeting, Chicago, IL, USA, 16–20 July 2017. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Mei, J.; Chen, C.; Wang, J.; Kirtley, J.L. Coalitional game theory based local power exchange algorithm for networked microgrids. Appl. Energy 2019, 239, 133–141. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Tushar, W.; Saha, T.K.; Yuen, C.; Morstyn, T.; McCulloch, M.D.; Poor, H.V.; Wood, K.L. A motivational game-theoretic approach for peer-to-peer energy trading in the smart grid. Appl. Energy 2019, 243, 10–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Chiş, A.; Koivunen, V. Coalitional Game-Based Cost Optimization of Energy Portfolio in Smart Grid Communities. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2019, 10, 1960–1970. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  56. Zhou, Y.; Tan, M.; Li, S.; Wang, R. A cooperative energy trading model for multi-energy microgrid cluster in an active distribution network. In Proceedings of the 2019 IEEE 3rd Conference on Energy Internet and Energy System Integration (EI2), Changsha, China, 8–10 November 2019; pp. 625–630. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Kim, B.; Ren, S.; van der Schaar, M.; Lee, J. Bidirectional Energy Trading and Residential Load Scheduling with Electric Vehicles in the Smart Grid. IEEE J. Sel. Areas Commun. 2013, 31, 1219–1234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Liu, W.; Gu, W.; Wang, J.; Yu, W.; Xi, X. Game theoretic non-cooperative distributed coordination control for multi-microgrids. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2018, 9, 6986–6997. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Paudel, A.; Chaudhari, K.; Long, C.; Gooi, H.B. Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading in a Prosumer-Based Community Microgrid: A Game-Theoretic Model. IEEE Trans. Ind. Electron. 2019, 66, 6087–6097. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Li, C.; Xu, Y.; Yu, X.; Ryan, C.; Huang, T. Risk-Averse Energy Trading in Multienergy Microgrids: A Two-Stage Stochastic Game Approach. IEEE Trans. Ind. Inform. 2017, 13, 2620–2630. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Kou, W.; Park, S.-Y. Game-theoretic approach for smart grid energy trading with microgrids during restoration. In Proceedings of the 2017 IEEE Power & Energy Society General Meeting, Chicago, IL, USA, 16–20 July 2017. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Belgana, A.; Rimal, B.P.; Maier, M. Open Energy Market Strategies in Microgrids: A Stackelberg Game Approach Based on a Hybrid Multiobjective Evolutionary Algorithm. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2015, 6, 1243–1252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Algarvio, H. The Role of Local Citizen Energy Communities in the Road to Carbon-Neutral Power Systems: Outcomes from a Case Study in Portugal. Smart Cities 2021, 4, 840–863. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Cooperation between Horizon 2020 Projects in the Field of Smart Grids and Energy Storage: Main Findings and Recommendations. Bridge Horizon 2020, Business Models Working Group. 2019. Available online: https://bridge-smart-grid-storage-systems-digital-projects.ec.europa.eu/sites/default/files/documents/working-groups/BRIDGE-Business-Models-Findings-and-Reco-July-2019.pdf (accessed on 10 December 2022).
  65. Warneryd, M.; Håkansson, M.; Karltorp, K. Unpacking the complexity of community microgrids: A review of institutions’ roles for development of microgrids. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2020, 121, 109690. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Hillberg, E. Flexibility Needs in the Future Power System; International Smart Grid Action Network (ISGAN). 2019. Available online: https://www.iea-isgan.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/03/ISGAN_DiscussionPaper_Flexibility_Needs_In_Future_Power_Systems_2019.pdf (accessed on 10 December 2022).
  67. Hirsch, A.; Parag, Y.; Guerrero, J. Microgrids: A review of technologies, key drivers, and outstanding issues. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2018, 90, 402–411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Kojonsaari, A.-R.; Palm, J. Distributed Energy Systems and Energy Communities Under Negotiation. Technol. Econ. Smart Grids Sustain. Energy 2021, 6, 17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Norouzi, F.; Hoppe, T.; Elizondo, L.R.; Bauer, P. A review of socio-technical barriers to Smart Microgrid development. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2022, 167, 112674. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Akinyele, D.; Belikov, J.; Levron, Y. Challenges of Microgrids in Remote Communities: A STEEP Model Application. Energies 2018, 11, 432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  71. Silva, R.; Alves, E.; Ferreira, R.; Villar, J.; Gouveia, C. Characterization of TSO and DSO Grid System Services and TSO-DSO Basic Coordination Mechanisms in the Current Decarbonization Context. Energies 2021, 14, 4451. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Holistic Architectures for Future Power Systems. European Technology and Innovation Platform Smart Networks for Energy Transition (ETIP SNET), Whitepaper. 2019. Available online: https://smart-networks-energy-transition.ec.europa.eu/sites/default/files/publications/ETIP-SNET_HolisticArchitecture_2019_04_01_Final.pdf (accessed on 10 December 2022).
  73. Oleinikova, I.; Hillberg, E.; Iliceto, A. Flexibility for Resilience: How Can Flexibility Support Power Grids Resilience? European Technology and Innovation Platform Smart Networks for Energy Transition (ETIP SNET): European Commission: Brussels, Belgium, 2022; Available online: https://smart-networks-energy-transition.ec.europa.eu/system/files/2022-06/MJ0722296ENN.en_.pdf (accessed on 10 December 2022).
  74. Smart Grid Case Studies: Microgrid Value Propositions 1.0. International Smart Grid Action Network (ISGAN), Communication Working Group (Task 2). 2022. Available online: https://www.iea-isgan.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/10/ISGAN-Casebook-on-Microgrids_FINALApproved_F.pdf (accessed on 10 December 2022).
  75. Asmus, P.; Forni, A.; Vogel, L. Microgrid Analysis and Case Studies Report; Energy Research and Development Division, California Energy Commission: Sacramento, CA, USA, 2018.
  76. Guerrero, J.; Chapman, A.C.; Verbič, G. Local Energy Markets in LV Networks: Community Based and Decentralized P2P Approaches. In Proceedings of the 2019 IEEE Milan PowerTech, Milan, Italy, 23–27 June 2019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Hamouda, M.R.; Nassar, M.E.; Salama, M.M.A. Centralized Blockchain-Based Energy Trading Platform for Interconnected Microgrids. IEEE Access 2021, 9, 95539–95550. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Ahlqvist, V.; Holmberg, P.; Tangerås, T. Centralization versus Decentralization in Electricity Markets. Energiforsk 2018, 2018, 533. [Google Scholar]
  79. Liu, C.; Li, Z. Comparison of Community-Market Designs: Centralized and Peer-to-peer Trading. In Proceedings of the 2020 IEEE 3rd Student Conference on Electrical Machines and Systems (SCEMS), Jinan, China, 4–6 December 2020; pp. 825–829. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Papadaskalopoulos, D.; Strbac, G. Decentralized Participation of Flexible Demand in Electricity Markets—Part I: Market Mechanism. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2013, 28, 3658–3666. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Ahlqvist, V.; Holmberg, P.; Tangerås, T. A survey comparing centralized and decentralized electricity markets. Energy Strategy Rev. 2022, 40, 100812. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Meeus, L.; Verhaegen, K.; Belmans, R. Block order restrictions in combinatorial electric energy auctions. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2009, 196, 1202–1206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Zhou, Y.; Wu, J.; Long, C. Evaluation of peer-to-peer energy sharing mechanisms based on a multiagent simulation framework. Appl. Energy 2018, 222, 993–1022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Wu, Y.; Tan, X.; Qian, L.; Tsang, D.H.K.; Song, W.-Z.; Yu, L. Optimal Pricing and Energy Scheduling for Hybrid Energy Trading Market in Future Smart Grid. IEEE Trans. Ind. Inform. 2015, 11, 1585–1596. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Yao, Y.; Gao, C.; Chen, T.; Yang, J.; Chen, S. Distributed electric energy trading model and strategy analysis based on prospect theory. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2021, 131, 106865. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Honarmand, M.E.; Hosseinnezhad, V.; Hayes, B.; Siano, P. Local Energy Trading in Future Distribution Systems. Energies 2021, 14, 3110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Luo, X.; Wang, Z.; Cai, W.; Li, X.; Leung, V.C.M. Application and evaluation of payment channel in hybrid decentralized ethereum token exchange. Blockchain Res. Appl. 2020, 1, 100001. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Salmon, J.; Myers, G. Blockchain and Associated Legal Issues for Emerging Markets; Encompass Note 63; International Finance Corporation: Washington, DC, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  89. Endemann, B.; Wladawsky-Berger, I.; LaPointe, C.; Yen, H. Blockchain, Technology Factsheet Series, Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs; Harvard Kennedy School: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2020; Available online: https://www.belfercenter.org/sites/default/files/files/publication/Blockchain.pdf (accessed on 15 September 2022).
  90. Andoni, M.; Robu, V.; Flynn, D.; Abram, S.; Geach, D.; Jenkins, D.; McCallum, P.; Peacock, A. Blockchain technology in the energy sector: A systematic review of challenges and opportunities. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2019, 100, 143–174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Zia, M.F.; Benbouzid, M.; Elbouchikhi, E.; Muyeen, S.M.; Techato, K.; Guerrero, J.M. Microgrid Transactive Energy: Review, Architectures, Distributed Ledger Technologies, and Market Analysis. IEEE Access 2020, 8, 19410–19432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Distributed Ledger Technology (DLT) and Blockchain; World Bank Group: Washington, DC, USA, 2017; Available online: https://documents1.worldbank.org/curated/en/177911513714062215/pdf/122140-WP-PUBLIC-Distributed-Ledger-Technology-and-Blockchain-Fintech-Notes.pdf (accessed on 10 December 2022).
  93. Thukral, M.K. Emergence of blockchain-technology application in peer-to-peer electrical-energy trading: A review. Clean Energy 2021, 5, 104–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Seven, S.; Yoldas, Y.; Soran, A.; Alkan, G.; Jung, J.; Ustun, T.S.; Onen, A. Energy Trading on a Peer-to-Peer Basis between Virtual Power Plants Using Decentralized Finance Instruments. Sustainability 2022, 14, 13286. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Peter, V.; Paredes, J.; Rivial, M.R.; Sepúlveda, E.S.; Astorga, D.A.H. Blockchain Meets Energy: Digital Solutions for a Decentralized and Decarbonized Sector; German-Mexican Energy Partnership (EP) and Florence School of Regulation (FSR): Florence, Italy, 2019; Available online: https://fsr.eui.eu/wp-content/uploads/Blockchain_meets_Energy_-_ENG.pdf (accessed on 20 December 2022).
  96. Fan, C.; Khazaei, H.; Chen, Y.; Musilek, P. Towards A Scalable DAG-based Distributed Ledger for Smart Communities. In Proceedings of the 2019 IEEE 5th World Forum on Internet of Things (WF-IoT), Limerick, Ireland, 15–18 April 2019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. Pervez, H.; Muneeb, M.; Irfan, M.U.; Haq, I.U. A Comparative Analysis of DAG-Based Blockchain Architectures. In Proceedings of the 2018 12th International Conference on Open Source Systems and Technologies (ICOSST), Lahore, Pakistan, 19–21 December 2018; pp. 27–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Definition of Overall SOGNO System Architecture: WP4—Implementation of SOGNO Services for Use in Field Trials; Service Oriented Grid for the Network of the Future (SOGNO). 2018. Available online: https://www.sogno-energy.eu/global/images/cms/Deliverables/774613_deliverable_D4.1.pdf (accessed on 27 December 2022).
  99. Platone Platform Requirements and Reference Architecture (v1): WP2—Platform Implementation and Data Handling. Platform for Operation of Distribution Networks (Platone). 2020. Available online: https://platone-h2020.eu/data/deliverables/864300_M12_D2.1.pdf (accessed on 28 December 2022).
  100. Power Ledger Whitepaper. Power Ledger. 2019. Available online: https://www.powerledger.io/company/power-ledger-whitepaper (accessed on 11 November 2022).
  101. Foti, M.; Vavalis, M. What blockchain can do for power grids? Blockchain Res. Appl. 2021, 2, 100008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  102. Osborne, M.J. An Introduction to Game Theory; Department of Economics, University of Toronto: Toronto, ON, Canada, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  103. Manshaei, M.H.; Zhu, Q.; Alpcan, T.; Bacşar, T.; Hubaux, J.-P. Game Theory Meets Network Security and Privacy. ACM Comput. Surv. 2013, 45, 1–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  104. Bayram, I.S.; Shakir, M.Z.; Abdallah, M.; Qaraqe, K. A Survey on Energy Trading in Smart Grid. In Proceedings of the 2014 IEEE Global Conference on Signal and Information Processing (GlobalSIP), Atlanta, GA, USA, 3–5 December 2014; pp. 258–262. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  105. Tushar, W.; Yuen, C.; Mohsenian-Rad, H.; Saha, T.; Poor, H.V.; Wood, K.L. Transforming Energy Networks via Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading: The potential of game-theoretic approaches. IEEE Signal Process. Mag. 2018, 35, 90–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  106. Cho, J.-H.; Wang, Y.; Chen, I.-R.; Chan, K.S.; Swami, A. A Survey on Modeling and Optimizing Multi-Objective Systems. IEEE Commun. Surv. Tutor. 2017, 19, 1867–1901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  107. Camarinha-Matos, L.M. Collaborative smart grids–A survey on trends. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 65, 283–294. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  108. Javed, H.; Irfan, M.; Shehzad, M.; Muqeet, H.A.; Akhter, J.; Dagar, V.; Guerrero, J.M. Recent Trends, Challenges, and Future Aspects of P2P Energy Trading Platforms in Electrical-Based Networks Considering Blockchain Technology: A Roadmap Toward Environmental Sustainability. Front. Energy Res. 2022, 10, 134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  109. Essayeh, C.; El Fenni, M.R.; Dahmouni, H. Optimization of energy exchange in microgrid networks: A coalition formation approach. Prot. Control. Mod. Power Syst. 2019, 4, 24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  110. Saad, W.; Han, Z.; Poor, H.V. Coalitional Game Theory for Cooperative Micro-Grid Distribution Networks. In Proceedings of the 2011 IEEE International Conference on Communications Workshops (ICC), Kyoto, Japan, 5–9 June 2011. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  111. Huang, H.; Nie, S.; Lin, J.; Wang, Y.; Dong, J. Optimization of Peer-to-Peer Power Trading in a Microgrid with Distributed PV and Battery Energy Storage Systems. Sustainability 2020, 12, 923. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  112. Wang, H.; Huang, J. Incentivizing Energy Trading for Interconnected Microgrids. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2018, 9, 2647–2657. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  113. Lee, J.; Guo, J.; Choi, J.K.; Zukerman, M. Distributed Energy Trading in Microgrids: A Game-Theoretic Model and Its Equilibrium Analysis. IEEE Trans. Ind. Electron. 2015, 62, 3524–3533. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  114. Wu, Y.; Barati, M.; Lim, G.J. A Pool Strategy of Microgrid in Power Distribution Electricity Market. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2020, 35, 3–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  115. Cintuglu, M.H.; Martin, H.; Mohammed, O.A. Real-Time Implementation of Multiagent-Based Game Theory Reverse Auction Model for Microgrid Market Operation. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2015, 6, 1064–1072. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  116. Park, S.; Lee, J.; Bae, S.; Hwang, G.; Choi, J.K. Contribution-Based Energy-Trading Mechanism in Microgrids for Future Smart Grid: A Game Theoretic Approach. IEEE Trans. Ind. Electron. 2016, 63, 4255–4265. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  117. Ilavendhan, A.; Saruladha, K. Comparative study of game theoretic approaches to mitigate network layer attacks in VANETs. ICT Express 2018, 4, 46–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  118. Abdalzaher, M.S.; Seddik, K.; Elsabrouty, M.; Muta, O.; Furukawa, H.; Abdel-Rahman, A. Game Theory Meets Wireless Sensor Networks Security Requirements and Threats Mitigation: A Survey. Sensors 2016, 16, 1003. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  119. Saad, W.; Han, Z.; Poor, H.V.; Basar, T. Game-Theoretic Methods for the Smart Grid: An Overview of Microgrid Systems, Demand-Side Management, and Smart Grid Communications. IEEE Signal Process. Mag. 2012, 29, 86–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  120. Sintov, N.D.; Schultz, P.W. Unlocking the potential of smart grid technologies with behavioral science. Front. Psychol. 2015, 6, 410. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  121. Goulden, M.; Bedwell, B.; Rennick-Egglestone, S.; Rodden, T.; Spence, A. Smart grids, smart users? The role of the user in demand side management. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2014, 2, 21–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  122. Regulatory Aspects of Self-Consumption and Energy Communities: CEER Report. Council of European Energy Regulators, Customers and Retail Markets and Distribution Systems Working Groups. 2019. Available online: https://www.ceer.eu/documents/104400/-/-/8ee38e61-a802-bd6f-db27-4fb61aa6eb6a (accessed on 18 December 2022).
  123. Park, B.R.; Chung, M.H.; Moon, J.W. Becoming a building suitable for participation in peer-to-peer energy trading. Sustain. Cities Soc. 2022, 76, 103436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  124. Cárdenas-Álvarez, J.P.; España, J.M.; Ortega, S. What is the value of peer-to-peer energy trading? A discrete choice experiment with residential electricity users in Colombia. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2022, 91, 102737. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  125. Teotia, F.; Bhakar, R. Local Energy Markets: Concept, Design and Operation. In Proceedings of the 2016 National Power Systems Conference (NPSC), Bhubaneswar, India, 19–21 December 2016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  126. Fell, M.J. Social Impacts of Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading: A Rapid Realist Review Protocol; Centre for Research into Energy Demand Solutions (CREDS): Oxford, UK, 2019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  127. Mendes, G.; Nylund, J.; Annala, S.; Honkapuro, S.; Kilkki, O.; Segerstam, J. Local energy markets: Opportunities, benefits and barriers. In Proceedings of the International Conference on Electricity Distribution (CIRED), Ljubljana, Slovenia, 7–8 June 2018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  128. Wilkins, D.J.; Chitchyan, R.; Levine, M. Peer-to-Peer Energy Markets: Understanding the Values of Collective and Community Trading. In Proceedings of the 2020 CHI Conference on Human Factors in Computing Systems (CHI ‘20), Honolulu, HI, USA, 25–30 April 2020; Association for Computing Machinery: New York, NY, USA, 2020; pp. 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  129. Junlakarn, S.; Kokchang, P.; Audomvongseree, K. Drivers and Challenges of Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading Development in Thailand. Energies 2022, 15, 1229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  130. Guerrero, J.; Chapman, A.C.; Verbič, G. Decentralized P2P Energy Trading Under Network Constraints in a Low-Voltage Network. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2019, 10, 5163–5173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  131. Wang, Y.; Tian, L.; Xia, J.; Zhang, W.; Zhang, K. Economic Assessment of the Peer-to-Peer Trading Policy of Distributed PV Electricity: A Case Study in China. Sustainability 2020, 12, 5235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  132. Ninomiya, Y.; Sasakawa, A. Peer-to-Peer (P2P) Electricity Trading and Power Purchasing Agreements (PPAs); German Japanese Energy Transition Council (GJETC): Wuppertal, Tokyo, 2020; Available online: https://gjetc.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/07/GJETC_Digitalization-Study-II_P2P-and-PPA.pdf (accessed on 16 September 2022).
  133. The Macro-Level and Sectoral Impacts of Energy Efficiency Policies. European Commission. 2017. Available online: https://energy.ec.europa.eu/system/files/2017-07/the_macro-level_and_sectoral_impacts_of_energy_efficiency_policies_0.pdf (accessed on 10 September 2022).
  134. Fell, M.J. Anticipating distributional impacts of peer-to-peer energy trading: Inference from a realist review of evidence on Airbnb. Clean. Responsible Consum. 2021, 2, 100013. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  135. Le Cadre, H. On the efficiency of local electricity markets under decentralized and centralized designs: A multi-leader Stackelberg game analysis. Cent. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2019, 27, 953–984. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  136. Varriale, V.; Cammarano, A.; Michelino, F.; Caputo, M. The Unknown Potential of Blockchain for Sustainable Supply Chains. Sustainability 2020, 12, 9400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  137. Azim, M.I.; Tushar, W.; Saha, T.K. Investigating the impact of P2P trading on power losses in grid-connected networks with prosumers. Appl. Energy 2020, 263, 114687. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  138. Blockchain Applications in Energy Trading; Deloitte: London, UK, 2016; Available online: https://www2.deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/uk/Documents/energy-resources/deloitte-uk-blockchain-applications-in-energy-trading.pdf (accessed on 21 September 2022).
  139. Digitalisation of the electricity system and customer participation: Technical Position Paper WG4. European Technology and Innovation Platform Smart Networks for Energy Transition (ETIP SNET). 2018. Available online: https://smart-networks-energy-transition.ec.europa.eu/sites/default/files/publications/ETIP-SNET-Position-Paper-on-Digitalisation-FINAL-1.pdf (accessed on 26 December 2022).
  140. Viviers, A.; Castadot, R.; Pascal, B. Peer-to-Peer (P2P) Energy: A Threat or an Opportunity for Traditional Suppliers? Sia Partners: Paris, France, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  141. Klein, L.P.; Krivoglazova, A.; Matos, L.; Landeck, J.; de Azevedo, M. A Novel Peer-To-Peer Energy Sharing Business Model for the Portuguese Energy Market. Energies 2020, 13, 125. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  142. Almeida, L.; Cappelli, V.; Klausmann, N.; van Soest, H. Peer-to-peer trading and energy community in the electricity market: Analysing the literature on law and regulation and looking ahead to future challenges. Int. Energy Agency 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  143. Kokchang, P.; Junlakarn, S.; Audomvongseree, K. Business model and market designs for solar prosumer on peer to peer energy trading in Thailand. IOP Conf. Ser. Earth Environ. Sci. 2020, 463, 012127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  144. Ahl, A.; Yarime, M.; Tanaka, K.; Sagawa, D. Review of blockchain-based distributed energy: Implications for institutional development. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2019, 107, 200–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  145. Diestelmeier, L. Changing power: Shifting the role of electricity consumers with blockchain technology—Policy implications for EU electricity law. Energy Policy 2019, 128, 189–196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  146. Wakefield, M. Guidebook for Cost/Benefit Analysis of Smart Grid Demonstration Projects: Revision 1, Measuring Impacts and Monetizing Benefit; Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI): Palo Alto, CA, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  147. Rodriguez-Calvo, A.; Cossent, R.; Frías, P. Scalability and replicability analysis of large-scale smart grid implementations: Approaches and proposals in Europe. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2018, 93, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  148. Fotis, G.; Dikeakos, C.; Zafeiropoulos, E.; Pappas, S.; Vita, V. Scalability and Replicability for Smart Grid Innovation Projects and the Improvement of Renewable Energy Sources Exploitation: The FLEXITRANSTORE Case. Energies 2022, 15, 4519. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  149. Sigrist, L.; May, K.; Morch, A.; Verboven, P.; Vingerhoets, P.; Rouco, L. On Scalability and Replicability of Smart Grid Projects—A Case Study. Energies 2016, 9, 195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  150. May, K.; Vingerhoets, P.; Sigrist, L. Barriers regarding scalability and replicability of smart grid projects. In Proceedings of the 2015 12th International Conference on the European Energy Market (EEM), Lisbon, Portugal, 19–22 May 2015; pp. 1–5. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Percentage of documents addressing LEMs for P2P energy trading in the topics of SGs, MGs, and smart cities with focus on market design, trading platform, game theory, and sustainability.
Figure 1. Percentage of documents addressing LEMs for P2P energy trading in the topics of SGs, MGs, and smart cities with focus on market design, trading platform, game theory, and sustainability.
Energies 16 00801 g001
Figure 2. Flowchart of the methodology used to identify, select, and categorize literature publications (* certain sources address aspects related to market design, game theory, and sustainability, being therefore counted in multiple categories).
Figure 2. Flowchart of the methodology used to identify, select, and categorize literature publications (* certain sources address aspects related to market design, game theory, and sustainability, being therefore counted in multiple categories).
Energies 16 00801 g002
Figure 3. Diagram of the typical structure of LEMs for P2P energy trading in MGs and its distinct virtual and physical layers.
Figure 3. Diagram of the typical structure of LEMs for P2P energy trading in MGs and its distinct virtual and physical layers.
Energies 16 00801 g003
Figure 4. Diagrams of market designs for P2P energy trading: (A) Centralized; (B) Decentralized; (C) Distributed.
Figure 4. Diagrams of market designs for P2P energy trading: (A) Centralized; (B) Decentralized; (C) Distributed.
Energies 16 00801 g004
Figure 5. Diagrams of the transaction process of blockchain technology and comparison between: (A) traditional and (B) smart contracts.
Figure 5. Diagrams of the transaction process of blockchain technology and comparison between: (A) traditional and (B) smart contracts.
Energies 16 00801 g005
Figure 6. Most common game-theoretic techniques used in the literature for P2P energy trading in SG and MG systems (+ + + = high relevance, + + = medium relevance, + = low relevance).
Figure 6. Most common game-theoretic techniques used in the literature for P2P energy trading in SG and MG systems (+ + + = high relevance, + + = medium relevance, + = low relevance).
Energies 16 00801 g006
Figure 7. Representation of economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal benefits of P2P energy trading and their relationship with smart city indicators.
Figure 7. Representation of economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal benefits of P2P energy trading and their relationship with smart city indicators.
Energies 16 00801 g007
Figure 8. Diagram of the suitability of centralized, decentralized, and distributed market designs for the economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal dimensions of sustainability.
Figure 8. Diagram of the suitability of centralized, decentralized, and distributed market designs for the economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal dimensions of sustainability.
Energies 16 00801 g008
Table 1. Selection of literature works proposing market design models, trading platforms, and game-theoretic approaches for P2P energy trading in LEMs.
Table 1. Selection of literature works proposing market design models, trading platforms, and game-theoretic approaches for P2P energy trading in LEMs.
Category Author YearApplicationObjective
Market designCentralizedAlam et al.[27]2019Smart homesEnergy cost optimization
Lüth et al.[28]2018Battery systemsEnergy cost reduction
Long et al.[29]2018MG systemsEnergy cost reduction
DecentralizedSorin et al.[30]2019MG systemsSocial welfare maximization
Morstyn et al.[31]2019Generator aggregatorsSubstitutable conditions and stable outcome
Khorasany et al.[32]2020Distributed resourcesSocial welfare maximization
Antal et al.[33]2021Prosumer communitiesEnergy profile flexibility trade
Lyu et al.[34]2021Smart buildingsSocial welfare maximization
Hu et al.[35]2020MG systemsEnergy cost reduction and profit maximization
DistributedLong et al.[36]2017MG systemsEnergy pricing mechanisms
Liu et al.[37]2017MG systemsDynamic internal pricing model
Nunna and Srinivasan[38]2017MG systemsTransactive energy management framework
Kang et al.[39]2017SG systemsSocial welfare maximization
Wang et al.[40]2020EV aggregatorsEnergy cost reduction and profit maximization
Khorasany et al.[41]2020Prosumer communitiesMarket stability and participant freedom
Trading platformCentralizedZhang et al.[42]2018MG systemsEnergy bidding and exchange platform
Zepter et al.[43]2019Prosumer communitiesWholesale market and prosumer interface
Alvaro-Hermana et al.[44]2016EV aggregatorsOptimal energy prices
DecentralizedKang et al.[45]2018MG systemsSmart contracts
Sabounchi and Wei[46]2017MG systemsSmart contracts
Hassan et al.[47]2020MG systemsBlockchain-based energy auction
Esmat et al.[48]2021Prosumer communitiesEconomic efficiency and deal privacy and security
Leeuwen et al.[49]2020MG systemsEnergy flow optimization and bilateral trade
Suthar and Pindoriya[50]2020Prosumer communitiesRenewable energy usage and energy security
Game theoryCooperativeTushar et al.[51]2018Prosumer communitiesEndorsed prosumer participation
Du et al.[52]2017MG systemsOptimal operation and economic stability
Mei et al.[53]2019MG systemsCoalitional operation and individual utility
Tushar et al.[54]2019SG systemsEnergy cost reduction and user participation
Chis and Koivunen[55]2019SG systemsEnergy cost minimization and distribution
Zhou et al.[56]2019MG systemsProfit maximization and allocation
Non-cooperativeKim et al.[57]2013EV aggregatorsCustomer profit maximization
Liu et al.[58]2018MG systemsControl and multi-operator energy trade
Paudel et al.[59]2019MG systemsGame-theoretic iterative pricing mechanism
Li et al.[60]2017MG systemsOverbidding risk minimization
Kou et al.[61]2017MG systemsEnergy price decision support and voltage stability
Belgana et al.[62]2015MG systemsProfit maximization and emissions minimization
Table 2. Value proposition ranking for different MG projects (based on [74,75]).
Table 2. Value proposition ranking for different MG projects (based on [74,75]).
CategoryNot ImportantSomewhat ImportantVery ImportantEssential
Project levelEfficiency---(GE)(CA), (SK)(US)
Reliability---(CA), (DE), (JA)(SK), (MO), (CH)(US), (GE), (IN), (SI)
Resiliency---(CA), (DE), (MO), (CH)(SK), (JA)(US), (GE), (IN), (SI)
Renewable energy integration---(SK)(MO), (CH)(US), (CA), (GE), (DE), (IN), (SI), (JA)
Bill savings/demand charge abatement(DE), (JA)(SK)(CA), (GE), (IN), (CH), (SI)(US), (MO)
P2P economy/sharing economy(GE), (MO)(CA), (SK), (IN), (CH)(US), (DE), (SI), (JA)---
New business models---(CA), (GE)(US), (SK)---
Ancillary service provision(CA), (MO)(SK), (IN), (CH)(US), (SI), (JA)(GE), (DE)
Energy/capacity service provision(MO)(CH), (SI)(IN), (JA)(DE)
Carbon footprint reduction------(MO), (CH), (JA)(DE), (IN), (SI)
Non-electricity services(IN), (CH), (JA)(MO)---(DE), (SI)
Virtual power plant (VPP) linkage(MO)(IN), (CH)(SI), (JA)(DE)
Player
Level
ProducerSelling electricity(MO)(US), (IN), (CH)(GE), (SK), (DE), (SI), (JA)---
CustomerElectricity fee reduction---(GE)(CA), (SK)(US)
Job creation(GE), (SK)---(US), (CA)---
Revenue generation(GE), (MO)(SK), (IN), (CH)(DE), (SI), (JA)(US)
OperatorSubscription fee(US), (GE), (SK)---------
Membership fee(US), (GE), (SK)---------
Selling electricity(MO)(GE), (SK), (IN), (CH)(DE), (SI), (JA)(US)
Government support(GE)---(SK)(US)
(US)—Kailua-Kona MG, United States; (CA)—Lac-Mégantic MG, Canada; (GE)—Suðuroy MG, Germany; (DE)—Bornholm MG, Denmark; (MO)—Medjumbe MG, Mozambique; (IN)—Chennai MG, India; (SK)—Ulsan MG, South Korea; (CH)—Shanghai MG, China; (SI)—Semakau MG, Singapore; (JA)—Nagoya MG, Japan.
Table 3. Comparison among centralized, decentralized, and distributed market designs.
Table 3. Comparison among centralized, decentralized, and distributed market designs.
AdvantagesDisadvantages
Centralized
[16,17,19,21,22,76,77,78,79,80,81]
  • Maximizes social welfare
  • Provides high market coordination and overall efficiency
  • Less supply and demand uncertainty
  • Ensures day-ahead dispatch feasibility
  • Offers clear and well-defined market prices
  • Provides grid services and high-quality energy delivery
  • Decreases participant autonomy and privacy
  • Suffers from single-point failure vulnerability
  • Increases computational and communication burden
  • Provides slow response to grid events in day-ahead markets
  • Offers low day-ahead dispatch flexibility
  • Reduces market transparency and network scalability
Decentralized
[16,17,19,21,22,30,76,77,78,79,81,82]
  • Provides high autonomy and privacy
  • Provides high reliability with no single-point failures
  • Offers scalability and plug-and-play capability
  • Facilitates hedging and simplifies market clearing
  • Increases market transparency
  • Deteriorates social welfare
  • Low market coordination and overall efficiency
  • Complex network management
  • Relies on block orders and complex bidding
  • Suffers from problems in continuous intra-day trading
  • Unable to ensure grid services and high-quality energy delivery
Distributed
[16,17,20,29,83,84]
  • Enables participant autonomy and privacy
  • Promotes cooperative communities and prosumer groups
  • Aims to optimize prices and benefit community members
  • Provides grid services and high-quality energy delivery
  • Increases ICT infrastructure scalability
  • Offers balance between centralized and decentralized designs
  • Complex pricing mechanism
  • Increases data integration and management difficulty
  • Requires further developments in P2P energy trading
Table 4. Relevant works on P2P energy trading in SG and MG systems using game theory.
Table 4. Relevant works on P2P energy trading in SG and MG systems using game theory.
Author GameApplicationObjectiveResults
CooperativeDu et al.[52]CoalitionalInterconnected MGsOptimal operation and economic stabilityIncreased utilization efficiency of energy resources and achieved the local optimum among MGs.
Mei et al.[53]CoalitionalInterconnected MGsCoalitional operation incentives and individual utilityIncreased individual utility by 16% on average for a set of 30 MGs in the network.
Tushar et al.[54]CoalitionalSG communitiesEnergy cost reduction and user participation motivationReduced daily energy costs and carbon emissions by 118¢ and 18.38% in summer and 87¢ and 9.82% in winter.
Chis and Koivunen[55]CoalitionalSG communitiesEnergy cost minimization and distributionReduced energy costs by 3% for consumers and 18% for households with RES and ESS.
Zhou et al.[56]CoalitionalInterconnected MGsProfit maximization and allocationImproved both the total gains of the MG cluster and the gains of each individual MG.
Essayeh et al.[109]CoalitionalInterconnected MGsEnergy trade optimization and power loss reductionReduced power losses by 5% using the first strategy stage and 20% using both first and second stages.
Saad et al.[110]CoalitionalInterconnected MGsEnergy trade coordination and power loss costs reductionReduced power losses by 31% for the full set of 30 MGs in the network.
Huang et al.[111]CoalitionalIndividual MGEnergy trade optimization and customer motivationPotential for customer motivation and grid operator decision-making while reducing energy costs.
Wang and Huang[112]BargainingInterconnected MGsBargain-based energy trade and fair benefit shareReduced operation cost by 13.2% for interconnected MGs and 29.4% for individual MGs.
Non-cooperativeLiu et al.[58]DifferentialInterconnected MGsDistributed control and multi-operator energy tradeAchieved fairness and effectiveness while providing adaptability to topology changes.
Paudel et al.[59]Evolutionary and StackelbergIndividual MGGame-theoretic iterative pricing mechanismReduced MG cost by 88.13% with DR and without BESS.
Li et al.[60]StochasticInterconnected MGsEnergy balance uncertainty and overbidding risk minimizationImproved the economic benefits for each MG and reduced the risk of overcommitting energy supply and not meeting demand.
Kou et al.[61]StackelbergInterconnected MGsEnergy price decision support and voltage stabilityAchieved a more economic energy trading strategy for the utility by considering the voltage stability effects on each participant.
Belgana et al.[62]StackelbergInterconnected MGsProfit maximization and carbon emissions minimizationObtained the optimal trade-off among carbon emissions, energy generation profits, and consumer energy bills.
Lee et al.[113]StackelbergInterconnected MGsEnergy trade and payoff maximization mechanismObtained unique equilibrium solution able to maximize the payoff for all participating MGs.
Wu et al.[114]StackelbergIndividual MGPool strategy for fair and competitive market environmentIncreased cost saving by $470.08 for MGs while reducing profit by $297.69 for the distribution system.
Cintuglu et al.[115]CompetitionIndividual MGGame-theoretic reverse auction modelObtained a platform capable of fully complying with industrial protocols and devices.
Park et al.[116]CompetitionInterconnected MGsEnergy trade mechanism for competitive marketAchieved fast convergence time
for practical implementation in real MG systems.
Table 5. Economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal impacts of LEMs for P2P energy trading.
Table 5. Economic, social, environmental, technical, and legal impacts of LEMs for P2P energy trading.
Positive ImpactsNegative Impacts
Economic
[20,25,29,37,125,126,127,128,129,130,131,132]
  • Energy prices and fees decrease as participants can buy cheaper energy from other peers and receive discounts and donations
  • Cost savings are obtained as changes in energy consumption are induced due to price volatility from intermittent generation
  • Grid costs are reduced for participants due to locally concentrated trade of energy with less grid usage
  • Exported energy income increases as participants sell energy to other peers
  • Initial investment and operation costs may be high as energy trading requires smart meters and ICT infrastructure
  • Energy prices and fees can increase for non-participants as utilities recover revenue loss
  • Energy prices can become suboptimal and hard to compare and participants may get less optimal deals
  • Return on investment in renewables can be negatively affected by low sales revenue
Social
[20,79,125,126,127,128,129,133,134,135]
  • Training and employment opportunity increases as new jobs are created and participants gain skills and education
  • Empowerment is developed as participants choose supply options and gain awareness and knowledge for better deals
  • Physical health and mental well-being may improve as participants are encouraged to implement energy efficiency
  • Social trust increases for participants due to increased transparency in transactions provided by DLTs
  • Autonomy and privacy may be enabled as participants have increased decision making and control over deals
  • Community attachment and cooperation increase due to direct connections and dependence between participants
  • Energy poverty and inequality can increase due to lack of skills and financial capacity to use ICTs for market operation and decisions
  • Negative and non-cooperative interactions may occur between certain rival participants
  • Energy trading can cause discrimination against specific individuals due to certain selection restrictions or features
Environmental
[20,25,29,125,126,127,129,136]
  • Renewables are encouraged as participants sell excess renewable energy at more favorable prices
  • Availability of renewable energy is increased as uncertainties in demand and community-based generation are mitigated
  • EV integration is improved as vehicle-to-grid support increases and becomes more affordable
  • Imported fuels and grid energy decrease as participants generate and trade renewable energy
  • GHG emissions decrease due to increased use of EVs and renewable energy generation
  • Energy consumption may increase due to increased charging of EVs
  • Energy consumption may increase due to desire of consuming cheaper energy during discounts or low-price periods
  • Energy trading requires several systems and ICT equipment with negative environmental impacts
  • Operation of blockchain networks using PoW mechanisms for energy trading can be energy intensive
Technical
[20,25,125,126,127,129,134,137]
  • Energy access in isolated MGs improves as participants use smart appliances and trade energy with other peers
  • Branch congestion and balance between supply and demand can be locally managed as participants trade energy
  • Ancillary services and flexibility are provided to the grid by the participants without grid reinforcement costs
  • Energy trading can provide incentives to service providers in areas with high network management requirements
  • Congestion in distribution branches may increase due to overvoltage/overload and bi-directional power flows
  • Implementation of energy markets in cities and other large-scale applications may be difficult due to scalability issues
Legal
[20,42,125,127,129,134,138]
  • High-quality energy services can be delivered and ensured as market participation becomes properly regulated
  • Energy trading offers opportunities to assign new responsibilities and legal obligations to participants
  • Vulnerable consumers can be protected through proper regulatory frameworks
  • Implementation of highly diverse energy trading markets can be difficult or impossible to regulate
  • Energy trading may be restricted to a regional or local area due to differences in regional legislation
  • Energy trading may cause some disruptions on business and regulatory models of traditional intermediaries
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Bandeiras, F.; Gomes, Á.; Gomes, M.; Coelho, P. Exploring Energy Trading Markets in Smart Grid and Microgrid Systems and Their Implications for Sustainability in Smart Cities. Energies 2023, 16, 801. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16020801

AMA Style

Bandeiras F, Gomes Á, Gomes M, Coelho P. Exploring Energy Trading Markets in Smart Grid and Microgrid Systems and Their Implications for Sustainability in Smart Cities. Energies. 2023; 16(2):801. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16020801

Chicago/Turabian Style

Bandeiras, Filipe, Álvaro Gomes, Mário Gomes, and Paulo Coelho. 2023. "Exploring Energy Trading Markets in Smart Grid and Microgrid Systems and Their Implications for Sustainability in Smart Cities" Energies 16, no. 2: 801. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16020801

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop