Next Article in Journal
EUDR Compliance in Ghana’s Natural Rubber Sector and Its Implications for Smallholders
Previous Article in Journal
Shifts in Seafood Distribution: Trends Among Retailers and Wholesalers Before and After COVID-19 in Japan
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

In Pursuit of Samuelson for Commodity Futures: How to Parameterize and Calibrate the Term Structure of Volatilities

Department of Applied Mathematics and Statistics, Whiting School of Engineering, Johns Hopkins University, Homewood Campus, Baltimore, MD 21218, USA
Commodities 2025, 4(3), 13; https://doi.org/10.3390/commodities4030013
Submission received: 26 May 2025 / Revised: 7 July 2025 / Accepted: 9 July 2025 / Published: 18 July 2025

Abstract

The phenomenon of rising forward price volatility, both historical and implied, as maturity approaches is referred to as the Samuelson effect or maturity effect. Disregarding this effect leads to significant mispricing of early-exercise options, extendible options, or other path-dependent options. The primary objective of the research is to identify a practical way to incorporate the Samuelson effect into the evaluation of commodity derivatives. We choose to model the instantaneous variance employing the exponential decay parameterizations of the Samuelson effect. We develop efficient calibration techniques utilizing historical futures data and conduct an analysis of statistical errors to provide a benchmark for model performance. The study employs 15 years of data for WTI, Brent, and NG, producing excellent results, with the fitting error consistently inside the statistical error, except for the 2020 crisis period. We assess the stability of the fitted parameters via cross-validation techniques and examine the model’s out-of-sample efficacy. The approach is generalized to encompass seasonal commodities, such as natural gas and electricity. We illustrate the application of the calibrated model of instantaneous variance for the evaluation of commodity derivatives, including swaptions, as well as in the evaluation of power purchase agreements (PPAs). We demonstrate a compelling application of the Samuelson effect to a widely utilized auto-callable equity derivative known as the snowball.

1. Introduction

Understanding the dynamics of futures price volatility is very important for many aspects of risk management, such as hedging, portfolio construction, derivative pricing, etc. Samuelson was the first to investigate the relationship between volatility and time until contract expiration, stating the hypothesis that the volatility of futures price changes should increase as the delivery date nears. This prediction is very well-known and referred to as the Samuelson hypothesis or maturity effect [1]. This backwardation of volatility of forward contracts arises across most markets, but this effect is especially pronounced in energy markets as a particular steep increase in volatility occurs in the last six (or less) months of the life of the contract. This is one of the most fascinating phenomena of commodity futures, which must be taken into account in pricing and managing of commodity contracts.
The primary objective of our article is to provide a method to parameterize and, more crucially, calibrate the rise in volatility as contract maturity approaches. We are not questioning the validity of the Samuelson effect for the examined commodity futures, nor do we model the entire volatility surface, which involves stochastic volatility models. We focus only on the Samuelson effect and seek a viable solution that yields stable results. Our primary objective is to identify a natural and practical way to integrate the Samuelson effect in the evaluation of path-dependent options, early-expiry options, CVA, and related matters. Consequently, we chose instantaneous variance of commodity futures as the focus of the study. This choice allows us to match the market information, such as option quotes on futures, perfectly (via implied volatilities).
We begin with a simple example that demonstrates the importance of the Samuelson effect and the consequences of ignoring it. We consider a future contract on WTI with expiration in T = 2 years priced at F ( 0 , T ) = USD 64 per barrel. Assume that the implied volatility quoted for this contract is σ i m p = 35 % , and we consider an ATM call option on this future expiring τ = 3 months before the contract expiration, thus in T τ = 1.75 years. Such options are called early-exercise options. The total variance during the lifetime of the contract will be v a r t o t a l = σ i m p 2 T = 0.245 . If we price the option using the quoted implied volatility, the price of the early-exercise ATM call option will be USD 11.72 per unit (no discount). However, under the Samuelson effect, the variance does not accumulate in a uniform fashion, so such a calculation will be wrong. Suppose we have a strong Samuelson such that half of the total variance happens in the last three months of the life of the contract. In such a case, to price the option, we have to use the following volatility:
σ 1 = 0.5 v a r t o t a l T τ = 26.46 %
The right option price is USD 8.89 , and ignoring the presence of Samuelson leads to overpricing the option by 32 % .
Now, let us analyze the consequences of using a wrong variance for the second part of the time, the last three months of the lifetime of the contract. Since half of the total variance realizes during a short period of time of three months, the average volatility σ 2 corresponding to the last three months will be much higher:
σ 2 = 0.5 v a r t o t a l τ = 70 %
Assume that in 1.75 years we have a right to buy a call option for premium X 2 = USD 10, and the strike X 1 of the call option is equal to the current forward price X 1 = F ( 0 , T ) . Thus, we consider a compound option with payoff
c c o m p = max c B L ( F ( T τ , T ) , X 1 , σ 2 , τ ) X 2 , 0
where c B L ( F , X , σ 2 , τ ) is the Black call price with price F of the underlying asset, strike X 1 , volatility σ 2 , and time to expiration τ . We can price the compound option by using standard numerical procedures (grid evaluation or Monte Carlo). Even though the right σ 2 with Samuelson is higher than with flat Samuelson, the expectation of the underlying call option c B L is the same in the two scenarios (we use risk-neutral pricing). However, the distribution of futures prices in 1.75 years with flat Samuelson is much wider (standard deviation of futures price of USD 31.37 vs. USD 23.06 ), which makes the compound option more expensive under flat Samuelson c c o m p = USD 8.32 vs. with Samuelson c c o m p = USD 6.41 . Disregarding Samuelson results in overpricing the option by 30 % .
Another example of an early-exercise option includes swaptions, which are widespread products in energy markets. Their evaluation is discussed in [2]; see also the recent book on quantitative trading in the oil market by Bouchoev [3]. The Samuelson effect must be taken into account in the evaluation of path-dependent options, such as extendibles, calculations of forward exposure of a portfolio (necessary for CVA computations), hedging decisions, etc.
We now provide a comprehensive summary of the current research on the subject, which includes the most recent developments.
Empirical analyses have been conducted on the Samuelson hypothesis in numerous studies, and it has been validated in a subset of markets. Many of them reach mixed conclusions. For example, Miller [4] investigates live cattle, Barnhill et al. [5] study U.S. Treasury bonds; Adrangi et al. [6] consider selected energy; Adrangi and Chatrath [7] analyze coffee, sugar, and cocoa. Andersen [8] finds evidence in the agricultural markets, such as wheat, oats, soybean meal, and cocoa, but not for silver. Milonas [9] finds strong support for the hypothesis in agricultural markets, but little or no support when using gold, copper, GNMA, T-bond, and T-bill prices. Rutledge [10] finds support for the Samuelson hypothesis with silver and cocoa, but inconclusive evidence for wheat and soybean oil. Galloway and Kolb [11] study the term structure of volatility in 45 markets, including agricultural and energy commodity futures, precious and industrial metal futures, and stock index, currency, and interest rate futures. Their findings provide support for the maturity effect in agricultural and energy commodities, but not in precious metals and financials. Liu [12] employs almost stochastic dominance and the power spectrum to investigate the maturity effect for five groups of energy futures, such as crude oil, reformulated regular gasoline, RBOB regular gasoline, No. 2 heating oil, and propane. The outcome provides mixed results, ranging from supporting to being contrary to the hypothesis. Jaeck and Lautier [13] find evidence of a Samuelson effect in various electricity markets, such as German, Nordic, Australian, and US, and show that storage is not a necessary condition for such an effect to appear. A recently published article by Castello [14] examines the term structure dynamics in the natural gas futures market, specifically analyzing the daily futures price of the Dutch Title Transfer Facility (TTF) via a machine-learning-based methodology, providing evidence supporting the Samuelson hypothesis.
“Negative” papers rejecting the hypothesis include Grammatikos and Saunders [15], who find no relationship between futures return volatility and time-to-maturity for currency futures prices, and a study by Park and Sears [16] provides evidence to disprove the Samuelson hypothesis for stock indices. The well-known study by Bessembinder et al. [17] suggests that the hypothesis will be generally supported in markets where spot price changes include a predictable temporary component, which is more likely to be met in real assets than for financial assets. They show that the hypothesis will generally be supported in markets where spot prices and convenience yields are positively correlated. The authors assume that the carry arbitrage model represents futures markets.
The carry arbitrage model is based on the notion that the underlying instrument can be “carried” (purchased) with 100 % financing (borrowing) and delivered against a short futures position. Brooks [18] identifies and explores the important link between the empirical Samuelson hypothesis and theoretical carry: the degree to which carry arbitrage is empirically validated is associated with the degree to which the Samuelson hypothesis is not supported. In the continuation of the research, Brooks and Teterin [19] study the volatility-term structure in 10 futures markets comprising three categories: agriculture, energy, and metals. To estimate the slope of the volatility-term structure, they use the Nelson and Siegel [20] functional form, borrowed from the literature on modeling the term structure of interest rates. The authors show that the slope of the volatility-term structure is more negative when inventories are low, and that the threshold for high/low inventory is specific to each market. The relationship between the Samuelson hypothesis and inventory levels is rooted in the cost-of-carry model.
The popular models in the academic literature arrive at the Samuelson effect of futures volatility by considering models formulated in terms of the spot energy price with mean reverting process; see Clewlow and Strickland [21]. The Schwatz single-factor model [22] results in the exponential decay of future volatility:
σ F ( t , T ) = σ e α ( T t )
where α is the mean reversion rate, and σ is the spot-price volatility. The long-term level of volatilities at T = is zero, which is not realistic. Two-factor models with mean reverting processes for spot price and convenience yield (see Schwartz [22]. Gibson and Schwartz [23], and Pilipović [24]) result in an exponential decay of futures volatility with non-zero long-term level volatility at long horizons.
The vital paper by Schwartz and Trolle [25] expands the framework of spot models to accommodate unspanned stochastic volatility. In their approach, the volatility of both spot price and forward cost of carry depend on two volatility factors that follow a mean reverting process, resulting in the Samuelson effect for futures volatility. Crosby and Frau [26] broaden the model in [25] by incorporating multiple jump processes. They explore the valuation of plain vanilla options on futures prices when the spot price follows a log-normal process, the forward cost of carry curve and the volatility are stochastic variables, and the spot price and forward cost of carry allow for time-dampening jumps. Frau and Fanelli [27] present a new term-structure model for commodity futures prices based on [25], which they extend by incorporating seasonal stochastic volatility represented with two different sinusoidal expressions and price plain vanilla options on the Henry Hub natural gas futures contracts. Hillard and Hillard [28] develop a jump-diffusion model for pricing and hedging with margined options on futures. They introduce a jump-diffusion process for spot prices, and mean reverting processes for interest rate and stochastic convenience yield. Under positive correlations between diffusion parts, futures volatility increases as maturity approaches. Model parameters are calibrated using data on Brent crude contracts.
Another class of models addresses the direct modeling of futures rather than relying on spot pricing and unobservable convenience yield. Chiarella et al. [29] propose a model encompassing hump-shaped unspanned stochastic volatility, which entails a finite-dimensional affine model for the commodity futures curve and quasi-analytical prices for options on commodity futures. Schnieder and Tavin [30] introduce a futures-based model capable of capturing the main features displayed by crude oil futures and options contracts, such as the Samuelson volatility effect and the volatility smile. They calculate the joint characteristic function of two futures contracts in the model in analytic form and use it to price calendar spread options.
In the contemporary analysis of commodity volatility, it is imperative to take into account both geopolitical and climate risks. For instance, a recent study by Özdemir et al. [31] examines the influence of the Geopolitical Risk Index (GPR) on the volatility of commodity futures returns. It broadens the scope of the research to encompass industrial metals, energy, agricultural products, and precious metals. Another recent paper by Guo et al. [32] introduces a climate change concern index to quantify climate risk and evaluate its impact on commodity futures volatility.
We will now delineate the fundamental concepts of our methodology and compare them with existing techniques.
We opt to utilize futures data and model their instantaneous variance using exponential decay models as the majority of commodity trading happens in futures markets. A natural generalization of (1), explicitly shown in many publications (see, for instance, [30] or [3]), is the following form of variance parameterization including two exponential decays:
σ F 2 ( t , T ) = σ 0 2 e 2 B ( T t ) + σ 2 e 2 β ( T t )
where B is the global decay and β is a long-term decay (much smaller than B); σ 0 is the normalization factor to match the implied market volatility, and σ is the level of a long-term volatility. Swindle [33] uses this representation to model the total implied variance of commodity futures.
Introducing time-dependent instantaneous variance can be interpreted as a non-uniform clock: we treat the total realized variance as “time.” Under Samuelson, the clock ticks slowly regarding the distant future and accelerates as we approach expiry. Figure 1 below depicts this concept. The example employs the simplest model (1) for instantaneous variance (hence, σ = 0 ). We compute the total variance of a futures contract with maturity of five years and plot it as a function of time t. The market-implied volatility of the future is set at σ i m p = 50 % . We examine several decay values: B = 0 , 0.05 , 0.2 , 0.5 , from no Samuelson to slight, moderate, and very strong decay. In every instance, the total realized variance from t = 0 to expiry T must correspond to the market-implied variance I = 0 . 5 2 × 5 = 1.25 , while the path used to achieve this is contingent upon B. For a strong Samuelson with B = 0.5 , about 60 % of the total variance occurs in the last year of the contract’s duration.
Our calibration technique involves capturing the instantaneous variance by computing variances of returns of nearby contracts. The closest research to our paper in the existing literature is the mentioned paper by Brooks and Teterin (“BT”) [19]. They also use returns of nearby futures, calculate the their standard deviations, and fit a three-factor parametrization by Nelson and Siegel [20] with exponential decay. However, there are key differences between our approaches. First, BT interpolate futures prices with a Nelson–Siegel curve [20], resulting in a vector of pseudo-price time-series with each time-series corresponding to an exact maturity on every trading day (in industry, such contracts are called constant-maturity contracts and used for risk management purposes). We use the raw prices of nearby future contracts. Even though, as calendar time passes, the time to expiration of nearby futures indeed changes and drifts to zero (Brooks and Teterin [19] called it “the maturity drift problem”), we deliver convincing results of the volatility–maturity relationship using raw prices.
Second, BT employ only 12 nearby contracts, while we include all available information, 60 contracts. BT do not account for seasonality when considering term structure of NG volatility. Our data includes crisis period of Spring 2020, which is quite an interesting period to test models.
Third, the models and the targets of the fit are different. The NS model [20] for yield curve y t ( τ ) given by the parametric form
y t ( τ ) = β 1 t + β 2 t 1 e λ t τ λ t τ + β 3 t 1 e λ t τ λ t τ e λ t τ
is based on the forward yield curve; see [34]:
f t ( τ ) = β 1 t + β 2 t e λ t τ + β 3 t λ t e λ t τ
BT use (3) to model average volatility σ t ( τ ) of a synthetic forward contract with constant maturity τ (in months). We fit instantaneous variance employing a representation (2) similar to (4) but with two exponential decays. The primary input in the model, which determines the Samuelson strength, is the exponential decay parameter B. In BT’s methodology, the exponential decay parameter λ t is constant during the initial fitting stages, while the key parameter reflecting the Samuelson effect is represented by the slope of the volatility-term structure β 2 t .
We generalize the calibration methodology to seasonal commodities such as natural gas. The natural gas term structure is defined by seasonality. Natural gas storage is a vital part of the natural gas delivery system and helps to balance supply and demand. During the winter season, from November to March (withdrawal season), gas consumption peaks as a result of increased heating demand. During the summer season, from April to October (injection season), gas demand decreases while production continues. Because of this, we fitted Samuelson independently after dividing the data for nearby futures into two periods: winter and summer. Due to our reliance on data regarding nearby contracts, this separation prevented us from combining returns from different periods, such as March and April. Consequently, we are compelled to employ only two months of the observation period data. Although the fitting findings were favorable, with errors remaining predominantly inside the statistical margin, the outcomes lack consistent stability due to the short observation period. Incorporating additional seasons might exacerbate the existing problems.
The next target is to find the methodology for the Samuelson effect for a more complicated case of seasonal commodities, in particular electricity futures. Electricity has always been the most fascinating commodity to study due to non-storability (at least in meaningful quantities), resulting in very high volatility and abundance of extreme events. Because supply and demand have to be in equilibrium at all times, the electricity seasonality is more refined than for any other seasonal commodity. Each hour in each weekday and month has its own pattern and can be traded separately. Therefore, using only two seasons would not be enough, and we need to come up with a more granular seasonal model. The previous seasonal model for natural gas implies that σ 0 is roughly the same for months in the same season, and the Samuelson parameters B, σ , and β are different for winter and summer months. Since we used only two months of nearby futures data, we were catching the Samuelson effect locally, at that particular period of time. The goal is to come up with a methodology that is applicable to long-term deals, such as popular power purchase agreements (“PPA”), which become increasingly more popular in view of growing use of renewable energy. We use the same model for the instantaneous variance (2), with β = 0 ; however, there are several differences between the two approaches. Firstly, we assume that the normalization constant σ 0 depends on a month in a year, and the Samuelson parameters B and σ are the same for all the months. We consider only the 1-decay model with β = 0 . Secondly, we use the real futures data and calculate the realized variance regarding a one-year observation period. As in the previous model, we calculate the ratios of variances, but now we use the variances of the same calendar month. We average the ratios for 12 moving observation periods and fit the model. The results are stable.
We demonstrate how the Samuelson effect can be used for commodity derivatives. Firstly, we outline the evaluation of early expiration options, such as swaptions. Secondly, we demonstrate how the calibrated model of the instantaneous variance can be used to extrapolate implied volatilities, which is crucially important in the evaluation of PPAs. Furthermore, we discovered an intriguing application of the Samuelson effect to a popular auto-callable equity derivative, the snowball; see [35]. The term ”snowball” describes an investor’s potential for profit accumulation. A snowball is type of auto-callable structure with two barriers: knock-out and knock-in set up as percentages of the initial price. The longer the investor retains an income certificate, the greater the profit, provided the underlying does not drop precipitously. Consequently, the payment of the snowball is contingent upon the realized variance of the underlying asset and the rate of its accumulation. Issuing auto-callable derivatives on assets influenced by the Samuelson effect can be beneficial as initial low volatility may extend the duration of the asset remaining within barriers, hence yielding greater profit. Furthermore, we identified that, based on the structure of a snowball, keeping the realized variance constant, there is an optimal rate of variance growth that yields maximal profit.
We will now delineate the subsequent sections of the article. Section 2 describes the calibration methodology, including generalization for seasonal commodities such as natural gas and electricity. Section 3 examines the results of the calibration employing 15 years of data for WTI, Brent, natural gas, and ERCOT North Hub electricity futures. We discuss the optimal choice in observation period, the model selection, and the analytics of the statistical errors to assess the goodness-of-fit. In Section 4, we demonstrate the application of the calibrated model of instantaneous variance for the evaluation of commodity derivatives, including swaptions, power purchase agreements (PPAs), and auto-callable derivatives linked to commodity futures. The main results of the article are presented in Section 5, which also details the direction of future research. Some specifics are provided in Appendix A and Appendix B.

2. Methodology for Samuelson Effect Calibration

This section is dedicated to providing an in-depth description of the Samuelson effect calibration process.

2.1. Data Selection and Calculation of Normalized Ratios

We start by going over the data selection process in depth, covering the features and scope of the data sample.
A variety of data types can be employed to calibrate a specific Samuelson form.
  • Market-implied at-the-money volatilities.
  • Historically realized volatilities of futures contract returns with expirations T i , i = 1 , 2 n , calculated at time period [ t a , t b ] , t b < T 1 , T 1 < T 2 < T n .
  • Historically realized volatilities of returns of nearby contracts.
In the last option, we employ the concept of “promptness” of a contract instead of specific contracts. The first nearby contract, referred to as the prompt, is the closest future contract that is accessible at time t and has the shortest duration to expiration. The second nearby contract is the next accessible contract, etc. The second neighboring contract takes over as the first one when the first one expires and so on. The Samuelson effect should result in lower volatility for futures with farther-off expirations.
Employing the first choice—market-implied volatilities, which include forward-looking information—offers clear benefits. The liquidity of options on futures beyond one year is, nevertheless, inadequate. The example below in Figure 2 does not show an immediate decrease in implied volatility, possibly due to local market disruptions. However, historical realized volatilities reveal that realized volatilities usually decrease with expiration T i . Figure 2 presents a comparison.
Since our approach is based on modeling instantaneous variance, the second source of data would involve integration to arrive to realized variance. Therefore, we choose to employ nearby contracts to capture the “true” instantaneous volatility. Thus, the third approach—the volatilities of returns of nearby contracts—is the data of choice for our analysis, with the exception that, for electricity, we had to resort to the second option. Our investigation includes 15 years of data for WTI, Brent, and natural gas futures obtained from the Barchart website. To calibrate Samuelson for electricity futures, we utilize eight years of historical data on electricity futures from Argus Media.
In order to eliminate the impact of volatility level and make the statistics comparable, we normalize the variances of the i-th nearby contract by the variance of the first nearby contract:
R i 2 = σ i 2 σ 1 2
These ratios form the basis of the calibration procedure. Joarder [36] examined the statistical properties of the product and ratio of two correlated chi-squared random variables. The findings of the research can be used to calculate the statistical errors of the ratios. Appendix A offers the specifics.

2.2. Calibration Procedures

We establish a set of model parameter Θ :
Θ = { B , σ , β }
and model ratios Y ( Θ ) i that are inferred from the instantaneous variance’s form (2):
Y ( Θ ) i = e 2 B ( T i t ) + σ 2 e 2 b ( T i t ) e 2 B ( T 1 t ) + σ 2 e 2 b ( T 1 t ) )
where T i and T 1 are times to maturity (in years) of the i-th and the first nearby contracts correspondingly.
The traditional model calibration procedure follows the conventional approach for identifying the model parameters that optimally align with historical data. First, we choose an observation period [ t a , t b ] and construct series of nearby contracts F m ( i ) of historical settlement prices observed daily at t m [ t a , t b ] and m = 1 , 2 , , M , t 1 = t a , t m = t b ; i = 1 , N , where N is the number of observed contracts. Usually, N = 60. For non-seasonal commodities, we employ observation periods of two and twelve months, while, for seasonal commodities, we utilize a two-month timeframe. A two-month observation period typically comprises M = 44 observations (days), whereas a twelve-month observation period has M = 252 days. We compute log-returns
ln ( F m ( i ) / F m 1 ( i ) ) ( t m t m 1 ) 1 / 2
We next compute realized variances of returns and document the previously established ratios. A constrained minimization of the total error determines the optimal set of model parameters
E ( Θ ) = i = 2 N [ Y ( Θ ) i R i ] 2 N 1
where Y ( Θ ) i are the model ratios given by (6). We assume that decay occurs mostly due to increase in T i and cancel out the normalization constant σ 0 . The specific choices in parameters Θ and constraints are revealed in each case.
The primary challenge of the minimization problem is the possibility of various solutions because of the way parameters influence the ratios: an increase in long-term volatility σ weakens the decay, whereas a higher B drives ratios to decay more quickly. We should stay away from certain areas of the parameter space where slight adjustments to ratios result in significant changes to decay or long-term volatility. Several contour plots of the 12-month ratio Y 12 for the scenario where the long-term decay β = 0 are shown in the following Figure 3 to demonstrate this.
The model with two decays, B and β , will be referred to as the 2-decay model, whereas the model with β = 0 will be called the 1-decay model. Only in times of crisis, when Samuelson is very strong, do we need to use a more intricate 2-decay model. The following section will provide examples.

2.3. Samuelson Effect for Seasonal Commodities

To accommodate Samuelson, the previous approach must be modified for seasonal commodities such as electricity, natural gas, heating oil, and gasoline. Our first emphasis is on natural gas, one of the most significant and “physical” commodities. The first seasonal model for natural gas assumes that σ 0 is roughly the same throughout months within the same season, and the Samuelson parameters B, σ , and β are different for winter and summer months.
The subsequent objective was to identify the methodology for the Samuelson effect in a more complex scenario involving seasonal commodities, specifically electricity futures. Seasonality is more nuanced for electricity than for any other seasonal commodity. Every hour of each weekday and month exhibits a distinct pattern and can be traded independently. Consequently, relying solely on two seasons is insufficient; we must develop a more detailed seasonal model. We employ the identical model for the instantaneous variance (2) with β = 0 while positing that the normalization constant σ 0 is contingent upon the month of the year, while the Samuelson parameters B and σ remain constant across all months. We utilize actual futures data to compute the realized variance over a one-year observation period. Similar to the prior model, we compute the ratios of variances; however, we now utilize the variances from the same calendar month. We compute the average ratios over a 12-month period, adjusting the observation timeframe, and subsequently fit the model. The results are stable.

2.3.1. Natural Gas

A typical monthly supply–demand chart for natural gas (NG) based on EIA data is shown in Figure 4. This type of chart can be found in many natural gas market references, such as [33]. Particularly during the winter, storage is essential to closing the gap between supply and demand.
There are significant winter peaks in demand because of the cold weather, and milder summer peaks because of rising power use. Demand is cyclical, which causes seasonal patterns in prices and volatility. This makes a volatility-term structure a superposition of decay with time to expiration and seasonal shape. An illustration of implied NG volatility can be found in Figure 5.
Based on the data and the widely accepted description of natural gas storage seasons, we also choose to divide the Samuelson data into two periods: a summer (injection) season that runs from April to October and a winter (withdrawal) season that runs from November to March.
Because of this division, we are unable to combine returns from various seasons, such March and April. Using an observation period of just one month is an easy fix. Fitting results are not convincing though because variance measured on (about) 22 data points is extremely noisy. As a result, we carefully chose a two-month observation period. For example, in September and October, we observe first nearby futures prices from different seasons; therefore, this period does not work. There are even more issues if we use additional months in the observation period, such as four or six, because we would have to leave out more combinations. Therefore, we decide to employ two months for the study time.
Using a similar process to that used for oil, mutatis mutandis, we fit a seasonal Samuelson independently.

2.3.2. Electricity

Electricity has consistently been the most intriguing commodity to examine due to its non-storability (at least currently, in significant quantities), resulting in considerable volatility and a prevalence of extreme events. Due to the necessity for supply and demand to be in equilibrium at all times, electricity seasonality is more nuanced than any other seasonal commodity regarding both prices and volatilities.
Given this behavior, we formulate the subsequent assumptions regarding the dynamics of instantaneous variance (2).
  • We presume β = 0 .
  • The parameters B and σ remain constant throughout the year.
  • The normalization constant σ 0 solely dependent on the month of the year and remains constant throughout all years.
We will now delineate the process for calibrating the Samuelson parameters B and σ using historical data of futures prices seen over a one-year period. For instance, we consider the year 2022 as the targeted observation period. We select the initial contract as the one we monitored until its expiration throughout the observation period, specifically January 2023.
We adhere to the subsequent steps:
  • Record prices for the chosen contract for about one year prior to the expiration. In this particular instance, observations commence at time t 1 , 1 January 2022, and continue until the contract’s expiration at t 2 = T 1 , contingent upon the market (for example, ERCOT futures expire on the second to last business day of the month prior to the contract month). The observation period is defined as [ t 1 , t 2 ] .
  • Calculate log-returns and their standard deviation σ r e a l J a n 23 . This represents the realized volatility of the first contract.
  • Simultaneously compute the log-returns of further forward contracts, including 23 February, 23 April, and extending four years forward to 26 December, with the identical observation period [ t 1 , t 2 ] , and determine the standard deviations of their log-returns. Document 48 realized volatilities.
  • Calculate ratios by dividing the volatility of each month and year by the volatility of the same month in the previous year:
    R ( t 1 , t 2 , T i + 1 , T i ) = σ r e a l i , y r + 1 σ r e a l i , y r , i = 1 , . . . 36
  • Record 36 ratios, which are functions of T i t 1 and T i t 2 , only assuming the normalization constant σ 0 .
Subsequently, replicate the aforementioned steps 1–4, commencing with 23 February, while advancing the observation term by one month, initiating from 1 February 2022, until the contract’s expiration. The approach yields an additional set of 36 ratios. Select 23 March and continue until December 2023. Consequently, we shall obtain 12 sets of 36 ratios. Observe that the time periods T i t 1 and T i t 2 are approximately same across all sets.
T i t 2 i 1 12 , T i t 1 i 1 12 + 1 , i = 1 , 2 . . . , 36 .
Given that they rely solely on times rather than the month of the year, we can average each promptness i across 12 sets to determine the optimal parameters B and σ that encapsulate the Samuelson effect.
Our objective is to develop a methodology suited to long-term agreements, such as prevalent power purchase agreements (PPAs). Consequently, we have opted to examine a global pattern of volatility-term structure rather than a more detailed seasonal decay as conducted in our analysis of natural gas.
We will now describe the outcomes of the calibration tasks.

3. Results

This section examines the calibration results using 15 years of data for WTI, Brent, and natural gas futures, along with the selection of the observation period and model (1-decay versus 2-decay). A 12-month observation period for WTI and Brent, a 2-month duration for natural gas, and a first-order decay model tend to be efficacious. During crises, when the Samuelson effect is significant, it is essential to employ a more refined 2-decay model. We provide analytics for statistical errors on normalized variances to provide a baseline for the calibration results and assess the error relative to the lower bound of the statistical error for WTI and Brent. To achieve this, we utilize a rolling window of 12 months (252-day interval). We conclude that, for a majority of times, excluding the crisis years of 2009 and 2020, the model aligns effectively with the data within the bounds of statistical error.
We provide the calibration results of the Samuelson effect for electricity futures at a major trading hub, namely ERCOT North in Texas. We begin with a review of the descriptive statistics of the log-returns for WTI, Brent, and natural gas futures.

3.1. Descriptive Statistics

We meticulously examine the returns of the first four nearby contracts. We label the first nearby contract series of WTI as WTI1, the second nearby as WTI2, and so forth. Correspondingly, we assign the names of the contracts Brent1 to Brent4 for Brent Oil futures and NG1 to NG4 for natural gas. The findings are displayed in Table 1. The standard deviations are daily and increase as maturity approaches. We opt to exclude the negative price date for WTI contracts to prevent complications in the calculation of log-returns.

3.2. Results of Samuelson Calibration, WTI, Brent, and Natural Gas

We conducted the fitting technique multiple times throughout a designated observation period for WTI, Brent Oil, and natural gas. Table 2 enumerates the outcomes of WTI calibration throughout a 12-month observation period. The last column denotes the root mean square error (8) computed using the optimal parameters Θ of the 1-decay model, scaled by the volatility of the prompt contract.
As an example, we examine the instantaneous volatility of WTI realized during a 12-month observation period, from t a = 21 February 2019 to t b = 20 February 2020, with N = 60 . Figure 6 illustrates a fitting graph. The scatter points denote the actual realized volatilities, whereas the line graphs illustrate the fitted model with exponential 1-decay. We calibrated the volatility level by aligning σ 0 with the volatility of the prompt contract.
Table 3 presents details on the RMSE errors for Brent over several observation periods.
To examine a seasonal instance of NG, we classify the data into two categories: summer, including April to October, and winter, spanning November to March. We eliminate inter-seasonal combinations and thereafter adjust the parameters for each season accordingly. Due to seasonality, we can only employ two months of return data. As a result, the assessments of true instantaneous volatility demonstrate increased noise. The model may not correspond as accurately as it does with WTI; however, it sufficiently represents seasonal fluctuations. The subsequent Table 4 presents the calibration results for NG across various time periods.
Figure 7 illustrates the actual NG volatility compared to the fitted volatility with a 1-decay model. The realized volatility is calculated using the log-returns of natural gas for the period from 30 October 2019 to 27 December 2019.

3.3. Results of Samuelson Calibration for Electricity Futures

ERCOT Markets

We begin with the ERCOT (Electric Reliability Council of Texas) market, which is very unique and widely known for its significant price volatility. It is an energy-only market, which means generators are only compensated for the energy they provide to the grid, unlike other markets that also compensate for capacity availability. ERCOT added another component to wholesale prices in 2015, a scarcity adder. This scarcity adder represents the value of additional resources to grid reliability. Further, ERCOT’s electricity system operates within Texas and is not subject to federal control by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC). ERCOT’s transmission grid is solely contained inside the state of Texas and is not linked to other states’ networks. These two facts make ERCOT an “energy island”.
ERCOT’s electricity prices are volatile due to several factors, including Texas’s unique weather patterns, its independent electrical grid, increasing demand, and the integration of intermittent renewable energy sources such as wind and solar. In February 2021, extremely low temperatures during Winter Storm Uri forced significant generation equipment to freeze, leading to prolonged outages throughout most of Texas. The scarcity adder resulted in elevated ERCOT energy prices, which remained at the price ceiling of USD 9000/MWh for three consecutive days.
Due to the inherent volatility of electricity contracts, we cannot anticipate flawless fitting results, as seen with WTI. The objective is to capture the general decline in volatility by calculating average seasonal ratios, as outlined in Section 2.3.2. The liquidity of energy futures tends to concentrate within the initial two to three years. Consequently, we employed only 24 ratios to calibrate Samuelson.
Figure 8 depicts the realized seasonal ratios in comparison to model ratios determined as of January 2021. This indicates that we computed the average of seasonal ratios for future contracts from January 2020 to December 2020. The fitted Samuelson is strong, which is unsurprising given that the period encompasses the COVID-19 era.
Not all ratios fit as well, but we can usually identify the trend. Figure 9 illustrates a more recent outcome of fitting the average of realized seasonal ratios from 23 June to 24 May.
Table 5 shows the results of the Samuelson effect calibration for ERCOT electricity futures. We record the parameters at the start of each year, using an average of 12 seasonal ratios from January to December of the preceding year.

3.4. Finding the Optimal Length of Observation Period

The length of the observation period is essential for volatility calculation and calibration procedures. We provide the subsequent considerations for its selection.
Calculating instantaneous volatility with one-month data from nearby contracts is not adequate as 22 data points might yield a noisy result, leading to a wide confidence interval for the volatility estimate. Therefore, we selected a minimum observation period of two months. A two-month observation period could be a judicious decision, especially during times of crisis. In the spring of 2020, global market volatility was exceptionally high, and conditions were rapidly changing. Employing a two-month period might prove a prudent choice. In a less volatile market, like that of 2019, one may choose a 6-month or 12-month period. A 12-month observation period is optimal as it consistently includes the most liquid December contract. Another rationale for selecting a 12-month observation period is the stability of the fitted parameters.
In conclusion, the selection of a 12-month observation period is our preference and primary case study.

3.5. Model Selection

Upon analyzing the results of the fit across several historical periods, we conclude that the 1-decay model yields fair results in comparison to the 2-decay model in the majority of periods. During stable market conditions, devoid of significant disruptions like the COVID-19 crisis in 2020 or the 2009 financial crisis, it is entirely justifiable to utilize the parsimonious 1-decay model.
Figure 10 illustrates a comparison between the 1-decay exponential model and the 2-decay exponential model. The black line illustrates the graph of the fitted 1-decay exponential model, while the blue line depicts the graph of the 2-decay exponential model. The observed realized volatilities in the tail exhibit a clear decay in long-term volatility. The 2-decay exponential model more accurately reflects the pattern, resulting in an improvement of around 80 basis points in RMSE accuracy, as seen in Table 6. In 2009 and 2020, the 2-decay model presents far better performance. Similar patterns emerge during periods of market volatility, namely during the crises of 2009 and 2020.

3.6. Statistical Errors on the Normalized Ratios

To evaluate model performance, we developed analytics on the statistical errors of the normalized ratios R i 2 as defined by (5). We consider log-returns (7) of nearby contracts, which have a multivariate normal distribution. The ratio of the variance of the i-nearby contract, normalized by the “true” variance S i 2 σ i 2 , follows a chi-squared distribution with m degrees of freedom, where m = M 1 and M equals the number of observations.
Define U i = m S i 2 σ i 2 and U 1 = m S 1 2 σ 1 2 . The joint distribution of U 1 and U 2 is referred to as the bivariate chi-squared distribution. Joarder (2009) examined the distribution of the product and the ratio of two correlated chi-squared random variables. We utilized the findings presented in this paper, namely the formulae of the first and second moments of the ratio W i = U i U 1 . Specifically, if ρ i denotes the correlation between the log-returns of the i-th nearby contract and the prompt contract, then, for m > 8 and 1 < ρ i < 1 , we have
(i)
E ( W i ) = m 2 ρ i 2 m 2 , m > 2
(ii)
E ( W i 2 ) = 1 ( m 2 ) ( m 4 ) 24 ρ i 4 8 ( m + 2 ) ρ i 2 + m ( m + 2 ) , m > 4
The variance of the ratio W can be computed by
V a r ( W i ) = E ( W i 2 ) ( E ( W i ) ) 2
As expected, V a r ( W i ) vanishes for perfect correlations ρ i = 1 . By substituting U i and U 1 into the equation, we can establish a relationship between W i and R i = S i 2 S 1 2 , which is our target variable, the normalized ratio.
V a r S i 2 S 1 2 = V a r R i 2 = σ i 2 σ 1 2 2 · V a r ( W i )
Since the “true” variances σ i and σ 1 are unknown, it is essential to derive a lower bound using their estimates, S i and S 1 . The variances of the normalized ratios (A1) are contingent upon the number of points M, correlations, and Samuelson strength. The ratios decrease with stronger Samuelson and increase with weaker Samuelson. Increasing the number of observations M results in a decline in the ratios. In times of crisis, strong Samuelson decay leads to lower statistical errors, hence compromising model performance. Conversely, during crises and severe Samuelson effects, calendar correlations decrease, leading to contrary outcomes.
We need to find a lower constraint on the total error and verify that the fitting error resides within this statistical error lower bound. For conciseness, the particulars are provided in Appendix A. We present the findings of the comparison between the actual error and the lower bound of the statistical error for WTI and Brent, utilizing a rolling window of 12 months. We conclude that, for the majority of periods, excluding the crisis years of 2009 and 2020, the model aligns closely with the data. We provide an example of computing statistical error and verify the computations using simulations. Simulation examples suggest that the lower bound might be 70 % of the true average error. Refer to Appendix A for details.

4. Applications of Samuelson Modeling to Commodity Derivatives

The Samuelson effect must be considered when evaluating early expiration options, path-dependent options (such as extendibles), CVA computations, hedging decisions, and numerous other scenarios. This section demonstrates the applicability of Samuelson modeling for early-exercise options, such as swaptions, which are prevalent in energy markets. Subsequently, we illustrate the application of the calibrated model of instantaneous variance to extrapolate implied volatilities, which is essential for the evaluation of PPAs.

4.1. Swaptions

A swaption is a derivative contract that grants the purchaser the right, but not the obligation, to partake in a swap agreement at a specified future date t s . The buyer compensates the seller with a premium for this option. The payoff of a swaption can be written as
max i d f i × N i × F ( t s , T i p a y ) i d f i × N i K , 0 , t s < T 1 , T n
where F ( t s , T i ) represent the futures prices in the underlying swap at the swaption expiry, t s and d f i denote the discount factors from the swap payment time T i p a y to the swaption expiry, and t s and N i represent the volumes, whereas K denotes the strike of the swaption. Swaptions are naturally embedded into more complex contracts like extendible swaps or callable swaps, which allow for the extension or reduction of the period.
The inputs to a swaption evaluation comprise futures prices F i , implied volatilities σ i , interest rates, and the correlation matrix. Samuelson decay must also be taken into account as the implied volatilities constitute the total variance of the underlying futures and should be properly mapped to the swaption expiration t s < min ( T i ) . We will outline the mapping process below.
We commence with the quotes for implied at-the-money volatilities of commodity futures. The implied volatility σ i represents the expectation of realized volatility over the interval [ 0 , T i ] (We must utilize the expiration of the option on the future τ i < T i . For the sake of simplicity, we elect to disregard this difference and assume τ i = T i . Thus, we must calibrate σ 0 i to align with the market-implied volatility. Consequently, we compute the total realized variance from the present time ( t = 0 ) to the contract delivery expiry T i :
V a r 0 , T = 0 T i σ i 2 ( s , T i ) d s = σ i m p i 2 · T i
where the instantaneous variance σ i 2 ( s , T i ) is given by (2). Upon calibrating σ 0 , i for each contract in the underlying swap, we can compute the variance realized between the present time and the swaption expiration t s :
V a r i [ 0 , t s ] = 0 t s σ i 2 ( s , T i ) 2 d s
and obtain the volatility to be utilized in the swaption Monte Carlo evaluation.
σ i [ 0 , t s ] = V a r i [ 0 , t s ] t s

4.2. Applications of Samuelson Modeling to Evaluation of Power Purchase Agreements

Power purchase agreements (PPAs) have grown in popularity as renewable energy has become more widely used. The client is able to purchase electricity from a renewable energy project at a fixed price over the course of the contract term, which enables them to maintain long-term cost stability. Typically, a PPA for renewable energy has a duration of between 10 and 20 years. The seller guarantees the client a fixed generation shape—a predetermined quantity of energy delivered over a predetermined period—in the case of the so-called Fixed Shape Fixed Price PPA. An evaluation of a fixed-price PPA is equivalent to the pricing of a swap.
In order to safeguard a buyer from low electricity prices, the contract may be subject to an additional floor feature: a floor that limits the utmost amount of the buyer’s loss per M W h downward a > 0 . The payoff is equivalent to a swap and a put option:
v f l o o r ( t ) = ω ( t ) max ( p ( t ) K , a ) = ω ( t ) p ( t ) K + ω ( t ) max ( K a ) p ( t ) , 0
where ω ( t ) represents a predefined volume in M W h , p ( t ) denotes the varying market price of electricity for period t, and K signifies the contractual fixed price in U S D M W h that the PPA customer remits to the generator. The period of time t may encompass an hour, a day, or peak hours during weekdays within a month.
In the same vein, the contract may include a cap provision that limits the buyer’s profit to a cap b > 0 in order to safeguard the vendor from exorbitant electricity prices. In this case, the payoff is equivalent to a swap and a short call option:
v c a p ( t ) = ω ( t ) min ( p ( t ) K , b ) = ω ( t ) p ( t ) K ω ( t ) max ( p ( t ) ( K + b ) , 0 )
The contract, which secures both parties with a cap and floor, is equivalent to a swap and a collar from the buyer’s viewpoint. To determine the cost of a PPA with protection (e.g., caps, floors, or both), it is necessary to evaluate hourly, daily, or Asian monthly options, contingent upon the contractual definition of the period t.
We examine the case of daily protection throughout peak hours. We utilize data from Argus Media, encompassing daily and monthly implied volatilities for a two-year horizon. Figure 11 displays the monthly and daily ATM peak volatilities as of 5 January 2023. Since a typical renewable energy PPA lasts between 10 and 20 years, we must be able to extrapolate market implied volatilities over periods longer than two years. We use our Samuelson effect model for volatility of electricity futures to demonstrate how we can achieve this.
To evaluate the previously presented caps and floors, we must first determine how to calculate daily volatility. The best way for calculating volatility is to employ market data, which is always a preference. Specifically, as detailed in the book by A. Eydeland et al. (2003) [37], there are several types of options (which “imply volatilities”). First, monthly options imply the volatility of monthly forwards σ m . Second, index options imply volatility within the month (cash volatility), σ c a s h . Finally, daily options imply daily volatility, σ D . They are related structurally in that the variance of the forward contract until the settlement date T m and the cash variance during the month make up the total variance underpinning daily options:
σ D 2 ( T d ) = σ m 2 ( T m ) + σ c a s h 2 ( T d T m )
where T m denotes the settlement date of the underlying forward, and T d signifies the expiration of the daily option. Therefore, if both monthly and daily options (pertaining to the same month) are accessible, we can calculate cash volatility utilizing (12). We present an additional presumption on cash volatility:
Cash volatility changes month to month; it is seasonal and does not change year to year.
We compute the average cash volatility (average of two numbers) for each month of the next 24 months using the data provided by Argus Media. This would be the cash volatility for all subsequent years. As a result, if we can extend monthly volatility over more than two years, we will have daily volatility for every month of the PPA’s lifetime.
We employ assumptions on instantaneous variance for electricity futures to extrapolate monthly implied volatilities. We assume that the Samuelson parameters B and σ have been calibrated according to the outlined method, together with the monthly normalization constants σ 0 , i for each month of the year, utilizing Equation (11). We opt to utilize market-implied volatilities σ i m p i for the second year provided by Argus Media. The rationale for this decision is the potential for an additional premium in the quoted implied volatilities for the first year, particularly for prompt months. For each month J during the duration of the PPA, we possess all the necessary components to compute the expectation of realized volatility by integrating the seasonal instantaneous variance until the contract’s expiration T J :
σ i m p l J = σ 0 ( m ) 1 exp ( 2 * B * T J ) 2 B T J + σ 2
where σ 0 ( m ) is the normalization constant for the calendar month m of the contract.

4.3. Snowball Derivative on Commodity Futures

In China, a structured instrument termed “snowball derivative” provides investors receive coupons if the underlying stock index remains within a specified range; see [35]. The phrase “snowball” refers to an investor’s capacity for profit accumulation. The longer one holds an income certificate, the greater her return, assuming the underlying asset does not decline sharply. Snowballs, providing annual returns between 12 and 20%, became increasingly popular among affluent Chinese investors and asset managers during the COVID-19 epidemic. Since 2019, snowball has transitioned to a non-principal-guaranteed income, rendering it hazardous. The two prominent small-cap indices, the CSI 500 and CSI 1000, are primarily associated with snowball.
We will now outline a typical snowball structure. Snowball is a type of auto-callable structure featuring two barriers: a knock-out and a knock-in, both established as a percentage of the initial price. The knock-out barrier is monitored monthly, whereas the knock-in is assessed daily. Upon knock-out, the contract is annulled, and the buyer receives the principal along with the annualized coupon accrued during the period preceding the knock-out. When a knock-in event occurs without a subsequent knock-out, the derivative transforms into a short at-the-money put option devoid of coupons:
N o t i o n a l × max S 0 S T S 0 , 0
The evaluation of snowball derivative can be conducted utilizing the Monte Carlo method, as well as by historical simulation. The latter can be accomplished by selecting a period of one or two years and evaluating the snowball using historical index prices and moving the window one day forward. Figure 12 presents a comparison of histograms generated from historical simulation of the CSI500 index with those derived from the Monte Carlo approach. For Monte Carlo simulations, we employed daily price simulations based on the Geometric Brownian Motion (GBM) assumption and aligned the volatility with the realized historical volatility.
The ideal scenario occurs when there are neither knock-outs nor knock-ins, allowing the investor to achieve maximum profit; conversely, the worst-case scenario arises when the underlying asset declines below the knock-in threshold and fails to rebound to the knock-out level. Figure 13 depicts a scenario using a snowball structured on the CSI500 index, featuring a knock-out at 110 % and a knock-in at 85 % of the initial price, a coupon rate of 20 % , and a maturity of one year. This setup will be maintained for all following cases.
Subsequently, Figure 14 presents a worst-case scenario of snowball payout with the same attributes written on the same underlying:
It appears that the expected snowball payout decreases as the realized variation increases. In the basic GBM case of constant volatility, the subsequent Figure 15 illustrates the relationship between the expected payoff and the volatility of the underlying asset. The evaluation is conducted using daily Monte Carlo simulation.
We now turn our attention to a more interesting example: a snowball written on a commodity future whose volatility is influenced by the Samuelson effect. Snowball payout would seem to benefit from a more quiet underlying behavior at the start of the observation period. To examine the relationship between the expected payoff of the snowball and the Samuelson strength, it is necessary to preserve a constant total realized variance while applying various Samuelson times, as depicted in Figure 15. The subsequent Figure 16 illustrates the behavior of the expected snowball payoff. We employed the 1-decay model, fixed the long-term volatility parameter σ = 0.1 , set the maturity of the snowball at T = 1 , and fixed the total realized variance at 0.04 . This parallels the scenario in which we analyze a snowball contract on a commodity future that will expire in one year, with an implied volatility of σ i m p = 20 % .
When B = 0 , indicating the absence of Samuelson, the snowball value corresponds to the value under constant volatility of σ = 0.2 . The reduction in the snowball value for stronger Samuelson can be attributed to an increased risk of knock-in, resulting in a negative payout. Notably, for a given parameter σ , there exists an optimal decay B that maximizes the expected profit, potentially resulting in a significant increase.

5. Conclusions

This paper is devoted to the well-known property of increased futures volatility as they reach maturity, called the Samuelson effect. The vast body of literature, comprising empirical studies regarding the effect, validates that it is supported in a subset of markets. The effect is especially pronounced for energy contracts, with a particularly steep increase in volatility occurring in the last months of the life of the contract.
In our research, we investigated how to parameterize and calibrate the effect for commodity futures, in particular oil, natural gas, and electricity. We chose to model the instantaneous variance and employ exponential decay models. We considered a simpler model with long-term zero decay, called the 1-decay model, and a more general model with non-zero long-term decay, called the 2-decay model. We demonstrated the effectiveness of our methodology on the historical data of WTI, Brent, NG, and electricity.
The main results of our paper are as follows:
  • We developed procedures for the calibration of the Samuelson effect, using the normalized variances (ratios) of returns of nearby contracts. We fit exponential decay models for WTI and Brent, using historical data of 15 years.
  • We generalized the calibration procedures for seasonal commodities, such as natural gas. This was achieved by separating the data into two seasons, winter and summer, and fitting Samuelson for each season.
  • In the more complex case of electricity futures, where seasonality is even more pronounced, we were compelled to use a more refined model to establish the calibration procedure of the Samuelson effect. Our objective was to identify a global decay in volatility and develop a methodology that could be applied to long-term electricity contracts. In light of this, we presupposed that the Samuelson parameters were the same across all the months of the year, while the normalization constant depended upon the month. We employed actual futures data, not nearby futures as for oil and NG. The historical data of the ERCOT North Hub futures indicates that the results are reasonable.
  • We worked out the analytics regarding statistical errors on the normalized ratios to serve as a benchmark for the model performance. The analysis shows very good results, with the error of the fit being well within the statistical error, except during periods that include crises.
  • We provided a rationale for choosing the optimal length of the observation period and the model choice. We established that, at normal times, the 1-decay model is adequate. During crisis times, when the Samuelson effect is strong, a more refined model with two decays should be used.
  • We demonstrated how the Samuelson effect can be used for commodity derivatives. We outlined the evaluation of early expiration options, such as swaptions. Next, we demonstrated how the calibrated model of the instantaneous variance can be used to extrapolate implied volatilities, which is important in the evaluation of PPAs. Furthermore, we discovered an intriguing application of the Samuelson effect to a popular auto-callable equity derivative, the snowball.
The limitation of our research is its exclusive focus on the Samuelson phenomenon and the term structure of volatility. Future studies may focus on developing a model for the entire volatility surface that integrates appropriate decay of volatility levels and coherent behavior of the skew term structure in alignment with empirical evidence. This demands having accurate and reliable information on liquid options regarding commodity futures. A different path for future research may entail an in-depth examination of the crisis period and refining the model to achieve better fit. Additionally, researchers may investigate the impact of geopolitical and climate risks on the Samuelson effect.
In conclusion, in this paper, we showed that the relatively simple and well-known exponential decay models capture the famous Samuelson effect consistently well. We determined the optimal method to calibrate it in practice, ensuring stability, proper model choice, and established goodness-of-fit criteria. The model can easily be calibrated to particular market information and effectively used for path-dependent or early-expiration pricing options, CVA calculations, and hedging decisions of commodity portfolios.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in this study are included in the article. Further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to my students: Ziqi Yuan for her invaluable help, persistence, and dedication, as well as Yuanqiu Tao for his assistance with snowball research. I am very grateful to Alexander Eydeland for useful discussions. I express my gratitude to the anonymous referees for their valuable suggestions.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Statistical Errors

Our objective is to establish the lower bound on the total error and establish a benchmark for model performance. First, we reference the formula for the normalized variance:
V a r S i 2 S 1 2 = V a r R i 2 = σ i 2 σ 1 2 2 · V a r ( W i )
where
V a r ( W i ) = E ( W i 2 ) ( E ( W i ) ) 2 = 1 ( m 2 ) ( m 4 ) 24 ρ i 4 8 ( m + 2 ) ρ i 2 + m ( m + 2 ) m 2 ρ i 2 m 2 2
and m = M 1 , where M is the number of observations. The unknown quantities are correlations ρ i and volatilities σ i .
  • Estimate Correlations
    We use conservative values for the correlations (higher). Calendar correlations follow the growth and decay model suggested in [2]. Since we only need correlations between the prompt contract and all other i-th nearby contracts, we can calculate the correlation between log-returns of nearby contracts in the same observation period [ t a , t b ] and take a higher bound ρ ¯ i
    Specifically,
    ρ ¯ i = e 2 z ¯ 1 e z ¯ + 1
    where z is obtained from the correlation estimate ρ ^ i by the Fisher transform; then, it is increased by the standard deviation 1 N 3 and transformed back by the inverse Fisher transform (A3):
    z = 1 2 ln 1 + ρ ^ i 1 ρ ^ i , z ¯ = z + 1 N 3
  • Search for Lower Bound of Variance Since σ 1 2 and σ i 2 are unknown, we seek to derive the lower bound of variance in order to be conservative. The error on standard deviation estimate is roughly S i 2 * M , where M is the number of observations. The confidence interval of S i (sample volatility) is [ S i S i 2 N , S i + S i 2 N ] . The lower bound of V a r S i 2 S 1 2 is derived as below (a very close result can be obtained by using quantiles of the chi-squared distribution, with confidence level of 70 % ).
    V a r S i 2 S 1 2 1 1 / 2 N 1 + 1 / 2 N 4 R i 4 · V a r ( W i ) L B ( V a r i )
    where V a r ( W i ) is given by (A2) with the conservative value of correlation (A3).
  • Statistical Error We define the aggregated variance of ratios to be statistical error,
    S t a t E r r o r = i = 1 N V a r R i 2 N i = 1 N L B ( V a r i ) N
  • Example. We consider 12-month observation period WTI, with t b = 20 January 2009.
    • Figure A1 illustrates the fitting results of 1-decay model.
      Figure A1. Normalized ratios vs. fitted 1-decay model ratios. The fitted parameters B = 0.5837 and σ = 0.79 . The realized volatility is computed using WTI log-returns calculated in the period 19 December 2008–20 January 2009.
      Figure A1. Normalized ratios vs. fitted 1-decay model ratios. The fitted parameters B = 0.5837 and σ = 0.79 . The realized volatility is computed using WTI log-returns calculated in the period 19 December 2008–20 January 2009.
      Commodities 04 00013 g0a1
    • The mean square error of the fit is E r r o r f i t = 0.0127 .
    • The estimates of correlations ρ ^ i are presented in Figure A2:
      Figure A2. Correlations between the prompt and i-th nearby contract, computed using WTI log-returns calculated in the period 19 December 2008–20 January 2009.
      Figure A2. Correlations between the prompt and i-th nearby contract, computed using WTI log-returns calculated in the period 19 December 2008–20 January 2009.
      Commodities 04 00013 g0a2
    • The calculated lower bound of the statistical error (A5) is S t a t E r r r o r = 0.027581 ; thus, the model fits well within the statistical error. Note that we get practically the same lower bound if, instead of using the realized ratios R i , we use the model ratios Y i with best-fitting parameters.
  • Checking by Simulations We checked the formulas by simulations:
    • Simulate daily prices of log-normal futures with known volatilities and correlations.
    • For each simulation path, calculate the standard deviations of log-returns and the normalized ratios R i . Compute variance of R i across simulations.
    • For each i, compare the variances of the ratios with the theoretical result (A1). They are in good agreement: the average ratio of real vs. model across simulations and contracts is 1.007 .
    • For each i and each simulation path, compute the lower bound (A5) and compare vs. the theoretical error. On average, the lower bound is about 71 % of the model error. Figure A3 provides an example of the histogram of the ratios of the lower bound in each simulation divided by the model error. Only 0.1 % from all simulations provides the error more than the theoretical model error.
      Figure A3. Checking by simulation: 10,000 simulations paths, σ i σ 1 = 0.5918 , ρ i = 0.9 , and n P o i n t s = 274 .
      Figure A3. Checking by simulation: 10,000 simulations paths, σ i σ 1 = 0.5918 , ρ i = 0.9 , and n P o i n t s = 274 .
      Commodities 04 00013 g0a3

Appendix B. Cross-Validation

Cross-validation (CV) is a technique used to obtain a more accurate estimate of out-of-sample accuracy. CV splits observations into two sets: the training set and the testing set. In the Samuelson case, the original dataset is given by volatilities of 60 nearby contracts. Following the standard CV process, we drop 20 % of data of the original dataset and keep the rest.
The volatility of prompt contract plays a crucial role in capturing Samuelson parameter B as it serves as a benchmark to normalize the volatilities of all other contracts. It also contributes the most to the increase in volatility as maturity approaches. For those reasons we choose to keep the return volatility of prompt contract and randomly drop 12 data points from the other 59 contracts. With the 48 data points, we repeat the calibration procedure and compare the fitted parameters, as well as in-sample and out-of-sample model errors obtained with the original dataset. The procedure is as follows:
  • Step 1: Generate 12 random numbers between 2 and 60 from uniform distribution; drop 12 data points from the dataset. This is our testing set.
  • Step 2: Perform the fitting procedure on the rest of data points (training set); record the in-sample error and out-of-sample error.
  • Step 3: Repeat steps 1–3100 times. Record out-of-sample errors and take averages of the 100 out-of-sample errors for all periods.
If the parameters estimated with training set are close to the original parameters, and the out-of-sample errors are reasonable, we can conclude that the model is stable.
In the table below Table A1, we provide statistics of cross-validation procedure for WTI with different observation periods, such as 2, 3…12 months. Specifically, we report the following:
  • The first column marked D B a v lists the average over all observation periods of the differences B a v t r B o r i g , where B a v t r is the average of decay parameter B fitted on 100 randomized training sets; B o r i g is the parameter B fitted on the whole set.
  • Second column D B max provides the maximum of the differences B a v t r B o r i g .
  • In the third column D σ a v and fourth column D σ max , we find similar statistics for the parameter σ .
  • In the fifth column D e r a v , we report the average over all observation periods of the differences between the out-of-sample errors and the in-sample errors; the last column provides the maximum of those differences.
In next Table A2, we report similar results of cross-validation procedure for Brent.
Table A1. WTI cross-validation results.
Table A1. WTI cross-validation results.
D B av D B max D σ av D σ max D er av D er max
2 m0.00100.03850.00030.00810.00210.0284
3 m0.00090.01940.00030.00380.00220.0248
4 m0.00080.01830.00020.00220.00220.0228
6 m0.00080.03400.00020.00270.00230.0159
8 m0.00060.00640.00020.00110.00240.0135
12 m0.00090.01110.00020.00140.00260.0135
Table A2. Brent cross-validation results.
Table A2. Brent cross-validation results.
D B av D B max D σ av D σ max D er av D er max
2 m0.00050.01070.00040.00960.00130.0168
3 m0.00040.00650.00030.00540.00140.0156
4 m0.00040.00400.00030.00280.00140.0134
6 m0.00030.00440.00070.05260.00150.0102
8 m0.00050.00820.00030.01010.00160.0092
12 m0.00030.00210.00030.00550.00170.0079
The results illustrate the stability of the fitted parameters and thus the stability of the model.

References

  1. Samuelson, P. Proof that Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly. Ind. Manag. Rev. 1965, 6, 41–49. [Google Scholar]
  2. Galeeva, R.; Haversang, T. Parameterized Calendar Correlations: Decoding Oil and Beyond. J. Deriv. 2020, 27, 7–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Bouchouev, I. Virtual Barrels: Quantitative Trading in the Oil Market; Springer Texts in Business and Economics; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2023; pp. 247–252. [Google Scholar]
  4. Miller, K. The Relation between Volatility and Maturity in Futures Contracts. Chic. Merc. Exch. 1979, 25–36. [Google Scholar]
  5. Barnhill, T.M.; Jordan, J.; Seale, W. Maturity and refunding effects on Treasury bond futures price variance. J. Financ. Res. 1987, 10, 121–131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Adrangi, B.; Chatrath, A.; Dhanda, K.; Raffiee, K. Chaos in oil prices? Evidence from futures markets. Energy Econ. 2001, 23, 405–425. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Adrangi, B.; Chatrath, A.; Dhanda, K.; Raffiee, K. On-linear dynamics in futures prices: Evidence from Coffee, Sugar and Cocoa Exchange. Appl. Financ. Econ. 2003, 13, 245–256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Andersen, R. Some determinants of the volatility of futures prices. J. Futur. Mark. 1985, 5, 331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Milonas, N. Price Variability and the Maturity Effect in Futures Markets. Futur. Mark. 1986, 3, 443–460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Rutledge, D. A note on the variability of futures prices. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1976, 58, 118–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Galloway, T.; Kolb, R. Futures prices and the maturity effect. J. Futur. Mark. 1996, 16, 809–828. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Liu, W. Revisiting the Samuelson hypothesis on energy futures. Quant. Financ. 2021, 21, 2089–2101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Jaeck, E.; Lautier, D. Volatility in electricity derivative markets: The Samuelson effect revisited. Energy Econ. 2016, 59, 300–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Castello, O.; Resta, M. A machine-learning-based approach for Natural gas Futures Curve Modeling. Energies 2023, 16, 4746. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Grammatikos, T.; Sauders, A. Futures Price Variability: A Test of Maturity and Volume Effects. J. Bus. 1986, 59, 319–330. Available online: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2353022 (accessed on 6 June 2025). [CrossRef]
  16. Park, H.; Sears, R. Estimating stock index futures volatility through the price of their options. J. Futur. Mark. 1985, 5, 123–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Bessembinder, H.; Coughenour, J.; Sequin, P.; Smeller, M. Is There a Term Structure of Futures Volatilities? J. Deriv. 1996, 4, 45–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Brooks, R. Samuelson hypothesis and carry arbitrage. J. Deriv. 2012, 20, 37–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Brooks, R.; Teterin, P. Samuelson hypothesis, arbitrage activity, and futures term premiums. J. Future Mark. 2020, 40, 420–1441. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Nelson, C.; Siegel, A. Parsimonious Modeling of Yield Curves. J. Biseness 1982, 60, 473–489. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Clewlow, L.; Strickland, C. Energy Derivatives: Pricing and Risk Management; Lacima Publications: London, UK, 2020; pp. 91–94. [Google Scholar]
  22. Schwartz, E. The Stochastic Behavior of Commodity Prices: Implications for Valuation and Hedging. J. Financ. 1997, 52, 923–973. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Gibson, R.; Schwartz, E. Stochastic Convenience Yield and the Pricing of Oil Contingent Claims. J. Financ. 1990, 45, 959–976. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Pilipović, D. Energy Risk: Valuing and Managing Energy Derivatives; McGraw-Hill: New York, NY, USA, 1987; pp. 114–115. [Google Scholar]
  25. Trolle, A.; Schwartz, E. Unspanned stochastic volatility and the pricing of commodity derivatives. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2009, 22, 4423–4461. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Crosby, J.; Frau, C. Jumps in commodity prices: New approaches for pricing plain vanilla options. Energy Econ. 2022, 114, 106302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Frau, C.; Fanelli, V. Seasonality in commodity prices: New approaches for pricing plain vanilla options. Ann. Oper. Res. 2023, 336, 1089–1131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Hilliard, J.; Hilliard, J. A jump-diffusion model for pricing and hedging with margined options: An application to Brent crude oil contracts. J. Bank. Financ. 2019, 98, 137–155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Chiarella, C.; Kang, C.; Nikitopoulos, C.S.; Thuy-Duong, T. Humps in the volatility structure of the crude oil futures market: New evidence. Energy Econ. 2013, 40, 989–1000. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Schneider, L.; Tavin, B. From the Samuelson volatility effect to a Samuelson correlation effect: An analysis of crude oil calendar spread options. J. Bank. Financ. 2018, 95, 185–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Özdemir, L.; Vurur, N.S.; Ozen, E.; Świeska, B.; Grima, S. Volatility Modeling of the Impact of Geopolitical Risk on Commodity Markets. Economies 2025, 13, 88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Guo, Y.; Peng, P.; Zhou, L.; Tang, Y. Forecasting volatility in commodity markets with climate risk. Financ. Res. Lett. 2025, 78, 107094. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Swindle, G. Valuation and Risk Management in Energy Markets; Cambridge University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2014; pp. 103–104. [Google Scholar]
  34. Diebold, F.; Li, C. Forecasting the term structure of government bond yields. J. Econ. 2006, 130, 337–364. [Google Scholar]
  35. Li, Y.; Wang, W. The Valuation of Google Snowball Option. Adv. Econ. Bus. Manag. Res. 2022, 211, 329–333. [Google Scholar]
  36. Joarder, A. Moments of the product and ratio of two correlated chi-square variables. Stat. Pap. Open Access 2009, 50, 581–592. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Eydeland, A.; Wolyniec, K. Energy and Power Risk Management; Wiley Finance: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2003; pp. 130–135. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Illustration of concept of Samuelson time.
Figure 1. Illustration of concept of Samuelson time.
Commodities 04 00013 g001
Figure 2. Implied volatility of WTI futures as of November 2018 (source: Bloomberg), and realized volatilities of WTI nearby futures, calculated in 2 months, September and October 2018.
Figure 2. Implied volatility of WTI futures as of November 2018 (source: Bloomberg), and realized volatilities of WTI nearby futures, calculated in 2 months, September and October 2018.
Commodities 04 00013 g002
Figure 3. Contour plot of the ratio Y 12 for 1-decay model.
Figure 3. Contour plot of the ratio Y 12 for 1-decay model.
Commodities 04 00013 g003
Figure 4. US monthly supply and demand data.
Figure 4. US monthly supply and demand data.
Commodities 04 00013 g004
Figure 5. Implied NG volatility in June 2020. Source: Bloomberg data.
Figure 5. Implied NG volatility in June 2020. Source: Bloomberg data.
Commodities 04 00013 g005
Figure 6. This graph illustrates the actual WTI volatility compared to the fitted volatility generated from the 1-decay model. The realized volatility has been calculated using WTI log-returns from 21 February 2019 to 20 February 2020.
Figure 6. This graph illustrates the actual WTI volatility compared to the fitted volatility generated from the 1-decay model. The realized volatility has been calculated using WTI log-returns from 21 February 2019 to 20 February 2020.
Commodities 04 00013 g006
Figure 7. The realized NG volatility and the fitted 1-decay model.
Figure 7. The realized NG volatility and the fitted 1-decay model.
Commodities 04 00013 g007
Figure 8. Calculated seasonal ratios vs. model ratios, B = 1.7 and σ = 0.15 .
Figure 8. Calculated seasonal ratios vs. model ratios, B = 1.7 and σ = 0.15 .
Commodities 04 00013 g008
Figure 9. Calculated seasonal ratios vs. model ratios, B = 0.766 and σ = 0.593 .
Figure 9. Calculated seasonal ratios vs. model ratios, B = 0.766 and σ = 0.593 .
Commodities 04 00013 g009
Figure 10. The graph illustrates the actual WTI instantaneous volatility compared to the fitted volatility calculated using both the 1-decay and 2-decay models. The realized volatility is calculated using WTI log-returns from the period of 21 November 2008 to 20 November 2009.
Figure 10. The graph illustrates the actual WTI instantaneous volatility compared to the fitted volatility calculated using both the 1-decay and 2-decay models. The realized volatility is calculated using WTI log-returns from the period of 21 November 2008 to 20 November 2009.
Commodities 04 00013 g010
Figure 11. ATM peak monthly and daily volatilities as of January 5 2023, ERCOT North, published by Argus Media.
Figure 11. ATM peak monthly and daily volatilities as of January 5 2023, ERCOT North, published by Argus Media.
Commodities 04 00013 g011
Figure 12. Comparison of histograms by historical simulation vs. Monte Carlo.
Figure 12. Comparison of histograms by historical simulation vs. Monte Carlo.
Commodities 04 00013 g012
Figure 13. The normalized index CSI 500 price history, September 2022–September 2023, with the best snowball payoff.
Figure 13. The normalized index CSI 500 price history, September 2022–September 2023, with the best snowball payoff.
Commodities 04 00013 g013
Figure 14. The normalized index CSI 500 price history, May 2015–May 2016, with the worst snowball payoff.
Figure 14. The normalized index CSI 500 price history, May 2015–May 2016, with the worst snowball payoff.
Commodities 04 00013 g014
Figure 15. The expected snowball payoff vs. volatility of the underlying.
Figure 15. The expected snowball payoff vs. volatility of the underlying.
Commodities 04 00013 g015
Figure 16. The expected snowball payoff for different decay values B, σ = 0.1 , and T = 1 .
Figure 16. The expected snowball payoff for different decay values B, σ = 0.1 , and T = 1 .
Commodities 04 00013 g016
Table 1. Descriptive statistics of WTI, Brent, and natural gas return series.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics of WTI, Brent, and natural gas return series.
SeriesCountMeanStd. Dev.MedianMinimumMaximumSkewnessKurtosis
Dataset 1: WTI (Data Period: 21 April 2006–9 June 2021)
WTI13813 0.0000 0.0246 0.0004 0.3008 0.2239 0.0854 21.1870
WTI23813 0.0002 0.0229 0.0006 0.3858 0.2182 1.3883 32.2534
WTI33813 0.0001 0.0213 0.0006 0.2461 0.2002 0.5281 13.6756
WTI43813 0.0000 0.0204 0.0007 0.2209 0.1858 0.4155 10.5347
Dataset 2: Brent (Data Period: 16 June 2006–9 June 2021)
Brent13869 0.0001 0.0211 0.0005 0.2798 0.1908 0.4527 14.8710
Brent23869 0.0000 0.0202 0.0006 0.2338 0.1352 0.3946 9.6590
Brent33869 0.0000 0.0195 0.0006 0.2054 0.1278 0.3646 7.6978
Brent43869 0.0000 0.0189 0.0006 0.1865 0.1240 0.3429 6.7611
Dataset 3: Natural Gas (Data Period: 29 June 2006–9 June 2021)
NG13772 0.0011 0.0266 0.0009 0.1805 0.1651 0.1735 2.6956
NG23772 0.0012 0.0238 0.0011 0.1918 0.1664 0.1204 3.0882
NG33772 0.0010 0.0216 0.0008 0.2021 0.1713 0.0427 4.3136
NG43772 0.0008 0.0199 0.0006 0.2180 0.1863 0.0078 7.2988
Table 2. Examples of WTI calibration results.
Table 2. Examples of WTI calibration results.
t a t b B σ RMSE
12/21/1112/19/120.29370.56780.0014
11/19/1211/20/130.46110.49530.0003
10/23/1310/21/140.66270.46630.0004
9/23/149/22/150.48030.48560.0006
8/21/158/22/160.46240.57730.0063
7/21/167/20/170.39590.59660.0007
6/21/176/20/180.48640.69640.0008
5/23/185/21/190.29800.67750.0008
4/23/194/21/200.90930.30280.0252
02/21/1902/20/200.32450.44580.0018
Table 3. Examples of Brent calibration results utilizing the 1-decay model.
Table 3. Examples of Brent calibration results utilizing the 1-decay model.
t a t b B σ RMSE
10/17/1210/16/130.28090.41590.0013
9/16/139/15/140.53060.49170.0004
8/15/148/14/150.38210.42670.0026
8/17/157/29/160.34980.55200.0012
7/1/166/30/170.33670.54950.00175
6/1/175/31/180.36290.68530.0025
5/1/184/30/190.23250.57150.0006
4/1/193/31/200.47890.38130.005
Table 4. Natural gas calibration results: “W” denotes winter, whereas “S” signifies summer.
Table 4. Natural gas calibration results: “W” denotes winter, whereas “S” signifies summer.
t b B W σ WB S σ SRMSE
11 / 24 / 08 0.721 0.434 0.660 0.487 0.0068
12 / 29 / 09 0.837 0.318 0.670 0.349 0.0118
12 / 28 / 10 0.913 0.265 0.865 0.294 0.0118
12 / 28 / 11 0.675 0.371 0.556 0.406 0.0071
11 / 28 / 12 0.647 0.375 0.526 0.416 0.006
11 / 26 / 13 0.486 0.327 0.447 0.368 0.0038
5 / 29 / 18 1.049 0.283 0.979 0.360 0.0038
12 / 27 / 19 1.586 0.137 1.581 0.181 0.0083
4 / 28 / 20 2.515 0.085 1.536 0.179 0.0141
Table 5. Calibrated Samuelson parameters and ERCOT electricity futures.
Table 5. Calibrated Samuelson parameters and ERCOT electricity futures.
DateB σ
1/1/18 0.638 0.427
1/1/19 0.358 0.638
1/1/20 3.088 0.24
1/1/21 0.1702 0.15
1/1/22 1.522 0.146
1/1/23 1.548 0.325
1/1/24 1.218 0.493
Table 6. WTI calibration results: 1 exponential decay model vs. 2 exponential decay model; “1-D” denotes 1-decay model, whereas “2-D” stands for 2-decay model.
Table 6. WTI calibration results: 1 exponential decay model vs. 2 exponential decay model; “1-D” denotes 1-decay model, whereas “2-D” stands for 2-decay model.
t a t b B σ bRMSE
2-D 11 / 2008 11 / 2009 1.51 0.71 0.07 0.0098
1-D 11 / 2008 11 / 2009 0.92 0.52 0 0.018
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Galeeva, R. In Pursuit of Samuelson for Commodity Futures: How to Parameterize and Calibrate the Term Structure of Volatilities. Commodities 2025, 4, 13. https://doi.org/10.3390/commodities4030013

AMA Style

Galeeva R. In Pursuit of Samuelson for Commodity Futures: How to Parameterize and Calibrate the Term Structure of Volatilities. Commodities. 2025; 4(3):13. https://doi.org/10.3390/commodities4030013

Chicago/Turabian Style

Galeeva, Roza. 2025. "In Pursuit of Samuelson for Commodity Futures: How to Parameterize and Calibrate the Term Structure of Volatilities" Commodities 4, no. 3: 13. https://doi.org/10.3390/commodities4030013

APA Style

Galeeva, R. (2025). In Pursuit of Samuelson for Commodity Futures: How to Parameterize and Calibrate the Term Structure of Volatilities. Commodities, 4(3), 13. https://doi.org/10.3390/commodities4030013

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop