3.1. New Manner of Fulfilling the Duty to Advise: Analysis, Results, and Discussion
To begin, one should consider how the application of new technologies—especially those used for personalizing the content presented to a potential client—may affect the liability of the professional party (on how the principle of “know your customer” affects the general conduct of the insurance business, see
Tereszkiewicz 2013b, p. 240;
Cousy 2017, pp. 45–48). It should be underscored that these mechanisms can be used by different classes of operators in the insurance distribution chain, including insurance agents, brokers, and insurers (
Cappiello 2018, p. 56). As a result, comparable challenges appear regardless of who takes part in the process of insurance distribution and sale. It is submitted that there is a strong case in favor of imposing on business parties a robust duty to advise a prospective client. Specifically, this means both strengthening the insurance broker’s duty to advise the client, and—provided that it is the insurer that uses the personalization technique—extending this duty to insurers as well.
The big data technology and AI-based mechanisms allow one to reduce the exploration effort necessary for the insurance distributor to get to know the customer (on “know your customer” duties see
Tereszkiewicz 2015, pp. 297–99). Big data enables the extracting and processing of an unprecedented amount of data on a (potential) client with such accuracy that in the end, the person using these tools may know more about the consumer than consumers themselves (
Tereszkiewicz 2020, p. 131). This phenomenon is especially easy to notice if the common misperceptions about oneself are considered. A powerful example comes from research on cognitive biases and the manner in which these may be used during the process of price personalization (
Bar-Gill 2019, pp. 217–54). The following illustration may be useful. Adam who is about to purchase a gym pass is likely to use the pass two to three times a month. However, he estimates the frequency of his gym visits too optimistically; he is convinced that he will go at least twice a week. As a result, his preference-based willingness to pay is significantly lower than his misperception-based willingness to pay, and the knowledge about this difference can be easily abused by an entrepreneur when setting the price of a gym pass. Another example is the IKEA effect—own amateurish creations tend to be considered having similar value to the creations of professionals by the consumers who were involved in their creation—if the consumer is given the opportunity to customize the product, then they are likely to value it more (e.g., see Share a Coke’ campaign).
The EU lawmaker appears to move consistently toward imposing on financial providers a broad duty to advise their clients (
Tereszkiewicz 2020, p. 142). In the field of EU insurance law, significant advances toward protecting consumers against the most common risks of misselling of insurance products were made by Directive 2002/92/EC on insurance mediation (hereafter: IMD). Significantly, Article 12 (3) of the IMD introduced into EU insurance law as the duty of an insurance intermediary the necessity to explore the potential policyholder’s needs (
Moloney 2010, p. 254, described it as “a quasi-know-your-client requirement”). The above-mentioned IMD provision imposed on an insurance intermediary a duty, on the one hand, to specify the demands and the needs of a prospective policyholder with a view to a specific contract, and, on the other hand, to specify the underlying reasons for any advice the intermediary gives to a customer. The language of Article 12 (3) IMD was very broad and did not provide detailed guidance on the precise extent of the intermediary’s duty. Yet, this allowed national lawmakers (i.e., legislators, courts, and oversight bodies) to “modulate details regarding the intermediary’s duties according to the complexity of the insurance contract proposed” to the consumer (cf. Article 12 (3) IMD). Enacted after the financial crisis of 2008, IDD considerably extended the level of protection offered by IMD (
De Maesschalck 2017;
Marano 2019). In what is a significant novelty in EU insurance law (
Cousy 2017, p. 48), insurance distributors have become subject to an overarching general duty to act honestly, fairly, and professionally in accordance with the best interests of their customers. This duty, set forth in Article 17 (1) IDD, mirrors the equivalent duty introduced first in MiFID I (Directive 2004/39/EC of 21 April 2004 on markets in financial instruments, referred to as MiFID I, meanwhile repealed by Directive 2014/65/EU of 15 May 2014 on markets in financial instruments, referred to as MiFID II). It lays down a general standard of conduct for insurance distributors that should guide the interpretation of more specific duties provided by the IDD. In what is a significant extension of the scope of consumer protection, the IDD applies to certain activities conducted through price comparison websites (
Marano 2019). Specifically, as Article 2(1) provides, the IDD applies to persons whose activity consists of the provision of information on one or more contracts of insurance in response to criteria selected by the customer, whether via a website or other media, or the provision of a ranking of insurance products or a discount on the price of an insurance contract when the customer is able to directly or indirectly conclude an insurance contract at the end of the process. While the IDD lays down no specific rules applicable only to comparison websites, its general principles and standards deal with most of the issues arising out of the comparison websites’ status as insurance intermediaries (
Marano 2019, p. 304). In our view, this is a significant improvement of the IMD standard, which will be subject to further regulatory developments in the future. In practice, most comparison websites use hyperlinks that transfer the insurance client to websites deployed by different distributors. As a result of using comparison websites, clients searching for insurance products may easily end up being subject to personalization by insurance distributors.
While it is arguable that IDD does not explicitly impose on insurers a duty to advise their clients, it does extend precontractual individualized duties of exploration to all insurance product distributors: Under Article 20 Sec. 1 IDD, insurance distributors are obligated to “specify demands and needs of a customer based on information obtained from them, and shall provide that customer with objective information about the insurance product in a comprehensible form to allow that customer to make an informed decision” (about whether they want to purchase an insurance product from this operator). This provision should be read in the light of Recital 44 IDD, which requires that any insurance product proposed to the customer always be consistent with the customer’s demands and needs.
What is more, insurance products are becoming more volatile nowadays, making it more difficult for a consumer to grasp the difference between the different products available from various providers, let alone to understand their essence and risks (
Tereszkiewicz 2013b, p. 237). As a result, the information and skill asymmetry between an individual client and an insurance distributor as to the possibility of assessing which product is the most suitable from the perspective of this client has increased significantly more than it had in the age of conventional (nondigital) insurance offering. Not only has the consumer virtually no capability to assess the adequacy of insurance products correctly in the light of their needs, but also the insurance distributor tends to be better informed about the characteristics of a potential client than the client themselves. This makes models in which it is the primary duty of the client (prospective policyholder) to obtain information on their own insurance needs (e.g., the German model, about which see
Cousy 2012a;
Tereszkiewicz 2013a), utterly unsuited for the new reality of digital insurance distribution.
With respect to digital insurance distribution, we submit that the consumer’s consent to profiling by an insurance distributor ought to be considered a request for advice by this insurance distributor. This, in certain national laws of insurance (e.g., Germany, Poland, the UK), could suffice to trigger an obligation on the part of the broker/insurer to explore the client’s insurance needs. Further, one should carefully analyze the scope of the client’s consent in this regard; the client might be consenting to the further processing of their personal data and by this “paying” with their personal data for the additional service of recommending to them the contract that is most appropriate for their needs and situation (
Elvy 2017, part II).
Finally, it needs to be emphasized that the personalization of content in the online environment has been presented as a tool for increasing trust and changing the relationship between the entrepreneur and the consumer (
Meyers 2018, p. 169, on the focus on assisting a policyholder by means of a driving skills development program;
Południak-Gierz 2020a). For the insurance sector, this means that technologically empowered distributors of insurance (including the underwriters themselves) may successfully strive to change the way they are perceived on the market so that they make good on their promise of becoming “trusted advisors helping customers anticipate, navigate and eliminate the unique risks they face in a changing world.” (so claimed by providers of personalizing mechanisms,
https://earnix.com/wp-content/uploads/2019/11/The-Age-of-Insurance-Personalization-1.pdf (accessed on 27 April 2021 P. 5; in this vein,
Tereszkiewicz 2020, p. 131).
When a personalizing tool selects or personalizes the product for the consumer, a question arises as to whether performing this functionality as such should be regarded as an act of providing advice regarding an insurance product under Art. 2 Sec. 1 Point 15 IDD. As soon as an insurance distributor starts offering personalized products, that is, products adjusted to the needs and the situation of a customer (“tailor-made” products), and not just grossly matching their profile, this conduct should be considered giving advice. The major reason in support of this view is that when an insurance distributor undertakes the personalization of this content, the balance of expectations and corresponding duties between the parties shifts. The insurance distributor has a much broader knowledge about both the products they offer and the features of a client (including a client’s biases); the insurance distributor is capable of selecting the product that fully meets the needs of that client. It is not only the information asymmetry between the parties that deepens. At the same time, the vulnerability of the client increases because an additional reason for their possible lack of critical scrutiny (mental alertness) appears, namely, the trust in the profiler (
Południak-Gierz 2020a). If a consumer consents to the processing of their personal data, they do it for a well-defined purpose, which is to obtain an offer indeed tailored to their needs and situation. Given the information asymmetry between the parties, the consumer voluntarily agrees to disclose a significant amount of data, which implies that the other party should reciprocate the trust placed in it and act accordingly.
In conclusion, the personalization process should be considered “the provision of personal recommendation” and thus should be subject to the requirements set forth by the IDD. This means that the customer should be informed whether “advice is provided on the basis of a fair and personal analysis,” i.e., whether the advice is provided on the basis of an analysis of a sufficiently large number of insurance contracts available on the market, and in accordance with professional criteria (cf. Recital 47, Art. 19, Sec. 1, letter c; Art. 20, Sec. 3 IDD). The technological system deployed by the insurer distributor should process sufficient personal data so as to identify customers’ demands and needs (Recital 44, Art. 20, Sec. 1 IDD). Furthermore, the information on the personalization process and its assumptions should be provided to the consumer, i.e., explaining why the price diverges from the standard or why the coverage of insurance was changed (Recital 45, Art. 20, Sec. 1 sentence 3 IDD). Finally, the personalizing program deployed by the insurance distributor should be sufficiently smart to appropriately classify the products in its database as to their functionality and the target group so that it correctly matches the product to the needs and situation of a potential customer (Recital 55 IDD).
The position on the insurance distributor’s duties toward clients that we advocate in this paper has significant ramifications for the conduct of insurance business in the digital environment.
Assuming that all insurance distributors are obligated to advise their prospective clients to the extent defined above, they should design their digital infrastructure in a manner that enables the fulfillment of that obligation. This means that once they start offering and selling products online, they should design their websites in such a manner that a consumer is advised on the product they aim to purchase in accordance with the requirements set forth by IDD. From a technical perspective, an insurance distributor can, in principle, fulfill this requirement in three manners. First, the insurance distributor can undertake measures to profile every consumer that accesses their website. As soon as a consumer decides to explore offers available to them or to launch the personalization of the insurance tool available on that website, the insurance distributor acquires all the necessary data to appropriately adjust the offer or to warn the potential client that the selected option is inappropriate or suboptimal from the perspective of their interests. However, the main difficulty of the model would be that the data obtained in such a manner would rarely suffice for the adequate personalization of a client. Second, the insurance distributor may use lengthy online forms that the consumer would need to fill out in order to obtain access to a personalized offer. Third, an insurance distributor may already collaborate with third-party operators that collect and store data, including data that may be crucial for the purpose of personalizing insurance offers. In this model, the insurance distributors may limit themselves to requesting the consumers to consent that their data be processed also for the purpose of an insurance offer made by an indicated third-party operator. If the law imposed on all insurance distributors a duty to advise their clients, those distributors would, in consequence, have to personalize their offers as well.
Additionally, one should also consider a different legal position, under which insurance distributors have to advise their clients only under narrowly defined circumstances (e.g., only with respect to certain insurance products or only in cases in which certain financial risks may materialize). Such a legal position would result in a need for an inquiry into when the use of new technologies by insurance distributors may be considered offering advice to clients. The typical and the strongest case is the personalization of an offer of an insurance product. Once the insurance distributor starts personalizing the content of offers of insurance products, they should be considered to be giving advice to prospective policyholders. Thus, provisions on advising on insurance products specified in IDD should become applicable. This invites the conclusion that whenever an insurance distributor uses personalization mechanisms that enable them to tailor an offer of insurance product to a particular client’s needs, they then assume a duty to advise their client on the product’s suitability.
3.2. Allocation of Risks Resulting from the Application of Personalizing Tools: Analysis, Results, and a Discussion of Typical Scenarios
Personalization mechanisms within the insurance sector allow businesses to offer consumers tailored recommendations based on one’s interests, lifestyle, and behavior, which, in principle, should on the one hand maximize their sales and profits, and on the other, incite client’s trust. From the consumer’s perspective, personalization means effortless access to better-adjusted content (including offers corresponding with their needs) as well as premiums and discounts (e.g., behavior-based pricing). Clearly, despite its benefits for insurers and consumers, the application of personalizing tools by insurers may lead to undesired outcomes. From the consumer’s perspective, these are typically inadequate insurance coverage (certain risks not covered), double insurance of the same risk, or overpriced insurance protection (
Loacker 2015, p. 28). The frequency of these outcomes will be increased due to consumers’ lack of expertise in using the technological tools deployed by insurance distributors. Our study thus needs to address the question of how risks resulting from the use of personalizing tools should be allocated.
As a matter of principle, it could be argued that regardless of the nature and technical details of the personalization tools applied by the professional party, the negative consequences resulting from failure to fulfill the duty to specify the demand and needs of customers and underlying reasons for any advice on a particular insurance product should burden this particular insurance distributor who has used a personalizing tool in their interaction with the consumer. We draw upon the underlying principle of IDD: “According to the approach toward client protection that underlies the IDD, consumers should benefit from the same level of protection despite the differences between distribution channels.” (
Cappiello 2018, p. 24;
Tereszkiewicz 2020, p. 140; cf. Recitals 6 and 8 IDD). It follows that it should not matter whether the insurance contract was concluded via a third-party website or whether the insurance was distributed by an agent, broker, ”bancassurance” operator, travel agent, car rental company, or directly by the underwriting insurance undertaking itself (the list of entities qualified as insurance distributors is included in Recital 5 IDD.) Should this principle be interpreted to mean that regardless of who is profiling the client, errors at the personalization stage, including those made during adjusting an insurance product to the individual needs of the client, should have the same effects? Before we offer a conclusive answer to these questions, a brief overview of typical classes of reasons for mispersonalization should be provided.
3.2.1. Defectiveness of the Personalizing Mechanism Provided by Another Professional Entity
The improper result of the personalization of an insurance product may be caused by the fact that the mechanism used for this process is defective. Typically, it may simply mismatch the product as the factors taken into account during the process are not correctly balanced, important factors are neglected, or those irrelevant are included in an algorithm that distorts the personalization outcome (e.g., presumptions are made based on single interactions or purchases). Another possibility is that the segmentation is not sufficiently granular, and consequently, offers sent to a customer only roughly match their profile (
Sitecore and Vanson Bourne study 2017, for an overview see:
https://www.sitecore.com/company/news-events/press-releases/2017/10/new-study-reveals-brands-fail-to-use-customer-data-to-deliver-personalized-digital-experiences (accessed on 27 April 2021);
Gartner Research 2018). The defectiveness of the personalizing tool may also be associated with the fact that the mechanism sends either too many or too personalized messages, which results in the consumer being discouraged from contracting as the distributor’s activities are viewed as an invasion of privacy. These instances, however, do not lead to the mispersonalization of the contract and thus shall not be discussed further.
When a personalizing tool is developed by the entity using it, determining the person liable for possible mispersonalization appears straightforward. However, the technology used in the personalization process is often developed and provided to the insurance distributor by a third-party operator (
Joint Committee Discussion Paper 2016, p. 12). In these scenarios, the entity providing the personalizing system may be liable for the defectiveness of that mechanism and the damage that resulted from its improper functioning. The allocation of liability will depend on the provisions governing liability for improper performance of a contract in a given case; the content of a contract concluded between these entities will constitute an important factor in determining the scope of the liability. In this regard, national rules of EU Member States implementing Directive 2019/770 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 20 May 2019 on certain aspects concerning contracts for the supply of digital content and digital services are relevant. Member States are free to broaden the scope of the application of these provisions so that this Directive covers non-consumer contracts (Recital 16), dual-purpose contracts (Recital 22), and platform providers who are not direct contractual partners of the consumer (Recital 23) (
Carvalho 2019, p. 195).
Requirements for liability of a third-party operator that provided the personalizing tools will be of importance for the insurance distributor since the latter carries the risk of the tool’s malfunction in relation to their clients. They are of no significance for the legal situation of the client who entered into an insurance contract following the use of a personalizing tool. This is because the consumer will usually have a direct claim against the insurance distributor. Thus, from the consumer’s perspective, it does not matter which entity in the insurance distribution chain (i.e., insurer, agent, or broker) uses the personalization mechanism or who supplies the mechanism with the use of which the personalization is carried out (it could be an IT company that provides the toolset to the insurer or an insurer who provides it to the agent or broker). The fact that the mispersonalization was caused by a defect of the personalizing mechanism supplied by a third-party operator to the insurance distributor will be relevant for the legal relationship between these two entities.
3.2.2. Incorrect Configuration of Personalization Mechanisms
A possible second category of cases is that the personalization tool applied by the insurer is not defective as such, but its configuration process was disturbed or improperly performed. As in the previous category, from the consumer’s perspective, these circumstances should be regarded as irrelevant, unless it is the consumer themselves that customizes the product with the use of the program provided by the insurance distributor (“design-your-own insurance model,” see, e.g.,
https://sidecarhealth.com/personalized (accessed on 27 April 2021);
https://www.hcf.com.au/insurance/health/get-a-quote/customise-cover (accessed on 27 April 2021)).
If that was the case, then the question is whether the consumer should bear the negative consequences of the fact that they, acting by themselves, tailored the insurance product in a manner that does not meet their actual needs and situation. In principle, it could be argued that the individual should not be restricted in exercising their own autonomy in this regard and should not be prevented from making suboptimal contractual decisions or taking disproportionate risks as long as their choice in this regard is actually free and autonomous (
Południak-Gierz 2020b, p. 79).
However, in the case of insurance products, consumers rarely act having sufficient knowledge both of the risks and content of a given insurance product, which means that the risks of miscustomizing insurance policies are real. Further, depending on the specific risk that the consumer wants to have covered by an insurance product, the consequences of making an error in the customization process may be detrimental for that consumer.
Given the above considerations, there is a strong case for regulating the customization of certain types of insurance policies. In particular, those policies aimed at covering risks, the materialization of which could lead to especially adverse effects for policyholders (e.g., liability insurance). This would prevent insurance operators from exploiting particular weaknesses (behavioral biases) of consumers (their classes) and tricking them into purchasing certain products while at the same time avoiding providing advice correlated with the personalization of the content. Yet, the design of such a regulatory framework should not overly impede innovation by indirectly preventing the emergence of new products or new models of product distribution in the insurance sector. As a middle way, product distributors could be obligated to provide personalized warning mechanisms. In order to impede the easy circumvention of that duty, the customization of the product should be allowed only for clients who are already profiled, since only then would the ex post verification of the adequacy of their choice and personalization of the warning system be possible.
3.2.3. Inadequate or Insufficient Data
With respect to data processed by the personalizing tool, several factors may hinder adequate personalization. In order to assure an adequate outcome of the personalization process, data of two types are needed: “(1) the relevant attributes of the products available to the consumer, which must include an adequate representation of the variety of potentially suitable products available in the market to provide meaningful choice; and (2) the relevant attributes of the consumers for whom the algorithm is ranking or matching the products” (
Baker and Dellaert 2018, p. 737). The main issues related to these two categories are the accessibility and quality of these data.
As for the first category of data, access to specific and up-to-date information on particular insurance products might be limited either due to technological reasons (e.g., a program not compatible with the database or unable to extract data from it in an adequate form, or the information necessary might not be saved in the accessible database) or because of the business or legal reasons (the insurer might be reluctant to make certain data available to the external robo-advisors) (
Baker and Dellaert 2018, pp. 737–38).
As for the second data category, in principle, a customer as an insurance applicant is obligated to inform the insurance distributor about risk-relevant circumstances (
Borselli 2020, p. 115). However, this obligation was developed in times when the insurance distributor had, as a rule, little knowledge of the insurance applicant and, to great extent, depended on the data provided by the latter (
Cousy 2012a;
Borselli 2020, p. 131). Technological evolution, which has enabled insurers to elicit material information successfully and to investigate risk-relevant factors, coupled with consumer law development, has brought about a new approach toward the disclosure by a policyholder.
Most recently, the law, as exemplified by new statutes in Germany and the UK, has shifted the emphasis from the insurance applicant’s duty to disclose risk-relevant factors toward the insurer’s obligation to collect contract-relevant information from the insurance applicant (
Cousy 2012b;
Tereszkiewicz 2013a;
Merkin and Gurses 2015;
Hertzell 2017).
Furthermore, the business model of insurance distributors underwent a significant evolution. Rather than requesting the insurance applicant for specific information, insurance distributors seek to obtain permission to gather and process their personal data. A question immediately arises as to what specific challenges this business model represents. Most importantly, one should ask whether it should be relevant for the scope of the liability of an insurance distributor for the mispersonalization of an insurance contract. The insurance law provisions do not answer this question in a direct manner. It is submitted that once the insurance applicant consents to data processing by the insurance distributor and the profiling process is launched, the active participation in the data provision of the insurance applicant ends. It can be argued that by giving consent, the applicant already fulfills their duty to disclose risk-relevant circumstances to the other party (
Borselli 2020, pp. 115, 131;
Christofilou and Chatzara 2020, p. 60); in practice, the automatization of data processing and personalization frequently leave no room for individual disclosures. In addition, insurance distributors have the resources and toolset necessary to extract and analyze the necessary information on the insurance applicant. The big-data-based mechanisms allow a business to deduce the features or circumstances of the person that the latter is unaware of. Thus, if the conclusions drawn by a smart personalization mechanism contradict the information given directly by the insurance applicant, they will be prioritized as more credible over the communication sent by the insurance applicant themselves. As a result, once an insurance applicant agrees to data processing for the purpose of the personalization of an insurance contract and the personalization mechanisms are launched, the information individually and actively provided by the insurance applicant becomes largely irrelevant. As a result, the case for requiring the insurance applicant to additionally inform the insurance distributor about the risk-relevant circumstances becomes much weaker, in particular when the insurance distributor does not actively ask any further questions related to risk-relevant factors.
The automatization of the stage of data collection poses numerous challenges. The mispersonalization may be caused by the fact that the data is insufficient for achieving the personalization purpose. In this regard, the main difficulty is setting the minimum threshold regarding when the data on the person becomes credible and sufficiently depicts individual traits, tendencies, or needs (
Południak-Gierz 2017, pp. 30, 32). Further, there is a need for constant updates of data, so that this does not become obsolete (
Sitecore and Vanson Bourne study 2017). This is particularly relevant when data is bought or downloaded ex post, e.g., from applications used for a different purpose. Additionally, the information thus obtained might be inadequate for the purpose of its processing (e.g., the content of the data might be altered intentionally or unintentionally by the individual—a famous example here is the increase in purchases of carbon-monoxide detectors when the public noticed that their purchase was considered a factor reflecting the trustworthiness of a debtor by some insurance companies (
Duhigg 2009), or predetermined by the design of the system from which it is obtained). Given our view that in the case of insurance offers made following the use of personalization tools by an insurance distributor, the insurance applicant’s duty to disclose may be fulfilled just by consenting to the profiling as long as no further questions are addressed to them, then all the above risks should in principle be allocated to the insurance distributor using the personalization tool.
In sum, though the inadequacy of the data fed to the personalization system may be caused by different entities, including the data subject themselves (i.e., the client buying insurance), it is the personalizing insurance distributor who will typically be liable for the consequences of data inadequacy.
3.2.4. Aim of the Personalization
Finally, the mispersonalization might result from the fact that the aim of the personalization might be set in a manner that diverges from the principle of contractual fairness (loyalty). However, it should be noted that the said disloyalty of an insurance distributor may take different forms (
Baker and Dellaert 2019, pp. 16–17). Typically, the price can be set not in accordance with the consumer’s situation and needs, but their misperceptions as to the latter (the price that is offered is the maximum that could be accepted by that consumer, regardless of what the regular price of such an insurance product is). Similarly, determining the consumers’ willingness to pay may be based on the misperceptions of that person (
Bar-Gill 2019, p. 246; in the context of insurance:
Baker and Dellaert 2018, p. 736). Additionally, the offered product may be ill suited from the perspective of the interests of the consumer but profitable from the perspective of the product distributor. This will typically qualify as misselling of insurance products.
Another example is restricting the consumer’s access to some offers by “surveying a strategic subset of options that are most profitable for the firm” (
Baker and Dellaert 2019, p. 16). In addition, the behavioral biases of the consumer might be exploited in different manners. Certain features of the offered product (i.e., the manner of its presentation, context, etc.) might suggest that the product is adequate for the needs of a particular consumer. For example, the hyperlink with travel insurance offer having an exclusion for winter sports can be presented on the website of a travel agency offering ski trips (
Tereszkiewicz 2013b, p. 236), or the insurance personalization tool may be correlated with the projections of future scenarios that underline certain factors (e.g., a risk that is not particularly probable will be presented as such). Finally, behavioral strategies, including framing or selective highlighting (on the power of architecture:
Baker and Dellaert 2018, pp. 739–40), might be used to steer the consumer to the option that may indeed be relatively well adjusted to their needs but, at the same time, more profitable for the personalizing entity than the equivalent alternative (
Baker and Dellaert 2019, p. 16).
In principle, the admissibility of such configurations of personalization tools could be reviewed on a case-by-case basis under the legal framework dealing with unfair business-to-consumer commercial practices (Directive 2005/29/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council on unfair commercial practices, referred to as UCPD). However, it is uncertain whether UCPD can be effective when it comes to controlling personalization as a market practice (
Południak-Gierz 2019, pp. 170–73). A major challenge in this regard results from the requirements for applying the EU Unfair Commercial Practices framework to the commercial practice concerned: the law requires the examining of whether a commercial practice at hand “materially distorts or is likely to materially distort the economic behaviour with regard to the product of the average consumer whom it reaches or to whom it is addressed” (Article 5 Sec. 2b UCPD). This means that the UCPD legal framework is grounded in the idea of protecting “an average consumer,” thus a typical member of a class, a separate question being how this notion is defined (empirically or normatively) and by whom (regulators ex ante or courts ex post,
Golecki and Tereszkiewicz 2019, pp. 97–99, see also the evolution of CJEU case law on the concept of “an average consumer,” especially: Case C-120/78 Cassis de Dijon 1979; Case C-382/87 Buet 1989; Case 362/88 GB-INNO-BM 1990; Case C-126/91 Yves Rocher 1993; Case C-373/90 Nissan 1992; Case C-315/92 Clinique 1994; Case C-470/93 Mars 1995; Case C-313/94 Graffione 1996; Case C-210/96 Gut Springenheide 1998). By nature, the notion of an average consumer is formulated without reference to personal characteristics that would distinguish one consumer from another.
The idea of the personalization of consumer products, including insurance policies, does not fit easily with this legal approach. The essence of personalization means that the content is highly persuasive for a selected individual only rather than a class of individuals or a typical average individual. A further difficulty lies in the fact that under the unfair commercial practices framework it is the isolated commercial practice of a provider that is subject to control. The power and appeal of personalization frequently lie in the coordination between different practices applied by a provider, neither of which, when assessed separately, materially distorts the consumer’s behavior, but each of these practices is designed to correlate with other factors. Thus, it is the whole bundle that materially distorts the market behavior of the consumer. Finally, there is a procedural difficulty. Proving that a commercial practice strongly limited the consumer’s ability to make an informed choice is difficult since it requires demonstrating that if the personalization was not unfair, the consumer would have not concluded the contract in question. In this regard, it would be crucial to draw a line between an effective and sophisticated market practice that is still legitimate and a personalization mechanism, the use of which amounts to an unfair market practice due to its impact on the consumer decision-making process (
Południak-Gierz 2019, pp. 170–73).
Finally, it should be noted that some of the negative effects related to the mispersonalization at the time of the contract making may be reduced by the application of the European Union Unfair Contract Terms Directive (Directive 93/13/EEC of 5 April 1993 on unfair terms in consumer contracts, referred to as UCTD). This can be illustrated by the following hypothetical: Certain abusive (“unfair”) contract terms are added only to those contracts that are concluded with individuals who, due to their characteristics or situation, are highly unlikely to notice such terms or to challenge them, whether in or out of courts. However, for the UCTD regime to apply, personalized agreements must be recognized as “not being individually negotiated,” that is, imposed by the trader on the consumer (
Południak-Gierz 2019, pp. 164–70).