1. Introduction
The International Financial Reporting Standard IFRS 9 and the ensuing changes in Bulgaria’s accounting rules have mandated that all banks conduct regular forecasts of expected credit loss (ECL) for credit portfolios. A key parameter for this estimation is the loss-given-default ratio, LGD, which measures what proportion of the exposure’s value will be lost in the event of a default.
In addition, estimating the LGD ratio is essential in navigating the regulatory requirements because it is instrumental in verifying the sufficiency of capital buffers for meeting unexpected credit losses. For larger banks, particularly those applying the internal-rating-based approach to credit risk estimation, this challenge was already familiar and they were well-equipped to handle it. Following the introduction of BASEL II and, later, BASEL III, the ample regulatory literature supported them in developing and applying best practices in this matter (cf., e.g., [
1,
2]).
In addition, several fundamental studies, including [
3,
4], lay out the theoretical framework for loss rate management under the value-at-risk framework, which is hereinbelow briefly described.
Let
denote the
q-th quantile of a given random variable
X:
Definition 1. (i) The loss rate of a loan i over a given time interval (usually 12 months) is a random variable
- (ii)
The loss rate of an n-loan portfolio, L, is the value-weighted average of the loss rates of all participating exposures ;
- (iii)
The q-th value-at-risk
, , of a bank’s credit portfolio is the q-th quantile of the loss rate:
The currently applied regulatory regime is based on credit ratings. A bank, aiming to preserve its current credit rating, has a target probability of survival q, e.g., 95, 99, 99.9%, etc. Hence, the bank needs to maintain the capital adequacy level of (i.e., to demonstrate the capacity to finance with equity) at least the q-th value-at-risk, .
A review of the shortcomings of this policy and a critical analysis of the properties of VaR as a risk indicator in comparison with the expected shortfall can be found in [
5,
6].
Following this guidance, nevertheless, studies often implement Merton-type asymptotic factor models (cf. [
7,
8]). In such models, the value of a specific obligor is assumed to follow a geometric random walk and is, hence, associated with a latent random variable
with standard normal distribution. Furthermore,
is decomposed as
on a single systemic risk factor
X and an
representing the idiosyncratic risk. All
and
X are independent, identically distributed (iid) with
.
As demonstrated in [
9,
10] under certain conditions, including a fine granularity of the portfolio,
can be asymptotically approximated with the
q-th quantile of the expected loss rate,
. Furthermore, under additional assumptions of the monotonicity of the relation between the loss rate and the macroeconomic factor
X,
is approximated by the loss rate’s expectation
, conditional on
X assuming its
q-th quantile.
In attempting to follow such a process, smaller banks experience significant costs due to the complexity of the requirements and insufficient or lower-quality data. For example, measuring realized LGD is challenging for smaller institutions because of scarce historical data on losses. Banks utilize various estimation techniques to fill the data gaps in such cases, e.g., superimposing time intervals, as suggested by [
11]. Further discussion on empirical difficulties in validating LGD can be found in [
12,
13].
Empirically, as an indicator, expected inferred loss rate, ILR, is computed on a portfolio-level compounding previously made estimates of LGD (potentially on individual exposure level). Similarly, the validity of the LGD estimate, as proposed in [
11], is a statement of collective, rather than individual accuracy. The study of ILR, as a proxy of the actual loss rate of a portfolio, was partly motivated by the possibility of developing a methodology for the forecasting and cross-validation of portfolios’ LGD estimates that would circumvent the difficulty in measuring realized LGDs.
Other studies of risks, focusing on the Bulgarian banks, including [
14,
15,
16], concentrate on the idiosyncratic characteristics of the local environment.
In contrast, the ILR is designed to study the systemic effect. It was introduced in [
17], hypothesizing that it can provide a conservative measure of the actual loss rate. Because of its asymptotical nature, this study ignores the idiosyncratic characteristics usually analyzed in individual credit risk estimation. Regarding the individual behavior of the debtors, such risks are acknowledged in two ways:
No assumption is made about individual losses being identically distributed. Because of the infinitely fine granularity of the portfolio, the effect of an individual debtor’s behavior is infinitesimal and shown to be inconsequential. If the collective behavior of the bank’s clients affects the loss rate, this is considered a part of the systemic risk factor;
Assumptions 5 and 6 in
Section 2 require only a partial continuity of the relation between the macro-factor X and the probability distribution of expected ILR. Generally, this functional dependence may have some jumps and flat sections due to individual defaults.
The construction of ILR utilizes the stages of the impairment of exposures introduced by IFRS 9:
Stage 1 designates all loans that perform within expectations for their originally assigned risk class. For such loans, ECL is computed over a 12-month horizon;
Stage 2 classifies loans that have exhibited significant increases in their risk. Usually, this is a narrower class of loans; for them, ECL is computed over the loan’s lifetime;
Stage 3 is the group of already defaulted loans. The loss for these loans is considered certain.
Assume that the bank has an infinite pool of credit exposures
that is structured in a filtration of portfolios.
Let
denote the
exposure-at-default, EAD, of the
i-th loan, i.e., the estimated amount on the loan when a default occurs. These are considered known deterministic values. For a portfolio of
n exposures, we denote its EAD by
Definition 2. (i) The inferred loss-rate of the i-th exposure is a random variable , which depends on the stage of the exposure:
- (ii)
is the inferred loss rate of the portfolio .
Without any loss of generality, we assume that all and are random variables, defined on the same probability space. We do not assume, however, that they are identically distributed.
For convenience, denote, by
and by
the condition on
X means of the inferred loss on exposure and portfolio level, respectively.
My main results are Theorems 1 and 2.
Theorem 1. Under Assumptions 1–5, as stated in Section 2, for sufficiently large n and for an arbitrary , we have the following: - (i)
A capital reserve in the amount per currency unit for each exposure is sufficient to cover the value at risk at the level of the probability of survival q for a portfolio of sufficiently large numerosity n;
- (ii)
The respective capital reserve proportion for the whole portfolio, , is
In [
17], Theorem 1 was stated as a proposition and the proof was sketched under rather strict assumptions about continuity. In
Section 2, a complete proof of this fact is given under a less restrictive, more realistic, set of assumptions.
To further demonstrate the similarity between ILR and the usual loss rate, my goal is to use
as an approximation of
. By definition, the inferred loss is both a more frequent and a costlier event than the actual insolvency during the 12-month horizon. Hence, the capital adequacy requirements obtained in this way will be more conservative than the usual rating-based capital rules.
Section 2 provides a proof that, under certain conditions of regularity, asymptotically,
equals
in the following sense.
Theorem 2. Under Assumptions 1–6, we have the following: My results closely parallel the development of techniques for studying the loss rate in [
9,
10,
18].
As demonstrated in [
17], the expected ILR can be computed using publicly available data reported regularly to the regulator.
The Bulgarian regulator, Bulgarian National Bank, BNB, discloses quarterly information on the quality of loans by bank groups and by the type of debtor. This report reveals the share of performing and non-performing loans in the cumulative exposure in the banking system. The total size of ECL is also disclosed. Let
denote the conditional expected credit loss for a portfolio of size
n, conditional on
. One can compute the expected inferred loss rate, as defined by (
1), based on these data, by setting
This technique is used in [
17] to provide empirical evidence of the usefulness of the ILR indicator. The main finding is that the capital adequacy threshold, computed using the expected ILR, is well within the regulatory requirement, alleviating some of the concerns about the excessive conservativeness of the indicator. This computation is performed for the cumulative portfolios of the whole banking system and Group 2, consisting of the smaller banks in the country.
Since then, 11 additional quarterly data points have become available for analysis. In
Section 3, the older empirical results are confirmed with the new data and extended to Group 1, comprising the top-five banks, allowing a more explicit comparison of the risk profiles of the two bank groups.
Section 3.3 provides an analysis of the dependence of the ILR on macroeconomic factors, confirming empirically that, for corporate loans, the ILR is a decreasing function of gross domestic product. The ILR for retail loans exhibits an increasing behavior on the unemployment rate.
To summarize, the focus of the current study is twofold: first, to provide a complete mathematical justification of the capacity of ILR to estimate unexpected credit loss; second, to empirically provide evidence of the validity of the assumptions made for the proofs and to investigate the extent of the inherent conservative bias of the estimation of LGD, using ILR.
The current study does not discuss the construction of reasonable forecasting models for ILR. This task would require a more careful analysis of the underlying random processes. The time series of expected ILR are expected to have expressed autocorrelation since the portfolio inherits many of its constituents from one moment to the next. Some cyclical effects are to be expected, particularly in smaller banks. As more data become available with time, more advanced techniques from the VaR literature (cf. e.g., [
19]) will be applicable in the study of the distribution of ILR.
Another aspect left to the future is the utilization of ILR for the validation of LGD models. Such analysis would require comparing the expected ILR for a given sub-portfolio to the available data of realized losses. This study, however, would require private bank data.
A further study of ILR, together with other credit risk indicators, would involve the application of the techniques of event study and principal component analysis (similarly to, e.g., refs. [
20,
21,
22]) to analyze the effect of various system-wide events and regulatory changes. Monte Carlo simulations, like the ones used in [
23,
24], would be a suitable approach to this problem. The development of our methodology in this direction will be left to future study.
2. Asymptotic Estimation of the Inferred Loss Rate
We focus on the relation between the quantiles , , and of ILR, the conditional expectation of ILR, and the systemic risk factor. I make the following assumptions, reflecting the specific characteristics of the credit loss environment.
Generally, it is justified to assume that credit loss is contractually bounded. In studies where an actuarial approach is taken, the loss rate never exceeds 1; in reality, however, banks may incur expenses greater than the original value of the loan. The upper limit of the loss may be affected further if one accounts for the market value of the exposure. For this reason, we make the following assumption.
Assumption 1. The inferred loss rates are non-negative and bounded.
In modeling credit risk, it is common to assume that exposure failures are independent events outside of the influence of a macro-factor X.
Assumption 2. The random variables are, conditionally on independent.
The following condition guarantees that the size of even the largest exposure vanishes to 0 as the number of exposures increases infinitely.
Assumption 3. The EADs form a sequence of positive numbers, such that and is convergent.
The following is a technical assumption, common for asymptotic credit risk models (cf., e.g., [
8]).
Assumption 4. The systematic risk factor X is one-dimensional.
A monotonicity condition similar to Assumption 5 is commonly expected from the systemic risk factors. For example, Ref. [
25] demonstrates that, in the Bulgarian banking system, the probability of default for retail and corporate loans is an increasing function of the unemployment rate and a decreasing function of the gross domestic product, respectively.
Assumption 5. There is an open interval surrounding the q-th quantile of X, , and number , such that, for any , we have the following:
- (a)
is non-decreasing in ;
- (b)
;
- (c)
.
Remark 1. Some assumptions postulated in [
17]
have been weakened in the current version: - (a)
The systemic factor X is not required to be an absolutely continuous random variable in Assumption 4;
- (b)
Assumption 5 does not require that expected loss rates for all
exposures are monotone functions of X. This would simplify the proof; however, this does not reflect the possibility of the portfolio containing loans to entities with countercyclical business rhythm. Furthermore, a strict monotonicity of is not assumed, which better reflects the actual conditions of credit portfolio management, compared to the assumptions made in [
17].
Proposition 1. Under the above assumptions, conditional on ,almost surely as . The proof makes use of the strong law of large numbers in the following form.
Lemma 1 (cf. [
26], Theorem 6.7).
Let be a sequence of independent random variables. If and is convergent, thenalmost surely as .
Proof of Proposition 1. Let and . Since , checking the requirements of Lemma 1 would suffice.
For any value
x of
X, we have
Assumption 2 implies that, for any
i,
for some constant
K. Hence,
Assumption 3 implies that the requirements of Lemma 1 are satisfied. □
Proposition 1 is not precisely what we seek. With the following proposition, we aim to approximate the quantile of with the respective one of .
Proposition 2. If is the cumulative distribution function (cdf) of , then, for any , Proof. Since almost sure convergence implies convergence in probability, by Proposition 1, for any
x and
, we have
Therefore,
Hence,
Let
be the set of values of
X for which
does not exceed its
quantile. By construction,
. The law of total probability implies
By design, for any
, the monotonicity of
implies
Hence, by bounded convergence theorem, (
8) implies that
Combined with (
10), this implies (
5).
To prove Equation (6), let
By construction,
; hence,
Notice that, if
,
implies
as
, thanks to (9).
An argument similar to the proof of (
5) justifies (6). □
Assumption 5 allows us to refine further the approximation of quantiles with the following proposition.
Proposition 3. For sufficiently large n, Proof. Assumption 5 implies that, for
, if
, then
. Hence,
Conversely, if
, then
and
for any
. Therefore,
□
Together, Propositions 2 and 3 imply the following theorem.
Proof Theorem 1. The actual loss of the portfolio is given by
and will exceed the suggested capital adequacy requirement if
Furthermore, for the inferred loss, we have
Hence,
□
This result is fully sufficient to attempt empirical work.
Remark 2. This finding implies that capital adequacy, considered not from a regulatory but from an economic perspective, can be validated externally, based on publicly disclosed data.
A more stringent condition of regularity, given by Assumption 6, is required to prove that, asymptotically, equals the value-at-risk threshold of inferred loss rate at a probability of survival q.
Assumption 6. There is an open interval surrounding the q-th quantile of X, , and number , such that, for any , in addition to the conditions in Assumption 5, we have the following:
- (d)
The cdf of the systemic factor X is continuous and strictly increasing in B;
- (e)
For any i, the function is differentiable in B;
- (f)
For sufficiently large n, is bounded in a positive finite interval, for .
Remark 3. Assumption 6 aims to guarantee the continuity of at the quantile. This form is, also, less restrictive than the requirement imposed in [
17].
Let
,
, and
H be the cdfs of
,
, and
X respectively. Assumption 6 implies that
is strictly increasing in
B, i.e., for any
,
is equivalent to
. Hence,
Proposition 4. For any value x of X, if , then The proof relies on the following lemma.
Lemma 2. Let Y and Z be two random variables with cdfs and , respectively. For any u and , Proof. Notice that, if
and
, then
. Hence,
and
Similarly, if
and
, then
. Hence,
and
Combining (
13) and (
14), we obtain (
12). □
Proof of Proposition 4. Take
,
B,
m, and
M provided by Assumptions 5 and 6 and fix
and
. Using (
11), and applying Lemma 2 for
and
, we have
for any
.
Next, take
, such that
and
. For any
, we have
Hence,
and
This implies
Similarly, we can see that
Therefore,
By Assumption 6,
H is a continuous strictly increasing function. Therefore, for any
, there exist values of
such that
On the other hand, Proposition 1 implies convergence in probability and, hence, for any
and
, there exists
such that
Therefore, we have that, for any
, if
,
which concludes the proof. □
Proof of Theorem 2. Applying Proposition 4 with
and noticing that
proves (
2).
To prove (3), suppose that
is chosen as in the proof of Proposition 4. Notice that for any
, and
, if
, then
Hence,
Since
,
, we have, by Proposition 4,
Assumption 6 implies that
, so there exists
such that, if
,
Therefore, (
15) implies
, so
.
Similarly,
and, likewise, there exists
such that, if
,
.
Thus, for
, we have
for any
. Since
can be chosen arbitrarily close to 0, this concludes the proof of (3). □