4.2.1. Parameter Estimation and Model Validation
The principle of stationarity testing is primarily to determine whether a time series possesses the characteristic of stationarity; that is, whether its statistical properties remain stable over different time periods. Stationarity in a time series means that the mean, variance, and autocorrelation structure do not change over time. If a time series is non-stationary, it may exhibit trends, seasonality, or other forms of systematic variation that could affect the validity of statistical analyses or models that assume stationarity.
In this paper, the augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) method is used to perform stationarity tests on variables such as IBO001, M0, and LIQ, with the lag order determined by the Schwarz information criterion (SIC). The test results are shown in
Table 3.
From
Table 3, the ADF statistical values of each variable are all below the critical value at the 5% significance level. Therefore, the null hypothesis of the existence of unit roots can be rejected; that is, the original data of each variable is stationary. This result indicates that these variables have stable statistical characteristics, which can be used for forecasting, modeling, and economic analysis, thereby providing valuable insights and recommendations.
Based on information criteria, such as the likelihood ratio (LR), the final prediction error (FPE), the Akaike information criterion (AIC), the Schwarz criterion (SC), and the Hannan–Quinn criterion (HQ), the optimal lag order of the model is determined. The test results of each criterion are shown in
Table 4.
According to the LR criterion, the optimal lag order is 6, while the FPE, AIC, SC, and HQ criteria all point to an optimal lag order of 1. Considering the lag significance between the variables, the optimal lag order of the model is set to 1. This means that the value of s in Formula (1) is 1.
The Markov chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) estimation method under the Bayesian framework was selected for the time-varying parameters of the TVP-SV-SVAR model. The number of model iterations was set to 10,000. Considering that the initial value would affect the stability of model estimation, the first 1000 pre-burned samples were discarded. The estimation results are shown in
Table 5.
The Geweke diagnostic values and ineffective factors are used to test the convergence and effectiveness of the TVP-SV-SVAR model, which are important indicators for evaluating the effectiveness of the MCMC method. According to
Table 5, the Geweke diagnostic values of the model parameters are all less than the critical value of 1.96, and the null hypothesis cannot be rejected at the 5% significance level. The Geweke diagnostics significantly converge to the posterior distribution, showing that the parameters of the model significantly converge to the posterior distribution, indicating good convergence of the selected sample in this study. Ineffective factors are mainly responsible for testing effectiveness, with smaller values indicating better sampling efficiency. In
Table 5, the values of ineffective factors corresponding to each parameter remain at a relatively low level, with a maximum value of 44.89, indicating that we can obtain at least 223 unrelated sample observations in this state. There is a lot of sample information contained in the observation period, allowing for effective estimation. Therefore, the samples extracted through the MCMC method are effective.
Based on the estimation results,
Figure 3 shows the trend of autocorrelation coefficient changes of the estimated variables in the TVP-SV-SVAR model. The sample path of MCMC sampling is shown in
Figure 4, and the posterior distribution of the MCMC simulated parameter samples is shown in
Figure 5.
From
Figure 3, the estimated parameter autocorrelation coefficient gradually decreases, and after 500 rounds of the MCMC, the fluctuation values tend to zero, indicating that the sampling is stable, and the preset initial values of each parameter make the sampling effective.
Figure 4 shows that, as the number of samples increases, the estimated variable exhibits a significant mean recovery characteristic, indicating that the estimation results of the variable become more robust. The posterior distribution density map in
Figure 5 shows that, after 10,000 MCMC sampling estimates, the parameter results have good convergence and clustering characteristics, indicating the effectiveness of the model simulation results. Therefore, the TVP-SV-SVAR model is highly effective for impact analysis.
4.2.3. Analysis of Time-Varying Pulse Response
Based on the estimation results of the TVP-SV-SVAR model, this paper analyzes two types of impulse response functions: the first is the equidistant impulse response function, which reflects the impact of a positive impact of one standard deviation shock on the liquidity of the local bond market at the same time interval under different lead times when monetary policy variables experience a positive impact; the second type is the time point impulse response function, which reflects the impact on the liquidity of local bond markets at different time points when a positive one standard deviation shock occurs in monetary policy variables.
Figure 7 and
Figure 8 show the impulse response effects of local bond market liquidity on two types of monetary policy shocks under different lead times. Among them, three periods, six periods, and twelve periods in advance correspond to the short-term, medium-term, and long-term time states, respectively.
From
Figure 7, we can observe that the pulse response of local bond market liquidity to price-based monetary policy is consistently negative, indicating that an increase in overnight interbank lending rates promotes a decrease in liquidity in the local bond market across the short, medium, and long terms.
The index’s negative response to IBO001—peaking at the medium horizons—captures the economic mechanism whereby higher policy rates, transmitted through the price channel, sap trading willingness and erode liquidity breadth. Entropy weights amplify this effect by assigning the dimension a high, data-driven loading. During the 2020 loan-pricing reform, the strongest index reaction illustrates how the composite weights dynamically adapt to policy transitions such as interest-rate liberalization: the coefficient-of-variation component rapidly registers the heightened sensitivity of turnover, furnishing the PBOC with an on-the-fly risk signal.
With the extension of the lag period, the pulse response intensity shows a trend of increasing and then decreasing. The response value with a lag of six periods is the highest, indicating that the medium-term impact of price-based monetary policy on the liquidity of local bond markets is the strongest, though its sustainability is not strong. The fluctuation amplitude of pulse response shows a gradually increasing trend, with more obvious time-varying characteristics. The fluctuation amplitude with a lag of 12 periods is the largest, indicating that the impact of price-based monetary policy is relatively stable in the short and medium term, and liquidity is more sensitive to its impact in the long term. As revealed by Goyenko and Ukhov [
10], the influence of monetary policy on the bond market is significant and lasts for a considerable duration.
From a market-microstructure perspective, the hump-shaped impulse response of local-government bond liquidity to an IBO001 hike—first intensifying, then fading—mirrors a two-stage adjustment. Immediately, the higher policy rate raises interbank funding costs, inflating the dealers’ inventory risk and prompting an abrupt narrowing of bid–ask spreads, and the response curve plunges. Over the medium term, institutional investors rebalance portfolios. Because local bonds are relatively illiquid, these trades generate sizeable price-impact costs, driving the impulse to its peak. In the long run, the market completes its repricing, and the PBOC may offset the shock through open-market operations, so the response gradually subsides.
Figure 8 illustrates the pulse response of liquidity in the local bond market to quantitative monetary policy. There is a notable shift in the response around 2015. Before 2015, the pulse response was positive, indicating that an increase in M0 had a positive effect on the liquidity of local bonds. This is consistent with Iwatsubo and Taishi (2018) [
34] and Christensen and Gillan (2019) [
15], who found that quantitative and qualitative monetary easing (QQE) policies adopted by the government significantly enhanced the liquidity of the bond market. From the perspective of Japan’s policy adjustments, increasing the frequency of purchases, reducing the amount of each transaction, and lowering the variability of the purchase volume have significantly improved market liquidity. After 2015, the pulse response turned negative, indicating that an increase in M0 would lead to a decrease in liquidity in the local bond market.
The sign-reversal of M0’s impact on the index around 2015 is rooted in the evolving weighting scheme. Before 2015, the entropy method highlighted the informational content of price deviations, so looser policy reduced information costs and lifted the index. After 2015, the coefficient-of-variation method assigned greater weight to the Amihud Ratio, causing quantitative expansions to translate into heavier price-impact penalties and a negative impulse. This micro-foundation aligns with, and helps interpret, the TVP-SV-SVAR model’s time-varying estimates. During the 2017 local-debt clampdown, the pronounced negative response cautioned policymakers to calibrate quantity tools carefully to avert market dysfunction.
Similar to price-based policy, with the extension of the hysteresis period, the pulse response intensity increases and the decreases with the lag period, with the greatest impact observed in the mid-term. The fluctuation amplitude of pulse response is the largest with a lag of 12 periods, indicating that the long-term impact is relatively stable, meaning that, in the long run, the sensitivity of local bond market liquidity to changes in money supply is relatively low.
The structural shift before and after 2015 mirrors a deeper transformation of China’s financial architecture. In the pre-2015 regime, an M0 increase worked through a “credit expansion—LGFV borrowing surge—rising demand for local bonds” pipeline, delivering a positive liquidity impulse. After 2015, the same expansion flips sign: higher M0 stokes inflation expectations, prompting investors to offload long-duration local bonds faster than new demand emerges; meanwhile, abundant liquidity is parked in highly liquid safe assets rather than channeled into the local bond market, reflecting heightened credit-risk aversion. The lesson for policymakers is clear—when clamping down on local-debt growth, quantitative easing must be paired with targeted risk-mitigation tools to prevent stimulus from “idling” outside the bond market.
In summary, both price-based and quantity-based monetary policies have significant time-varying impacts on the liquidity of the local bond market. The relationship between impulse response and lag period shows nonlinear characteristics, with the medium-term impact being the most significant. Overall, the impact of quantitative monetary policy on the liquidity of local bond markets is greater than that of price-based monetary policy.
The asymmetry and time-varying nature of impulse responses carry immediate policy implications. A negative response to price-based shocks (IBO001) shows that rate hikes curb market activity through the price channel: higher funding costs lead investors to scale back bond trading, eroding liquidity breadth (wider bid–ask spreads) and depth (lower turnover). This mechanism was starkly visible during the 2017 clampdown on local-government debt, where the peak response at a lag of six periods coincided with regulatory tightening—a reminder that overlapping measures can tip the market toward dysfunction. Likewise, the sign reversal in quantitative-policy shocks (M0) around 2015 signals a structural break: pre-2015 expansions in M0 boosted liquidity by lowering information costs, whereas post-2015 expansions dampened it as the rise of digital finance amplified the price impact. Policymakers should therefore prioritize quantitative tools for day-to-day liquidity management and avoid clustering rate adjustments, particularly during episodes of interest-rate liberalization (e.g., the 2020 loan-pricing reform) to safeguard market stability.
To analyze the effect in more details, several specific time points are selected for the time-point pulse response analysis. We have selected three points that reflect the process of China’s financial market transitioning from a regulated to a market-oriented system. Each step has had a profound impact on the efficiency, stability, and competitiveness of the financial market.
In October 2015, the restrictions on the fluctuation of deposit and loan interest rates in China were basically lifted, and the market-oriented reform of interest rates entered a new stage. The formation mechanism and regulatory mechanism of market-oriented interest rates were at the core. This marks a significant turning point in China’s financial market. The marketization of interest rates helps to improve the efficiency of the financial market, to promote the rational allocation of resources, and to enhance the competitiveness and risk management capabilities of banks. This reform also lays the foundation for subsequent innovation in financial products and the deepening of the financial market.
In July 2017, the National Financial Work Conference made important arrangements for local debt, including proposing to strictly control its scale, further promoting deleveraging, resolutely implementing a prudent monetary policy, and emphasizing the local government’s responsibility for risk disposal. This conference indicated that the government is aware of the risks associated with local debt and has taken measures to prevent and to resolve these risks. This policy adjustment helps to maintain macroeconomic stability and to promote sustainable economic development.
The third time period is January 2020, and new loans will no longer be priced based on the benchmark loan interest rate starting from that day. This change signifies that China’s loan market interest rates are becoming more market-oriented. This reform helps to enhance the flexibility and sensitivity of loan interest rates, enabling them to reflect more accurately the market supply and demand relationship and the level of risk.
Based on the selected time point, the pulse response of local bond market liquidity to two types of monetary policies is shown in
Figure 9 and
Figure 10.
Figure 9 shows that, at three time points, the pulse response pattern of liquidity in the local bond market to price-based monetary policy shocks is consistent, all of which have a sustained negative effect and produce relatively weak responses in the current period. The degree of response increases and then weakens, ultimately exceeding the initial level, and reaches its maximum value between the sixth and seventh periods. The difference lies in the response intensity and duration. In the event of “new loans no longer being priced based on loan benchmark interest rates” in January 2020, the impact of price-based monetary policy on liquidity was the greatest and the duration was the longest. The impact on the liquidity of the local bond market was minimal and the duration was the shortest during the “basic lifting of floating restrictions on deposit and loan interest rates” event in October 2015.
Figure 9 illustrates how price-based monetary policy transmits to local-government bond liquidity at three pivotal junctures. In October 2015, shortly after the formal completion of interest-rate liberalization, the impulse response is modest, reflecting China’s lingering “dual-track” interest-rate regime. Although the deposit-rate ceiling had been abolished, the banks’ liability costs adjusted sluggishly, blunting the pass-through of policy rates to the bond market. By July 2017, under the banner of “strictly controlling local-debt expansion” issued at the National Financial Work Conference, the response intensifies sharply. The tightening narrative heightened institutional sensitivity to rate hikes. Tighter interbank funding (IBO001 surged) coincided with a flight from local bonds, prompting market-makers to scale back quotes and turnover to fall. The liquidity shock exceeded that of 2015 but remained below the 2020 peak. After the LPR reform in 2020, the impulse response reaches its apex. The synchronized liberalization of loan and deposit pricing generated a policy synergy that markedly improved transmission efficiency. These contrasting episodes demonstrate that the dividends of interest-rate liberalization materialize only when sequenced and coordinated with broader financial reforms.
From
Figure 10, at three time points, quantitative monetary policy also has a sustained negative effect on the liquidity of the local bond market. With the extension of time, there is a crossover in the pulse response at the three time points. However, under the “strict control of local government debt increment” event in July 2017, the degree of pulse response is the highest.
In summary, the pulse response of liquidity in the local bond market to both quantity and price-based monetary policy shocks exhibits asymmetric, nonlinear, and time-varying characteristics. The impact differences caused by quantitative monetary policy at three time points are greater, including the fluctuation amplitude of the impulse response function, the position of the maximum value, and the response form, indicating that liquidity has a more significant time-varying impulse response to quantitative monetary policy shocks. In addition, the pulse response value of liquidity to quantitative monetary policy is larger, indicating that quantitative monetary policy has a deeper impact on the liquidity of local bond markets.
Figure 10 disentangles the heterogeneous impact of quantity-based monetary policy on local-bond liquidity at three critical junctures. In 2015, an expansion of M0 produced only a mild adverse reaction, as the market’s pricing flexibility absorbed the extra base money without major disruption. By July 2017, however, an identical increase in M0 coincided with a sharp deterioration in liquidity. The “tight supervision–loose money” mix of that episode induced banks to hoard liquidity rather than redeploy it; excess reserves piled up in the interbank market while risk-asset allocations were slashed, creating a textbook case of “liquidity hoarding”. After the LPR reform in 2020, the policy shifted emphasis toward price signals, muting the marginal impact of M0 growth. The impulse-response curves diverge markedly from the sixth month onward, underscoring three lessons: quantity measures are hostage to the regulatory backdrop—2017’s intensified oversight lengthened the transmission lag; they hinge on market expectations—stable sentiment during the 2020 pandemic shortened it; and they depend on the policy mix—targeted instruments proved decisive in restoring efficiency.
These point-in-time responses (
Figure 9 and
Figure 10) yield granular operational guidance. At the October 2015 milestone of interest-rate liberalization, the muted reaction to an IBO001 shock (≈−0.02) reflected pre-emptive duration adjustments; regulators can exploit such “policy windows” to deepen reforms without replicating the heightened sensitivity observed in 2020 (≈−0.08). The six-period lag to peak response calls for coupling policy moves with forward guidance (Lee et al., 2016) [
13] to smooth expectations. When M0 expansion coincides with a digital-finance boom—as in January 2020—tightening maturity-mismatch limits on wealth-management products can force banks to reduce the share of long bonds funded by short liabilities, cushioning price shocks. Conversely, when M0 is being drained amid a debt clampdown—as in July 2017—activating the Standing Lending Facility to inject emergency liquidity can stabilize bid–ask spreads (the breadth dimension) and avert market seizures.