Next Article in Journal
The Proximal Point Method with Remotest Set Control for Maximal Monotone Operators and Quasi-Nonexpansive Mappings
Next Article in Special Issue
Retail Service, Pricing, and Channel Selection Strategies for Fashion Products in a Two-Stage Decision Model
Previous Article in Journal
Novel Analytical Methods for and Qualitative Analysis of the Generalized Water Wave Equation
Previous Article in Special Issue
Pricing and Emission Reduction Strategies of Heterogeneous Automakers Under the “Dual-Credit + Carbon Cap-and-Trade” Policy Scenario
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Pricing Strategy and Blockchain-Enabled Data Sharing in Cross-Border Port Systems

1
College of Management, Shenzhen University, Shenzhen 518061, China
2
Shenzhen International Maritime Institute, Shenzhen 518083, China
3
School of Business Administration and Customs, Shanghai Customs College, Shanghai 201204, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Mathematics 2025, 13(14), 2281; https://doi.org/10.3390/math13142281
Submission received: 11 June 2025 / Revised: 8 July 2025 / Accepted: 14 July 2025 / Published: 15 July 2025

Abstract

The study examines the impact of pricing strategies on the competition and cooperation of cross-border ports, focusing on unified pricing and differential pricing. The results show that the inside border port can adopt a differentiation strategy to enhance its benefits, as this strategy allows for better control. Additionally, while the differentiated pricing strategy is an equilibrium strategy for the inside border port, blockchain technology can enhance the economic benefits of the inside border port under certain conditions, which also demonstrates the commercial value of blockchain in data sharing. Moreover, the expansion of port capacity can reduce the congestion of the inside border port to some extent under specific conditions. Finally, the study analyzes the environmental impact, tariff impact, and influence of port cooperation, which provides some management implications for inside border port. In summary, the findings highlight the potential of blockchain to optimize pricing strategy and promote cooperation between regional ports, thus improving economic benefits.

1. Introduction

Ports, as a basis for regional economic development, generally offer the value of increasing port throughput, which has broad economic impacts [1,2,3,4,5]. To achieve a synergistic effect for ports in a specific region, different ports employ various methods to maximize benefits from the economy or environment, such as price adjustments or increased environmental benefits [6,7,8]. For example, in China, the Guangdong–Hong Kong–Macao Greater Bay Area is in the process of integrating regional economic development, with frequent port activities and complex commercial relations. From this case, the unified market is being implemented in relevant policies [9]. Then, in the port field, is it possible to realize a unified policy, such as the price strategy from the port? In particular, under the special circumstances of crossing the border, whether it is possible to achieve the rational operation of regional ports in a specific way is a realistic problem that needs to be considered urgently in the current policy of regional economic integration.
Additionally, the wave of digitalization is constantly empowering every link of port operation [10,11,12,13]. For example, blockchain technology not only enhances the transparency of port logistics and the security of data sharing but also automates workflow through smart contracts, significantly reducing human errors and delays, thereby improving overall operational efficiency [14,15,16,17]. At the same time, blockchain technology also helps the port cope with the increasingly complex international trade environment and volatile customer needs, ensuring the port’s core position in the global logistics network. Hence, as a port used for regional activity, it needs to consider how to utilize its technical superiority to enhance port service efficiency, such as data sharing through the support of blockchain technology, which helps to improve customer experience.
The existing literature on port operations has explored pricing strategies and operational strategies using game-theoretical models, laying the groundwork for understanding strategic interactions among ports. Blockchain technology, as an emerging technology, holds significant potential for enhancing data sharing and operational collaboration. Therefore, we aim to explore a potential solution for improving the service level of ports using blockchain technology in regional development. Additionally, this study addresses three questions:
(1)
What is the equilibrium for the inside border port in the context of cross-border ports for regional rationalization development?
(2)
What is the value of blockchain technology in facilitating data sharing between ports in across-border activity?
(3)
What is the equilibrium strategy for inside border port, as an incumbent port, when facing different cases such as port congestion?
Through these discussions, we can show the research value in enhancing the level of port service and blockchain service while highlighting the unique features of studying port activities.
Based on these questions, we develop a game-theoretical model to investigate the equilibrium between inside and outside border ports, considering existing activities. Correspondingly, the analytical questions are shown below.
Firstly, we analyze the equilibrium strategy for competitive ports in the different zones. Specifically, we find that the equilibrium is a differentiated price strategy from the view of the inside border port due to its controllability in the local area. In this case, a differential price strategy can enhance the diversity of port services to obtain economic benefits for the inland border port.
Secondly, we explore the equilibrium strategy by supporting blockchain technology for competitive ports. Specifically, although it is an equilibrium strategy to use a differentiated price strategy, the empowerment of blockchain technology can realize the economic benefits of an inside border port under limited conditions, due to a controllable degree of port strategy in local zones, which also demonstrates the commercial value of blockchain in data sharing.
Finally, we discuss port congestion about the feature of port research. Specifically, we investigate the decision to expand the inside border port. The results suggest that the port manager should consider the economic benefits of expanding port capacity. Furthermore, we also analyze the environmental impact, tariff impact, and influence of port cooperation, which provides some management implications for ports located within the border (also referred to as incumbent ports).
Therefore, this study makes two contributions. On the one hand, our study proposes a management strategy. In this study, we develop a game-theoretical model to investigate the optimal strategy in the context of an across-border port, considering two pricing strategies: unified price and differential price. Specifically, we examine the influence of an inside border port with controllability on business strategy. The analytical results can be used as a reference for ports from the view of flexibility in the price decision and economic strategy. On the other hand, the results emphasize the importance of improving port operation efficiency by using the new technology. By introducing blockchain technology for data sharing, the operational efficiency of the local port can be significantly improved, costs can be reduced, and service quality can be enhanced. Moreover, the study proposes an analytical framework for integrating blockchain-enabled data sharing into a pricing strategy model for cross-border port interactions. Further discussion shows that it can be applied to actual situations in port management.
The paper is structured as follows: Section 2 presents a literature review; Section 3 describes the model setting, including scenario analysis and game-theoretical model setting; Section 4 provides an analysis of service price, service quantity, firms’ profits and decisions, decision of data sharing by blockchain service, and decision of expansion for incumbent port; Section 5 analyzes the environment impact, tariff impact, and influence of port cooperation; and Section 6 presents the main findings and managerial implications. Appendix A provides proof to support the propositions.

2. Literature Review

Our study addresses three key aspects: price strategy, blockchain services in data sharing, and port congestion. According to these topics, we can obtain the value and necessity of research.

2.1. Price Strategy in the Scope of Cooperation and Competition for the Port

In this section, we present the existing literature on price strategy in the context of cooperation and competition. Specifically, from the perspective of port cooperation, existing studies focus on changes in price activity and regional goals. For example, Lu et al. analyze how the incentive competition strategy has both a service quality effect and a price distortion effect [18]. Xing et al. explore the influence of social welfare from the uniform price and discrimination price in the adjacent ports [19]. Zheng and Luo investigate the relationship between price changes and vertical cooperation, which is shown to affect changes in social welfare [20]. Li et al. discuss strategic planning in inland river ports, considering both coordinated and independent operations, and support the price changes [21]. Song et al. analyze how partial and complete alliances are influenced by heterogeneous prices and service levels [22].
From the perspective of the port competition, the port needs to formulate a reasonable price strategy to attract more goods. This includes adjusting prices according to market demand and port capacity, offering differentiated services, and fostering cooperation with other ports. For example, Xu et al. investigate the price strategy for responding to capacity sharing between two regional ports [23]. Li et al. discuss the impact of subsidies for overlapping hinterland shippers on port competition under the condition of port service price [24]. Zheng et al. analyze the price changes in the value of demand information sharing in the port concession arrangement [25]. Xie et al. point out that the price competition increases the fierceness in the same port area [26].
In summary, existing studies analyze the influence of price strategy for port services in specific regions, particularly concerning cooperation and competition between ports. However, a few studies consider the contradiction between the choice of pricing method and the solution for ports. Therefore, we adopt the case of cross-border trade in regional ports to explore a technique for local ports by supporting changes in price strategy, which offers valuable insights for improving price strategy across borders.

2.2. Blockchain Technology and Data Sharing

In this section, we discuss the role of data sharing facilitated by blockchain technology. Specifically, blockchain technology possesses the characteristics of decentralization and tamper-proofness [27,28]. These characteristics can be utilized for information sharing within the supply chain. Previous studies highlight the value of blockchain technology for various aspects of information sharing. For example, Wu et al. investigate the incentive mechanism for cross-border logistics supervision and data sharing in the case of blockchain technology [29]. Zhang et al. discuss the quality decision and demand information sharing to demonstrate the value of blockchain technology [30]. Li et al. analyze the influence of information sharing on reducing carbon emissions in the case of support by blockchain technology [31].
In summary, existing studies investigate the value of blockchain technology for information sharing. However, within the scope of port activity, business contacts have been established between ports in similar areas, such as Shekou Port and Jiangmen Gaoxin Port in China. Nevertheless, there is little discussion on how to realize data sharing through blockchain technology in a cross-border port setting [32]. In this case, the literature needs to highlight and explore the technical advantages of information sharing among regional ports. In particular, blockchain has achieved more transparent and efficient data sharing. By allowing the port to adjust pricing dynamically according to real-time data, decision-making under the background of congestion is enhanced, thereby alleviating congestion more effectively. Therefore, we need to consider how to use the technological advantages of blockchain to improve the level of information sharing among regional ports.

2.3. Port Congestion

Port congestion, as a topic in traditional transport, primarily illustrates the relationship between port capacity and the number of ships (or containers) arriving at the port. Existing studies provide insight into port congestion and its consequences. For example, Li et al. analyze port congestion and its impact on shipping emissions in China [33]. Gu and Liu investigate the relationship between port congestion and air quality [34]. Shu et al. design waterways for ships to avoid port congestion [35]. Guo et al. put forward capacity integration in port clusters with congestion [36]. Li et al. adopt smart technology to reduce the impact of congestion [37]. In summary, existing studies employ various methods to mitigate congestion impacts, rather than adopting a comprehensive framework to optimize strategies for individual ports. In our study, we adopt the expansion of port capacity to reduce the impact of congestion. Although many studies have discussed how to solve congestion, our research focuses more on finding the best solution for local ports while also reflecting the research characteristics of the port field.

3. Model Setting

3.1. Scenario Description

In this subsection, we describe two scenarios based on the model setting. Specifically, we analyze two cases, such as the unified price model (U model) and the differential price model (D model). Two cases involve two ports (Port 1 and Port 2) at the same time, in which Port 1 is inside (incumbent port) and Port 2 is outside the border. The border represents customs, for example, Yantian Port in Shenzhen, China and Kwai Tsing Port in Hong Kong, China have customs relations. Furthermore, in the U model, Port 1 uses the unified price p 1 U to obtain the benefit from the quantity of its own container ( q 1 U ) and the container transferred from Port 2 ( q 3 U ), paying the unit cost ( w 1 U ) to Port 2. Correspondingly, in the D model, due to the differential price in the market, Port 1 determines two types of service prices, such as the price determined by its own quantity ( p 1 D ) and the service price of the container transferred from Port 2 ( p 3 D ). Additionally, in the D model, the container quantity has q 3 D from Port 2. The major difference between the two models is whether the pricing of Port 1 is unique. Therefore, in this case, our primary concern is the change in Port 1 because it is controllable from the aspect of adjusting business strategy. In summary, we can use Figure 1 to illustrate the business relationship.

3.2. Notation and Assumption

The notation can support the model framework, which arranges the symbols in Table 1. In addition, the assumption about the model setting is shown below.
(1)
According to the model setting and the existing literature, we can adopt the reverse demand function [38]. Specifically, in the U model and D model, we set the mathematical expression as follows:
p 1 U = a q 1 U b q 2 U q 3 U + q 1 U + q 3 U K 1
p 2 U = a q 2 U b q 1 U + q 3 U + β q 2 U K 2
w 1 U = a q 3 U
p 1 D = a q 1 D b q 2 D q 3 D + q 1 D + q 3 D K 1
p 2 D = a q 2 D b q 1 D + q 3 D + β q 2 D K 2
p 3 D = a b q 1 D q 3 D + q 1 D + q 3 D K 1
It is notable that the terms q 1 D + q 3 D K 1 and β q 2 D K 2 show port congestion according to the service delay for the customer, which show the feature of port management. The constants K 1 and K 2 represent the total capacity of Port 1 and Port 2, respectively.
(2)
In order to find the changes in port congestion, we set K 2 = Γ K 1 ( 0 < Γ < 1 ) and K 1 = 2 to reflect the changes in capacity for Port 2. Moreover, we set the congestion parameter of Port 1 as 1 and the congestion parameter of Port 2 as β ( 0 < β < 1 ) to show the difference in congestion degree between Port 1 and Port 2. Similar parameter design methods can be found in the existing literature, such as in Niu et al. [39].
(3)
In order to find the main conclusion, we mainly analyze the relationship between Port 1 and Port 2 without the condition of the border’s tariff. In further analysis, we discuss the optimal strategy for Port 1 with the unit tariff to find the favorable choice for Port 1.
(4)
The stakeholders seek the maximum profit since they are rational when they face the benefit.

3.3. Profit Function

According to the model setting, we use Figure 1 to set the profit function. Specifically, we can sort the model setting in Table 2.

3.4. Decision Sequence

The decision sequence of the model can be divided into two cases. Specifically, in the U model, Port 1 needs to consider obtaining the container quantity from Port 2 ( q 3 U ) by the service price ( w 1 U ). Moreover, Port 1 and Port 2 determine the container quantities to the market at the same time ( q 1 U and q 2 U ), respectively. Correspondingly, in the D model, Port 1 determines the service price ( w 1 U ) with Port 2 according to q 3 D . Finally, Port 1 considers the sale container quantities ( q 1 D and q 3 D ), while Port 2 determines the container quantity ( q 2 D ) to the market. Two models aim to obtain the maximum benefit from the market, which can deduce the optimal results.

4. Basic Analysis

In the basic analysis, we discuss several aspects, including service price, service quantity, firms’ profits, the decision to share data via blockchain services, and capacity expansion.

4.1. Service Price

In this part, we analyze the service price of ports. Specifically, we compare the service price between Port 1 to Port 2 and the market prices of two ports, respectively. The findings are shown in Proposition 1.
Proposition 1.
(Service price):
(1) 
w 1 U > < w 1 D ;
(2) 
p 1 U > < p 1 D ; p 2 U > p 2 D ; p 1 U < p 1 D + p 3 D / 2 .
Proposition 1 illustrates the service price for ports under the two cases of price strategy. Specifically, the first finding shows w 1 U > < w 1 D that the two pricing methods will not have a clear price size. Both Port 1 and Port 2 need to consider the transferred container quantity when determining their pricing strategy in relation to the upstream price. Note that the flexible upstream price refers to the changes in service price between Port 1 and Port 2 in a horizontal direction, which are uncertain.
Moreover, from the aspect of downstream price activity, Port 1’s price shows the same tendency. Note that the downstream price represents the service price changes in Port 1 and Port 2 in the market, moving in a vertical direction. Therefore, Port 1 has no clear pricing preference due to the uncertain upstream price. However, we find that unified pricing is higher than differentiated pricing as the latter is more flexible. In addition, unified pricing is equivalent to transferring low price to high price and high price to low price in a unified market, reaching a unified price in a market. Finally, we also found that unified pricing is more advantageous than differential pricing ( p 1 U < p 1 D + p 3 D / 2 ). This case also reflects the value of a unified market in pricing.
Therefore, from the viewpoint of service price, we can deduce two aspects of management implications. On the one hand, the incumbent port (e.g., Port 1) could consider using a unified pricing strategy to attract the most customers, given the relatively low price level for customers. On the other hand, the incumbent port could determine the upstream service price according to the cooperation level of other ports due to their uncontrollable business behavior.

4.2. Service Quantity

In this part, we analyze the service quantity for ports between two price models. Specifically, we discuss the changes in container quantity in the U model and D model. Moreover, we also reflect the quantity changes for the incumbent port (e.g., Port 1), which are shown in Proposition 2.
Proposition 2.
(Service quantity):
(1) 
q 1 U < q 1 D ; q 2 U > q 2 D ; q 3 U > q 3 D ;
(2) 
q 1 U < q 1 D + q 3 D / 2 .
Proposition 2 shows the service quantity changes for two models. The strategy of differential price shows the quantity effect from Proposition 2(1). Although the incumbent port has no clear price strategy, the D model has high level quantity ( q 1 U < q 1 D ). That is the differentiated pricing targets specific market segments, attracting more customers. One the one hand, the container quantity from Port 2 to Port 1 prefers the U model since a unified price strategy could reduce potential market risk ( q 3 U > q 3 D ). This case is named the quantity effect in our study. On the other hand, q 1 U < q 1 D + q 3 D / 2 shows that the sales quantity under unified pricing is lower than the average sales quantity under differentiated pricing for the incumbent port (e.g., Port 1). This is because the price acceptable to consumers in differentiated pricing reconciles the sales quantity when consumers choose unified pricing. In this case, from the view of customers, they prefer to use the low price (such as acceptable price p 1 U ) to obtain more container quantity. However, q 1 U < q 1 D + q 3 D / 2 shows the different results in general cognition. Therefore, from this view, we could point out that the U model is beneficial to some extent for the incumbent port (e.g., Port 1).
Therefore, from the perspective of the quantity effect, we can derive management implications. To meet customer requirements, the D model can offer a relatively low price and capture a substantial transferred quantity for the incumbent port (e.g., Port 1). Moreover, the incumbent port can consider adopting a new model to achieve a consistent choice between price and quantity strategies, such as implementing new technology to facilitate strategy changes.

4.3. Profit and Firm’s Decision

In this section, we analyze the profit and the firm’s decision in the U model and D model based on Proposition 3 to determine the optimal strategy.
Proposition 3.
(Profit analysis): π 1 U < π 1 D ; π 2 U > π 2 D .
Proposition 3 reflects the profit changes between Port 1 and Port 2. Specifically, the result indicates that the optimal strategy of Port 1 is the D model. The potential reason has two aspects. On the one hand, the D model has a large market share compared to the U model, which can satisfy the needs of consumers, thus gaining the motivation of continuous investment and key support. On the other hand, the differentiated pricing scheme helps the port to optimize the service quality and quantity. By offering various levels of service to cater to the diverse needs of different customers, the port can utilize its resources more effectively and enhance operational efficiency. From the perspective of Port 2, as an outside border port, it is more willing to increase its benefits and capture a larger market share through a unified price. However, since Port 2 is located on the outside border, its optimal strategy does not need to be considered.
Therefore, we can obtain the two aspects of management implications. On the one hand, ports should pay attention to the importance of market segmentation and positioning. The port’s adoption of a differentiated price scheme first shows the importance of market segmentation. By deeply understanding the needs, preferences, and payment ability of different customers, ports can divide the market into different customer groups and provide customized services and prices for each group. This kind of market segmentation is helpful for ports to meet customers’ needs more accurately, improve customer satisfaction, and then increase market share and profits. On the other hand, ports also need to consider the level of price decision. In other words, ports need to constantly adjust prices according to market changes, customer demand, and competitive situations to ensure steady growth of benefits. This flexible pricing ability is very important for the long-term development of the port because it can help the port maintain its competitiveness in the complex and changing market environment.

4.4. Decision of Data Sharing by Blockchain Service

In this part, we consider adopting the blockchain service into the port decision. The motivation is that ports can increase the service experience by data sharing with blockchain services, such as information of cargo circulation or increasing supply chain activity. In this case, we use the blockchain service to increase consumer experience s . Moreover, in order to improve the data cooperation between ports, an inside border port may choose to share certain data or information with an external border port ( θ ), but an outside port needs to pay related fees. In other words, the openness of data will have a direct bearing on the benefit of out-board ports. This case has the advantage of improving the service experience of the two ports and bringing higher service efficiency to consumers.
According to this setting, we can redesign the analytical model based on the basic model. Specifically, we adopt the new inverse demand functions and profit function as follows:
p 1 U B = a q 1 U B b q 2 U B q 3 U B + q 1 U B + q 3 U B K 1 + s U B
p 2 U B = a q 2 U B b q 1 U B + q 3 U B + β q 2 U B K 2 + θ s U B
π 1 U B = p 1 U B q 1 U B + q 3 U B w 1 U B q 3 U B θ s U B 2 2
π 2 U B = p 2 U B q 2 U B + w 1 U B q 3 U B 1 θ s U B 2 2
Based on these settings, we consider the new results between the new U-B model and the D model, which obtain the equilibrium strategy in Proposition 4 from Ports 1 and 2. Note that 1 θ shows that the higher participation usually means lower marginal cost for Port 2, which also shows the value of technology maturity for technology investment of blockchain service. θ s U B means the benefits of blockchain information opening. 1 θ s U B 2 2 is the technical cost to be shared.
Proposition 4.
(Decision of data sharing by blockchain service):
(1) 
π 1 U B > < π 1 D ; π 2 U B > < π 2 D ;
(2) 
The equilibrium is zone D in Figure 2.
Proposition 4 shows the decision of data sharing using the blockchain service for ports. Specifically, we can find that the result is π 1 U B > < π 1 D , which shows the value of the blockchain service between the U-B model and the D model. The result reveals that the openness of blockchain services can improve the efficiency of port services and the value of data. The potential reasons can be divided into two parts. For example, blockchain technology ensures that data is encrypted and stored on multiple nodes through distributed ledger technology, making it difficult to be tampered with or deleted, thereby providing a highly secure data sharing environment. At the same time, the openness of the blockchain enhances the transparency of the supply chain, allowing ports to access the status and information of goods in real-time. In addition, the blockchain also optimizes the cross-border trade process, reduces the detention time of goods in the port, and improves the logistics efficiency by simplifying document processing, realizing paperless trading, and accelerating customs clearance.
However, from the port’s perspective, the result shows that the equilibrium strategy is the D model. In other words, the D model is more flexible for port’s services. Although the D model is an equilibrium strategy between ports, the inside border port can better control a reasonable strategy. Therefore, the management implications of blockchain technology and differential price strategy for ports can be adopted in two aspects.
On the one hand, through the introduction of blockchain technology, ports within the border can establish a decentralized and tamper-proof data sharing platform, enabling ports, shipping companies, and other parties to share and update cargo information in real-time and accurately, thereby improving logistics efficiency. On the other hand, the differentiated pricing strategy can provide personalized service prices according to the needs of different customers and the characteristics of goods, which can not only attract more customers but also enhance the profitability of the port. By combining blockchain technology and differentiated pricing strategy, ports can achieve more efficient, flexible and safer operation and management, enhance competitiveness, and meet the diversified needs of the market.

4.5. Decision of Expansion for Incumbent Port

In this section, we consider the decision to expand an incumbent port. Specifically, we analyze the case where the incumbent port is located inside a border port (e.g., Port 1), which demonstrates the influence of port capacity on port activity based on the U-B model. Specifically, we adjust the term K 1 to K 1 1 + 1 / F , one of term 1 / F as the level of expansion level for Port 1. In addition, we can adopt the profit function for the U-BE model as follows:
π 1 U B E = p 1 U B E q 1 U B E + q 3 U B E w 1 U B E q 3 U B E θ s U B E 2 2 F
Note that the term F is the expansion cost of the port. According to the quantity changes for Port 1, we can obtain the term C 1 i = q 1 i q 1 i + q 3 i ,   i = U , U B E , which describes port congestion in the cases of the two models. Based on these changes for model setting in the new model, we can deduce Proposition 5 about the decision of expansion for an incumbent port.
Proposition 5.
(Decision of expansion for incumbent port):
(1) 
The F is small; the result is C 1 U > < C 1 U B E .
(2) 
The F is the maximum for satisfying a specific condition; the result is C 1 U > C 1 U B E .
Proposition 5 shows the decision of expansion for an incumbent port. Specifically, when the cost of port capacity expansion is small, we need to consider its impact from two aspects. On the one hand, a unified pricing strategy is the key to efficient port operation. It simplifies the port operation process, eliminates the complicated negotiations caused by price differences, and effectively relieves the port congestion problem. On the other hand, the application of blockchain technology has brought revolutionary changes to port management. Through real-time data sharing and the automatic execution of intelligent contracts, the port can accurately track cargo dynamics, optimize resource allocation, and maximize the utilization of port capacity.
When the cost of port capacity expansion is high, it is particularly necessary to choose a unified pricing scheme. On the one hand, the unified pricing scheme can effectively reduce the management and operational costs of ports, as it avoids the complicated negotiation and contract management associated with differentiated pricing. In the context of high expansion costs, this simplified operation method can help the port better control costs and improve economic benefits. On the other hand, unified pricing can also enhance the market competitiveness of ports, attract more customers, and stabilize market share by providing a consistent and transparent price system. Furthermore, the scheme can also reduce management risk, avoid uncertainty caused by price fluctuations and changes in market demand, and provide a guarantee for the stable operation of the port.
Therefore, we can adopt some management implications for ports. On the one hand, cost-effectiveness and decision-making flexibility are the elements that must be weighed when ports make strategic decisions. When the port faces capacity expansion, if the cost is low, we should actively adopt new technologies, such as blockchain, to promote innovation in port operations and improve service quality and efficiency. However, when the cost of expansion is high, it is necessary to consider cost-effectiveness more carefully and choose a more economical and less risky scheme, such as a unified pricing scheme, to ensure a return on investment and stable port operation.
On the other hand, technological innovation and market demand are the two driving forces for the sustainable development of ports. The introduction of blockchain and other technologies has brought unprecedented opportunities for port management, which can significantly improve the efficiency of data sharing and optimize resource allocation. However, the application of these technologies also needs to be closely combined with market demand to ensure that the technologies are in line with the actual business scenarios and to enhance the competitiveness and customer satisfaction of the port.

5. Further Analysis

5.1. Influence of Environment by Port Activity

In this part, we analyze the influence of the environment on port activity between the U model and the U-B model. According to some existing studies [40,41], we can adopt the quantity between two models to obtain the environment impact: E I i = q 1 , 2 , 3 i , i = U , U B . This model can be understood as every unit of quantity having pollution emissions. Hence, we can obtain Proposition 6.
Proposition 6.
(Influence of environment by port activity): E I U > < E I U B .
Proposition 6 shows the environment impact by port activity between the U model and U-B model according to the above analysis. Specifically, we found that the result is E I U > < E I U B . The potential reason has two aspects. On the one hand, the unified price strategy primarily focuses on pricing methods and market strategies and has a limited direct impact on the environment. It pays more attention to the economic benefits and market competition of enterprises and less directly involves the consumption and emission of environmental resources. Therefore, from this perspective, the environmental impact of the unified price strategy is not significant. On the other hand, the unified price strategy supported by blockchain technology, although enhanced by the high efficiency and transparency of blockchain technology, has an impact on the environment that is not single and stable. The operation of blockchain technology consumes a lot of energy and may produce certain carbon emissions. At the same time, the application of blockchain technology may also lead to an increase in hardware waste and a challenge to data storage, which will have a certain impact on the environment. However, the size of this impact depends on the specific implementation of blockchain technology and is related to energy-saving and emission-reduction measures.
Therefore, when developing a pricing strategy, a port should not only consider economic benefits and market competition, but also fully evaluate its impact on the environment. Port needs to realize that any business activity may have a direct or indirect impact on the environment. Therefore, environmental sustainability should be taken into consideration when formulating strategies to ensure that ports can contribute to environmental protection while pursuing economic benefits. Furthermore, when introducing new technologies such as blockchain, ports should not only focus on improving efficiency and transparency but also consider the environmental challenges it may bring. While promoting the application of technology, ports should take corresponding measures to reduce energy consumption, emissions, and waste management to minimize the adverse impact on the environment.

5.2. Influence of Tariffs on Incumbent Port

In this part, we adopt the tariff in the incumbent port, namely as an inside border port. Specifically, we redescribe the profit function based on the U model as follows:
π 1 U T = p 1 U T q 1 U T + q 3 U T 1 + T w 1 U T q 3 U T
In this case, Port 1 needs to pay the across-border fee T from Port 2’s quantity. The case is based on a realistic situation. For example, Yantian Port and Kwai Tsing Port are combined modes of water and water transport. In order to improve the transportation efficiency, we can consider adopting the employment method to realize the circulation of goods between the two ports. At this time, it is equivalent to the state that the goods need to pass through customs and pay customs tariffs. Therefore, we can obtain Proposition 7 between the U model and U-T model.
Proposition 7.
(Influence of tariffs on incumbent port): π 1 U < π 1 U T .
Proposition 7 shows the influence of tariffs on an incumbent port, which refers to the inside border port for Port 1. Specifically, first of all, the addition of tariffs may affect the cargo quantity of the port. If tariffs increase the import cost, the quantity of imported goods may decrease, thus reducing the cargo quantity of the port. However, if the addition of tariffs promotes the export of some commodities, the cargo quantity of the port may increase, which in turn will promote the port’s benefit. Secondly, the addition of tariffs may change the value of goods and the demand for services. High tariffs may lead to higher prices of imported goods, thus increasing the demand for high-value goods and services, such as stricter warehousing and logistics requirements. This may prompt the port to offer more professional and high-end services, thereby increasing the port’s revenue. Finally, the addition of tariffs may also affect the operational efficiency of the port. More complex processes and procedures often accompany the introduction of tariffs, and ports need to improve their operational efficiency to cope with these changes. If the port can optimize the process and improve service efficiency, it can maintain or even improve its benefits even under the challenge brought by tariffs.
Based on the above analysis, we can obtain the three aspects of management implication. First of all, port managers should pay close attention to the change in tariff policy and analyze its influence on cargo quantity, cargo value, and service demand, so as to adjust port operation strategy in time. Secondly, it is very important to improve the operational efficiency and service quality of the port. Under the tariff policy, ports need to optimize processes and improve service efficiency to cope with complex import and export procedures and higher service demand. Finally, the port should actively explore diversified development, reducing its dependence on a single source of trade by expanding into new business areas and service models, thereby enhancing its anti-risk ability and market competitiveness.

5.3. Influence of Port Cooperation on Incumbent Port

In this part, we analyze the port cooperation of Port 1 and Port 2, which aims to simulate the cooperation between regional ports, such as the same operational part (e.g., Hutchison Port Holdings in the Yantian Port and Kwai Tsing Port) or unified regional port policy (e.g., Shandong Port integration policy in China). Based on these cases in reality, we reset the model as π 1 U J = π 1 U + π 2 U , which means centralized decision-making in ports. Furthermore, we discuss the relationship between the new model U-J and the U model in Proposition 8.
Proposition 8.
(Influence of port cooperation on incumbent port): π U J > < π 1 U .
Proposition 8 shows the influence of port cooperation on the incumbent port from Port 1, the inside border port. Specifically, the result is π U J > < π 1 U , which shows inconsistency of the results. The potential reasons may have three aspects. Firstly, centralized decision-making may bring a scale effect and increase market bargaining power, but it may also lead to regulatory pressure and limit pricing power due to market monopoly. Although the inside border port is small in terms of market size, it may maintain a certain market share due to its flexibility or special services. Secondly, although centralized decision-making helps to unify procurement and reduce cost, it may also lead to decreased efficiency due to increased management complexity. An inside border port may have lower operating costs or enjoy cost advantages due to geographical advantage. Thirdly, centralized decision-making binds the fate of the two ports together, which is riskier. Once the market changes or policies are adjusted, it may affect the whole system. An inside border port is more independent and adaptable and can adjust its strategies to cope with market changes more quickly.
Therefore, from a management implication perspective, we can identify two aspects. On the one hand, managers at the inside border port should recognize that flexibility should not be overlooked while pursuing economies of scale. Although centralized decision-making can bring advantages in scale, it may also slow down the response speed to market changes because it is too large. Therefore, managers need to find a balance between the two, not only to ensure economies of scale, but also to maintain sufficient flexibility to cope with market changes. On the other hand, whether centralized decision-making or local management (e.g., inside border port), risk management is very important. Centralized decision-making may bring greater risks because it involves more resources and interests. Therefore, managers need to establish a sound risk management system to identify, evaluate, and monitor potential risks to ensure the stability and sustainability of decision-making. At the same time, local management cannot ignore risk management, and it needs to be vigilant at all times to guard against various potential risks.

6. Conclusions

In this study, we analyze unified price or differential price in the port system, which discusses the possible strategy of competition and cooperation between regional ports. Moreover, we also show the technical value of blockchain services in the data sharing of market information between an inside border port and outside border port. Furthermore, the expansion of port capacity can reduce congestion at the internal border port to some extent under specific conditions. Finally, we also analyze some other cases, including the environmental impact, tariff impact, and influence of port cooperation, which further give some management implications for the inside border port (also called the incumbent port within).
Based on the above main points, we can further put forward some new management implications for the inside border port. On the one hand, from the perspective of the synergy strategy from within the port, the port can adopt a differential price strategy to increase its benefits. The strategic synergy is not only the pursuit of the scale effect, but more importantly, how to achieve differentiated competition through synergy. When the two ports make centralized decisions, they can jointly study market demand, formulate differentiated development strategies, and avoid homogenized competition, thereby giving full play to their respective advantages and enhancing their overall competitiveness. Inside border ports can also utilize their unique advantages, such as geographical location, policy differential superiority, or special services, to complement centralized decision-making ports and jointly explore the market.
On the other hand, in the face of a changing market environment, centralized decision-making for ports in different regions needs to pay attention to innovation management and technology application. By introducing new technologies (such as blockchain technology for data sharing) and optimizing management processes, the port operation efficiency can be improved, the cost can be reduced, and the service quality can be improved to meet the diversified needs of customers.
In this study, we mainly discussed two cases of price models with the empowerment of blockchain technology in different regions of the ports. Furthermore, we also discussed how the impact of digital upgrading on regional port services, especially when there are cross-border goods, will be more complicated to analyze. Furthermore, in the uncertain environment of an inside border port, we can use the asymmetry theory to explain the influence of competition and cooperation on ports. Moreover, future work could employ agent-based models to explore how pricing and blockchain adoption evolve in heterogeneous port networks or under learning-based decision frameworks. Finally, to increase the credibility and persuasiveness of the research conclusions, future studies can employ empirical tests to reflect the actual performance of port competition and cooperation.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, H.Z. and C.L.; methodology, H.Z.; software, H.Z. and C.L.; formal analysis, H.Z. and C.L.; investigation, H.Z. and C.L.; resources, H.Z. and C.L.; writing—original draft preparation, H.Z. and C.L.; writing—review and editing, H.Z. and C.L.; visualization, H.Z.; supervision, C.L.; project administration, C.L.; funding acquisition, H.Z. and C.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (72404190); The National Social Science Foundation of China (23CGL077); Guangdong Basic and Applied Basic Research Foundation (2023A1515110302); Guangdong Planning Office of Philosophy and Social Science (GD24YGL09); Shenzhen Key Research Base of Humanities and Social Sciences; Shenzhen Peacock Pengcheng Talents Funding; and Shenzhen University Young Teachers Research Initiation Project (000001032153, GY00007).

Data Availability Statement

No data was used for the research described in the article.

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the editors and anonymous reviewers for their constructive comments.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that there are no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.

Appendix A

In the appendix, we provide the basic results and proof of the analytical results to explain the calculation and analysis process.

Appendix A.1. Proof of Basic Results

Based on the model setting in the manuscript, the optimal results can be obtained.
In the U model:
p 1 U = a β 2 b Γ 2 β 2 b 2 Γ
p 2 U = a 1 b β 2 Γ 2 β 2 b 2 Γ
w 1 U = a 2
q 1 U = a β 2 b Γ β 2 b 2 Γ a 2
q 2 U = a 1 b Γ 2 b 2 Γ β
q 3 U = a 2
π 1 U = 1 4 a 2 2 β 2 b Γ 2 β 2 b 2 Γ 2 1
π 2 U = 1 4 a 2 1 2 1 b 2 β 2 Γ Γ β 2 b 2 Γ 2
In the D model:
p 1 D = a β 2 b Γ β + 3 b β 2 1 + 3 b b Γ 2 1 + b β 2 1 + 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ
p 2 D = a 1 b β 2 Γ 2 + b β 2 2 b 1 + b Γ 2 1 + b β 2 1 + 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ
p 3 D = a 5 + b 2 b 2 β 2 20 + b 3 b 17 4 b Γ β + 2 10 + b 13 b 2 + 5 b 3 Γ 2 2 1 + b β 2 1 + 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ
w 1 D = a 1 b β 2 Γ 1 + b β 2 + 3 b 2 b 2 Γ 2 1 + b β 2 + 8 8 b + 5 b 2 + b 3 Γ β + 2 4 + 4 b 5 b 2 b 3 + b 4 Γ 2
q 1 D = a β 2 b Γ 2 + b β 2 2 b 1 + b Γ 1 + b β 2 1 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ
q 2 D = a b 1 Γ 2 + b β 2 2 b 1 + b Γ 1 + b β 2 1 + 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ
q 3 D = a β 2 Γ β 2 b Γ 1 + b β 2 1 + 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ
π 1 D = a 2 β 2 b Γ 2 5 + 8 b + 3 b 2 β 2 4 1 + b 2 5 2 b Γ β + 4 5 + 8 b b 2 4 b 3 + b 4 Γ 2 2 2 β 4 b 2 Γ 2 1 + b β + 2 1 b + b 2 Γ 2
π 2 D = a 2 1 b β 2 Γ β + 2 2 + b Γ 2 2 β 4 b 2 Γ 1 + b β + 2 1 b + b 2 Γ
In the U-B model:
p 1 U B = a β 2 b Γ β 2 b 2 Γ θ 2 β 2 1 θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2
p 2 U B = a β 2 Γ β 2 b β θ Γ 2 + 4 + b + b 2 b 3 θ + b θ 2 2 β 2 1 θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2
w 1 U B = a 2
q 1 U B = a β 2 1 + θ 4 Γ β 1 + 1 b θ + Γ 2 4 4 + 8 b 2 b 3 + b 4 θ + b 2 θ 2 2 β 2 1 θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2
q 2 U B = a Γ β 2 b β θ Γ 2 + 4 + b + b 2 b 3 θ + b θ 2 β 2 1 θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2
s U B = a β 2 b Γ β Γ 2 b θ β 2 1 θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2
q 3 U B = a 2
π 1 U B = a 2 β 2 1 + θ 2 Γ β 2 + 2 3 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 4 + 12 b 6 b 2 + b 4 θ + b 2 θ 2 4 β 2 1 θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2
π 2 U B = a 2 2 β + 2 + b Γ 2 1 + θ β + Γ 2 + b θ 2 2 β 2 Γ Γ β + 2 + b β θ Γ 2 + 4 + b + b 2 b 3 θ + b θ 2 2 + β 2 1 + θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2 2 4 β 2 1 + θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2 2
In the U-BE model:
p 1 U B E = a 2 + F 2 + b Γ + F β + 2 + b Γ 4 + b 2 Γ + 2 F β + 3 + b 2 Γ + F 2 β + 2 + b 2 Γ θ 2 Γ 2 8 + 16 + 8 b 8 b 2 + b 4 θ 2 b 2 θ 2 + F 2 β 2 2 + 4 θ + 2 β Γ 10 + 16 5 b + 5 b 2 θ + Γ 2 36 + 52 + 36 b 36 b 2 + 6 b 4 θ 9 b 2 θ 2 + F Γ 4 β 2 + 4 b + b 2 θ + Γ 28 + 4 12 + 7 b 7 b 2 + b 4 θ 7 b 2 θ 2 + F 3 β 2 3 + 4 θ + 4 β Γ 4 + 5 2 b + 2 b 2 θ + Γ 2 20 + 4 6 + 5 b 5 b 2 + b 4 θ 5 b 2 θ 2 + F 4 β 2 1 + θ + 2 β Γ 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2
p 2 U B E = a F β 2 Γ 2 Γ Γ 4 + 12 2 b 2 b 2 + b 3 θ 2 b θ 2 + F 3 β + 2 + b β θ Γ 2 + 4 + b + b 2 b 3 θ + b θ 2 + F 2 β 3 + 7 + 3 b θ Γ 8 + 18 + 4 b + 4 b 2 3 b 3 θ + 4 b θ 2 + F 2 β 1 + 3 + b θ Γ 10 + 26 + 5 b + 5 b 2 3 b 3 θ + 5 b θ 2 2 Γ 2 8 + 16 + 8 b 8 b 2 + b 4 θ 2 b 2 θ 2 + F 2 β 2 2 + 4 θ + 2 β Γ 10 + 16 5 b + 5 b 2 θ + Γ 2 36 + 52 + 36 b 36 b 2 + 6 b 4 θ 9 b 2 θ 2 + F Γ 4 β 2 + 4 b + b 2 θ + Γ 28 + 4 12 + 7 b 7 b 2 + b 4 θ 7 b 2 θ 2 + F 3 β 2 3 + 4 θ + 4 β Γ 4 + 5 2 b + 2 b 2 θ + Γ 2 20 + 4 6 + 5 b 5 b 2 + b 4 θ 5 b 2 θ 2 + F 4 β 2 1 + θ + 2 β Γ 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2
w 1 U B E = a 2
q 1 U B E = a ( Γ 2 8 16 b θ + 2 b 3 θ b 4 θ + 2 b 2 θ 2 + θ + F 4 β 2 1 + θ + 4 Γ β 1 + 1 + b θ + Γ 2 4 4 + 8 b 2 b 3 + b 4 θ + b 2 θ 2 + F 3 β 2 3 + 2 θ 2 Γ β 8 + 6 8 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 20 4 4 + 10 b b 2 2 b 3 + b 4 θ + 5 b 2 θ 2 + F Γ 2 β 4 4 b θ + b 2 θ + Γ 28 4 2 + 14 b 3 b 2 2 b 3 + b 4 θ + 7 b 2 θ 2 + F 2 2 β 2 4 Γ β 5 + 2 5 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 36 + 20 72 b + 12 b 2 + 12 b 3 6 b 4 θ + 9 b 2 θ 2 2 Γ 2 8 + 16 + 8 b 8 b 2 + b 4 θ 2 b 2 θ 2 + F 2 β 2 2 + 4 θ + 2 Γ β 10 + 16 5 b + 5 b 2 θ + Γ 2 36 + 52 + 36 b 36 b 2 + 6 b 4 θ 9 b 2 θ 2 + F Γ 4 β 2 + 4 b + b 2 θ + Γ 28 + 4 12 + 7 b 7 b 2 + b 4 θ 7 b 2 θ 2 + F 3 ( β 2 3 + 4 θ + 4 Γ β 4 + 5 2 b + 2 b 2 θ + Γ 2 20 + 4 6 + 5 b 5 b 2 + b 4 θ 5 b 2 θ 2 ) + F 4 β 2 1 + θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2
q 2 U B E = a 1 + F Γ Γ 4 12 2 b 2 b 2 + b 3 θ + 2 b θ 2 + F 3 β 1 + 2 + b θ + Γ 2 + 4 + b + b 2 b 3 θ + b θ 2 + F 2 β 3 + 7 3 b θ + Γ 8 + 18 + 4 b + 4 b 2 3 b 3 θ + 4 b θ 2 + F 2 β 1 + 3 + b θ + Γ 10 + 26 + 5 b + 5 b 2 3 b 3 θ + 5 b θ 2 Γ 2 8 16 + 8 b 8 b 2 + b 4 θ + 2 b 2 θ 2 + F 4 β 2 1 + θ + 2 β Γ 2 + 2 + b b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ + b 2 θ 2 F 3 β 2 3 4 θ 4 β Γ 4 + 5 2 b + 2 b 2 θ + Γ 2 20 4 6 + 5 b 5 b 2 + b 4 θ + 5 b 2 θ 2 + F Γ 4 β 2 + 4 b + b 2 θ + Γ 28 4 12 + 7 b 7 b 2 + b 4 θ + 7 b 2 θ 2 + F 2 ( β 2 2 4 θ 2 β Γ 10 + 16 5 b + 5 b 2 θ + Γ 2 36 2 26 + 18 b 18 b 2 + 3 b 4 θ + 9 b 2 θ 2
q 3 U B E = a 2
s U B E = a 1 + F 2 + F F β + 2 + b 1 + F Γ F β 2 Γ 2 F Γ + b 1 + F Γ θ 1 + F 2 + F F β 2 1 + F Γ 2 + F 2 2 + F 2 β 2 + 2 F 1 + F 2 + F 1 + b b 1 + F 2 2 + F β Γ + 1 + F 2 b 4 1 + F 2 + 4 b 1 + F 2 + F 4 b 2 1 + F 2 + F + 4 2 + F 2 Γ 2 θ b 2 1 + F 3 2 + F Γ 2 θ 2
π 1 U B E = F + a 2 Γ 2 8 24 b θ b 4 θ + 2 b 2 θ 6 + θ + F 4 β 2 1 + θ 2 β Γ 2 + 2 3 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 4 + 12 b 6 b 2 + b 4 θ + b 2 θ 2 + F 3 β 2 3 + 2 θ 4 β Γ 4 + 3 6 b + 2 b 2 θ + Γ 2 20 + 16 60 b + 30 b 2 4 b 4 θ + 5 b 2 θ 2 + F Γ 4 β 2 3 b θ + b 2 θ + Γ 28 + 8 84 b + 42 b 2 4 b 4 θ + 7 b 2 θ 2 + F 2 2 β 2 2 β Γ 10 + 4 15 b + 5 b 2 θ + Γ 2 36 + 20 108 b + 54 b 2 6 b 4 θ + 9 b 2 θ 2 4 Γ 2 8 + 16 + 8 b 8 b 2 + b 4 θ 2 b 2 θ 2 + F 2 β 2 2 + 4 θ + 2 β Γ 10 + 16 5 b + 5 b 2 θ + Γ 2 36 + 52 + 36 b 36 b 2 + 6 b 4 θ 9 b 2 θ 2 + F Γ 4 β 2 + 4 b + b 2 θ + Γ 28 + 4 12 + 7 b 7 b 2 + b 4 θ 7 b 2 θ 2 + F 3 ( β 2 3 + 4 θ + 4 β Γ 4 + 5 2 b + 2 b 2 θ + Γ 2 20 + 4 6 + 5 b 5 b 2 + b 4 θ 5 b 2 θ 2 ) + F 4 β 2 1 + θ + 2 β Γ 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2
π 2 U B E = 1 4 a 2 1 2 ( 1 + F ) 2 ( 2 + F ) 2 ( F β + ( 2 + b ) ( 1 + F ) Γ ) 2 ( 1 θ ) ( F β 2 Γ 2 F Γ + b ( 1 + F ) Γ θ ) 2 ( 1 + F ) ( 2 + F ) ( F β 2 ( 1 + F ) Γ ) 2 ( F 2 ( 2 + F ) 2 β 2 + 2 F ( 1 + F ) ( 2 + F ) ( ( 1 + b ) b ( 1 + F ) 2 ( 2 + F ) ) β Γ + ( 1 + F ) 2 ( b 4 ( 1 + F ) 2 + 4 b ( 1 + F ) ( 2 + F ) 4 b 2 ( 1 + F ) ( 2 + F ) + 4 ( 2 + F ) 2 ) Γ 2 ) θ + b 2 ( 1 + F ) 3 ( 2 + F ) Γ 2 θ 2 ) 2 + 2 ( 1 + F ) Γ ( F β + 2 Γ + 2 F Γ ) ( Γ ( 4 ( 12 2 b 2 b 2 + b 3 ) θ + 2 b θ 2 ) + F 3 ( β ( 1 + ( 2 + b ) θ ) + Γ ( 2 + ( 4 + b + b 2 b 3 ) θ + b θ 2 ) ) + F 2 ( β ( 3 + ( 7 3 b ) θ ) + Γ ( 8 + ( 18 + 4 b + 4 b 2 3 b 3 ) θ + 4 b θ 2 ) ) + F ( 2 β ( 1 + ( 3 + b ) θ ) + Γ ( 10 + ( 26 + 5 b + 5 b 2 3 b 3 ) θ + 5 b θ 2 ) ) ) 2 Γ 2 ( 8 + ( 16 + 8 b 8 b 2 + b 4 ) θ 2 b 2 θ 2 ) + F 2 ( β 2 ( 2 + 4 θ ) + 2 β Γ ( 10 + ( 16 5 b + 5 b 2 ) θ ) + Γ 2 ( 36 + ( 52 + 36 b 36 b 2 + 6 b 4 ) θ 9 b 2 θ 2 ) ) + F Γ ( 4 β ( 2 + ( 4 b + b 2 ) θ ) + Γ ( 28 + 4 ( 12 + 7 b 7 b 2 + b 4 ) θ 7 b 2 θ 2 ) ) + F 3 ( β 2 ( 3 + 4 θ ) + 4 β Γ ( 4 + ( 5 2 b + 2 b 2 ) θ ) + Γ 2 ( 20 + 4 ( 6 + 5 b 5 b 2 + b 4 ) θ 5 b 2 θ 2 ) ) + F 4 ( β 2 ( 1 + θ ) + 2 β Γ ( 2 + ( 2 b + b 2 ) θ ) + Γ 2 ( 4 + ( 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 ) θ b 2 θ 2 ) ) ) 2
In the U-T model:
p 1 U T = a β 2 b Γ 2 β 2 b 2 Γ
p 2 U T = a 1 b β 2 Γ 2 β 2 b 2 Γ
w 1 U T = a 2
q 1 U T = a β 2 b Γ β 2 b 2 Γ a 2
q 2 U T = a 1 b Γ 2 b 2 Γ β
q 3 U T = a 2
π 1 U T = 1 4 a 2 2 β 2 b Γ 2 β 2 b 2 Γ 2 1 T
π 2 U T = 1 4 a 2 1 2 1 b 2 β 2 Γ Γ β 2 b 2 Γ 2
In the U-J model:
p 1 U J = a 2
p 2 U J = a 2
w 1 U J = a q 3 U J
q 1 U J = a β 2 1 b Γ β 2 Γ + 4 b 2 Γ q 3 U J
q 2 U J = a 1 2 b Γ β 2 Γ + 4 b 2 Γ
q 2 U J = a 1 2 b Γ β 2 Γ + 4 b 2 Γ
Here, we show an example to describe the process of the optimal solution. In the U model, we set the mathematical expression p 1 U = a q 1 U b q 2 U q 3 U + q 1 U + q 3 U K 1 , p 2 U = a q 2 U b q 1 U + q 3 U + β q 2 U K 2 , w 1 U = a q 3 U . According to the assumption, we can obtain simplified expressions as p 1 U = a q 1 U b q 2 U q 3 U + q 1 U + q 3 U 2 , p 2 U = a q 2 U b q 1 U + q 3 U + β q 2 U 2 Γ , w 1 U = a q 3 U . The profit functions as π 1 U = p 1 U q 1 U + q 3 U w 1 U q 3 U and π 2 U = p 2 U q 2 U + w 1 U q 3 U . Therefore, the inverse demand function is substituted into the profit expression, and the first-order partial derivatives of q 1 U and q 2 U are obtained, respectively.
π 1 U q 1 U = a q 1 U b q 2 U q 3 U
π 2 U q 2 U = a b q 1 U + q 3 U q 2 U 2 β Γ
Here, we can obtain the optimal solution for q 1 U and q 2 U when they simultaneously equal to 0.
q 1 U * = a β 2 b Γ β 2 b 2 Γ q 3 U
q 2 U * = a 1 b Γ 2 b 2 Γ β
The value of the second-order Hessian matrix needs to meet the condition that the determinant value is greater than 0. The condition that can be satisfied is β 2 b 2 < Γ < 1 . Based on these values, we can obtain the optimal values for inverse demand functions. Moreover, we can obtain the optimal quantity for q 3 U * = a 2 under the condition of the maximum profit function π 2 U for q 3 U . Hence, we can obtain the optimal solutions about profit, prices, and quantities, respectively. Finally, we need to ensure that all output values are greater than 0 with the condition of β 2 b 2 < Γ < 1 . In this case, we can obtain the optimal solutions about the U model. Similarly, we can calculate the optimal value of the discussion scenario.

Appendix A.2

Proof of Proposition 1.
According to the optimal results for the U model and D model, we can obtain the analysis results of service prices from upstream and downstream prices. Specifically, comparing the service price of both the U model and D model, it was determined that a = 1 . The other discussion parameters can support all output results with positive value.
(1)
w 1 U w 1 D = a 2 a 1 b β 2 Γ 1 + b β + 2 3 b + 2 b 2 Γ 2 1 + b β 2 + 8 8 b + 5 b 2 + b 3 Γ β + 2 4 + 4 b 5 b 2 b 3 + b 4 Γ 2 > < 0 ;
(2)
p 1 U p 1 D = a β 2 b Γ 2 β 2 b 2 Γ a β 2 b Γ β + 3 b β 2 1 + 3 b b Γ 2 1 + b β 2 1 + 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ > < 0 ;
(3)
p 2 U p 2 D = a 1 b β 2 Γ 2 β 2 b 2 Γ a 1 b β 2 Γ 2 + b β 2 2 b 1 + b Γ 2 1 + b β 2 1 + 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ > 0
(4)
p 1 U p 1 D + p 3 D / 2 = a β 2 b Γ 2 β 2 b 2 Γ a 3 b β + 3 2 b Γ 4 β 2 4 b 2 Γ > 0 ;
Here, we give an example to support the results. In the relationship between w 1 U and w 1 D , we can obtain the difference function of two values as follows.
w 1 U w 1 D = a b 2 1 + b β 2 6 + 9 b 5 b 2 Γ β + 2 2 + 5 b 5 b 2 + b 3 Γ 2 2 2 β 4 Γ + b 2 Γ β + b β 2 Γ 2 b Γ + 2 b 2 Γ
According to the value range of the parameters, the denominator 2 β 4 Γ + b 2 Γ β + b β 2 Γ 2 b Γ + 2 b 2 Γ can be confirmed to be greater than 0. However, the result of 2 1 + b β 2 6 + 9 b 5 b 2 Γ β + 2 2 + 5 b 5 b 2 + b 3 Γ 2 cannot judge the size relationship between it and 0. Therefore, the results are greater than 0 or less than 0. Similarly, we can obtain the other results regarding service prices.
Therefore, we can prove Proposition 1 based on the above. □

Appendix A.3

Proof of Proposition 2.
According to the optimal results for the U model and D model, we can obtain the analysis result of service quantity. Specifically, we compare the service quantities with the U and D models, where it was determined that a = 1 . The other discussion parameters can support all output results with positive value.
(1)
q 1 U q 1 D = a β 2 b Γ β 2 b 2 Γ a 2 a β 2 b Γ 2 + b β 2 2 b 1 + b Γ 1 + b β 2 1 + 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ < 0 ;
(2)
q 2 U q 2 D = a 1 b Γ 2 b 2 Γ β + a 1 b Γ 2 + b β 2 2 b 1 + b Γ 1 + b β 2 1 + 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ > 0 ;
(3)
q 3 U q 3 D = a 2 a β 2 Γ β 2 b Γ 1 + b β 2 1 + 1 b b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ > 0 ;
(4)
q 1 U q 1 D + q 3 D / 2 = a β 2 b Γ β 2 b 2 Γ a 2 a 3 + b β 2 + 12 b + 3 b 2 Γ β + 2 6 b 3 b 2 + b 3 Γ 2 2 2 β 4 b 2 Γ 1 + b β + 2 1 b + b 2 Γ < 0
Therefore, we can prove Proposition 2 based on the above. □

Appendix A.4

Proof of Proposition 3.
According to the optimal results for the U model and D model, we can obtain the analysis result of economic benefit. Specifically, we compare the profit of the ports with the U and D models, where it was determined that a = 1 . The other discussion parameters can support all output results with positive value.
(1)
π 1 U π 1 D = 1 4 a 2 1 + 2 β 2 b Γ 2 β 2 b 2 Γ 2 2 β 2 b Γ 2 5 + 8 b + 3 b 2 β 2 4 1 + b 2 5 2 b Γ β + 4 5 + 8 b b 2 4 b 3 + b 4 Γ 2 2 β 4 b 2 Γ 2 1 + b β + 2 1 b + b 2 Γ 2 < 0
(2)
π 2 U π 2 D = 1 4 a 2 1 2 1 b 2 β 2 Γ Γ β 2 b 2 Γ 2 2 1 b β 2 Γ β 2 2 b Γ 2 β 4 b 2 Γ 1 + b β + 2 1 b + b 2 Γ > 0
Therefore, we can prove Proposition 3 based on the above. □

Appendix A.5

Proof of Proposition 4.
According to the optimal results for the U-B model and D model, we can obtain the analysis results of economic benefit. Specifically, we compare the profit of the ports with the U-B and D models, where it was determined that a = 1 . The other discussion parameters can support all output results with positive value.
(1)
π 1 U B π 1 D = 1 4 a 2 2 β + 2 + b Γ 2 5 + 8 b + 3 b 2 β 2 + 4 1 + b 2 5 + 2 b Γ β + 4 5 + 8 b b 2 4 b 3 + b 4 Γ 2 2 β + 4 + b 2 Γ 2 1 + b β + 2 1 b + b 2 Γ 2 β 2 1 + θ 2 Γ β 2 + 2 3 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 4 + 12 b 6 b 2 + b 4 θ + b 2 θ 2 β 2 1 + θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2 > < 0 ;
(2)
π 2 U B π 2 D = 1 4 a 2 2 1 + b β 2 Γ β + 2 2 + b Γ 2 β + 4 + b 2 Γ 1 + b β + 2 1 b + b 2 Γ 2 β + 2 + b Γ 2 1 + θ β + Γ 2 + b θ 2 2 β 2 Γ Γ β + 2 + b β θ Γ 2 + 4 + b + b 2 b 3 θ + b θ 2 2 + β 2 1 + θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2 2 β 2 1 + θ + 2 Γ β 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2 2 > < 0
According to the above analysis, we further describe the comparing result by figure in Figure 1 from the views of optimal strategy and equilibrium strategy, respectively.
According to Figure 1, we can obtain the equilibrium strategy using the D model. Therefore, we can prove Proposition 4 based on the above. □

Appendix A.6

Proof of Proposition 5.
In this section, we discuss the results of the decision of expansion for the incumbent port. Based on the manuscript, we can obtain C 1 i ,   i = U , U B E , representing the port congestion of different scenarios. We can also obtain
C 1 U = 1 2 a β 2 Γ β + 2 + b Γ 1 + b β + 2 1 + 1 + b b Γ 2 β + 4 + b 2 Γ + a β + 2 + b Γ 2 + b β + 2 2 + b 1 + b Γ 1 + b β + 2 1 + 1 + b b Γ 2 β + 4 + b 2 Γ
and
C 1 U B E = 1 2 a 2 + a ( Γ 2 8 16 b θ + 2 b 3 θ b 4 θ + 2 b 2 θ 2 + θ + F 4 β 2 1 + θ + 4 Γ β 1 + 1 + b θ + Γ 2 4 4 + 8 b 2 b 3 + b 4 θ + b 2 θ 2 + F 3 β 2 3 + 2 θ 2 β Γ 8 + 6 8 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 20 4 4 + 10 b b 2 2 b 3 + b 4 θ + 5 b 2 θ 2 + F Γ 2 β 4 4 b θ + b 2 θ + Γ 28 4 2 + 14 b 3 b 2 2 b 3 + b 4 θ + 7 b 2 θ 2 + F 2 2 β 2 4 β Γ 5 + 2 5 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 36 + 20 72 b + 12 b 2 + 12 b 3 6 b 4 θ + 9 b 2 θ 2 2 Γ 2 8 + 16 + 8 b 8 b 2 + b 4 θ 2 b 2 θ 2 + F 2 β 2 2 + 4 θ + 2 β Γ 10 + 16 5 b + 5 b 2 θ + Γ 2 36 + 52 + 36 b 36 b 2 + 6 b 4 θ 9 b 2 θ 2 + F Γ 4 β 2 + 4 b + b 2 θ + Γ 28 + 4 12 + 7 b 7 b 2 + b 4 θ 7 b 2 θ 2 + F 3 β 2 3 + 4 θ + 4 β Γ 4 + 5 2 b + 2 b 2 θ + Γ 2 20 + 4 6 + 5 b 5 b 2 + b 4 θ 5 b 2 θ 2 + F 4 β 2 1 + θ + 2 β Γ 2 + 2 b + b 2 θ + Γ 2 4 + 4 + 4 b 4 b 2 + b 4 θ b 2 θ 2 ,
respectively. Therefore, we compare C 1 i ,   i = U , U B E with the U and U-BE models as follows:
(1)
The F is small, e.g., F = 3 / 50 : C 1 U > < C 1 U B E .
(2)
The F is max, e.g., F = 7 / 100 : C 1 U > C 1 U B E .
Therefore, we can prove Proposition 5 based on the above. □

Appendix A.7

Proof of Proposition 6.
In this subsection, we consider the influence of the environment on port activity. Therefore, we compare the ports’ environmental impacts with the U and U-B models.
E I U E I U B = a β + 2 + b Γ β 3 3 + b + 1 + b θ + β Γ 2 36 + 2 6 + b b 2 + 4 7 b 2 + b 4 θ + 1 + b b 2 + b θ 2 + β 2 Γ 18 + 4 θ + 1 + b b 3 + 3 + b θ + 2 2 + b Γ 3 6 + b 3 θ 2 2 b 2 1 + θ b 2 + θ + θ 2 1 + b β + 2 1 + 1 + b b Γ 2 β + 4 + b 2 Γ β 2 1 + θ + 2 β Γ 2 + 2 + b 1 + b θ + Γ 2 4 + θ 4 + b 4 + b 3 b 4 + θ > < 0
Therefore, we can prove Proposition 6 based on the above. □

Appendix A.8

Proof of Proposition 7.
The proof process is similar to Proposition 4, so it is omitted. □

Appendix A.9

Proof of Proposition 8.
The proof process is similar to Proposition 4, so it is omitted. □

References

  1. Theo, N.; Pallis, A.; Rodrigue, J.-P. Port Economics, Management and Policy; Routledge: New York, NY, USA, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  2. Ma, Q.; Jia, P.; She, X.; Haralambides, H.; Kuang, H. Port integration and regional economic development: Lessons from China. Transp. Policy 2021, 110, 430–439. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Meng, H.; Xu, H.; Cui, Y.; Liu, J. International container intermodal competitiveness: An empirical study from Chinese hub ports. Ocean Coast. Manag. 2024, 254, 107178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Gu, B.; Liu, J.; Ye, X.; Gong, Y.; Chen, J. Data-driven approach for port resilience evaluation. Transp. Res. Part E. Logist. Transp. Rev. 2024, 186, 103570. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Liu, J.; Wang, X.; Chen, J. Port congestion under the COVID-19 pandemic: The simulation-based countermeasures. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2023, 183, 109474. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Wang, J.; Xu, S.; He, F. Independence or alliance? Shipping lines’ capacity configuration and strategies analysis facing market disturbance risk. Marit. Policy Manag. 2024, 51, 1764–1787. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Chen, K.; Guo, J.; Xin, X.; Zhang, T.; Zhang, W. Port sustainability through integration: A port capacity and profit-sharing joint optimization approach. Ocean Coast. Manag. 2023, 245, 106867. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Ardelean, A.; Lugovskyy, V. It pays to be big: Price discrimination in maritime shipping. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2023, 153, 104403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Southern Metropolis Daily. National Unified Market! Expert: Guangdong-Hong Kong-Macao Greater Bay Area Has an Advantage. Available online: https://m.mp.oeeee.com/a/BAAFRD000020220415672252.html (accessed on 10 June 2024).
  10. Zhang, Z.; Song, C.; Zhang, J.; Chen, Z.; Liu, M.; Aziz, F.; Kurniawan, T.A.; Yap, P.S. Digitalization and innovation in green ports: A review of current issues, contributions and the way forward in promoting sustainable ports and maritime logistics. Sci. Total Environ. 2024, 912, 169075. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  11. Wang, H.; Ruan, Y.; Niu, B.; Zhang, H. Intra-port demand coordination and inter-port competition: Ports’ pricing strategies with congestion concerns. Ocean Coast. Manag. 2024, 248, 106918. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Liu, J.; Zhang, H.; Zhen, L. Blockchain technology in maritime supply chains: Applications, architecture and challenges. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2023, 61, 3547–3563. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Zhao, H.; Liu, J.; Hu, X. Servitization with blockchain in the maritime supply chain. Ocean Coast. Manag. 2022, 225, 106195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Wang, J.; Liu, J.; Wang, F.; Yue, X. Blockchain technology for port logistics capability: Exclusive or sharing. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 2021, 149, 347–392. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Zheng, S.; Jiang, C. Consortium blockchain in Shipping: Impacts on industry and social welfare. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2024, 183, 104071. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Yu, M.; Tan, X.; Chen, J. Pricing competition in maritime transportation with blockchain technology and empty container repositioning. Adv. Eng. Inform. 2024, 59, 102318. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Nguyen, S.; Chen, P.S.L.; Du, Y. Blockchain adoption in container shipping: An empirical study on barriers, approaches, and recommendations. Mar. Policy 2023, 155, 105724. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Lu, B.; Fan, L.; Wang, H.; Moon, I. Price-cutting or incentive? Differentiated competition between regional asymmetric ports. Transp. Policy 2024, 147, 215–231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Xing, W.; Liu, Q.; Chen, G. Pricing strategies for port competition and cooperation. Marit. Policy Manag. 2018, 45, 260–277. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Zheng, S.; Luo, M. Competition or cooperation? Ports’ strategies and welfare analysis facing shipping alliances. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2021, 153, 102429. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Li, Z.C.; Wang, M.R.; Fu, X. Strategic planning of inland river ports under different market structures: Coordinated vs. independent operating regime. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2021, 156, 102547. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Song, Z.; Tang, W.; Zhao, R. Liner alliances with heterogeneous price level and service competition: Partial vs. full. Omega 2021, 103, 102414. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Xu, L.; Xie, F.; Wang, C. Passive or proactive capacity sharing? A perspective of cooperation and competition between two regional ports. Marit. Policy Manag. 2022, 49, 492–509. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Li, D.; Qu, Y.; Ma, Y. Study on the impact of subsidies for overlapping hinterland shippers on port competition. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2020, 135, 24–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Zheng, S.; Ge, Y.E.; Fu, X.; Nie, Y.M.; Xie, C. Demand information sharing in port concession arrangements. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 2020, 138, 118–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Xie, F.; Wang, C.; Xu, L. Whether to invest in terminal efficiency: A perspective considering customer preference and capital constraint in competitive environment? Ocean Coast. Manag. 2021, 205, 105563. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Zhang, K.; Choi, T.M.; Chung, S.H.; Dai, Y.; Wen, X. Blockchain adoption in retail operations: Stablecoins and traceability. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2024, 315, 147–160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Shen, L.; Yang, Q.; Hou, Y.; Lin, J. Research on information sharing incentive mechanism of China’s port cold chain logistics enterprises based on blockchain. Ocean Coast. Manag. 2022, 225, 106229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Wu, L.; Li, X.; Zhao, R.; Lu, W.; Xu, J.; Xue, F. A blockchain-based model with an incentive mechanism for cross-border logistics supervision and data sharing in modular construction. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 375, 133460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Zhang, C.; Zhu, Y.; Ren, X. Quality decision and demand information sharing: The role of blockchain adoption. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2024, 189, 109991. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Li, Z.; Xu, X.; Bai, Q.; Chen, C.; Wang, H.; Xia, P. Implications of information sharing on blockchain adoption in reducing carbon emissions: A mean–variance analysis. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2023, 178, 103254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Nanfang Daily. Greater Bay Area Combined Port Realizes Full Coverage of Nine Mainland Cities in the Bay Area. Available online: https://www.gd.gov.cn/gdywdt/dsdt/content/post_4281310.html (accessed on 10 June 2024).
  33. Li, X.; Zhao, Y.; Cariou, P.; Sun, Z. The impact of port congestion on ship emissions in Chinese ports. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2024, 128, 104091. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Gu, B.; Liu, J. COVID-19 pandemic, port congestion, and air quality: Evidence from China. Ocean Coast. Manag. 2023, 235, 106497. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  35. Shu, Y.; Xiong, C.; Zhu, Y.; Liu, K.; Liu, R.W.; Xu, F.; Gan, L.; Zhang, L. Reference path for ships in ports and waterways based on optimal control. Ocean Coast. Manag. 2024, 253, 107168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Guo, L.; Ng, A.K.; Jiang, C.; Long, J. Stepwise capacity integration in port cluster under uncertainty and congestion. Transp. Policy 2021, 112, 94–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Li, K.; Gharehgozli, A.; Lee, J.Y. Smart technologies and port operations: Optimal adoption strategy with network externality consideration. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2023, 184, 109557. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Xiao, Y.; Ng, A.K.; Yang, H.; Fu, X. An analysis of the dynamics of ownership, capacity investments and pricing structure of ports. Transp. Rev. 2012, 32, 629–652. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Niu, B.; Chen, K.; Chen, L.; Ding, C.; Yue, X. Strategic waiting for disruption forecasts in cross-border E-commerce operations. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2021, 30, 2840–2857. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Krass, D.; Nedorezov, T.; Ovchinnikov, A. Environmental taxes and the choice of green technology. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2013, 22, 1035–1055. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Niu, B.; Yu, X.; Shen, Z. Structure adjustment of automobile supply chain facing low-carbon emission standard. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2021, 171, 105629. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. (a) U model and (b) D model.
Figure 1. (a) U model and (b) D model.
Mathematics 13 02281 g001
Figure 2. The equilibrium strategy. (a) The optimal result for the incumbent port; (b) the optimal result for the outside border port; (c) the equilibrium results. Note: The values are a = 1 , θ = 0.7 , and b = 0.5 . The equilibrium strategy is the D model with marked blue zone in Figure 2c.
Figure 2. The equilibrium strategy. (a) The optimal result for the incumbent port; (b) the optimal result for the outside border port; (c) the equilibrium results. Note: The values are a = 1 , θ = 0.7 , and b = 0.5 . The equilibrium strategy is the D model with marked blue zone in Figure 2c.
Mathematics 13 02281 g002
Table 1. The main notations.
Table 1. The main notations.
SymbolRemarkSymbolRemark
Decision Variable
p 1 U , p 2 U , p 1 D , p 2 D Service price of Ports q 1 U , q 2 U , q 3 U , q 1 D , q 2 D , q 3 D Container quantity
w 1 U , w 1 D Service price from Port 1 to Port 2 s Blockchain service level
Parameter
b Competitive level of service quantity β Sensitivity of congestion for Port 2
Γ Degree of differentiation between Port 2’s capacity and Port 1’s capacity θ The openness of information supported by blockchain technology
Constant and benefit variable
K 1 , K 2 Ports’ capacity a Market size
π 1 U , π 1 D , π 2 U , π 2 D , π 1 U B , π 1 U T , π 1 U J Profit of ports E I Environment impact
T Unit tariff
Table 2. Profit function.
Table 2. Profit function.
U ModelD Model
Port 1 π 1 U = p 1 U q 1 U + q 3 U w 1 U q 3 U π 1 D = p 1 D q 1 D + p 3 D w 1 D q 3 D
Port 2 π 2 U = p 2 U q 2 U + w 1 U q 3 U π 2 D = p 2 D q 2 D + w 1 D q 3 D
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zhao, H.; Liu, C. Pricing Strategy and Blockchain-Enabled Data Sharing in Cross-Border Port Systems. Mathematics 2025, 13, 2281. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13142281

AMA Style

Zhao H, Liu C. Pricing Strategy and Blockchain-Enabled Data Sharing in Cross-Border Port Systems. Mathematics. 2025; 13(14):2281. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13142281

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zhao, Huida, and Chanjuan Liu. 2025. "Pricing Strategy and Blockchain-Enabled Data Sharing in Cross-Border Port Systems" Mathematics 13, no. 14: 2281. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13142281

APA Style

Zhao, H., & Liu, C. (2025). Pricing Strategy and Blockchain-Enabled Data Sharing in Cross-Border Port Systems. Mathematics, 13(14), 2281. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13142281

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop