Next Article in Journal
A Mathematical Interpretation of Autoregressive Generative Pre-Trained Transformer and Self-Supervised Learning
Next Article in Special Issue
Research on Decision Analysis with CVaR for Supply Chain Finance Based on Blockchain Technology
Previous Article in Journal
A Variant Iterated Greedy Algorithm Integrating Multiple Decoding Rules for Hybrid Blocking Flow Shop Scheduling Problem
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman Equation for Differential Games with Composite Distribution of Random Time Horizon
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Optimisation of Cycling Trends in Hamiltonian Systems of Economic Growth Models

by
Alexander Mikhailovich Tarasyev
1,2,†,
Anastasia Alexandrovna Usova
1,† and
Alexander Alexandrovich Tarasyev
2,*,†
1
Krasovskii Institute of Mathematics and Mechanics of Ural Branch of Russian Academy of Sciences, 16 S. Kovalevskaya Street, 620990 Yekaterinburg, Russia
2
Research Laboratory on the Problems of University Development, Research Department, Ural Federal University, 19 Mira Street, 620002 Ekaterinburg, Russia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
These authors contributed equally to this work.
Mathematics 2023, 11(11), 2452; https://doi.org/10.3390/math11112452
Submission received: 10 April 2023 / Revised: 14 May 2023 / Accepted: 23 May 2023 / Published: 25 May 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Application of Game Theory)

Abstract

:
The paper analyses dynamical growth models predicting the cyclic development of investigated economic factors. The provided research deals with an optimal control problem based on the economic growth model with the production function of Cobb–Douglas type. Following the Pontryagin maximum principle, we derived the Hamiltonian system and conducted its qualitative analysis, which reveals conditions for the cyclic behaviour of the optimal solutions around the isolate steady state. Numerical experiments visually illustrated the obtained results by demonstrating a phase portrait corresponding to a steady state of the focal type.

1. Introduction

The paper investigated stabilised solutions of an optimal control problem [1,2] that is based on an economic growth model [3,4]. More precisely, the work focused on the case when a steady state has the focal character and applies theoretical results [5,6] of a qualitative behaviour of the Hamiltonian systems to the specific growth model. At the end of the past and the beginning of the present century, optimal control problems found their wide application in economics [1,2,3,4]. This was caused by the usage of dynamical principles for designing economical models to predict scenarios of economic development (see [7]). Moreover, optimal control approaches have the opportunity to pursue a certain goal in the design of different scenarios of economic development and reveal the ways to achieve this goal by choosing specific control regimes (see [1,2,4,8]. For example, this goal can be the maximisation of the cumulative consumption level, the maximisation of an output, or cost optimisation. Often, models are aimed at constructing long-term forecasts that lead to the analysis of the corresponding control problems at the infinite time interval and to the study of the limit character of the optimal trends [1,9,10,11]. Therefore, we concentrated on the limit behaviour of an optimal solution when time goes to infinity. The present paper describes a classical growth model [1,2,3,4] and analysed conditions under which the economic development of some region has the cyclic character. The research operated with the Hamiltonian systems arising in the Pontryagin maximum principle, which was applied to a control problem of an optimal distribution of investments directed to the production factors. Production factors determine the output by means of the production function. The quality of the control process is estimated by the integral consumption index of logarithmic type discounted on the infinite time interval [1,3,8,10,12]. In these types of problems, the Jacobi matrix of a Hamiltonian system has a property that allows for making twice less the degree of its characteristic polynomial (see [5,6,13]). Using this property, we derived the condition for a cyclic behaviour of optimal trajectories around an isolate steady state. It is worth mentioning the previous works [2,9,10,14] that deal with a steady state having a saddle character. The paper is organized as follows: the next section describes a growth model and poses the problem, then we construct the Hamiltonian function and discuss its properties. The third section analyses the corresponding Hamiltonian system and its Jacobian. Using properties of the Jacobi matrix, we investigated conditions for the focal character of a steady state. As an example, we provide a numerical example illustrating theoretical results.

2. Growth Model

The paper investigated an optimal control problem that is based on an economic growth model aimed at the analysis of the gross domestic product (GDP) Y = Y ( t ) , depending on production factors such as capital stock K = K ( t ) and labour L = L ( t ) , where parameter t stands for time. The relationship between the output (GDP) and the production factors is determined by the production function Y = f ( K , L ) .
Labour L = L ( t ) is a share of the employed population of a region P [4], i.e., L = E · P , where the positive coefficient E = E ( t ) is the labour efficiency. The capital dynamics depends on savings S = S ( t ) and the positive capital depreciation rate δ (1):
K ˙ ( t ) = S ( t ) δ K ( t ) , K ( 0 ) = K 0 .
The labour L = L ( t ) changes due to the investments R = R ( t ) in increasing the labour efficiency E = E ( t ) (2):
L ˙ ( t ) = b R ( t ) , L ( 0 ) = L 0 .
Under the condition of the closedness of the economy, for any moment of time t, investments S ( t ) = u 1 ( t ) Y ( t ) and R ( t ) = u 2 ( t ) Y ( t ) cannot exceed the output; thus, we have the restrictions (3):
Y ( t ) > S ( t ) + R ( t ) = ( u 1 ( t ) + u 2 ( t ) ) Y ( t ) 0 0 u 1 ( t ) + u 2 ( t ) < 1 .
Shares u 1 ( t ) and u 2 ( t ) of GDP invested in the capital K ( t ) and labour L ( t ) are nonnegative. Moreover, we assume that there exist two nonnegative constants a 1 and a 2 such that (4):
0 u 1 ( t ) a 1 < 1 , 0 u 2 ( t ) a 2 < 1 .
Let symbol U indicate the domain for investment shares u = u 1 , u 2   U = [ 0 , a 1 ] × [ 0 , a 2 ] . Following the work [4], we suppose that the employed population exponentially grows, i.e., P ˙ ( t ) = γ P ( t ) , where γ is a positive growth rate.
Introduce relative variables y ( t ) , x 1 ( t ) , x 2 ( t ) as GDP Y ( t ) , capital K ( t ) , and labour L ( t ) per one worker (5), i.e.,:
y ( t ) = Y ( t ) P ( t ) , x 1 ( t ) = K ( t ) P ( t ) , x 2 ( t ) = L ( t ) P ( t ) E ( t ) .
Due to the property of the production function Y = f ( K , L ) of positive homogeneity, in new variables it has the form (6):
y ( t ) = F ( K ( t ) , L ( t ) ) P ( t ) = f ( x 1 ( t ) , x 2 ( t ) ) = f ( x ( t ) ) ,
where symbol x ( t ) denotes the vector of phase variables x = x 1 , x 2 .
The dynamics of per capita capital x 1 ( t ) and the labour efficiency x 2 ( t ) satisfy the Equations (7) and (8):
x ˙ 1 ( t ) = u 1 ( t ) y ( t ) ( δ + γ ) x 1 ( t ) , x 1 ( t 0 ) = x 1 0 ,
x ˙ 2 ( t ) = b u 2 ( t ) y ( t ) γ x 2 ( t ) , x 2 ( t 0 ) = x 2 0 .
It is assumed that the per capita output y = f ( x ) has the properties commonly corresponding to a production function. Function f ( x ) is a twice continuously differentiable, increasing, strictly concave function in its variables x 1 and x 2 . The last property of strict concavity means the Hessian matrix (9) is negative definite:
H f = f x 1 2 ( x ) f x 1 x 2 ( x ) f x 1 x 2 ( x ) f x 2 2 ( x ) < 0 .
Due to the closedness of the economy system (see (3)), we can derive the consumption level as the difference between total output and investments in capital and labour efficiency (10):
C ( t ) = Y ( t ) ( 1 u 1 ( t ) u 2 ( t ) ) .
In relative variables, this equality can be rewritten as follows (11):
c ( t ) = C ( t ) P ( t ) = y ( t ) ( 1 u 1 ( t ) u 2 ( t ) ) y ( t ) ( 1 u 1 ( t ) ) ( 1 u 2 ( t ) ) .
The estimate can be applied since the product u 1 · u 2 has a higher order of smallness than u i ( u i [ 0 , a i ] [ 0 , 1 ) , i { 1 , 2 } ).
Utility function is the integral index of logarithmic type discounted in the infinite time interval. This type of index measures the cumulative value of relative consumption, expressed in the currency of a region, adjusted for the amount of currency depreciation rate over the time (12).
J ( · ) = 0 + e ρ t ln ( 1 u 1 ( t ) ) + ln ( 1 u 2 ( t ) ) + ln f ( x ( t ) ) d t , ρ > 0 .
Here (12), the positive parameter ρ is a discount factor.
Proposition 1 (Assumption 1).
Population growth satisfies exponential law. Production F(K, L) is positive homogeneous of the first degree.
Based on the described model of economy development, one can pose the optimal control problem with the infinite horizon, where the investment shares u 1 , u 2 in production factors x 1 , x 2 , respectively, play the role of control parameters.
Problem 1 (Optimal Control Problem).
The problem is to synthesise such control strategies, u 0 ( t ) = u 1 0 ( t ) , u 2 0 ( t ) U , which maximise the utility function J ( · ) (12) along the trajectories x ( t ) = x 1 ( t ) , x 2 ( t ) of the dynamical system (7) and (8).

3. Control Problem Analysis

The posed problem satisfies all conditions of the existence theorem [11,15], and the optimality conditions for the problems in the infinite time interval within the Pontryagin maximum principle [1] (Theorem 18.2, p. 171).
The Hamiltonian function of the optimal control problem has the form (13)
H ˜ ( t , x , u , ψ ˜ ) = e ρ t ln ( 1 u 1 ) + ln ( 1 u 2 ) + ln f ( x ) + ψ ˜ 1 ( u 1 f ( x ) ( δ + γ ) x 1 ) + ψ ˜ 2 ( b u 2 f ( x ) γ x 2 ) .
Here, the conjugate variables ψ ˜ = ( ψ ˜ 1 , ψ ˜ 2 ) determine the “shadow prices” of capital x 1 and labour efficiency x 2 , respectively. However, for further analysis, we introduce adjusted “shadow prices” ψ 1 = e ρ t ψ ˜ 1 , ψ 2 = e ρ t ψ ˜ 2 and rewrite the Hamiltonian function as follows: H ^ ( · ) = e ρ t H ˜ ( · ) . This change of conjugate variables excludes time variable t from the Hamiltonian function (14),
H ^ ( x , u , ψ ) = ln ( 1 u 1 ) + ln ( 1 u 2 ) + ln f ( x ) + ψ 1 ( u 1 f ( x ) ( δ + γ ) x 1 )   +   ψ 2 ( b u 2 f ( x ) γ x 2 ) .
According to [14], the Hamiltonian function H ^ ( x , u , ψ ) (14) has the following properties:
P1.
The Hamiltonian H ^ ( x , u , ψ ) (14) is strictly concave in control variables u 1 and u 2 .
This property together with the compactness of the control domain U ensures the existence of maximum of the Hamiltonian in control variables.
P2.
The maximised Hamiltonian H ( x , ψ ) can be constructed by the rule (15)
H ( x , ψ ) = max u U H ^ ( x , u , ψ ) = H ^ ( x , u i j , ψ ) , u i j 0 = ( u 1 i 0 , u 2 j 0 ) , ( x , ψ ) D i j = Δ 1 i Δ 2 j , ( i , j = 1 , 2 , 3 ) ,
where sets Δ 1 i and Δ 2 j are determined as follows (16):
Δ 1 1 = { ( x , ψ ) : ψ 1 f ( x ) 1 } , u 1 = 0 ; Δ 2 1 = { ( x , ψ ) : b ψ 2 f ( x ) 1 } , u 2 = 0 ; Δ 1 2 = ( x , ψ ) : 1 ψ 1 f ( x ) A 1 , u 1 0 = 1 1 ψ 1 f ( x ) ; Δ 2 2 = ( x , ψ ) : 1 b ψ 2 f ( x ) A 2 , u 2 0 = 1 1 b ψ 2 f ( x ) ; Δ 1 3 = ( x , ψ ) : ψ 1 f ( x ) A 1 , u 1 0 = a 1 ; Δ 2 3 = ( x , ψ ) : b ψ 2 f ( x ) A 2 , u 2 0 = a 2 .
Here, constant A i is equal to A i = ( 1 a i ) 1 , i { 1 , 2 } . Thus, the maximised Hamiltonian H ( x , ψ ) has nine branches H i j ( x , ψ ) . Moreover, each branch is determined in the domain D i j under the controls ( u 1 i 0 , u 2 j 0 ) , i , j { 1 , 2 , 3 } .
P3.
The maximised Hamiltonian H ( x , ψ ) is a smooth function of its variables x 1 , x 2 , ψ 1 , ψ 2 .
P4.
The maximised Hamiltonian H ( x , ψ ) is a strictly concave function in phase variables x 1 and x 2 for all positive values of the conjugate variables ψ 1 > 0 , ψ 2 > 0 in any domains D i j , i , j = 1 , 2 , 3 except the domain D 22 of the non-constant control regime u 12 0 , u 22 0 . In domain D 22 , strict concavity of the maximised Hamiltonian takes place if the matrix f is negative definite (17):
f ( x ) = f ( x ) f x 1 ( x ) f x 2 ( x ) f x 1 ( x ) f x 1 2 ( x ) f x 1 x 2 ( x ) f x 2 ( x ) f x 1 x 2 ( x ) f x 2 2 ( x ) ( x , ψ ) D 22 , ψ 1 > 0 , ψ 2 > 0 .
The mentioned properties of the maximised Hamiltonian H ( x , ψ ) guarantee that the necessary optimality conditions (in [1]) are sufficient for the optimality [2,9].

4. Hamiltonian System

According to the Pontryagin maximum principle, we construct the Hamiltonian system by the rule (18):
x ˙ i ( t ) = H ( x ( t ) , ψ ( t ) ) ψ i , ψ ˙ i ( t ) = ρ ψ i ( t ) H ( x ( t ) , ψ ( t ) ) x i , i = 1 , 2 , 3 .
Applying formulae (18) to the investigated problem, the Hamiltonian system has the form (19):
x ˙ 1 ( t ) = u 1 0 ( t ) f ( x ( t ) ) ( δ + γ ) x 1 ( t ) = G 1 ( x ( t ) , ψ ( t ) ) x ˙ 2 ( t ) = b u 2 0 ( t ) f ( x ( t ) ) γ x 2 ( t ) = G 2 ( x ( t ) , ψ ( t ) ) ψ ˙ 1 ( t ) = ( δ + γ + ρ ) ψ 1 ( t ) f x 1 ( x ( t ) ) 1 f ( x ( t ) ) + u 1 0 ( t ) ψ 1 ( t ) + b u 2 0 ( t ) ψ 2 ( t ) = G 3 ( x ( t ) , ψ ( t ) ) ψ ˙ 2 ( t ) = ( γ + ρ ) ψ 2 ( t ) f x 2 ( x ( t ) ) 1 f ( x ( t ) ) + u 1 0 ( t ) ψ 1 ( t ) + b u 2 0 ( t ) ψ 2 ( t ) = G 4 ( x ( t ) , ψ ( t ) ) .
Relying on the results in [14], the steady state may exist in any domain D i j with non-zero controls, i.e., i , j 2 . We pay attention to the case in which a steady state belongs the domain of variable controls D 22 , which is described by the formula (20):
D 22 = ( x , ψ ) : 1 ψ 1 f ( x ) 1 1 a 1 , 1 b ψ 2 f ( x ) 1 1 a 2 .
The Hamiltonian system in the domain D 22 (20) has the form (21):
x ˙ 1 ( t ) = f ( x ( t ) ) ( δ + γ ) x 1 ( t ) 1 ψ 1 ( t ) = G 1 ( x ( t ) , ψ ( t ) ) x ˙ 2 ( t ) = b f ( x ( t ) ) γ x 2 ( t ) 1 ψ 2 ( t ) = G 2 ( x ( t ) , ψ ( t ) ) ψ ˙ 1 ( t ) = ( δ + γ + ρ ) ψ 1 ( t ) ψ 1 ( t ) + b ψ 2 ( t ) 1 f ( x ( t ) ) f x 1 ( x ( t ) ) = G 3 ( x ( t ) , ψ ( t ) ) ψ ˙ 1 ( t ) = ( γ + ρ ) ψ 2 ( t ) ψ 1 ( t ) + b ψ 2 ( t ) 1 f ( x ( t ) ) f x 2 ( x ( t ) ) = G 4 ( x ( t ) , ψ ( t ) ) .
Next, we provide a qualitative analysis of the system (21) assuming the existence of an isolated steady state belonging the domain of variable control regime D 22 .
Remark 1.
For the model with the Cobb–Douglas production function y = f ( x ) = : μ x 1 α x 2 β , a steady state ( x , ψ ) does always exist (see [14]). The same work provides sufficient conditions guaranteeing belongingness of the steady state ( x , ψ ) to the domain D 22 (20).
Proposition 2.
Let the system (21) have the only steady state ( x , ψ ) and the following conditions on the maximum level of investment shares take place (22):
a c a 1 < 1 , a c a 2 < 1 , where a c = δ + γ δ + γ + ρ ;
then, the steady state ( x , ψ ) belongs the domain of variable control regime D 22 (20).
Remark 2.
The steady state x and the corresponding controls ( u 1 , u 2 ) satisfying (22) and equal to the following values (23),
u 1 = ( δ + γ ) x 1 f ( x ) , u 2 = γ b x 2 f ( x ) ,
are an equilibrium solution of the optimal control problem.
The next step is to determine a type of the steady state ( x , ψ ) .

4.1. Qualitative Analysis of a Steady State

Within the qualitative analysis of the Hamiltonian system, let us calculate Jacobi matrix J (24) at the steady state ( x , ψ ) .
J = G x 1 G ψ 1 G x 2 G ψ 2 ,
where partial derivatives (25) are:
G x 1 = G i ( x , ψ ) x j i , j = 1 2 , G ψ 1 = G i ( x , ψ ) ψ j i , j = 1 2 , G x 2 = G 2 + i ( x , ψ ) x j i , j = 1 2 , G ψ 2 = G 2 + i ( x , ψ ) ψ j i , j = 1 2 .
Partial derivatives of the right-hand parts G i ( x , ψ ) , ( i = 1 , , 4 ) of the system (21) satisfy Formulae (26):
G x 1 = f x 1 f x 2 b f x 1 b f x 2 δ + γ 0 0 γ , G ψ 1 = ψ 1 0 0 ψ 2 2 , G ψ 2 = G x 1 T + ρ E 2 G x 2 = 1 f 2 ( x ) ( f x 1 ) 2 f x 1 f x 2 f x 1 f x 2 ( f x 2 ) 2 ψ 1 + b ψ 2 1 f ( x ) f x 1 2 ( x ) f x 1 x 2 ( x ) f x 1 x 2 ( x ) f x 2 2 ( x ) .
Jacobi matrix (26) has some useful properties for estimating its eigenvalues. These properties are based on the notion of the Hamiltonian matrix. There are several equivalent definitions of a Hamiltonian matrix; however, for the considered problem the next definition is more convenient to use.
Definition 1.
A block matrix M of the form M = A B C A 2 n × 2 n is said to be Hamiltonian if its blocks B and C are symmetric sub-matrices.
The most valuable properties of a Hamiltonian matrix are listed below.
 PH1. 
Characteristic polynomial is an even function.
 PH2. 
Eigenvalues of a Hamiltonian matrix are symmetric with respect to the imaginary axis.
 PH3. 
If blocks B and C are positive-definite matrices then the Hamiltonian matrix M does not have purely imaginary eigenvalues (see [13]).
 PH4. 
If blocks B and C are positive definite matrices then the determinant of the Hamiltonian matrix M satisfies the inequality (see [5]): ( 1 ) n det M det B det C > 0 .
In [5], the authors proved that the Jacobi matrix J (24)–(26) of the considered problem can be represented as the sum of Hamiltonian and diagonal matrices, i.e., J = M + ρ / 2 E 4 . Consequently, the eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix and the Hamiltonian matrix are tied to equality λ J = λ M + ρ / 2 . Blocks G ψ 1 and G x 2 of the Jacobi matrix (24)–(26) are positive definite due to the property P4 of the maximised Hamiltonian function H ( x , ψ ) . Hence, the Hamiltonian matrix M = J ρ / 2 E 4 does not have purely imaginary eigenvalues. Finally, one can derive explicit formulae for eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix using the corresponding Hamiltonian matrix.
Theorem 1.
Characteristic polynomial det ( J λ E 4 ) = 0 of the Jacobi matrix J (24) can be reduced to the form (27):
τ 2 + a 2 τ + a 4 = 0 , a 2 = tr M 2 2 < 0 , a 4 = 1 4 ( 2 a 2 2 tr M 4 ) = det M > 0 ,
where new variable τ is related to λ by the equality τ = ( λ ρ / 2 ) 2 . Analysis of the quadratic polynomial (27) implies that four eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix are found by the formula (28):
λ 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 = ± τ 1 , 2 + ρ / 2 , i f a 2 2 4 a 4 , r ± cos ( φ / 2 ) ± i sin ( φ / 2 ) + ρ / 2 , i f a 2 2 < 4 a 4 ,
where τ 1 , 2 = a 2 ± a 2 2 4 a 4 / 2 , r = a 4 and φ = arctan 4 a 4 / a 2 2 1 .
Next, we performed the analysis of the model parameters which cause the cyclic behaviour of the optimal trajectories around the steady state. In other words, we paid attention to the case in which the discriminant D = a 2 2 4 a 4 of the quadratic Equation (27) is strictly negative.

4.2. Numerical Results for Cobb-Douglass Production Function

Let us consider the Cobb–Douglas production function of the form y = f ( x ) : = μ x 1 α x 2 β , where parameters α , β , and their sum α + β belong to interval ( 0 , 0.5 ) . In [14], one can find a detailed analysis of this problem with the Cobb–Douglas production function. We focused on the analysis of the discriminant D as a function of model parameter ρ . Elements of the matrix M in (27) depend on ρ , thus (29):
D ( ρ ) = a 2 2 4 a 4 = tr M 4 1 2 tr 2 M 2 , where M = M ( ρ ) .
Figure 1 demonstrates the discriminant as a function of the discount factor ρ . One can see that there exists a range for the parameter ρ , when the discriminant D = D ( ρ ) is strictly negative. According the experimental data, this range can be estimated as ( 0 , 0.055 ) . Selecting parameter ρ at the level of 5 % , we solved the Hamiltonian system stabilised (see [5,6]) around the steady state. One can see the phase portrait of the stabilised solution in Figure 2. Obviously, the phase trajectory has a spiral-form cyclically converging to the steady state. Thus, under the small values of the discount factor, optimal trends of the growth model may behave cyclically. Here, we provide numerically the effect of time-dependent control on the system by the values of u 1 ( t ) and u 2 ( t ) (Figure 3 and Figure 4), which are given in Equation (16) for the Cobb–Douglas production function in the focal equilibrium (see (23)).

5. Conclusions

The paper described the two-factors growth model behaving in a cyclic way under some values of the discount factor. Based on the qualitative analysis of the Hamiltonian system and its relation with the Hamiltonian matrix, we explicitly found the eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix. It provides the possibility of considering the discriminant of the characteristic polynomial as a function of the chosen parameter (in this case, it is the discount factor). Next, performing a numerical analysis of the discriminant function, we estimated the range of the cyclic behaviour of the system. Finally, solving the stabilised Hamiltonian system with the parameter selected from the obtained range, we are convinced that the trajectory has a spiral form.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, A.M.T.; Data curation, A.A.T.; Formal analysis, A.A.U.; Investigation, A.M.T., A.A.U. and A.A.T.; Methodology, A.M.T., A.A.U. and A.A.T.; Project administration, A.M.T.; Software, A.A.U.; Supervision, A.M.T.; Validation, A.M.T., A.A.U. and A.A.T.; Visualization, A.A.U. and A.A.T.; Writing—original draft, A.M.T., A.A.U. and A.A.T.; Writing—review & editing, A.M.T. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

Research of A.M. Tarasyev and A.A. Usova is supported by the Russian Scientific Foundation, Project No 19-11-00105. https://rscf.ru/en/project/19-11-00105/ (accessed on 3 February 2023). Research of A.A. Tarasyev is supported by the research funding from the Ministry of Science and Higher Education of the Russian Federation (Ural Federal University project within the Priority-2030 Program).

Data Availability Statement

Data available in a publicly accessible repository that does not issue DOIs Publicly available datasets were analyzed in this study. This data can be found here: [https://rosstat.gov.ru/compendium] (accessed on 3 February 2023).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Aseev, S.M.; Kryazhimskiy, A.V. The Pontryagin maximum principle and optimal economic growth problems. Proc. Steklov Inst. Math. 2007, 257, 1–255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Aseev, S.M.; Veliov, V.M. Another view of the maximum principle for optimal control problems with an infinite horizon in economics. Successes Math. Sci. 2019, 74, 3–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Ayres, R.; Warr, B. The Economic Growth Engine: How Energy and Work Drive Material Prosperity; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  4. Sanderson, W.C. The SEDIM Model: Version 0.1; IIASA Interim Report; IR-04-041; IIASA: Laxenburg, Austria, 2004; pp. 1–42. [Google Scholar]
  5. Tarasyev, A.; Usova, A. Structure of the Jacobian in economic growth models. IFAC-PapersOnLine 2015, 48, 191–196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Tarasyev, A.; Usova, A. Robust methods for stabilization of Hamiltonian systems in economic growth models. IFAC-PapersOnLine 2018, 51, 7–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Bagliano, F.-C.; Bertola, G. Models for Dynamic Macroeconomics; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  8. Tarasyev, A.; Zhu, B. Optimal proportions in growth trends of resource productivity. IFAC-PapersOnLine 2012, 45, 182–187. [Google Scholar]
  9. Palokangas, T. Optimal Taxation with Endogenous Population Growth and the Risk of Environmental Disaster. In Dynamic Economic Problems with Regime Switches, 1st ed.; Haunschmied, J.L., Kovacevic, R.M., Semmler, W., Veliov, V.M., Eds.; Springer Nature: Cham, Switzerland, 2021; pp. 267–285. [Google Scholar]
  10. Tarasyev, A.; Usova, A. Construction of a regulator for the Hamiltonian system in a two-sector economic growth model. Proc. Steklov Inst. Math. 2010, 271, 1–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Balder, E. An existence result for optimal economic growth problems. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 1983, 95, 195–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Ledyaev, Y. On analytical solutions of matrix Riccati equations. Proc. Steklov Inst. Math. 2011, 273, 214–228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Paige, C.; Loan, C.V. A Schur decomposition for Hamiltonian matrices. Linear Algebra Appl. 1981, 41, 11–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Usova, A. Analysis of Properties of Hamiltonian Systems and Cost Functions in Dynamic Growth Models. Ph.D. Thesis, Krasovskii Institute of Mathematics and Mechanics of Ural Branch of Russian Academy of Sciences, Yekaterinburg, Russia, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  15. Grass, D.; Caulkins, J.P.; Feichtinger, G.; Tragler, G.; Behrens, D.A. Optimal Control of Nonlinear Processes; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2008. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. The discriminant as a function of ρ .
Figure 1. The discriminant as a function of ρ .
Mathematics 11 02452 g001
Figure 2. The stable cyclic behaviour.
Figure 2. The stable cyclic behaviour.
Mathematics 11 02452 g002
Figure 3. The effect of time-dependent control on the system by the value of u1(t).
Figure 3. The effect of time-dependent control on the system by the value of u1(t).
Mathematics 11 02452 g003
Figure 4. The effect of time-dependent control on the system by the value of u2(t).
Figure 4. The effect of time-dependent control on the system by the value of u2(t).
Mathematics 11 02452 g004
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Tarasyev, A.M.; Usova, A.A.; Tarasyev, A.A. Optimisation of Cycling Trends in Hamiltonian Systems of Economic Growth Models. Mathematics 2023, 11, 2452. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11112452

AMA Style

Tarasyev AM, Usova AA, Tarasyev AA. Optimisation of Cycling Trends in Hamiltonian Systems of Economic Growth Models. Mathematics. 2023; 11(11):2452. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11112452

Chicago/Turabian Style

Tarasyev, Alexander Mikhailovich, Anastasia Alexandrovna Usova, and Alexander Alexandrovich Tarasyev. 2023. "Optimisation of Cycling Trends in Hamiltonian Systems of Economic Growth Models" Mathematics 11, no. 11: 2452. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11112452

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop