Next Article in Journal
Comparing Push and Pull Factors Affecting Migration
Next Article in Special Issue
Spatial Market Integration: A Case Study of the Polish–Czech Milk Market
Previous Article in Journal
Muslim Clothing Online Purchases in Indonesia during COVID-19 Crisis
Previous Article in Special Issue
Socio-Economic Impact of the Interest-Free Community Investment Fund: A Case Study of Rural Sindh, Pakistan
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Effects of Insurance Adoption and Risk Aversion on Agricultural Production and Technical Efficiency: A Panel Analysis for Italian Grape Growers

by
Simone Russo
1,*,
Francesco Caracciolo
2 and
Cristina Salvioni
3
1
Department of Agriculture, Food, Natural Resources and Engineering (DAFNE), University of Foggia, 71122 Foggia, Italy
2
Department of Agricultural Sciences, University of Naples, Federico II, 80055 Portici, Italy
3
Department of Economics, University of Chieti-Pescara, 65127 Pescara, Italy
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2022, 10(1), 20; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10010020
Submission received: 6 December 2021 / Revised: 4 January 2022 / Accepted: 5 January 2022 / Published: 10 January 2022

Abstract

:
This article aims to evaluate the effect of insurance on production, technical efficiency, and input use of Italian specialised-quality grape growers. A panel instrumental variable stochastic frontier approach is applied over the years 2008–2017 using data from the Farm Accountancy Data Network. The results show the requirement to correct for the endogeneity that stems from insurance adoption. Insurance has an enhancing effect on production and efficiency and reduces the use of intermediate inputs. It suggests that insurance helps to diminish the risk-averse farmers’ suboptimal input use due to the presence of uncertainty. Crop insurance leads risk-averse farmers to behave as if they were risk neutral and employs the profit-maximising input vector. Therefore, by reducing the risks linked to the uncertainty of outcomes, crop insurance leads grape growers to go in the direction of profit maximisation.

1. Introduction

Agricultural production has always had to cope with uncertainty (Moschini and Hennessy 2001). Farmers make their resource allocation decisions in a complex environment made up of poorly controllable biological (diseases, insects, pests, weeds), environmental (i.e., weather, soil, and water conditions), and institutional (i.e., markets, legislation) factors. Additionally, economic, and financial markets, as well as the political and institutional environment, can be sources of uncertainty. In the future, it is expected that the exposure to risk in agriculture is likely to increase due to upcoming challenges related to land degradation and climate change (IPCC 2013; Raimondo et al. 2021). Such a situation explains the wide array of farming practices and management approaches available to the farmers to manage their risks at the farm level, basically involving three broad areas of farming decisions: production, marketing, and financial (Boehlje and Trede 1977; McConnell and Dillon 1997). These management approaches and practices include, among others: on- and off-farm diversification of income-generating activities (Chavas and Kim 2010; Corsi and Salvioni 2012; Bellon et al. 2020), inputs intensification (Foudi and Erdlenbruch 2012; Pagnani et al. 2021), varietal diversification (Di Falco and Chavas 2006; Gotor et al. 2021), vertical integration and contract farming (Hennessy 1996; Otsuka et al. 2016), forward contracting and futures hedging (Asplund et al. 1989), and finally crop insurance (Ahsan et al. 1982; Nelson and Loehman 1987; Ramaswami 1993). In this paper, we specifically focus on the latter, since crop insurance has recently been gaining the attention of policymakers, especially in the European Union with the recent development of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) (Enjolras et al. 2012; Santeramo et al. 2016; Vigani and Kathage 2019). Furthermore, crop insurance might cover different sources of uncertainty, supporting farmers in the process of adaptation to climate challenges (Di Falco et al. 2014).
Crop insurance represents one of the most investigated subjects in agricultural economics. There is a large amount of literature addressing crop insurance demand (Enjolras et al. 2012; Santeramo et al. 2016), pricing and subsidies (Skees et al. 1997; Lusk 2017), impact on farming decisions (Ahsan et al. 1982; Nelson and Loehman 1987; Ramaswami 1992; Mieno et al. 2018) and moral hazards (Horowitz and Lichtenberg 1993; Quiggin et al. 1993; Smith and Goodwin 1996). Additionally, there is wide range of literature examining the effect of crop insurance on input use (Wu 1999; Goodwin et al. 2004; Möhring et al. 2020a, 2020b) and input demand under crop insurance (Ramaswami 1993; Babcock and Hennessy 1996). More recently some attention, though still limited, has been directed towards the effective economic impact of crop insurance in terms of farming productivity (Vigani and Kathage 2019) or technical efficiency (Roll 2019). For instance, Roll estimated a stochastic production frontier to investigate whether insurance affects Norwegian salmon farming in terms of inputs use, productivity, and technical efficiency. Looking at the literature, the effects of insurance on input use are largely an empirical issue. Some authors found that insurance is positively related to input intensity (e.g., Horowitz and Lichtenberg 1993), while other studies found a negative relation (e.g., Quiggin et al. 1993; Smith and Goodwin 1996; Babcock and Hennessy 1996). Finally, Goodwin et al. (2004) found a positive and negative effects depending on the crop analysed.
In this paper, we intend to add to this latter stream of literature. Similar to Roll (2019), we explore the effect of expenditure in crop insurance on the production and technical efficiency of a nationally representative sample of Italian grape growers. More specifically, this paper aims to clarify whether insurance adoption might solve the risk-averse farmers’ suboptimal input use due to the presence of uncertainty. Of course, there is no simple answer to this: on one hand, crop insurance, by making risk-averse farmers prone to being risk neutral (Nelson and Loehman 1987; Ramaswami 1993), should facilitate optimal resource allocation, allowing farmers to maximise profit, enhance the production level, and to specialise their production (Ahsan et al. 1982), consequently improving their technical efficiency (Roll 2019). However, on the other hand, insurance adoption may incentivise farmers in reducing the number of safety measures against harm as a consequence of moral hazard (Horowitz and Lichtenberg 1993; Quiggin et al. 1993). This would result in a major exposure to risk and might reduce the production level and technical efficiency.
From a methodological point of view, using data from the Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN), a panel stochastic frontier estimation approach is implemented on a sample of commercial Italian farms specialising in the production of quality grapevines1 over the period 2008–2017. Different from previous studies, we account for the potential endogeneity of insurance, therefore providing more reliable parameter estimates (Karakaplan and Kutlu 2017a).
The dominant insurance schemes in Italian agriculture, as for grape growing, are single-peril (mainly hail) and multi-peril crop insurance (ISMEA 2018). Farmers pay a premium to cover yield damages caused by one or more eligible events listed in the Italian Insurance Plan. Premium per hectare varies in relation to the risk exposure of the farmer. A specific focus has been given to the grape growers because crop insurance has been widely adopted in this sector in Italy, which represents around 27% of the Italian crop insurance market in terms of monetary values and 14% in terms of land (ISMEA 2018). Additionally, it is widely assumed that the viticulture sector is exposed to many risks which are progressively increasing due to climate change. Global warming causes increases in temperature in grapevine regions. This may cause changes to the grape chemistry, and an increase in insects and insect-borne diseases (Mozell and Thachn 2014). Additionally, the increase in the frequency of extreme weather events such as rainfall, late frost, or hailstorms (IPCC 2013) has potentially negative effects on yields and wine quality, and increases income variability (Holland and Smit 2010).
The rest of this article is organised as follows. In the next section, we present a brief literature review on the role of risk in production choices. Then we introduce the methodology utilised with a focus on the endogeneity problem. Successively, we show the dataset and the model specification. We then show and discuss the results. The conclusions are presented in the final section.

2. Theoretical Background

Farmers choose the level of inputs to maximise profit before knowing the true state of nature; therefore, productive factors are allocated according to farmers’ risk perception and aversion (Roosen and Hennessy 2003). Risk-taking or risk-loving farmers would take an opportunity to gain a higher profit rather than taking a safer position, with the chance of sustaining a large loss. Vice versa, the risk-averse farmers prefer to avoid the worst possible outcome. Finally, risk-neutral farmers would hypothetically consider the weighted expected outcome of the different expected states of nature. Thus, risk aversion has direct consequences on the optimum resource-use level. To maximise profit, farmers should operate at the profit-maximising point, i.e., where the expected marginal value product of input equals the marginal factor cost. This is the risk-neutral farmer’s choice, while the risk-averse farmer operates at the position where profit is not being maximised except in “bad” seasons. In other words, risk aversion results in suboptimal economic decisions with respect to input allocation. The difference in input use of risk-averse and risk-neutral farmers depends on the marginal risk premium (MRP) (MacMinn and Holtmann 1983), which is the wedge between input cost and expected marginal product at the optimum level of input use. In general, the sign of MRP depends on risk preferences and technology. MRP is positive if the use of the input increases the production uncertainty (risk increasing input). MRP is negative when the input is risk-decreasing (MacMinn and Holtmann 1983; Ramaswami 1992). Consequently, in the single-input single-output case, the risk-averse level of input use is higher (lower) than the risk-neutral level of input use if the input is risk-decreasing (increasing) (Nelson and Loehman 1987). In farm decision-making, fertilisers are often considered risk-increasing inputs (Just and Pope 1979; Pope and Kramer 1979) while pesticides and herbicides are usually considered risk-decreasing (Möhring et al. 2020b).
This study aims to evaluate the effect of crop insurance on grape producers’ decision-making process. Crop insurance has the potential to affect both the input (Nelson and Loehman 1987; Ramaswami 1993) and output choices (Ahsan et al. 1982) with consequences for production and technical efficiency (Roll 2019). On one hand insurance may enhance the farming results, allowing input choice independent of the farmer’s preference function over uncertain outcomes (Nelson and Loehman 1987). The purchase of insurance induces risk-averse farmers to behave as if they were risk neutral and choose the optimal quantity of inputs by setting the expected marginal product of inputs to its opportunity cost (Ahsan et al. 1982). According to Ramaswami (1993), this is due to the risk reduction effect of the insurance adoption, which reduces the wedge between expected marginal product and input price and makes farmers adjust input application in the direction of risk-neutral levels, i.e., to increase the level of input if risk-increasing and to decrease the input use if risk-decreasing. The risk reduction effect implies that the mean output could increase or decrease depending on the nature of the production technology.
On the other hand, the possible existence of a moral hazard may alter insured farmers’ optimal decisions (Quiggin et al. 1993). More specifically, a moral hazard may reduce the input used independently of whether it is risk-reducing or risk-increasing (Ramaswami 1993). Moral hazard decreases the mean expected output because the insurance contract reduces the loss associated with the insured event and may change the farmer’s behaviour. As a result, farmers reduce the precautions to cope with risk since there are much fewer consequences for an incident. Therefore, when the input is risk-decreasing, insurance increases the riskiness of output and decreases the expected output, while if it is risk-increasing this effect will depend on the effect of moral hazard and risk reduction effects.
With regards to output choice, farmers tend to allocate more resources to insured cultivation and, in more detail, will specialise in the production of higher-value risky activities that can be insured (Ahsan et al. 1982) According to this view, Roll (2019) found that insured farmers might gain from greater specialisation since they do not need to diversify their activities to manage their idiosyncratic risk. The higher specialisation achieved by insurance adoption might explain the increase in technical efficiency. On the other hand, the moral hazard could lead to a change in the farmers’ ordinary behaviour, influencing the quality and the intensity of the production factors. These actions, including the managerial effort devoted to farming activities, will have a direct consequence on technical efficiency, limiting the impact of the specialisation achievable by insurance (Kirkley et al. 1998).
This paper aims to tackle the above-mentioned dilemma about the effect of crop insurance on inputs use and technical efficiency of a nationally representative sample of Italian grape growers. The following section will clarify the methodological approach employed and the data used for the analysis.

3. Data and Methodology

3.1. Methods

The foundations of efficiency analysis started from the contribution of Farrell (1957), and since the 1960s it was extensively applied to analyse the way production inputs are combined into valuable outputs. Efficiency analysis can involve a parametric estimate of the production function as independently proposed by Aigner et al. (1977) and Meeusen and van Den Broeck (1977) through the stochastic frontier models. These models are composed of a deterministic part identifying the frontier (i.e., the maximum output obtainable, given the available technology and input levels) and of a stochastic part including a two-sided error term, and a one-sided inefficiency error term: the latter identifies the distance from the stochastic frontier. Battese and Coelli (1995) implemented a stochastic frontier production function for panel data, which accounts for potential unobserved heteroscedasticity, and includes environmental variables in the inefficiency distribution. Accordingly, the frontier equation was specified as:
ln yit = β0 + ∑k βk ln xkit + vit − uit
where yit is the logarithm of the output of the i-th farm at time t; xkit is a vector of k inputs and other explanatory variables of the i-th farm at time t; β is a vector of k unknown parameters to be estimated; vit is a two-side error term capturing the standard random errors, and uit is a non-negative error term associated with the technical inefficiency effects. In turn, the variance of technical inefficiency (uit) can be assumed to be a function of a set of s explanatory variables (zsit), a conformable vector of coefficients to be estimated (δ), and a random term (ω) as in the following equation:
σ2uit = δ0 + ∑s δs ln zsit + ωit.
When analysing production and efficiency it is important to account for the potential endogeneity of the explanatory variables to obtain unbiased estimates of technical efficiency (Shee and Stefanou 2014; Amsler et al. 2016; Karakaplan and Kutlu 2017b). According to Vigani and Kathage (2019), there are different potential endogeneity sources regarding insurance adoption in the estimation of the production frontier. Potential endogeneity may arise due to reverse causality between the adoption of risk management tools and productivity (Ramaswami 1993). For instance, bigger farms are more likely to have the financial and human resources to adopt risk-management practices (Vigani and Kathage 2019). As for Italian farmers, the adoption of crop insurance has been demonstrated to be influenced by farm performance, total assets, and financial leverage (Enjolras et al. 2012; Santeramo et al. 2016). Furthermore, insurance adoption is voluntary and not randomly assigned and therefore may be adopted by farms that find it most useful. This means that insured farmers are self-selected, i.e., they have common unobservable characteristics influencing both the performance and adoption choice. This will lead to inconsistent estimates of the impact of insurance on farm production (Di Falco and Veronesi 2013). To deal with endogeneity issues, we follow the general maximum likelihood-based approach proposed by Karakaplan and Kutlu (2017a). These authors start from the model proposed by Battese and Coelli (1995) described in Equations (1) and (2) above and developed an endogenous panel stochastic frontier model which handles endogenous variables in both the frontier and/or in the inefficiency by using an instrumental variable approach. Unlike the standard control function methods where estimations are performed in two stages, authors estimated the parameters using a single maximum likelihood function, gaining statistical efficiency2. Additionally, a potential source of endogeneity may arise from the substitution effect between insurance and inputs since the adoption of insurance can increase the use of risk-increasing inputs and decrease the level of risk-decreasing inputs (Nelson and Loehman 1987; Ramaswami 1992). The most popular production functions used in the stochastic frontier analysis are Cobb-Douglas and translog. In this study we consider the translog functional to capture the substation effect of insurance.
Finally, to avoid the potential endogeneity due to omitted variables, we included other risk management tools in the model specification, namely irrigation and on-farm diversification. Previous studies have shown that farmers often adopt different risk management strategies and that the global risk mitigation effect is not necessarily equal to the sum of the effects of adopting each strategy separately (Wu and Babcock 1998).

3.2. Data

We used farm-level data for vine growers specialising in quality grape production, located in Italy and observed from 2008 to 2017. The data have been extracted from the FADN, which provides high-quality and consistent datasets of commercial farms, i.e., farms with an economic size, in terms of standard output3, exceeding EUR 8000 in the case of Italy. FADN consists of an annual survey aimed to provide representative data, harmonised among EU member states, along three dimensions: the region, economic size, and type of farming. Due to the rotation over the years of the observed farms in the sample, the dataset is an unbalanced panel.
By excluding observations with null or inconsistent values on the main variables of interest, our dataset was composed of 9419 observations of 2587 farms. The descriptive statistics of the variables included in the model are reported in Table 1.
Production refers to the total gross production of the grape, measured in euros. We use the monetary value of the output produced considering that grape growing in Italy evolved significantly towards higher-quality production (Urso et al. 2018). Land is measured in hectares and refers to the Utilised Agricultural Area (UAA). Capital is an aggregate, measured in euros, formed by working capital and real estate, less the farmland value to avoid problems of multicollinearity with land. Intermediate inputs, measured in euro, refer to expenditures on water, crop certification, fertilisers, pesticide, services, energy (fuel, electricity, and heating), marketing (materials, transport, and intermediation), and other generic expenses. Labour4 refers to the total number of hours worked per year in grape growing.
To investigate the insurance’s relation to production and efficiency we use expenses in crop insurance. Many previous studies used dummy variables to represent the farmers’ insurance decisions (e.g., Horowitz and Lichtenberg 1993; Smith and Goodwin 1996). Similar to Weber et al. (2016) and Möhring et al. (2020b), we use the intensity of insurance (measured by the amount of insurance premiums paid) to capture changes in the input use at different levels of insurance expenditures. Given that a significant number of observed farms have no expenses in crop insurance, we added the value one for uninsured farms to obtain the logarithm and not to incur biased results as suggested by Battese (1997). Battese (1997) has also shown that simply adding a small number may not be the most appropriate solution and proposed the inclusion of a dummy variable that takes a value of one when the input, insurance in our case, is not used. If the coefficient of such a dummy is statistically significant, then the intercepts of insured and uninsured farms are not equal, and the absence of the dummy will provide biased results. Additionally, to mitigate possible omitted variables bias we include a set of variables referring to risk-management tools that are an alternative to insurance, namely irrigation and on-farm agricultural and non-agricultural diversification. Irrigation is the percentage of irrigated over total land. Non-agricultural diversification is a dummy variable taking a value of one when the farm is producing non-agricultural services (agritourism, educational, etc.) in addition to farming. Agricultural diversification is a dummy variable taking a value of one when the farm produces other crops or livestock in addition to grape, and the value zero otherwise. The inclusion of such different risk mitigating strategies in addition to insurance allows us to avoid omitted variables bias since the global effect of adapting different risk strategies is not necessarily equal to the effect of adopting each strategy separately (Wu and Babcock 1998).
We also included a set of variables to control for additional sources of heterogeneity due to the environmental and economic characteristics of the farm. As for the location of the farm, there are three dummy variables referring to altimetry (plain, hill, and mountain) and four dummy variables for farms located in the Southern, Central, North-eastern, and North-western regions. Economic size is defined based on standard output and is divided into five classes: small (less than 25,000 euros), medium-small (25,000–50,000 euros), medium (50,000–100,000 euros), medium-large (100,000–500,000 euros), and large farms (over than 500,000 euros).
Table 2 shows the mean and standard deviation values of all variables included in the model, dividing the sample into insured and uninsured farms. As shown in Figure 1, production and input use are larger in terms of absolute value in insured than uninsured farms. Insured farms have a higher percentage of irrigated land, while there is no difference in the participation in both the agricultural and non-agricultural diversification strategies of the larger the economic size and the greater the percentage of insured farms. Finally, most of the insured farms are in the North-Eastern regions while insurance is less diffused in the South.

3.3. Empirical Strategies

The translog production frontier is specified as follows:
ln yit = β0* + ∑k βk ln xkit + ½ ∑kj βkj ln xkit ln xjit + βins ln insit + ½ βins2 ln ins2it + ∑k βkins ln xkit ln insit + βirr irrit + βdn dnit + βda dait + βt t + ½ βtt t2 + ∑k βkt ln xkit t + βtins ln insit t + vit − uit
where the dependent variable is the gross production of the i-th farm at time t. β are the parameters to be estimated. β0* contain the effects of constant term and control factors, i.e., economic size, altitude, and location. Four inputs (xkit) are included in the model: land, labour, capital, and intermediate inputs. Since the translog functional form, we also include inputs squares and interactions. In addition, we included the effect of the insurance expenditures (insit), its square, and the interactions with other inputs. The other risk management strategies, i.e., the percentage of irrigated land (irrit) and the two dummy variables referred to non-agricultural (dnit) and agricultural diversification (dait), are also included. Finally, a time trend (t) has been added to control for any technological change or innovations during the period analysed and to measure the effect of insurance on technological change (βtins).
The variance of technical inefficiency is specified as follows:
σ2uit = δ0* + δins ln insit + δirr irrit + δdn dnit + δda dait + δt t + ωit
where the variance of the non-negative error term uit is a function of expenditure in insurance (insit), irrigation (irrit), non-agricultural (dnit) and agricultural diversification (dait), and time trend (t) As before, δ0* includes the effects of constant term and other control factors, i.e., economic size, altitude, and location. The coefficient δins indicates the effect of insurance on technical efficiency. Since we estimate an inefficiency effect, a negative sign indicates that insurance increases efficiency and vice versa.
Finally, to deal with the potential endogeneity of insurance, we need to identify proper instrumental variables. Valid instruments need to be correlated with the endogenous variables, insurance expenditure, but uncorrelated with the error or inefficiency terms. Enjolras et al. (2012) have shown that the cost of insurance, i.e., the premium per hectare, has an influence on the demand for crop insurance in Italy. At the same time, the decision to become insured does not affect the overall demand for crop insurance at the provincial level. Hence, the insurance premium paid by each farmer affects both the production and efficiency. On the contrary, the average insurance premium at the provincial level is correlated with the endogenous variable (insurance), but it is uncorrelated with the error or inefficiency terms. Therefore, the average premium per hectare measured at the province level has been used to instrument insurance in the frontier and the efficiency equations.
As proposed by Karakaplan and Kutlu (2017a), another equation is estimated simultaneously to include the relationship between the endogenous variable, the instrumental variable, inputs included in the production frontier, time trend, and other risk-management tools. As in the previous equations, the effect of control variables is in the constant term.

4. Results

The endogeneity test indicates that insurance is endogenous, and correction is needed (X2 = 21.25; p < 0.0001)5. Therefore, we implemented the IV panel approach as proposed by Karakaplan and Kutlu (2017a). First, we assessed the instrument’s strength. The chi-squared statistic of the instrument in the prediction equation of insurance is 484.13, which is greater than 10 and passes the rule of thumb for not being a weak instrument. Additionally, we checked if the inclusion of the dummy variable is needed to allow for different intercepts for insured and uninsured farms and avoid biased results, as proposed by Battese (1997). The z statistic of the coefficient estimated for the dummy is −0.47 (p = 0.635). This indicates that the intercepts of insured and uninsured farms are equal, and the inclusion of the dummy is not necessary to obtain unbiased coefficient estimates.
The estimated parameters of the production frontier are presented in Table 3 while output elasticities with respect to inputs are calculated and reported in Table 4. Estimated output elasticities are statistically significant and positive for all inputs. The estimated elasticity of the time trend shows that there is a positive and significant technological change during the period under analysis.
The output elasticity with respect to insurance (Єins) has been calculated as the partial derivative of the logarithm of the production function with respect to the logarithm of the crop insurance expenditure:
Єins = δ ln yit/δ ln insit = βins + βins2 ln insit + ∑k βkins ln xkit + βtins t
Єins mean value is positive and statistically significant, indicating an enhancing effect of insurance on production.
We are also interested in investigating whether insurance affects the use of inputs. We intend to analyse the substitutability between insurance and other inputs, i.e., the ability to substitute insurance for another input without affecting the output level, in more detail. The technical relationship between insurance and other inputs depends on the curvature of the isoquant. Measures of substitution possibilities between inputs are obtained with elasticities of intensity (Diewert 1974). As shown by Roll (2019) the elasticity of intensity between insurance and other inputs is given by:
δ Єins/δ ln xkit = βkins
where k are the inputs land, capital, intermediate inputs, and labour. Negative elasticity indicates a substitute relationship, while positive elasticity indicates a complementary one. We find that the coefficients of the interaction terms are all statistically non-significant apart from the interaction term between insurance and intermediate inputs, which is statistically significant, negative, but close to zero. This latter finding indicates that insurance is a very weak substitute for intermediate inputs. This presumes right-angled isoquant with inputs used in nearly fixed proportions to each other. As for the interaction among inputs, the signs of these coefficients show that land is complementary for capital and intermediate inputs, while capital is a substitute for intermediate inputs. Finally, land and capital usage decreased over time, while the use of intermediate inputs increased. The parameter βtins measures the effect of insurance on technological change. As seen from Table 3, this is found to be positive but not statistically significant, indicating that insurance expenditures have not affected the technological change. Regarding risk-management tools different from insurance, the percentage of irrigated land has a positive but not significant effect on production, while both agricultural and non-agricultural diversification negatively affect production in accordance with what was previously found (Vidoli et al. 2016). Furthermore, in terms of economic size, medium and medium-small farms are less productive with respect to the smaller farms. The production level grows with the growing of altimetry and farms located in the South produce more than farms located in the Centre and less than farms located in the North.
The results of the efficiency function are presented in Table 5. Since we are estimating the inefficiency function, a negative parameter indicates that the variables considered have a positive effect on technical efficiency. Like Roll (2019), our estimates show that insurance has an enhancing effect on efficiency. Irrigation has a statistically significant and positive effect on efficiency. This may be related to the fact that irrigation decreases the variability of yields, and hence the variability of income (Foudi and Erdlenbruch 2012) allowing farmers to invest to enhance efficiency. Agricultural and non-agricultural diversifications do have not a statistically significant effect on efficiency. The estimated parameter of the time trend indicates that efficiency decreased during the analysed period. This result may be due to some events such as pests, rainfall, and drought, etc., that negatively influenced the efficiency. As for economic size, the significant coefficient of the medium-smaller farms shows that this group of farms is more efficient than the smaller farms6. The coefficients of the other size classes are not statistically significant. This result could be due to the fact that there is an important presence of small and highly specialised farms in the market (Kim et al. 2012). Farms operating in Southern areas of Italy were found to be more efficient compared to the farms operating in Northern areas, similar to what was found by Urso et al. (2018). Finally, farms located in the hilly areas are less efficient compared to those located in the plain areas. There is no statistical difference in the mountain compared to the lowland areas.

5. Discussion

This article aims to clarify the effect of expenditure in crop insurance on the production, technical efficiency, and input use of commercial grape-growing farms in Italy. Crop insurance might be an important tool for enhancing farm performances by reducing suboptimal input use (Ahsan et al. 1982; Nelson and Loehman 1987; Ramaswami 1993). On the contrary, insurance adoption may lead to inefficient farming actions driven by moral hazard, which causes non-optimal economic results (Horowitz and Lichtenberg 1993; Kirkley et al. 1998; Quiggin et al. 1993).
The net result of risk reduction and moral hazard effects on input use and output is indeterminate and remains an empirical issue. Our study intends to add to this stream of the empirical literature. We focus on the Italian grape growers’ sector because it is the type of farming with the highest participation in the crop insurance program in Italy (ISMEA 2018). Using FADN data, we estimated the impact of crop insurance on input use, production, and efficiency by using the endogenous panel stochastic frontier model proposed by Karakaplan and Kutlu (2017a).
Similar to Roll (2019), our results show that insurance has a boosting effect on both production and technical efficiency. With regards to the insurance effect on input use, we find that insurance does not have a statistically significant impact on labour, land, and capital while it has a significant influence on the use of intermediate inputs. The non-significant effect on labour and land was expected as labour is a quasi-fixed input in household farms and the quantity of land is fixed in the short-medium term in the case of perennial crops as grapevines. The results on land are not in line with those of Enjolras and Aubert (2020), who found a reduction in land allocated to grape production in France. Moreover, the statistically insignificant effect on capital does not confirm the enhancing investment effect of insurance found by Vigani and Kathage (2019) in French and Hungarian farms specialising in wheat. Finally, the negative, significant effect of insurance on intermediate inputs indicates that insurance is a substitute for intermediate goods. In our sample, most of the expenses in intermediate inputs are tied to the purchase of crop protection chemicals. Hence, the choice to purchase intermediate inputs in our sample is largely dominated by the choice about the use of crop defence chemicals, i.e., fungicide, pesticides, and herbicides. Our results contribute to the growing literature on the intensive margin relations of insurance and pesticide use (Horowitz and Lichtenberg 1993; Quiggin et al. 1993; Smith and Goodwin 1996; Babcock and Hennessy 1996; Möhring et al. 2020a, 2020b), showing that, contrary to that which was found by Enjolras and Aubert (2020) in France, in the case of grape production in Italy, insurance decreases the intermediate input use while increasing output. Our results differ from that which was previously found by Enjolras and Aubert (2020) in the case of French grape growers (no insurance effect on chemical inputs) and by Möhring et al. (2020b) for French arable crops (insurance’s positive effect on pesticides use). This highlights that insurance and pesticide policies need to account not only for the heterogeneity of pesticide type as showed by Möhring et al. (2020a), but also the heterogeneity due to the specific condition in which each sector operates (Goodwin et al. 2004). Hence, it is not possible to give a policy indication based on the observation of what happens in a single sector (Möhring et al. 2020b).
The causes of the changes found in input use and supply, as explained in Section 2, can be the risk reduction and moral hazard effects induced by insurance. As for the risk reduction effect, as described in earlier work by Ahsan et al. (1982), a Pareto optimal insurance program that provides full coverage has a risk-reduction effect which causes risk-averse farmers to reduce (increase) the use of risk-decreasing (increasing) inputs toward (away from) the optimal level of risk-neutral farmers and improve (reduce) output. However, in reality, crop insurance is often affected by information asymmetries (Just et al. 1999) that lead to opportunistic behaviour. Under such circumstances, farmers undertake actions that change the probability of loss relative to what the losses might be if the farmer were uninsured, in this way deviating from Pareto optimality (Nelson and Loehman 1987). Moral hazard reduces the use of all inputs and decreases mean output (Ramaswami 1993). Therefore, the net effect of the two adjustments induced by insurance depends on the degree of farmers’ risk aversion and the effect of the input on the probability of low yields (Horowitz and Lichtenberg 1993; Ramaswami 1993; Babcock and Hennessy 1996).
As for the risk preferences of grape growers, previous work has shown they are risk averse (Aka et al. 2018). This risk-averse attitude is mainly due to the existence of sunk costs related to high investments in land and capital equipment. In consideration of this aversion to risk, the increase in output found in this study suggests that in the case of grape production, the risk reduction effect dominates the moral hazard effect. In other words, the reduction in input use induced by insurance can be interpreted as a re-optimisation of input use rather than the effect of moral hazard. This conclusion is supported by the fact that when crop insurance targets specific weather hazards, such as insurance contracts in use in Italy and France, moral hazard does not play an important role as a driver of intensive margin effects (Möhring et al. 2020b) because there are hardly any agronomical adjustments possible to cause an insurance pay-out (Quiggin et al. 1993). Moreover, the decision to participate in a crop-insurance program must be made before the beginning of the season to avoid an opportunistic farmer taking out insurance after the observation of unfavourable conditions (Aubert and Enjolras 2014).
The decrease in the use of chemicals induced by insurance in grapevine production in Italy is good news for the success of the EU Commission’s strategy aimed at reducing pesticide use. Grape production is characterised by the highest level of pesticide use per hectare (Aka et al. 2018) mainly fungicide (Mailly et al. 2017), followed by insecticides and herbicides. At the same time, the grapevine is the agricultural sector where insurance has been widely adopted both in the EU and Italy (ISMEA 2018). The reduction in the use of defence chemicals induced by insurance can contribute both to reducing production costs and external costs attributed to farmers’ health and environment, in addition to preventing pest resistance (Wilson and Tisdell 2001). Moreover, the relevant increase in intermediate input used during the period analysed may be associated with the impact of global warming on grapevine regions (Mozell and Thachn 2014). For example, it may be reasonable for the overuse of pesticides due to the increase in insects and insect-borne diseases. Therefore, insurance may have the potential to be an instrument that contributes to the reduction in environmental and health adverse effects derived from the risk-averse farmers’ suboptimal input allocation (Möhring et al. 2020b).
Furthermore, the input use optimisation due to insurance adoption may also explain the increase in efficiency. By changing the use of inputs, insurance allows risk-averse grape growers to decrease the use of efficiency-reducing inputs due to the uncertainty of outcomes. Additionally, insurance may provide farmers with the possibility to invest in efficiency-improving practices. For example, grape growers may invest in precision agriculture to predict the field-specific optimum requirement of resources such as irrigation, fertilisers, pesticides, and herbicides (Bhakta et al. 2019). Likewise, they may change the rate of replanting perennial crops, thereby affecting the age distribution of the orchard and the yield. Moreover, improvement in efficiency may also be related to the fact that insurance allows farms to specialise in insured crop production (Ahsan et al. 1982) since they do not have to diversify to manage their idiosyncratic risk (Roll 2019)
Finally, our findings show the requirement to treat endogeneity of insurance to estimate unbiased parameters. The importance of considering endogeneity is due to different aspects. First, the endogeneity test provided by Karakaplan and Kutlu (2017b) shows the endogeneity presence due to self-selection and reverse causality in our model. Second, the significance of the substitution effect between insurance and intermediate input use shows that the adoption of the translog specification is also necessary. Lastly, the significance of the coefficients of the variables referred to the risk management tools alternative to insurance underlines the importance of including them to avoid omitted variables bias.

6. Conclusions

This article analysed how insurance affects the production decisions of commercial grape-growing farmers in Italy through the estimation of an endogenous panel stochastic frontier. More specifically, we investigated the crop insurance’s effect on production, technical efficiency, and input use in Italian grape-growers’ farms. Similar to Roll (2019), our findings show that insurance has a positive impact on production and efficiency, while it reduces the use of intermediate inputs. These results are fully consistent with neoclassic theory and indicate that insurance can play an essential role in the reduction of suboptimal input use due to the presence of uncertain outcomes. The increase in output found in this study suggests that in the case of grape production in Italy, the risk reduction effect dominates the moral hazard effect. In other words, the reduction in input use induced by insurance can be interpreted as a re-optimisation of input use rather than the effect of moral hazard. Furthermore, the input use optimisation due to insurance adoption may explain the gain in efficiency. Finally, we find that controlling for endogeneity in the causal relationship between insurance and production is needed to avoid biased parameters estimates.
A limitation of the study is related to the not fully reliable data in terms of labour. First, there is a high rate of missing values in hours worked in grape growing in during the years 2008 to 2010. Second, data referring to labour generally contain measurement errors because of the presence of factors such as illegal employment. Last, we have not considered the quality of labour distinguishing, for example, between skilled and unskilled labour or family and hired labour.
The main limitation of the study, though, is due to the different risk profiles of inputs included in the intermediate inputs that do not allow us to investigate the effect of insurance on the use of input with different attributes.
Since the substitution effect between insurance and intermediate inputs and the different nature of the inputs included in this variable in this study, further studies are needed to investigate the relationship between insurance and specific intermediate inputs used in the grape-growing sector.
Our findings have several policy implications. First, our results differ from that which was previously found in different crops and countries. This suggests that insurance and pesticide policies need to account for heterogeneity due to the specific condition in which each sector operates. Hence, it is not possible to give a policy indication based on the observation of what happens in a single sector. Second, the decrease in the use of intermediate inputs induced by insurance is good news for the success of the EU Commission’s strategy aimed at reducing pesticide use. Insurance can contribute to reducing the external costs attributed to farmers’ health and environment, in addition to preventing pest resistance.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, S.R.; Data curation, S.R.; Formal analysis, S.R., F.C. and C.S.; Investigation, S.R., F.C. and C.S.; Methodology, S.R., F.C. and C.S.; Supervision, F.C. and C.S.; Validation, S.R., F.C. and C.S.; Visualization, S.R.; Writing—original draft, S.R.; Writing—review & editing, S.R. and C.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

Restrictions apply to the availability of these data. Data were obtained from CREA (Consiglio per la ricerca in agricoltura e l’analisi dell’economia agraria) and are available (at URL https://bancadatirica.crea.gov.it/Account/Login.aspx?ReturnUrl=%2f, accessed on 30 July 2019) with the permission of CREA.

Acknowledgments

We thank Lerato Phali (University of Pretoria, Pretoria, South Africa) for language editing. We also thank Maurizio Prosperi and Antonio Lopolito (University of Foggia, Foggia, Italy) for the topical and intellectual discussions about the research and assistance and coordination for the research activity planning and execution.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Notes

1
This paper defines “quality grapevines” as those certified by the EU quality certification scheme.
2
Proofs and more technical details are provided in (Karakaplan and Kutlu 2017a, 2017b).
3
In the FADN the “standard output” (SO), of an agricultural product (crop or livestock) is the average monetary value of the agricultural output at farm-gate price. The SO excludes direct payments, value added tax and taxes on products.
4
In total, 27% of the observations for the total number of hours worked on grape growing were missing in the sample. Most of these missing values are related to some specific years and provinces. When the information of farm labour was available for a specific farm in at least one year, then the missing value has been replaced by the hours obtained based on the proportion between hours worked on grape growing and total hours worked on the farm. When hours worked on grape growing were missing in all years for one farm, we replaced them with an approximation based on year and location (province, region, and altimetry) specific mean.
5
A test similar to the Durbin–Wu–Hausman test has been used to assess the correlation between the instrumented variables and the two-side error term vit. This test examines the joint significance of the components of the bias correction terms (see Karakaplan and Kutlu 2017a, 2017b for more details). If the bias correction terms components are not jointly significant, one would conclude that correction for endogeneity is not necessary, and the variables can be estimated by the traditional frontier models.
6
Please note that being more efficient does not necessarily imply that farms are more productive. In fact, technical efficiency is a part of productivity, along with technical change and scale economies (Coelli et al. 2005). We find that smaller farms are more productive but less efficient than the medium-small farms. The explanation of such differences in the productivity and efficiency of different size classes deserves a specific study that is beyond the scope of our analysis.

References

  1. Ahsan, Syed M., Ali A. G. Ali, and N. John Kurian. 1982. Toward a Theory of Agricultural Insurance. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 64: 510–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Aigner, Dennis, C. A. Knox Lovell, and Peter Schmidt. 1977. Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models. Journal of Econometrics 6: 21–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Aka, Joël, A. Alonso Ugaglia, and Jean-Marie Lescot. 2018. Pesticide Use and Risk Aversion in the French Wine Sector. Journal of Wine Economics 13: 409–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Amsler, Christine, Artem Prokhorov, and Peter Schmidt. 2016. Endogeneity in stochastic frontier models. Journal of Econometrics 190: 280–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Asplund, Nathan, D. Lynn Forster, and Thomas T. Stout. 1989. Farmers’ use of forward contracting and hedging. Review of Futures Markets 8: 24–37. [Google Scholar]
  6. Aubert, Magali, and Geoffroy Enjolras. 2014. The Determinants of Chemical Input Use in Agriculture: A Dynamic Analysis of the Wine Grape–Growing Sector in France. Journal of Wine Economics 9: 75–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Babcock, Bruce A., and David A. Hennessy. 1996. Input Demand under Yield and Revenue Insurance. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78: 416–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Battese, George E. 1997. A note on the estimation of Cobb-Douglas production functions when some explanatory variables have zero values. Journal of Agricultural Economics 48: 250–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Battese, George E., and Timothy J. Coelli. 1995. A Model for Technical Inefficiency Effects in a Stochastic Frontier Production Function for Panel Data. Empirical Economics 20: 325–32. [Google Scholar]
  10. Bellon, Mauricio R., Bekele H. Kotu, Carlo Azzarri, and Francesco Caracciolo. 2020. To diversify or not to diversify, that is the question. Pursuing agricultural development for smallholder farmers in marginal areas of Ghana. World Development 125: 104682. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Bhakta, Ishita, Santanu Phadikar, and Koushik Majumder. 2019. State-of-the-art technologies in precision agriculture: A systematic review. Journal of the Science of Food and Agriculture 99: 4878–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  12. Boehlje, Michael D., and Larry D. Trede. 1977. Risk Management in Agriculture. Journal of ASFMRA 41: 20–29. [Google Scholar]
  13. Chavas, Jean-Paul, and Kwansoo Kim. 2010. Economies of diversification: A generalization and decomposition of economies of scope. International Journal of Production Economics 126: 229–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Coelli, Timothy J., D. S. Prasada Rao, Christopher J. O’Donnell, and George E. Battese. 2005. An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis. Berlin and Heidelberg: Springer Science & Business Media. [Google Scholar]
  15. Corsi, Alessandro, and Cristina Salvioni. 2012. Off- and on-farm labour participation in Italian farm households. Applied Economics 44: 2517–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Di Falco, Salvatore, and Jean-Paul Chavas. 2006. Crop genetic diversity, farm productivity and the management of environmental risk in rainfed agriculture. European Review of Agricultural Economics 33: 289–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Di Falco, Salvatore, and Marcella Veronesi. 2013. How can African agriculture adapt to climate change? A counterfactual analysis from Ethiopia. Land Economics 89: 743–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Di Falco, Salvatore, Felice Adinolfi, Martina Bozzola, and Fabian Capitanio. 2014. Crop Insurance as a Strategy for Adapting to Climate Change. Journal of Agricultural Economics 65: 485–504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Diewert, W. Erwin. 1974. Functional Forms for Revenue and Factor Requirements Functions. International Economic Review 15: 119–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Enjolras, Geoffroy, and Magali Aubert. 2020. How Does Crop Insurance Influence Pesticide Use? Evidence from French Farms. Review of Agricultural, Food and Environmental Studies 101: 461–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Enjolras, Geoffroy, Fabian Capitanio, and Felice Adinolfi. 2012. The demand for crop insurance: Combined approaches for France and Italy. Agricultural Economics Review 13: 5–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Farrell, Michael J. 1957. The Measurement of Productive Efficiency. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series A (General) 120: 253–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Foudi, Sébastien, and Katrin Erdlenbruch. 2012. The role of irrigation in farmers’ risk management strategies in France. European Review of Agricultural Economics 39: 439–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Goodwin, Barry K., Monte L. Vandeveer, and John L. Deal. 2004. An Empirical Analysis of Acreage Effects of Participation in the Federal Crop Insurance Program. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86: 1058–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Gotor, Elisabetta, Muhammed A. Usman, Martina Occelli, Basazen Fantahun, Carlo Fadda, Yosef G. Kidane, Dejene Mengistu, Afewerki Y. Kiros, Jemal N. Mohammed, Mekonen Assefa, and et al. 2021. Wheat varietal diversification increases Ethiopian smallholders’ food security: Evidence from a participatory development initiative. Sustainability 13: 1029. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Hennessy, David A. 1996. Information Asymmetry as a Reason for Food Industry Vertical Integration. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78: 1034–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Holland, Tara, and Barry Smit. 2010. Climate change and the wine industry: Current research themes and new directions. Journal of Wine Research 21: 125–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Horowitz, John K., and Erik Lichtenberg. 1993. Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Chemical Use in Agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75: 926–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2013. Climate Change 2013: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  30. Istituto di Servizi per il Mercato Agricolo Alimentare (ISMEA). 2018. Rapporto sulla gestione del rischio in Italia 2018. Rome: Romana Editrice S.r.l. [Google Scholar]
  31. Just, Richard E., and Rulon D. Pope. 1979. Production Function Estimation and Related Risk Considerations. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 61: 276–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Just, Richard E., Linda Calvin, and John Quiggin. 1999. Adverse Selection in Crop Insurance: Actuarial and Asymmetric Information Incentives. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 81: 834–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Karakaplan, Mustafa U., and Levent Kutlu. 2017a. Endogeneity in panel stochastic frontier models: An application to the Japanese cotton spinning industry. Applied Economics 49: 5935–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Karakaplan, Mustafa U., and Levent Kutlu. 2017b. Handling endogeneity in stochastic frontier analysis. Economics Bulletin 37: 889–901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Kim, Kwansoo, Jean-Paul Chavas, Bradford Barham, and Jeremy Foltz. 2012. Specialization, diversification, and productivity: A panel data analysis of rice farms in Korea. Agricultural Economics (United Kingdom) 43: 687–700. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Kirkley, James, Dale Squires, and Ivar E. Strand. 1998. Characterizing Managerial Skill and Technical Efficiency in a Fishery. Journal of Productivity Analysis 9: 145–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Lusk, Jayson L. 2017. Distributional effects of crop insurance subsidies. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy 39: 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. MacMinn, Richard D., and Alphonse G. Holtmann. 1983. Technological Uncertainty and the Theory of the Firm. Southern Economic Journal 50: 120–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Mailly, Florine, Laure Hossard, Jean-Marc Barbier, Marie Thiollet-Scholtus, and Christian Gary. 2017. Quantifying the impact of crop protection practices on pesticide use in wine-growing systems. European Journal of Agronomy 84: 23–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. McConnell, Douglas J., and John L. Dillon. 1997. Farm Management for Asia: A Systems Approach. FAO Farm Systems Management Series; Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization, vol. 13. [Google Scholar]
  41. Meeusen, Wim, and Julien van Den Broeck. 1977. Efficiency Estimation from Cobb-Douglas Production Functions with Composed Error. International Economic Review 18: 435–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Mieno, Taro, Cory G. Walters, and Lilyan E. Fulginiti. 2018. Input use under crop insurance: The role of actual production history. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 100: 1469–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  43. Möhring, Niklas, Martina Bozzola, Stefan Hirsch, and Robert Finger. 2020a. Are pesticides risk decreasing? The relevance of pesticide indicator choice in empirical analysis. Agricultural Economics (United Kingdom) 51: 429–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Möhring, Niklas, Tobias Dalhaus, Geoffroy Enjolras, and Robert Finger. 2020b. Crop insurance and pesticide use in European agriculture. Agricultural Systems 184: 102902. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Moschini, Giancarlo, and David A. Hennessy. 2001. Uncertainty, risk aversion, and risk management for agriculture producers. Handbook of Agricultural Economics 1: 88–153. [Google Scholar]
  46. Mozell, Michelle R., and Liz Thachn. 2014. The impact of climate change on the global wine industry: Challenges & solutions. Wine Economics and Policy 3: 81–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  47. Nelson, Carl H., and Edna T. Loehman. 1987. Further Toward a Theory of Agricultural Insurance. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 69: 523–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Otsuka, Keijiro, Yuko Nakano, and Kazushi Takahashi. 2016. Contract farming in developed and developing countries. Annual Review of Resource Economics 8: 353–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Pagnani, Tiziana, Elisabetta Gotor, and Francesco Caracciolo. 2021. Adaptive strategies enhance smallholders’ livelihood resilience in Bihar, India. Food Security 13: 419–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Pope, Rulon D., and Randall A. Kramer. 1979. Production Uncertainty and Factor Demands for the Competitive Firm: An Extension. Southern Economic Journal 46: 489–501. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  51. Quiggin, John C., Giannis Karagiannis, and Julie Stanton. 1993. Crop Insurance and Crop Production: An Empirical Study of Moral Hazard and Adverse Selection. Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics 37: 95–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  52. Raimondo, Maria, Concetta Nazzaro, Giuseppe Marotta, and Francesco Caracciolo. 2021. Land degradation and climate change: Global impact on wheat yields. Land Degradation and Development 32: 387–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Ramaswami, Bharat. 1992. Production Risk and Optimal Input Decisions. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74: 860–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Ramaswami, Bharat. 1993. Supply Response to Agricultural Insurance: Risk Reduction and Moral Hazard Effects. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75: 914–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Roll, Kristin H. 2019. Moral hazard: The effect of insurance on risk and efficiency. Agricultural Economics 50: 367–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Roosen, Jutta, and David A. Hennessy. 2003. Tests for the role of risk aversion on input use. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85: 30–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  57. Santeramo, Fabio G., Barry K. Goodwin, Felice Adinolfi, and Fabian Capitanio. 2016. Farmer Participation, Entry and Exit Decisions in the Italian Crop Insurance Programme. Journal of Agricultural Economics 67: 639–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Shee, Apurba, and Spiro E. Stefanou. 2014. Endogeneity corrected stochastic production frontier and technical efficiency. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 97: 939–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Skees, Jerry R., J. Roy Black, and Barry J. Barnett. 1997. Designing and Rating an Area Yield Crop Insurance Contract. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79: 430–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Smith, Vincent H., and Barry K. Goodwin. 1996. Crop Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Agricultural Chemical Use. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78: 428–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Urso, Arturo, Giuseppe Timpanaro, Francesco Caracciolo, and Luigi Cembalo. 2018. Efficiency analysis of Italian wine producers. Wine Economics and Policy 7: 3–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Vidoli, Francesco, Concetta Cardillo, Elisa Fusco, and Jacopo Canello. 2016. Spatial nonstationarity in the stochastic frontier model: An application to the Italian wine industry. Regional Science and Urban Economics 61: 153–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Vigani, Mauro, and Jonas Kathage. 2019. To Risk or Not to Risk? Risk Management and Farm Productivity. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 101: 1432–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Weber, Jeremy G., Nigel Key, and Erik. O’Donoghue. 2016. Does federal crop insurance make environmental externalities from agriculture worse? Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 3: 707–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  65. Wilson, Clevo, and Clem Tisdell. 2001. Why farmers continue to use pesticides despite environmental, health and sustainability costs. Ecological Economics 39: 449–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  66. Wu, JunJie. 1999. Crop Insurance, Acreage Decisions, and Nonpoint-Source Pollution. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 81: 305–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Wu, JunJie, and Bruce A. Babcock. 1998. The Choice of Tillage, Rotation, and Soil Testing Practices: Economic and Environmental Implications. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80: 494–511. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The graphs show the distribution of the mean values of the logarithm of output and input levels for insured and uninsured farmers over all observations from 2008 to 2017.
Figure 1. The graphs show the distribution of the mean values of the logarithm of output and input levels for insured and uninsured farmers over all observations from 2008 to 2017.
Economies 10 00020 g001
Table 1. Descriptive statistics.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics.
Variable and AbbreviationDescriptionMeanStandard Deviation
Output and Inputs
yProductionTotal Gross Production (EUR)57,338136,247
x1LandUtilised Agricultural Area (ha)8.9217.30
x2CapitalAmount of Capital (EUR)472,6961,446,921
x3Intermediate InputsIntermediate Inputs Costs (EUR)11,90837,635
x4LabourTotal number of hours worked per year (h)24184511
Risk Management Strategies
insInsuranceExpenditure on crop insurance (EUR)8915168
dinsInsurance DummyOne for insured farm, zero otherwise0.220.41
irrIrrigationPercentage of irrigated land over total land (%)0.280.43
dnNon-agricultural DiversificationDummy for services diversification0.110.32
daAgricultural DiversificationDummy for crop or livestock diversification0.740.44
Control Variables
es1Economic Size (1) [base category]One for small farms, zero otherwise0.130.33
es2Economic Size (2)One for medium-small farms, zero otherwise0.210.41
es3Economic Size (3)One for medium farms, zero otherwise0.280.45
es4Economic Size (4)One for medium-large farms, zero otherwise0.320.47
es5Economic Size (5)One for large farms, zero otherwise0.060.24
alt1Altimetry (1) [base category]One if located in the plain, zero otherwise0.240.42
alt2Altimetry (2)One if located in the hill, zero otherwise0.590.49
alt3Altimetry (3)One if located in the mountain, zero otherwise0.170.37
loc1Location (1) [base category]One for farms located in the South, zero otherwise0.120.33
loc2Location (2)One for farms located in the Central, zero otherwise0.250.43
loc3Location (3)One for farms located in the Northeast, zero otherwise0.320.47
loc4Location (4)One for farms located in the Northwest, zero otherwise0.310.46
Table 2. Descriptive statistics (insured vs. uninsured farms).
Table 2. Descriptive statistics (insured vs. uninsured farms).
VariableNo InsuranceInsurance
MeanStandard DeviationMeanStandard Deviation
Output and Inputs
Production50,024130,62783,761151,990
Land8.0716.0311.9820.99
Capital410,4061,116,236697,7272,256,782
Intermediate Inputs10,43933,15517,21547,099
Labour2146346233997025
Risk Management Strategies
Insurance00411010,489
Irrigation0.240.410.390.47
Non-agricultural Diversification0.110.310.110.31
Agricultural Diversification0.740.440.730.44
Control Variables
Economic Size (1)0.150.350.070.25
Economic Size (2)0.230.420.150.35
Economic Size (3)0.280.450.290.45
Economic Size (4)0.290.460.400.49
Economic Size (5)0.050.220.090.29
Altimetry (1)0.230.420.260.44
Altimetry (2)0.620.480.490.50
Altimetry (3)0.150.350.250.43
Location (1)0.150.350.060.24
Location (2)0.240.430.280.45
Location (3)0.280.450.460.50
Location (4)0.330.470.200.40
Table 3. Production function.
Table 3. Production function.
VariableParameterEstimateStandard Error zP > |z|
Inputs
Landβ10.34570.14472.390.017
Capitalβ20.39340.08984.380.000
Int. Inputsβ30.28890.08063.580.000
Labourβ4−0.01580.0638−0.250.805
Trendβt−0.01960.0251−0.78 0.437
Land2β11−0.05600.0238−2.35 0.019
Capital2β22−0.00180.0087−0.20 0.838
Int. Inputs2β330.01240.00841.47 0.140
Labour2β440.00310.00570.54 0.586
Trend2βtt0.00380.00152.61 0.009
Land ∗ Capitalβ120.02160.01121.94 0.053
Land ∗ Int. Inputsβ130.02270.01092.09 0.036
Land ∗ Labourβ14−0.00750.0093−0.81 0.420
Land ∗ Trendβ1t−0.00840.0035−2.38 0.017
Capital ∗ Int. Inputsβ23−0.02970.0080−3.72 0.000
Capital ∗ Labourβ240.00720.00571.27 0.204
Capital ∗ Trendβ2t−0.01130.0021−5.27 0.000
Int. Inputs ∗ Labourβ34−0.00260.0066−0.39 0.694
Int. Inputs ∗ Trendβ3t0.02110.00268.14 0.000
Labour ∗ Trendβ4t−0.00150.0021−0.71 0.479
Risk-Management Strategies
Insuranceβins0.06400.02602.460.014
Insurance2βins20.00760.00193.920.000
Land ∗ Insuranceβ1ins−0.00180.0034−0.530.594
Capital ∗ Insuranceβ2ins−0.00060.0020−0.330.745
Int. Inputs ∗ Insuranceβ3ins−0.00560.0027−2.050.041
Labour ∗ Insuranceβ4ins−0.00210.0020−1.040.300
Trend ∗ Insuranceβtins0.00020.00070.320.750
Irrigationβirr0.03890.03011.29 0.196
Non-Agr. Diversificationβdn−0.09830.0350−2.81 0.005
Agr. Diversificationβda−0.07310.0253−2.89 0.004
Control Variables
Medium-Smallβes2−0.07820.0371−2.11 0.035
Mediumβes3−0.07810.0445−1.75 0.079
Medium-Largeβes4−0.04930.0529−0.93 0.352
Largeβes50.05490.07920.69 0.488
Hillβalt20.14680.02885.10 0.000
Mountainβalt30.28300.04476.34 0.000
Centreβloc2−0.13450.0385−3.49 0.000
Northeastβloc30.17310.03884.46 0.000
Northwestβloc40.23910.03996.00 0.000
Constantβ04.48030.62037.22 0.000
Note: The coefficients related to insurance expenditure are shown in bold.
Table 4. Output elasticity.
Table 4. Output elasticity.
VariableEstimateStandard ErrorzP > |z|
Land0.59260.028420.870.000
Capital0.14270.01459.850.000
Int. Inputs0.13120.01946.780.000
Labour0.03580.01502.380.017
Insurance0.10650.01566.850.000
Trend0.02190.00563.980.000
Table 5. Inefficiency estimates.
Table 5. Inefficiency estimates.
VariableParameterEstimateStandard Error zP > |z|
Insuranceδins−0.02260.0111−2.030.042
Irrigationδirr−0.27830.1188−2.340.019
Non-Agr. Diversificationδdn−0.01190.1168−0.100.919
Agr. Diversificationδda0.04160.09310.450.655
Trendδt0.06170.01344.620.000
Medium-Smallδes2−0.26470.1176−2.250.024
Mediumδes3−0.16700.1212−1.380.168
Medium-Largeδes4−0.00340.1260−0.030.978
Largeδes50.08810.20240.440.663
Hillδalt20.46530.12713.660.000
Mountainδalt3−0.19310.1878−1.030.304
Centreδloc2−0.04390.1586−0.280.782
Northeastδloc30.43360.15532.790.005
Northwestδloc40.24430.15931.530.125
Constantδ0−1.62180.2227−7.280.000
Note: The coefficients related to insurance expenditure are shown in bold.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Russo, S.; Caracciolo, F.; Salvioni, C. Effects of Insurance Adoption and Risk Aversion on Agricultural Production and Technical Efficiency: A Panel Analysis for Italian Grape Growers. Economies 2022, 10, 20. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10010020

AMA Style

Russo S, Caracciolo F, Salvioni C. Effects of Insurance Adoption and Risk Aversion on Agricultural Production and Technical Efficiency: A Panel Analysis for Italian Grape Growers. Economies. 2022; 10(1):20. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10010020

Chicago/Turabian Style

Russo, Simone, Francesco Caracciolo, and Cristina Salvioni. 2022. "Effects of Insurance Adoption and Risk Aversion on Agricultural Production and Technical Efficiency: A Panel Analysis for Italian Grape Growers" Economies 10, no. 1: 20. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10010020

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop