Next Article in Journal
Unrelated Parallel Machine Scheduling Problem Considering Job Splitting, Inventories, Shortage, and Resource: A Meta-Heuristic Approach
Previous Article in Journal
Pricing Decisions in Construction and Demolition Waste Recycling Supply Chains under Carbon Tax Scenarios
Previous Article in Special Issue
How Does Digital Transformation Impact Green Supply Chain Development? An Empirical Analysis Based on the TOE Theoretical Framework
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Research on the Product Positioning Strategy of the Independent Seller under Platform Encroachment

1
School of Economics and Management, Beijing University of Posts and Telecommunications, Beijing 100876, China
2
School of Modern Post (School of Automation), Beijing University of Posts and Telecommunications, Beijing 100876, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Systems 2024, 12(1), 36; https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12010036
Submission received: 15 December 2023 / Revised: 12 January 2024 / Accepted: 19 January 2024 / Published: 22 January 2024
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Enablers and Capabilities for the Digital Supply Chain)

Abstract

:
The platform owner promotes the transaction between independent sellers and consumers, while entering the marketplace of independent sellers to compete with them for consumers. Faced with the threat of platform encroachment, independent sellers establish their own competitive advantages through ex ante category quality selection and ex post product differentiation. This study discusses how independent sellers should determine product positioning (including vertical and horizontal dimensions) in the face of platform category encroachment. We establish a game model and determine the best strategy. In addition, we develop a multi-agent model to reach conclusions for more complex market situations. We show that when the consumer’s platform preference is low, the independent seller is willing to locate in the high-end product market; otherwise, the independent seller is willing to locate in the low-end product market. In a competitive environment, when consumers’ ideal preferences are concentrated, the independent seller vertically positions in the low-end product market and horizontally positions close to the concentrated area of consumers’ ideal preferences. Similarly, the platform owner is more likely to encroach on the low-end product market. However, the independent seller positions in the high-end product market with greater horizontal differentiation, and the platform owner’s motivation to encroach is weakened.

1. Introduction

E-commerce breaks through the limitations of time and space and plays an increasingly important role in economic development. The global e-commerce market is expected to reach USD 6.5 trillion by 2023. In this rapid development trend, each e-commerce platform adopts different operating models according to its own situation. Some e-commerce platforms, such as Taobao and Tmall, adopt a pure platform model, whereby they only provide trading platforms for independent sellers and consumers and do not participate in specific transactions. They profit by charging commissions to independent sellers. In addition, platforms, such as Amazon, Suning Tesco, and Jingdong Mall, while providing platform services for buyers and sellers, also encroach on the retail market and make profits by opening their own stores [1]. Statistics show that since 2023, Jingdong’s self-operated GMV has accounted for more than 70% of Jingdong Mall’s overall sales.
The encroachment of e-commerce platform owners into the retail market has an impact on the supply chain structure. The platform owner not only acts as an intermediary cooperating with independent sellers to facilitate transactions but also acts as an occupier competing with independent sellers for consumers in the same market. For more authoritative platforms, consumers tend to show a stronger sense of trust and have a higher preference for platform self-owned products. Product positioning is an effective way for independent sellers to enhance their competitive advantage. Product positioning involves two aspects: vertical product positioning and horizontal product positioning [2]. Vertical product positioning emphasizes the professionalism and depth of the product, focusing on product quality and function. The difference in the material, process, and function of the product creates products of a different quality. According to the difference in product quality and value, the market can be roughly divided into low-, medium-, and high-end markets [3]. Reliable and excellent quality is the key for medium- and high-end products, while low-end products have become a pragmatic choice for consumers with their high cost-effectiveness. Enterprises vertically position their market by selecting the quality of the products they sell. Faced with the threat of encroachment, some incumbent enterprises establish market competitive advantages through quality improvement in advance [4]. There are also some incumbent enterprises that respond by reducing the level of product quality [5]. On the e-commerce platform, some independent sellers are positioned in the high-end product market, and the platform owner will not engage in encroachment. For example, luxury brands such as LV and GUCCI have flagship stores on Jingdong Mall, and there are no Jingdong self-owned stores. At the same time, many independent sellers expect to take advantage of the high pricing of the platform’s self-owned products [6], positioning in the low-end product market, such as the digital accessories market and the second-hand book market. When the platform’s self-owned stores enter, independent sellers may need a lot of resources to reposition vertically, which is very difficult for them [7]. Therefore, in the face of serious product homogeneity and weak competitive position, independent sellers can form differences with the platform owner through horizontal product positioning [8]. Unlike vertical product positioning, horizontal product positioning focuses on the breadth and diversity of products, that is, the appearance, design, characteristics, etc., necessary to distinguish them from competitors’ products, positioning on a specific attribute or feature to attract potential consumers. For example, clothing brands such as GLM and A21 specialize in selling certain styles in their flagship stores to differentiate them from products in the platform’s self-owned stores. Third-party sellers on Amazon try to tap into differentiated blue ocean products from Red Sea markets. The retailer of selfie ring lights, by analyzing user reviews on Amazon, developed the large-sized ring light and replaced the flimsy tripod with a sturdy circular base. In short, product positioning is a primary and important business decision for independent sellers.
The above analysis leads to the research questions of this paper: Under what conditions is the independent seller positioned in the high-end product market, and under what conditions is the independent seller positioned in the low-end product market? Is the platform owner willing to encroach on the retail market? How does platform encroachment affect the independent seller’s positioning decision? What is the equilibrium strategy for the interaction between the two parties? Which equilibrium strategy can yield more consumer surplus and social welfare?
In view of the above questions, we establish a Stackelberg game model under the framework of the Hotelling model, involving an independent seller and a platform owner. If there is no encroachment, then the independent seller as a monopoly only needs to carry out vertical product positioning and pricing. If there is platform encroachment, the independent seller also needs to carry out horizontal product positioning to alleviate competition by selling a product that is different from the platform’s self-owned product. We not only explore the optimal strategies of both parties but also develop an agent-based model for more complex consumer markets and conduct simulation experiments. In addition, we extend the model to further analyze the impact of positive production costs, pricing order, and the platform’s consumer surplus concerns.
The rest of this paper is arranged as follows. Section 2 reviews the relevant literature and emphasizes the differences between this paper and the existing literature. Section 3 establishes the main model and investigates the independent seller’s product positioning strategy and the platform owner’s encroachment strategy. Section 4 conducts multi-agent simulation experiments and further analyzes the impact of heterogeneity of consumers’ ideal preferences on equilibrium decision making. Section 5 considers several extensions to the main model. Section 6 presents the conclusions of this study and discusses management insights and future research directions.

2. Literature Review

2.1. Platform Encroachment

This article considers the literature on platform encroachment. Previous studies have focused on the motivation for platform encroachment and the impact of platform encroachment on supply chain members. In terms of empirical research, Zhu and Liu [9] conducted an empirical study on Amazon’s motivation to invade the third-party sellers’ marketplace. They found that Amazon is more likely to enter the product field with successful and small specific investments, and Amazon’s entry hinders the business growth of third-party sellers. However, some scholars [6,10] have found through empirical studies that Google’s entry into the Android market has a positive impact on complementary innovation. In terms of game theory research, Ryan et al. [11] focused on the competition and coordination of the online market and studied the conditions of platform encroachment and retailers’ entry into the online market. They found that when retailers are weak competitors, the platform is more likely to encroach, and retailers do not enter the online market; on the contrary, retailers enter and the platform does not encroach; and when the competition is equal, retailers enter the online marketplace and compete with the platform encroachment. Lam and Liu [12] studied platform encroachment strategy based on different levels of information usage and the pricing strategy of independent sellers under different encroachment strategies. They found that platforms use personalized information to target more successful independent sellers, who charge higher prices and can benefit from platform encroachment, but consumers may be harmed. Zennyo [13] examined platform encroachment and content owner bias, comparing platforms’ three strategies of pure intermediation, fair encroachment, and biased encroachment. The results show that platform bias encroachment can increase the number of platform users (sellers and consumers) by reducing the equilibrium between commission rate and price. Wu et al. [14] constructed a dual-channel supply chain consisting of a manufacturer, a third-party seller, and an electronic platform and studied the electronic platform’s encroachment strategy and the manufacturer’s pricing strategy under platform encroachment. The study found that the electronic platform is always willing to encroach on the third-party seller market, and the manufacturer tends to choose a price discrimination strategy that provides a more favorable wholesale price to the third-party seller. However, these studies do not consider how the product positioning strategies of independent sellers are affected by platform encroachment. This paper contributes to the literature on platform encroachment by studying different product positioning strategies under, or not under, platform encroachment.
The literature contains reports describing a combination of platform encroachment and product positioning studies. Tian et al. [15] investigated the impact of product differentiation among suppliers in a business model selection of electronic platforms. Unlike their article, where the focus is on upstream vendor competition, we explore the competitive and cooperative relationship between the independent seller and the platform owner. Jiang et al. [16] constructed a two-period dynamic game model with asymmetric information, where independent sellers locate either with a high-demand product type or low-demand product type and can mask product demand by lowering the service level, while the platform owner identifies products with high-demand potential in the first period and invades them in the second period. However, unlike their model, which assumes that independent sellers exit the marketplace after platform encroachment, we assume that when platform encroachment occurs, the independent seller can compete with the platform owner by selling horizontally differentiated products. Moreover, they did not investigate which product type independent sellers tend to sell, whereas we examined the optimal product selection strategy of the independent seller under platform encroachment. Etro [17] considered product differentiation in price competition on a platform that allows sellers to retain positive profits after platform imitation. In comparison, this paper examines the endogenous product differentiation of the independent seller.

2.2. Product Positioning

Product positioning mainly considers the strategic decision of product differentiation. Some scholars have studied product vertical differentiation. Wang and Sun [18] differentiated second-hand platform products in terms of reliability and timeliness. Su et al. [19] measured the quality of online knowledge payment products from the perspective of consumer experience value, providing a more optimized method for knowledge payment platforms to select high-quality products. Du and Guan [20] studied the product introduction strategy (decreasing quality or increasing quality) of a monopoly enterprise under the dual drive of consumer strategic behavior and enterprise cost reduction. Liu and Zhai [21] compared and analyzed the impact of progressive innovation (positioning in the low-end market first, the high-end market later) and breakthrough innovation strategy (positioning in the high-end market all the time) on enterprise operation. Lauga and Ofek [22] and Yi and Chen [23] used the customer willingness to pay model to study the product quality positioning of duopoly enterprises. Chen et al. [24] and Ha et al. [25] studied the product quality selection of suppliers under dual channels. Feng et al. [26] studied the combination of product positioning strategies of a start-up platform company and a third-party seller under bilateral network effects. Guo and Li [27] studied the impact of potentially entering retailers on the product upgrading strategies of upstream manufacturers and found that the higher the product substitution of entrants, the lower the willingness of upstream manufacturers to upgrade product quality. Bardon [28] explored how two competing enterprises use product positioning to cope with the threat of potential entrants. Their study showed that narrowing the quality gap between the products of incumbent enterprises can prevent invasion.
Some scholars have studied product horizontal differentiation. Kapkin and Joines [29] considered multiple dimensional roundness to explore the impact of product form on consumers’ perceived meaning. Sajeesh and Raju [30] studied pricing and positioning decisions in a variety-seeking market. Ottaviano and Thisse [31] discussed the impact of strategic interaction between multi-product firms on product diversity, mainly focusing on horizontal differentiation. Ebina et al. [32] built a horizontal differentiation duopoly competition model and studied the entry timing and product positioning decisions of leaders and followers under the uncertainty of market size. Chen and Liang [33] analyzed the product positioning and pricing decisions of competitive enterprises when customers return goods under the framework of the Hotelling model. Chen et al. [2] studied the product positioning decision of duopoly competitive enterprises under the rebate promotion model. Tian et al. [34] analyzed the conditions under which manufacturers sell homogeneous or differentiated products through their own online channels and independent retailers under the free ride of consumers. Although the research on product positioning decision making has been relatively rich, most of the existing literature studies either horizontal product positioning or vertical product positioning. Shangguan et al. [35] explored a single manufacturer’s differentiated design and pricing strategy for its two products from horizontal and vertical dimensions. In contrast, we focus on the enterprise’s product positioning strategy in a competitive environment. However, most of the existing literature studies the product positioning problem of competitive enterprises. The independent seller in this paper relies on the intermediary role of the platform while facing the threat of platform self-operation. Based on this, in the context of platform encroachment, this paper not only focuses on the independent seller’s horizontal product differentiation strategy after the platform owner’s encroachment but also investigates ex ante product quality positioning strategy (high quality or low quality), aiming to enhance the competitive advantage through product positioning.

3. Modeling and Analysis

We consider an e-commerce platform supply chain consisting of a platform owner (O) and an independent seller (S). There are vertically differentiated categories and sellers within a category that sell horizontally differentiated variants (products). In our model, we consider two categories with a vertical differentiation of α, one is a lower quality category L and the other is a higher quality category H. S chooses to sell one of the categories (that is, vertical product positioning) and transact with consumers through O. At the same time, S needs to pay a commission of r (0 < r < 1) per unit sales to O, and r is an exogenous variable [36,37,38]. In addition, observing the category selection of S, O may introduce its own product into the market to encroach on S’s category (encroachment strategy is denoted as E, non-encroachment strategy is denoted as N). Figure 1 illustrates the supply chain structure under the two platform strategies. In reality, in order to reduce the risk of new product development, platform owners often use information advantages to encroach on products with good sales performance [12,16], and the platform owner has product display advantages [39]. To avoid being squeezed out of the market by the platform’s self-owned store, S will take the initiative to adopt a product differentiation strategy to distinguish from O’s product of the same level (i.e., horizontal product positioning) and establish its own competitive advantage [40]. We denote S’s product and O’s product in category j ( j { L ,   H } ) as Sj and Oj, respectively, and the degree of horizontal differentiation between the two products is expressed as d j , where S determines the optimal d j value. For simplicity of analysis, we assume that both parties produce at zero cost (in Section 5, we consider the case where the production costs are not zero, and the main result is still valid).
According to the Hotelling model, we assume that consumers are uniformly distributed along a straight line with density 1 [41]. We use a modified Hotelling model where the line extends to infinity at both ends [42]. The location of each consumer indicates its ideal variant (product) preference. If the consumer buys the non-ideal product, it will cause the loss of its purchase utility. Assume that the distance between the consumer’s ideal and each seller’s product is x i j ( i { O ,   S } , j { L ,   H } ). The utility loss caused by consumers purchasing product ij without satisfying their preferences is x i j · t , where t represents the utility loss per unit distance. We distinguish the consumer’s purchase behavior in the following two scenarios.
When O does not encroach, there is only S’s product in the linear space. The utility obtained by the consumer from purchasing Sj is U S j = q j p S j x S j · t , where q j represents the category j’s quality, q H / q L = α > 1 ; p S j represents Sj’s retail price. The value x S j is defined as the boundary position at which the consumer acquires non-disutility when purchasing Sj, i.e., U S j = 0 when x S j = x S j . Figure 2a shows the range in which consumers buy products from S in the case of non-encroachment. The market demand of S is D S j N = 2 x S j = 2 ( q j p S j ) t .
When O encroaches, there are Sj and Oj in the linear space. It is assumed that consumers have a higher value evaluation δ (δ > 1) for the platform owner’s products [43,44,45]. The utility obtained by the consumer from purchasing Oj is U O j = δ q j p O j x O j · t . The utility obtained by the consumer from purchasing Sj is U S j = q j p S j x S j · t . The value x O j is defined as the boundary position at which the consumer acquires non-disutility when purchasing Oj, i.e., U O j = 0 when x O j = x O j . In addition, we define the value x S O j as the undifferentiated location where the consumer purchases Sj and Oj. Let x S j = x S O j , x O j = d x S O j , by solving U S j = U O j , we can obtain x S O j = ( 1 δ ) q j p S j + p O j + d t 2 t . Figure 2b shows consumers’ purchases of different sellers’ products in the case of encroachment. The market demand of S is D S j E = x S j + x S O j = ( 3 δ ) q j 3 p S j + p O j + d t 2 t . The market demand of O is D O j E = x O j + d x S O j = ( 3 δ 1 ) q j + p S j 3 p O j + d t 2 t . Note that the boundary values x S j and x O j are positive.
We only consider that both products have high enough valuations, so that there is a competitive relationship between the two parties. Specifically, the constraint is 0 < d < x S j + x O j . In Table 1, we summarize all the main symbols.
The sequence of events for this article is shown in Figure 3. S first vertically positions its product (L or H), and then, observing S’s market position (category selection), O decides whether to encroach on the category. According to whether O encroaches, there are two sub-games: If O does not encroach, S decides the retail price p S j . If O encroaches, S takes the lead in determining the horizontal differentiation degree d j from Oj, and second, S and O successively decide the retail price p S j and p O j .

3.1. In the Case of Non-Encroachment

When O does not encroach, S’s profit is π S j N = 1 r · D S j N · p S j N , and O’s profit is π O j N = r · D S j N · p S j N . S decides the retail price to maximize profit, and the equilibrium result is as described in Lemma 1.
Lemma 1.
In the case of non-encroachment, S’s optimal retail price is  p S j N * = q j 2 , the market demand is D S j N * = q j t , and the profit is π S j N * = q j 2 ( 1 r ) 2 t . The profit of O is π O j N * = q j 2 r 2 t .
Proposition 1.
In the case of non-encroachment, the independent seller is positioned in the high-end product market.
The result of Proposition 1 is intuitive. First, the higher the quality of the product, the higher the price consumers are willing to pay for it. Second, the high-quality product’s valuation advantage helps to make up for the utility loss caused by the product’s failure to meet the horizontal preferences of consumers, and there is a wider range of consumers to buy the product. As a result, the monopolistic independent seller chooses to sell high-quality products.

3.2. In the Case of Encroachment

When O encroaches, S’s profit is π S j E = 1 r · D S j E · p S j E d j · c , where c represents the horizontal differentiation cost per unit [46]. O’s profit is π O j E = r · D S j E · p S j E + D O j E · p O j E . S first sets the horizontal differentiation from Oj, then determines the retail price, and finally, O determines the retail price. According to backward induction, the equilibrium result is obtained as described in Lemma 2.
Lemma 2.
In the case of platform encroachment, if the consumer’s valuation (product quality) is high enough to satisfy  q j > c ( 41 r ) 14 ( 1 r ) , then S and O compete for consumers in the competitive range.  Equilibrium decisions are  d j * = 24 c ( 17 r ) + 7 q j ( 1 r ) ( 17 + 3 δ ) 49 ( 1 r ) t , p S j E * = 12 c 7 ( 1 r ) , and p O j E * = 2 c ( 41 + 5 r ) 49 ( 1 r ) + 4 q j ( δ 1 ) 7 . The market demand of S and O are  D S j E * = c ( 17 r ) 7 ( 1 r ) t and D O j E * = 3 ( c 41 9 r + 14 q j δ 1 1 r ) 49 t ( 1 r ) . The profits of S and O are  π S j E * = c ( 12 c ( 17 + r ) + 7 q j ( 1 + r ) ( 17 + 3 δ ) ) 49 ( 1 r ) t and π O j E * = 6 ( c 2 ( 1681 + ( 1502 143 r ) r ) + 28 c q j ( 1 r ) ( 41 2 r ) ( 1 + δ ) + 196 q j 2 ( 1 r ) 2 ( 1 + δ ) 2 ) 2401 ( 1 r ) 2 t .
Proposition 2.
(1)  d j * q j < 0  when  1 < δ < 17 3 , and  d j * q j > 0  when  δ > 17 3 p S j *  is not related to  q j p O j * q j > 0 . (2)  d j * δ > 0 p S j *  is not related to  δ p O j * δ > 0 . (3)  d j * c > 0 p S j * c > 0 p O j * c > 0 . (4)  d j * r > 0 ,   p S j * r > 0 ,   p O j * r > 0 .
Proposition 2 (1) shows that when δ is small, the horizontal differentiation between products is negatively correlated with q j ; when δ is large, the horizontal differentiation between products is positively correlated with q j . This is because, for lower quality products, S increases market demand by expanding horizontal differentiation between products, thereby increasing revenue. For higher quality products, S does not need to invest more in product differentiation costs. However, when δ is larger, the valuation advantage of Oj is significant, and because ( U O j U S j ) q j = 3 ( δ 1 ) 7 > 0 , the greater the δ, the greater the encroachment threat caused by the increase in product quality. To mitigate the threat of encroachment, S needs to broaden the differentiation from Oj. Moreover, unlike Proposition 1, Proposition 2 (1) shows that under platform encroachment, the retail price and market demand of Sj are independent of product quality. This is because S can regulate competition by endogenizing the degree of horizontal differentiation between its product and O’s product. Proposition 2 (2) further indicates that the greater the δ, the higher O’s pricing, and S will expand the horizontal differentiation from Oj to alleviate competition and ensure that the retail price and market demand remain unchanged.
Propositions 2 (3) and (4) show that the pricing of S and O and the degree of horizontal differentiation between their products are positively correlated with c and r. This is because the higher the cost coefficient of horizontal differentiation and the higher the commission rate, the more S will be forced to increase pricing. O then gets a free ride, and its retail price rises. In addition, due to the increase in the retail price, S will expand its horizontal differentiation from Oj to avoid excessive decline in market demand. Therefore, d j * is positively correlated with c and r.
Proposition 3.
In the case of platform encroachment, when  1 < δ < 17 3 , the independent seller is positioned in the high-end product market, and when  δ > 17 3 , the independent seller is positioned in the low-end product market.
Proposition 3 shows that when δ is small, S chooses to sell category H; when δ is large, the excessive encroachment of O forces S to enter the low-end market to sell category L. Similar to Proposition 2 (1), if δ is small, the positive influence of q j on S will outweigh the negative influence, and S is positioned in the high-end product market. Conversely, if δ is large, the negative impact of q j on S is larger than the positive impact, and S is positioned in the low-end product market.
Proposition 4.
(1)  p S j N * > p S j E *  when  c < 7 q j 24 1 r , and  p S j N * < p S j E * when  c > 7 q j 24 1 r . (2)  D S j N * > D S j E * . (3)  π S j N * > π S j E * .
Proposition 4 shows that platform encroachment leads to reduced market demand and a lower retail price of Sj (when c is relatively small), thereby damaging S’s profit. Although the retail price of Sj under platform encroachment is higher when c is larger, its essence is the forced pricing increase caused by the increase in differentiation cost. The decrease in demand and the higher product differentiation cost ultimately reduce S’s profit.

3.3. O’s Encroachment Strategy

In this section, we examine the platform owner’s encroachment strategy, i.e., strategy N or strategy E. By comparing the profits of O under strategy N and strategy E, we obtain the conditions under which O adopts different encroachment strategies, as stated in Proposition 5.
Proposition 5.
When  δ > 31 + 8 62 93 1 < δ < 31 + 8 62 93  and  0 < r r ; or  1 < δ < 31 + 8 62 93 r < r < 1 , and  c > c , the platform owner adopts strategy E; when  1 < δ < 31 + 8 62 93 r < r < 1 , and  c < c , the platform owner adopts strategy N.
Where  r  is the root for the equation  289 + 3366 δ 9801 δ 2 + 4114 + 2868 δ + 882 δ 2 r + 769 282 δ 9 δ 2 r 2 + 48 r 3 = 0 c = ( 84 q j ( 1 r ) ( 41 2 r ) ( δ 1 ) 49 3 q j ( 1 r ) r 49 143 r 2 1632 δ 2 δ + 2 r 823 + 72 δ 2 δ ) / ( 858 r 2 10,086 9012 r ) .
Proposition 5 shows that when δ is large, or δ and r are small, or δ is small and r and c are large, O will encroach on S’s category; when δ is small, r is large, and c is small, O does not encroach. This is because when δ is large, O can earn higher profits by selling self-owned products. The lower the r, the lower O’s shared profit from S. Therefore, O is willing to introduce self-owned products to the market. In addition, when c is large, S will expand d j , which encourages O’s category encroachment. Figure 4 summarizes our findings.
In addition, Proposition 5 further shows that platform encroachment is related to category quality. When δ is small (i.e., 1 < δ < 1 93 31 + 8 62 ) and r is large (i.e., r < r < 1 ), if q H > q L > q , O will not encroach on any category of S; if q H > q > q L , S’s positioning in the high-end market can prevent platform encroachment; if q > q H > q L , O will encroach regardless of the vertical positioning strategy adopted by S. We obtain the following Proposition 6.
Where q = 24 c ( 41 + 2 r ) ( 1 + δ ) 14 3 c 2 r ( 49 143 r 2 1632 ( 2 + δ ) δ + 2 r ( 823 + 72 ( 2 + δ ) δ ) ) 7 ( 1 + r ) ( 49 r 48 ( 1 + δ ) 2 ) .
Proposition 6.
The platform owner is more likely to encroach on the low-quality category of the independent seller.
As stated in Proposition 2 above, when δ is small, the degree of horizontal differentiation between two sellers’ products is inversely proportional to quality. The lower the q j , the greater the d j , and the more likely O is to encroach.

3.4. Equilibrium Strategy Analysis

As stated in Proposition 1 and Proposition 3 above, S’s positioning strategy is different in competitive and non-competitive environments, and, as stated in Proposition 6 above, O’s encroachment strategy is also different under a different vertical positioning of S. Therefore, in this section, we construct the game matrix as shown in Table 2 and obtain the game equilibrium strategy and equilibrium conditions of S’s vertical positioning and O’s encroachment according to the profits of both parties under four different strategy combinations.
Proposition 7.
The equilibrium strategy is the following: (1) When  1 < δ < 1 93 31 + 8 62 r < r < 1 , and  q H > q > q L  or  q H > q L > q , the equilibrium strategy is {P,N}. (2) When  1 < δ < 1 93 31 + 8 62 r < r < 1 , and  q > q H > q L ; when  1 < δ < 1 93 31 + 8 62  and  0 < r < r ; or when  1 93 ( 31 + 8 62 ) δ < 17 3 , the equilibrium strategy is {P,E}. (3) When  δ > 17 3 , the equilibrium strategy is {T,E}.
Proposition 7 shows that when δ is small and r is large, O has little incentive to encroach. If α is large (i.e., α > q / q L ), the positioning of S in the high-end market can prevent O’s category encroachment. Even if the platform encroachment cannot be prevented ( 1 < α < q / q L ), S can still make a higher profit selling category H than selling category L. However, when r is small, O is willing to introduce self-owned products into the market even if the competitive advantage is not significant. Similarly, category H is the optimal vertical positioning strategy for S. In addition, when δ is large, O will inevitably encroach on the category of S to maximize the benefit. If δ is in the middle and the market competition is not fierce, category H can still bring more profits to S; if δ is too large, more consumers will buy high-quality products from O rather than S. Therefore, to ease competition and avoid more horizontal differentiation costs, S will be positioned in the low-end market.

3.5. Consumer Surplus and Social Welfare

In this section, we discuss the impact of the independent seller positioning strategy and platform encroachment strategies on consumer surplus and social welfare.
In the case of non-encroachment, the consumer surplus and social welfare are, respectively:
C S N = 2 0 x S j ( q j p S j x S j t )   d x S j = q j 2 4 t ,
S W N = C S N + π S j N * + π O j N * = 3 q j 2 4 t ,
In the case of encroachment, the consumer surplus and social welfare are, respectively:
C S N = 0 x S j ( q j p S j x S j t )   d x S j + 0 x S O j ( q j p S j x S j t )   d x S j + 0 d x S O j ( δ q j p O j x O j t )   d x O j + 0 x O j ( δ q j p O j x O j t )   d x O j = M 6 + q j 2 M 7 + q j M 8 2401 ( 1 + r ) 2 t ,
S W E = C S E + π S j E * + π O j E * = M 9 + q j 2 M 10 q j M 11 2401 ( 1 + r ) 2 t ,
where M 6 = c 2 ( 68,589 + 5658 r + 51 r 2 ) , M 7 = 49 ( r 1 ) 2 ( 3 δ ( 8 + 3 δ ) 131 ) , M 8 = 84 c ( 1 r ) ( 517 41 δ r ( 23 + 5 δ ) ) , M 9 = 9 c 2 ( 7611 + r ( 155 r 2806 ) ) , M 10 = 49 ( 1 r ) 2 ( 3 δ ( 11 δ 8 ) 107 ) , and M 11 = 7 c ( 1 + r ) ( 6053 + 345 δ + r ( 39 δ 1061 ) ) .
Proposition 8.
(1)  C S N q j > 0 ,  S W N q j > 0 C S E q j > 0 S W E q j > 0 . (2)  C S E > C S N S W E > S W N .
Proposition 8 shows that high-quality products always enable consumers to obtain a higher surplus, and social welfare is always higher. Although both O and consumers prefer S to adopt a high-end market positioning strategy, S is only willing to sell high-quality products if δ is small. Proposition 8 shows that the increase in O’s profit and consumer surplus under the high-quality category positioning strategy can compensate for the decline in S’s profit. In addition, Proposition 8 shows that consumers are inclined to platform encroachment, and social welfare can always be improved under O’s strategy E. Although O’s profit is low under strategy E when δ is small (i.e., 1 < δ < 1 93 31 + 8 62 ), r is high (i.e., r < r < 1 ), and c is low (i.e., c < c ), the increase in consumer surplus under strategy E makes up for the decrease in the profit of S and O. Therefore, the overall social welfare is higher under platform encroachment.

4. Numerical Simulation

To examine the robustness of the main results, we develop a multi-agent model, which is numerically studied in this section. We have formulated the decision rules of agents, and the interaction between agents is shown in Figure 5. S’s product positioning strategy and pricing strategy, on the one hand, affect consumers’ market demand for Sj, and on the other hand, they affect O’s encroachment strategy and pricing strategy (if there is encroachment), and O’s decisions, in turn, affect S’s decisions and consumers’ potential market demand for Oj. At the same time, consumer demand has an impact on the decisions of both S and O. In short, agents interact through their own decisions. Agents learn rules and adapt to the environment (different parameter combinations in the simulation experiment). Through multiple iterations, the agents make decisions adaptively and interact with each other to achieve convergence.

4.1. Multi-Agent Model Construction

4.1.1. Consumer Behavior

We use “~” to describe the multi-agent model. This model differs from the previous setup in that the consumer ideal is normally distributed, i.e., x ~ i j N ( 0 , σ 2 ) , as shown in Figure 6.
When O does not encroach, S positions the product at point 0 in the preference space to maximize profits. The utility that consumers obtain from buying Sj is U ~ S j = q j p ~ S j x ~ S j · t . The values x ~ 1 S j and x ~ 2 S j are defined as the boundary locations where consumers on the left and right sides of S obtain non-disutility by purchasing Sj. We obtain x ~ 1 S j = p ~ S j q j t , x ~ 2 S j = q j p ~ S j t , and S’s market demand is D ~ S j N = x ~ 1 S j x ~ 2 S j Φ x d x , where Φ x = 1 2 π σ exp x 2 2 σ 2 .
When O encroaches, without a loss of generality, S and O are located at d ~ j 2 and d ~ j 2 , respectively. The utility that consumers obtain from buying Sj is U ~ S j = q j p ~ S j x ~ S j + d ~ j 2 · t . The utility that consumers obtain from buying Oj is U ~ O j = δ q j p ~ O j x ~ O j d ~ j 2 · t . The values x ~ 1 O j and x ~ 2 O j are defined as the boundary locations where consumers on the left and right sides of O obtain non-disutility by purchasing Oj. The value x ~ S O j is defined as the undifferentiated location where the consumer buys Sj and Oj. In this case, we obtain x ~ 1 S j = 2 q j d ~ j t + 2 p ~ S j 2 t , x ~ 2 S j = 2 q j d ~ j t 2 p ~ S j 2 t , x ~ 1 O j = d ~ j t 2 q j δ + 2 p ~ O j 2 t , x ~ 2 O j = d ~ j t + 2 q j δ 2 p ~ O j 2 t , and x ~ S O j = q j q j δ p ~ S j + p ~ O j 2 t . When x ~ S O j d ~ j 2 , the market demand of both parties is D ~ S j E = 0 and D ~ O j E = x ~ 1 O j x ~ 2 O j Φ x d x , respectively; when d ~ j 2 < x ~ S O j < d ~ j 2 , the market demand of both parties is D ~ S j E = x ~ 1 S j x ~ S O j Φ x d x and D ~ O j E = x ~ S O j x ~ 2 O j Φ x d x , respectively; when x ~ S O j d ~ j 2 , the market demand of both parties is D ~ S j E = x ~ 1 S j x ~ 2 S j Φ x d x and D ~ O j E = 0 , respectively.

4.1.2. Decision Makers’ Behavior

As in the main model, when O does not encroach, S’s profit is π ~ S j N = 1 r · D ~ S j N · p ~ S j N and O’s profit is π ~ O j N = r · D ~ S j N · p ~ S j N . When O encroaches, S’s profit is π ~ S j E = 1 r · D ~ S j E · p ~ S j E d ~ j · c and O’s profit is π ~ O j E = r · D ~ S j E · p ~ S j E + D ~ O j E · p ~ O j E .
In addition, we set rules for decision makers. Due to space limitations, this paper only describes the rules under platform encroachment in detail; the case of non-encroachment is relatively simple, and the rules are similar. The rules under encroachment follow backward induction in game theory. Considering the complexity of real-world consumer markets and the bounded rationality of decision makers, we focus on the interaction between S and O in the decision-making process. Note that the adaptive process of the multi-agent model consists of multiple iterations. Figure 7 shows the decision-making process of the sequential game in one iteration.
In the Stackelberg game, the first two levels are S and the third level is O. At the first level, there are three possibilities for S to set up horizontal differentiation for iteration I, namely, d ~ ( I ) = d ~ ( I 1 ) + d ~ , d ~ ( I ) = d ~ I 1 , and d ~ ( I ) = d ~ ( I 1 ) d ~ , where d ~ is the change in horizontal differentiation during each iteration. At the second level, the retail prices that S may set are p ~ S ( I ) = p ~ S ( I 1 ) + p ~ , p ~ S ( I ) = p ~ S ( I 1 ) , and p ~ S ( I ) = p ~ S ( I 1 ) p ~ , where p ~ is the change in retail price during each iteration. As a result, S has a total of nine decision combinations. At the third level, corresponding to each decision combination of S, O also has three optional retail prices, namely p ~ O ( I ) = p ~ O ( I 1 ) + p ~ , p ~ O ( I ) = p ~ O ( I 1 ) , and p ~ O ( I ) = p ~ O ( I 1 ) p ~ . Therefore, we finally obtain 27 two-party decision-making combinations. We describe the decision rules of both parties as follows.
First, at the third level, corresponding to each decision combination of S, O selects one of the three retail prices to maximize its own profit. Then, moving up, as a leader, S can identify the response of O. Therefore, S can calculate the profit under its nine decision combinations and select a decision combination that maximizes its profit. Thus, through a round of iterative decision-making interaction, the decision-making results of the round of iteration are obtained. After several rounds of iteration, the final decision-making results converge to equilibrium.

4.2. Simulation Results and Analysis

To further discuss the influence of consumer ideal preference heterogeneity on equilibrium decision making, we experimentally analyze the impact of σ on S’s vertical and horizontal product positioning and O’s encroachment strategy. We set the parameters q L = 6 , q H = 9 , and t = 1; the initial values of the decision variables are d ~ ( 0 ) = 2 , p ~ S ( 0 ) = 1 , and p ~ O ( 0 ) = 3 ; and the change in horizontal differentiation d ~ and the change in price p ~ are both 0.01.

4.2.1. The Impact of σ on S’s Vertical Positioning

With different δ, the relationship between the profit difference of S’s positioning in the high-end and low-end product markets and σ is shown in Figure 8.
Observation 1.
(1) When σ is small, S is positioned in the low-end market, and when σ is large, S is positioned in the high-end market. (2) The willingness of S to locate a high-end market decreases with the increase in δ.
Figure 8 shows that when σ is small, π ~ S H E π ~ S L E < 0 , and when σ is large, π ~ S H E π ~ S L E > 0 . This is because the greater the product quality, the greater the threat of platform encroachment, and S intends to widen the horizontal differentiation from O’s product. However, when σ is small and the d value is larger, S will lose more consumers in concentrated areas. Compared with giving up some high-demand markets to provide profitable category H, providing traffic-attracting category L for high-demand markets can achieve higher returns. Therefore, S is positioned in the low-end market. When σ is large, the market competition is alleviated, and the horizontal preference distribution of consumers is dispersed, making category H’s valuation advantage appear, and S is more willing to locate in the high-end market. In addition, Figure 8 shows that the larger the δ is, the less likely S is to locate in the high-end market due to the influence of competition intensity. This is consistent with the conclusion in the main model.

4.2.2. The Impact of σ on S’s Horizontal Positioning

With different vertical positioning, the relationship between both parties’ horizontal differentiation and σ is shown in Figure 9.
Observation 2.
Horizontal differentiation between Sj and Oj first increases and then decreases with σ, and horizontal differentiation is greater in the high-end market.
As Figure 9 shows, d ~ j * first increases and then decreases with σ. This is because when σ is small, the ideal preferences of consumers are concentrated in the competitive range, and the product positioning of S is close to the ideal concentration to compete for more consumers. The larger the σ, the more dispersed the ideal preference distribution of consumers, and S increases the market demand by expanding the competition range. At the same time, the greater the horizontal differentiation between products, the higher the differentiation cost paid by S. When the profit increment brought by increasing market demand through expanding d is not enough to make up for the profit loss caused by the differentiation cost, S will narrow the horizontal differentiation from Oj. In addition, Figure 9 shows that d ~ H * is always greater than d ~ L * when the consumer’s ideal preference is normally distributed.

4.2.3. The Impact of σ on O’s Encroachment Strategy

For different quality categories, Figure 10 shows the relationship between O’s profit and σ under strategy E and strategy N.
Observation 3.
The motivation of O to encroach increases first and then decreases with σ, and O is more motivated to encroach on the low-end product market.
As Figure 10 shows, π ~ O j E < π ~ O j N when σ is small or large, and π ~ O j E > π ~ O j N when σ is centered. This is because when σ is small, S sets a small horizontal differentiation to win over consumers concentrated at the 0 point, resulting in fierce product competition, and O will not encroach to avoid excessive damage to shared revenue. When σ increases, the horizontal differentiation between products increases and the motivation of platform encroachment increases. However, when σ further increases, considering the horizontal differentiation cost and the excessively dispersed ideal preferences of consumers, S does not need to set a large d, and the platform’s self-operating revenue also declines, resulting in lower profits under strategy E than under strategy N. Therefore, O gives up encroachment. In addition, a comparison of Figure 10a,b shows that for the low-quality category, in a wider range of σ values, O’s profit under strategy E is higher than that under strategy N. Therefore, O has more incentive to encroach on the low-quality category. This is consistent with the conclusion of Proposition 6.

5. Three Extensions

5.1. Positive Production Cost

In the main model, for the simplicity of analysis, we assume that sellers’ vertical production costs are normalized to zero. Therefore, we extend the model to explore whether positive vertical production costs affect the equilibrium outcome. Specifically, we define k as the cost per unit of product quality and k q j as the vertical production cost, that is, the higher the quality of the product, the higher the vertical production cost.
In the case of non-encroachment, the profit functions of S and O are π S j N = 1 r · D S j N · p S j D S j N · k q j and π O j N = r · D S j N · p S j . In the case of encroachment, the profit functions of S and O are π S j E = 1 r · D S j E · p S j D S j E · k q j d j · c and π O j E = r · D S j E · p S j + D O j E · ( p O j k q j ) . Table 3 shows the equilibrium results obtained by backward induction.
Proposition 9.
(1) In the case of non-encroachment, the independent seller is positioned in the high-end product market. (2) In the case of platform encroachment, when  k k  or when  0 < k < k  and  δ > δ , the independent seller locates in the low-end product market; when  0 < k < k  and  1 < δ < δ , the independent seller locates in the high-end product market.
Where  δ = 17 3 2 k ( 7 + r ) 3 ( 1 r )  and  k = 7 1 r 7 + r .
Consistent with the results of the main model, S chooses to sell products in a high-quality category in the absence of platform encroachment. Proposition 9 shows that in the case of platform encroachment, the vertical production cost has an impact on the vertical positioning strategy of S. When k is large, S will not target the high-quality category. When k is small, like the results of the main model, and if δ is large, S will target the low-quality category; otherwise, the high-quality category will be targeted. In addition, because δ < 17 3 , the positive vertical production cost makes it more likely that S will target the low-end market under platform encroachment.
Proposition 10.
When  δ > 31 + 8 62 93 1 < δ < 31 + 8 62 93  and  0 < r r 1 < δ < 31 + 8 62 93 r < r < 1 , and  c > c ; or  1 < δ < 31 + 8 62 93 r < r < 1 c < c , and  k k , the platform owner adopts strategy E; when  1 < δ < 31 + 8 62 93 r < r < 1 c < c , and  0 < k < k , the platform owner adopts strategy N.
Where  k = 48 c ( 3 r 37 ) 7 q j ( 49 + 40 r ) + 46 ( r 1 ) ( δ 1 ) 49 + 40 r + M 18 + q j M 19 + q j 2 M 20 q j 2 r ( 49 + 40 r ) 2 M 18 = 12 c 2 ( r ( 2490 + r ( 152 r 1953 ) ) 1681 ) M 19 = 336 c ( r 1 ) ( 41 38 r + 4 r 2 ) ( δ 1 ) , and  M 20 = 49 1 r 2 ( 40 r 2 48 δ 1 2 + r ( 53 + 4 ( δ 2 ) δ ) ) .
Proposition 10 shows that the influence of δ, r, and c on O’s encroachment decision is the same as that of the main model. In addition, Proposition 10 shows that when δ is small, r is large and c is small; if k is large, then O is willing to encroach the category; otherwise, O does not encroach. This is because a larger k allows S to set a higher retail price and horizontal product differentiation, and O gains more benefits by free riding through encroachment than by larger production costs.

5.2. Pricing Decision Order

Next, we assume that when O encroaches, S and O simultaneously determine the retail price of the product. Other settings remain unchanged. S first conducts vertical positioning, observes whether O encroaches, and then conducts horizontal positioning. Finally, S and O simultaneously determine the retail price of their respective products. Through backward induction, the equilibrium results under platform encroachment are obtained, as Table 4 shows.
We find that the optimal vertical positioning strategy of S in the case of simultaneous pricing is consistent with Proposition 3.
Proposition 11.
When  δ > 17 ( 17 + 2 283 ) 843 1 < δ < 17 ( 17 + 2 283 ) 843  and  0 < r r ; or  1 < δ < 17 ( 17 + 2 283 ) 843 r < r < 1 , and  c > c , the platform owner adopts strategy E; when  1 < δ < 17 ( 17 + 2 283 ) 843 r < r < 1 , and  c < c , the platform owner adopts strategy N.
Where  r  is the root for the equation  306 δ 867 δ 2 27 + 361 + 280 δ + 24 δ 2 r 46 + 8 δ r 2 + r 3 = 0 ,  c = 42 q j ( 42 r ) ( r 1 ) ( δ 1 ) ( 35 r ) ( 147 + 4 ( 35 r ) r ) + 147 q j 2 1 r 2 r ( 3 4 r 2 144 δ 2 δ + 4 r ( 36 + ( δ 2 ) δ ) ) ( 35 r ) 2 ( 147 4 ( 35 + r ) r ) 2 .
Relative to Proposition 5 of our main model, we find that the encroachment strategy of O is essentially similar. In addition, Proposition 11 shows that in the simultaneous pricing scenario, O will choose to encroach only if there is a larger δ or a smaller r. This is because S loses the advantage of early pricing, leading to lower pricing and expanding the horizontal differentiation from Oj. Therefore, platform encroachment has a greater negative impact on S’s profit. To avoid an excessive decline in shared profits, platform encroachment motivation is weakened.

5.3. O’s Consumer Surplus Concern

More and more e-commerce platforms are not only pursuing their own profits but also pursuing the interests of consumers. Therefore, in this section, we consider the impact of O’s consumer surplus concern on S’s positioning strategy and O’s encroachment strategy.
In the case of non-encroachment, the profit functions of S and O are π S j N = 1 r · D S j N · p S j N and π O j N = r · D S j N · p S j N + μ · C S N . In the case of encroachment, the profit functions of S and O are π S j E = 1 r · D S j E · p S j E d j · c and π O j E = r · D S j E · p S j E + D O j E · p O j E + μ · C S E , where μ (μ > 0) represents the degree of O’s consumer surplus concern. Table 5 shows the equilibrium results obtained by backward induction.
Proposition 12.
When  μ > 7 4 , or when  0 < μ < 7 4  and  1 < δ < 1 3 ( 17 8 μ ) , the independent seller is positioned in the high-quality product market; when  0 < μ < 7 4  and  δ > 1 3 ( 17 8 μ ) , the independent seller is positioned in the low-quality product market.
By comparison with the results in the main model, we can confirm that the product positioning strategy structure of S is essentially similar when O pays less attention to consumer surplus. In addition, Proposition 12 shows that when O pays more attention to consumer surplus, S is positioned in the high-quality product market. This is because competition and conflict caused by larger consumer surplus concerns are dominant, and the higher quality product can reduce O’s sacrifice behavior to a certain extent, which is also beneficial to S.
We find that the equilibrium result obtained by backward induction is rather complex. Therefore, we numerically discuss the influence of consumer surplus concern on O’s encroachment strategy. Figure 11 shows the equilibrium results when μ = 0, μ = 1, and μ = 4.
We note that because platform encroachment is beneficial to consumer surplus, O is very willing to encroach when it starts to pay attention to consumer surplus. However, as O pays more attention to consumer surplus, O sacrifices more, resulting in excessive competition with S and hindering profits. Therefore, O does not encroach. In short, O’s proper attention to consumer surplus incentivizes encroachment, thereby enhancing social welfare.

6. Conclusions

Focusing on the vertical and horizontal positioning of S’s product under platform category encroachment, we build a Stackelberg game model under the framework of the Hotelling model to explore the interaction between O’s encroachment strategy and S’s product positioning strategy. We combine this with the multi-agent method to further analyze the influence of consumer preference heterogeneity on equilibrium decision making. In addition, we extend our model to consider the positive production cost, the simultaneous price game, and the platform owner’s focus on consumer surplus.
The research findings are as follows: (1) O’s category encroachment will encroach on the sales of S. Therefore, S will regulate competition through endogenous horizontal differentiation from O’s product. In particular, the greater the consumer preference for platform self-owned products, the greater the horizontal differentiation between the two products. However, when the horizontal differentiation between the two products is expanded, the horizontal differentiation cost is higher, determining, to some extent, the vertical positioning of S. When O’s encroachment effect is weak, S can often obtain higher profits by positioning in the high-end product market and even prevent platform encroachment. However, when O’s encroachment effect is strong, the positioning of S in the low-end product market can effectively alleviate competition. (2) O will decide whether to encroach by weighing self-operating income and shared income. When the consumer preference for platform self-owned products is large and the commission rate is small, O is more willing to profit from the self-operated products. In addition, the higher the unit cost of horizontal differentiation, the higher the pricing of S, which encourages O’s free riding and enhances the encroachment motivation. (3) Our simulation experiments show that when consumers’ ideal preferences are concentrated, S vertically locates in the low-end product market and horizontally locates close to the consumers’ ideal preference concentration area to obtain more market demand. Conversely, S locates in the high-end product market and adopts the strategy of expanding the horizontal differentiation of products. However, simultaneously, limited by the cost of horizontal differentiation, S will narrow the horizontal differentiation of products when consumers’ ideal preferences are relatively dispersed. Similarly, when the ideal preferences of consumers are concentrated, O is more likely to encroach on the low-end product market, and when the ideal preferences of consumers are dispersed, O’s encroachment does not increase its revenue. (4) Positive production costs have a negative impact on O’s encroachment and S’s high-end market positioning. The price decision order does not affect S’s vertical positioning strategy, but compared with the sequential order, the simultaneous pricing increases the horizontal differentiation between S’s product and O’s product. This is not conducive to S’s profit and hinders the platform encroachment to a certain extent. (5) Platform encroachment and high-end product positioning are good for consumer surplus and social welfare. O’s appropriate attention to consumer surplus encourages encroachment, while excessive attention to consumer surplus hinders encroachment but encourages S to locate in the high-end product market.
We obtain some management insights. It is critical for independent sellers to identify the heterogeneity of consumer preferences and understand platform encroachment. When consumers have a high preference for platform self-operation, independent sellers can choose to locate in the low-end product market to survive. Independent sellers can also improve consumer preferences by providing services that accompany products, as well as further improving product quality, reducing unit production cost, and raising barriers to imitation by improving production technology, thereby increasing revenue and preventing platform encroachment. In addition, when consumers’ ideal preferences are concentrated, independent sellers should adopt a high-demand strategy (positioning in the low-end product market with less competition), and when consumers’ ideal preferences are dispersed, independent sellers should adopt a high-margin profit strategy (positioning in the high-end product market with higher valuation advantages). From the perspective of platform owners, first, improving self-preference will certainly bring more self-operating profits, but excessive self-preference will lead to independent sellers positioning in the low-end product market, thus damaging supply chain profits; second, platform owners can encourage independent sellers to expand their horizontal differentiation between products by moderately increasing the commission rate, thereby alleviating competition and increasing revenue. In addition, platform owners can use their own information advantages to find and enter the product market where consumers’ ideal preferences are concentrated and quality competition is not fierce. Finally, platform owners should allow independent sellers to set prices first, considering both profit and consumer surplus, while keeping consumer surplus concerns within reasonable limits. Considering that the positioning of high-end product markets and platform encroachment have a positive impact on consumer surplus and social welfare, the government can take appropriate measures to guide platform owners to weaken their self-preference (for example, platform owners can narrow the gap between consumers’ preference for self-owned products and independent sellers’ products by helping independent sellers with marketing promotions) and reduce the commission rate.
Future research could take the following approaches: First, this paper focuses on the heterogeneity of consumers’ ideal preferences and channel preferences. However, the heterogeneity of consumer preferences is diverse, as is the heterogeneity of consumers’ product quality preferences. Future studies could complicate the model setting of consumer heterogeneity and compare the impact of horizontal and vertical preferences on consumer choice. Second, this paper assumes that platform owners collect deductible income from independent sellers, while some composite e-commerce platforms implement two-part fees. Moreover, this paper only considers the short-term behavior of platform owners, whereby the commission rate is an exogenous variable. In the future, we can compare the different charging modes of the platform and consider the long-term behavior of the platform owner with an endogenous commission rate and fixed membership fee and further study the coordination mechanism with independent sellers. Finally, this paper does not consider the encroachment cost of platform owners. In reality, because independent sellers may have more resource advantages for the products they sell, the fixed cost is usually silent, while platform owners need to pay a positive fixed cost to enter the product market, which is also a potential future research direction.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Z.W. and T.Y.; methodology, Z.W.; software, Z.W.; validation, Z.W. and T.Y.; formal analysis, Z.W.; investigation, T.Y.; resources, T.Y.; data curation, Z.W.; writing—original draft preparation, Z.W.; writing—review and editing, Z.W. and T.Y.; visualization, Z.W.; supervision, T.Y.; project administration, T.Y.; funding acquisition, T.Y. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

Data are contained within the article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Zhang, K. Business models of hybrid e-commerce platforms: The number of third-party. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2019, 22, 110–126. [Google Scholar]
  2. Chen, T.; Hou, W.H.; Zhang, X.X. Decision analysis of product positioning with manufacturer rebate competition. Soft Sci. 2019, 33, 72–79. [Google Scholar]
  3. Chen, Q.; Ren, J. The methodology of scientific research programmer foundation of innovative low-cost strategy. Stud. Sci. Sci. 2011, 29, 349–358. [Google Scholar]
  4. Seamans, R.C. Fighting City Hall: Entry deterrence and technology upgrades in cable TV markets. Manag. Sci. 2012, 58, 461–475. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Ethiraj, S.; Zhou, Y.M. Fight or flight? Market positions, submarket interdependencies, and strategic responses to entry threats. SMJ 2019, 40, 1545–1569. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Wen, W.; Zhu, F. Threat of platform-owner entry and complementor responses: Evidence from the mobile app market. Strateg. Manag. J. 2019, 40, 1336–1367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Wang, R.D.; Shaver, J.M. Competition-driven repositioning. SMJ 2014, 35, 1585–1604. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Amaldoss, W.; He, C. Product variety, informative advertising, and price competition. J. Mark. Res. 2010, 47, 146–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Zhu, F.; Liu, Q.H. Competing with complementors: An empirical look. Amazon.com. Strateg. Manag. J. 2018, 39, 2618–2642. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Foerderer, J.; Kude, T.; Mithas, S.; Heinzl, A. Does platform owner’s entry crowd out innovation? Evidence from Google photos. Syst. Res. 2018, 29, 444–460. [Google Scholar]
  11. Ryan, J.K.; Sun, D.; Zhao, X. Competition and coordination in online marketplaces. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2012, 21, 997–1014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Lam, W.M.W.; Liu, X.Y. Dancing with rivals: How does platform’s information usage benefit independent sellers? Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2023, 309, 421–431. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Zennyo, Y. Platform encroachment and own-content bias. J. Ind. Econ. 2022, 70, 684–710. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Wu, J.; Bi, G.B.; Xu, Y.; Dang, X.J. Channel structure of E-platform encroachment. RAIRO—Oper. Res. 2023, 57, 157–181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Tian, L.; Vakharia, A.J.; Tan, Y.; Xu, Y. Marketplace, reseller, or hybrid: Strategic analysis of an emerging e-commerce model. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2018, 27, 1595–1610. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Jiang, B.; Jerath, K.; Srinivasan, K. Firm strategies in the ‘mid tail’ of platform-based retailing? Mark. Sci. 2011, 30, 757–775. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Etro, F. Product selection in online marketplaces. Econ. Manag. Strategy 2021, 30, 614–637. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Wang, L.L.; Sun, H. Influencing factors of second-hand platform trading in C2C E-commerce. J. Intell. Manag. Decis. 2023, 2, 21–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Su, J.F.; Wang, D.; Xu, B.J.; Zhang, F.T.; Zhang, N. An interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy group decision-making method for evaluating online knowledge payment products. Appl. Soft Comput. 2024, 150, 111046. [Google Scholar]
  20. Du, H.F.; Guan, Z.Z. The vertically differential product introduction strategy considering strategic consumers and enterprise cost reduction. J. Syst. Manag. 2023, 32, 1–22. [Google Scholar]
  21. Liu, J.C.; Zhai, X. Optimal product innovation and pricing strategies in the presence of strategic consumers. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2023, 31, 56–65. [Google Scholar]
  22. Lauga, D.O.; Ofek, E. Product positioning in a two-dimensional vertical differentiation model: The role of quality costs. Mark. Sci. 2011, 30, 903–923. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Yi, Y.Y.; Chen, Y.X. Product Appearance and Functionality Quality Competition Model in Toy Manufacturers Duopoly Market. CIMS 2020, 26, 2216–2231. [Google Scholar]
  24. Chen, J.X.; Liang, L.; Yang, F. Cooperative quality investment in outsourcing. IJPE 2015, 162, 174–191. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Ha, A.; Long, X.Y.; Nasiry, J. Quality in supply chain encroachment. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2016, 18, 280–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Feng, N.; Chen, J.J.; Feng, H.Y.; Li, M.Q. Optimal product selection and pricing strategies for platform vendors under two-sided network effects. Commer. Res. Appl. 2020, 43, 100990. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Guo, X.L.; Li, K. Research on impacts of manufacturers’ innovation investment decision-making under different competition modes. J. Northeast. Univ. (Nat. Sci.) 2022, 43, 124–132. [Google Scholar]
  28. Baron, D.P. Dynamic positioning, product innovation, and entry in a vertically differentiated market. Econ. Manag. Strategy 2021, 30, 287–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Kapkin, E.; Joines, S. An investigation into the relationship between product form and perceived meanings. Int. J. Ind. Ergon. 2018, 67, 259–273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Sajeesh, S.; Raju, J.S. Positioning and pricing in a variety seeking market. Manag. Sci. 2010, 56, 949–961. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Ottaviano, G.I.P.; Thisse, J.F. Monopolistic competition, multiproduct firms and product diversity. Manch. Sch. 2011, 79, 938–951. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Ebina, T.; Matsushima, N.; Shimizu, D. Product differentiation and entry timing in a continuous-time spatial Competition Model. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2015, 247, 904–913. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Chen, J.X.; Liang, L. Decision analysis of product positioning of competing firms with consumer return. Syst. Eng. Theor. Pract. 2016, 36, 3123–3132. [Google Scholar]
  34. Tian, C.; Xiao, T.; Shang, J. Channel differentiation strategy in a dual-channel supply chain considering free riding behavior. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2022, 301, 473–485. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Shangguan, L.L.; Miao, Z.W.; Lan, Y.Q. Two-dimensional product differentiation and pricing strategies. Syst. Eng. Pract. 2021, 41, 93–112. [Google Scholar]
  36. Geng, X.; Tan, Y.; Wei, L. How add-on pricing interacts with distribution contracts. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2018, 27, 605–623. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Qin, X.; Liu, Z.; Tian, L. The optimal combination between selling mode and logistics service strategy in an e-commerce market. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2021, 289, 639–651. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Wu, J.; Lu, W.; Ji, X. The interactions between upstream quality disclosure and downstream entry. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2023, 309, 545–559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Hagiu, A.; Teh, T.H.; Wright, J. Should Platforms Be Allowed to Sell on Their Own Marketplaces? Rand J. Econ. 2022, 53, 297–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Li, Q.; Wang, Q.S.; Song, P.J. Third-party sellers’ product entry strategy and its sales impact on a hybrid retail platform. Electron. Commer. Res. Appl. 2021, 47, 101049. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Xia, N.; Rajagopalan, S. Standard vs. custom products: Variety, lead time, and price competition. Mark. Sci. 2009, 28, 887–900. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Zhang, Z.J.; Liu, W.J. Research on channel mode selection of online platform product competition. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2023, 31, 245–254. [Google Scholar]
  43. Li, X.; Cai, X.Q.; Chen, J. Quality and private label encroachment strategy. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2021, 31, 374–390. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Zhou, C.; Yu, J.; Li, H. Single or hybrid: Selling mode choices of self-run platform under dual competition environment. J. Northeast. Univ. (Nat. Sci.) 2021, 42, 1349–1359. [Google Scholar]
  45. Lu, X.J.; Lin, J.; Sun, L.J. Green new product investment strategy considering demand uncertainty and externality. Syst. Eng. 2023, 41, 29–38. [Google Scholar]
  46. Li, K.J.; Liu, Y. Same or different? An aesthetic design question. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2019, 28, 1465–1485. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Supply chain structure.
Figure 1. Supply chain structure.
Systems 12 00036 g001
Figure 2. Consumer market segmentation (a) in the case of non-encroachment and (b) in the case of encroachment.
Figure 2. Consumer market segmentation (a) in the case of non-encroachment and (b) in the case of encroachment.
Systems 12 00036 g002
Figure 3. Sequence of events.
Figure 3. Sequence of events.
Systems 12 00036 g003
Figure 4. O’s decision on category encroachment (analysis results).
Figure 4. O’s decision on category encroachment (analysis results).
Systems 12 00036 g004
Figure 5. Interaction between agents.
Figure 5. Interaction between agents.
Systems 12 00036 g005
Figure 6. Normal distribution of consumers’ ideal preferences.
Figure 6. Normal distribution of consumers’ ideal preferences.
Systems 12 00036 g006
Figure 7. Decisions in an iteration.
Figure 7. Decisions in an iteration.
Systems 12 00036 g007
Figure 8. Joint effect of σ and δ on S’s vertical positioning (c = 0.05, r = 0.1).
Figure 8. Joint effect of σ and δ on S’s vertical positioning (c = 0.05, r = 0.1).
Systems 12 00036 g008
Figure 9. Joint effect of σ and q j on S’s horizontal positioning (c = 0.05, r = 0.1, δ = 1.5).
Figure 9. Joint effect of σ and q j on S’s horizontal positioning (c = 0.05, r = 0.1, δ = 1.5).
Systems 12 00036 g009
Figure 10. Joint effect of σ and q j on O’s encroachment strategy (c = 0.01, r = 0.9, δ = 1.1): (a) encroachment on the low-quality category; (b) encroachment on the high-quality category.
Figure 10. Joint effect of σ and q j on O’s encroachment strategy (c = 0.01, r = 0.9, δ = 1.1): (a) encroachment on the low-quality category; (b) encroachment on the high-quality category.
Systems 12 00036 g010
Figure 11. Impact of μ on O’s encroachment strategy ( q j   = 9, r = 0.99, t = 1): (a) μ = 0; (b) μ = 1; (c) μ = 4.
Figure 11. Impact of μ on O’s encroachment strategy ( q j   = 9, r = 0.99, t = 1): (a) μ = 0; (b) μ = 1; (c) μ = 4.
Systems 12 00036 g011
Table 1. Main symbols.
Table 1. Main symbols.
SymbolsDefinition
αDegree of vertical differentiation between category L and category H. Category L corresponds to the low-quality category, while category H corresponds to the high-quality category.
rPlatform commission rate.
tThe utility loss per unit distance, when a consumer purchases a product that is not their ideal preference.
δThe consumer preference for platform self-owned products.
cThe horizontal differentiation cost per unit.
q j The category j’s quality ( j { L ,   H } ).
d j The degree of horizontal differentiation between Sj and Oj. S and O indicate the independent seller and platform owner, respectively.
x i j The distance between the consumer’s ideal and product ij ( i { O ,   S } ).
p i j N ( p i j E )The retail price of product ij under strategy N (strategy E). Strategy N indicates that O does not encroach, while strategy E indicates that O encroaches.
U i j The utility obtained by the consumer from purchasing product ij.
D i j N ( D i j E )The market demand of product ij under strategy N (strategy E).
π i j N ( π i j E )The i’s profit when S chooses to sell category j and O adopts strategy N (strategy E).
C S N ( C S E )The consumer surplus under strategy N (strategy E).
S W N ( S W E )The social welfare under strategy N (strategy E).
σThe heterogeneity of consumers’ ideal preferences.
kThe cost per unit of product quality.
μThe degree of O’s consumer surplus concern.
Table 2. The equilibrium profits of both parties under the four strategy combinations.
Table 2. The equilibrium profits of both parties under the four strategy combinations.
OS
LH
N π S L N * = q L 2 ( 1 r ) 2 t π S H N * = α 2 q L 2 ( 1 r ) 2 t
π O L N * = q L 2 r 2 t π O H N * = α 2 q L 2 r 2 t
E π S L E * = c ( M 1 + q L M 2 ) 49 ( 1 r ) t π S H E * = c ( M 1 + α q L M 2 ) 49 ( 1 r ) t
π O L E * = 6 ( M 3 + q L M 4 + q L 2 M 5 ) 2401 ( 1 r ) 2 t π O H E * = 6 ( M 3 + α q L M 4 + α 2 q L 2 M 5 ) 2401 ( 1 r ) 2 t
Where  M 1 = 12 c ( 17 + r ) , M 2 = 7 1 r 17 3 δ , M 3 = c 2 ( 1681 + ( 1502 143 r ) r ) , M 4 = 28 c 1 r 41 2 r δ 1 ,   a n d   M 5 = 196 ( 1 r ) 2 ( δ 1 ) 2 .
Table 3. Equilibrium results in the case of positive production cost.
Table 3. Equilibrium results in the case of positive production cost.
NE
d j * 24 c 17 r q j M 12 49 ( 1 r ) t
p S j * q j ( 1 + k r ) 2 ( 1 r ) 12 c + 7 k q j 7 ( 1 r )
p O j * 2 c ( 41 + 5 r ) + q j M 13 49 ( 1 r )
π S j * q j 2 ( 1 + k + r ) 2 2 ( 1 r ) t c ( 12 c 17 + r q j M 14 ) 49 ( 1 r ) t
π O j * q j 2 r ( 1 k + r ) ( 1 + k + r ) 2 ( 1 r ) 2 t 2 ( M 15 + q j 2 M 16 q j M 17 ) 2401 ( 1 + r ) 2 t
Where M 12 = 7 ( 2 k ( 7 + r ) + ( 1 + r ) ( 17 + 3 δ ) ) , M 13 = 7 ( k ( 7 2 r ) + 4 ( 1 r ) ( 1 + δ ) ) , M 14 = 14 k ( 7 + r ) 7 ( 1 + r ) ( 17 + 3 δ ) , M 15 = c 2 ( 5043 + 4506 r 429 r 2 ) , M 16 = 49 ( r ( 3 + 2 k 3 δ ) + 3 ( 1 + δ ) ) ( r ( 4 + 5 k 4 δ ) + 4 ( 1 + δ ) ) , and M 17 = 84 c ( k r ( 74 + 6 r ) 41 ( 1 + δ ) r ( 43 + 2 r ) ( 1 + δ ) ) .
Table 4. Equilibrium results of platform encroachment in the case of simultaneous pricing.
Table 4. Equilibrium results of platform encroachment in the case of simultaneous pricing.
E
d j * c ( 35 + r ) 2 147 t ( 1 r ) + q j ( 3 δ 17 ) 7 t
p S j * c ( 35 r ) 21 ( 1 r )
p O j * c ( 35 r ) ( 7 + r ) 147 ( 1 r ) + 4 q j ( δ 1 ) 7
π S j * c ( c ( 35 + r ) 2 + 42 q j ( 1 + r ) ( 17 3 δ ) ) 294 ( 1 + r ) t
π O j * M 21 + q j M 22 + q j 2 M 23 43,218 ( 1 + r ) 2 t
Where M 21 = c 2 35 + r 2 ( 147 + 4 ( 35 r ) r ) , M 22 = 84 c ( 42 r ) ( 35 r ) ( 1 r ) ( δ 1 ) , and M 23 = 21,168 ( 1 + r ) 2 ( 1 + δ ) 2 .
Table 5. Equilibrium results in the case of O’s consumer surplus concern.
Table 5. Equilibrium results in the case of O’s consumer surplus concern.
NE
d j * 12 c ( 2 + μ ) ( 17 + r + 8 μ ) + q j ( 1 + r ) ( 7 + 4 μ ) ( 17 + 3 δ + 8 μ ) ( 1 r ) t ( 7 4 μ ) 2
p S j * q j 2 6 c ( 2 + μ ) ( 1 r ) ( 7 + 4 μ )
p O j * 4 q j ( 1 + r ) ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + μ ) ( 7 + 4 μ ) + 2 c ( 41 5 r + 61 μ + 2 r μ 20 μ 2 ) ( 1 + r ) ( 7 4 μ ) 2
π S j * q j 2 ( 1 r ) 2 t c ( 6 c ( 2 + μ ) ( 17 + r + 8 μ ) + q j ( 1 + r ) ( 7 + 4 μ ) ( 17 + 3 δ + 8 μ ) ) ( 1 + r ) t ( 7 4 μ ) 2
π O j * q j 2 ( 2 r + μ ) 4 t 6 ( q j 2 M 24 q j M 25 + M 26 ) ( 1 + r ) 2 t ( 7 4 μ ) 4
Where M 24 = 4 ( 1 + r ) 2 ( 1 + δ ) 2 ( 7 4 μ ) 2 ( 1 + μ ) , M 25 = 2 c ( 1 + r ) ( 1 + δ ) ( 7 + 4 μ ) ( 82 + 4 r + 122 μ 11 r μ + 4 ( 10 + r ) μ 2 ) , and M 26 = c 2 ( ( 41 20 μ ) 2 ( 1 + μ ) + r 2 ( 143 + μ ( 199 + 16 ( 6 + μ ) μ ) ) + 2 r ( 751 + μ ( 1495 + 16 μ ( 75 + 4 ( 7 + μ ) μ ) ) ) ) .
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, Z.; Yang, T. Research on the Product Positioning Strategy of the Independent Seller under Platform Encroachment. Systems 2024, 12, 36. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12010036

AMA Style

Wang Z, Yang T. Research on the Product Positioning Strategy of the Independent Seller under Platform Encroachment. Systems. 2024; 12(1):36. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12010036

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Ziyan, and Tianjian Yang. 2024. "Research on the Product Positioning Strategy of the Independent Seller under Platform Encroachment" Systems 12, no. 1: 36. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12010036

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop