Next Article in Journal
Validation of an Inventory of Sensitivity to Ideological Radicalization (ISIR-14) in a Mexican Sample
Previous Article in Journal
In Her Multimedia Words: Ukrainian Women in The Netherlands, Belonging and Temporary Protection Status
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Poverty Effectiveness of Social Security Benefits in Türkiye

by
Zeynep Gizem Can
1,2
1
Department of International Trade and Finance, Adana Alparslan Türkeş Science & Technology University, No:1U, 01250 Adana, Turkey
2
School of Geography, Archaeology & Irish Studies, University of Galway, H91 TK33 Galway, Ireland
Soc. Sci. 2025, 14(7), 421; https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci14070421
Submission received: 25 May 2025 / Revised: 1 July 2025 / Accepted: 4 July 2025 / Published: 8 July 2025
(This article belongs to the Section Social Policy and Welfare)

Abstract

This research investigates the role and effectiveness of Türkiye’s social security system and transfer expenditures in addressing poverty. Social security mechanisms are designed to alleviate poverty by helping individuals meet their essential needs. In Türkiye, transfer payments offer temporary relief, particularly to disadvantaged populations; however, they may also foster long-term dependency. Although the immediate impacts of such transfers are widely discussed in the academic literature, their contribution to alleviating structural poverty remains underexplored. This study focuses on how transfer expenditures influence individuals’ ability to achieve lasting well-being. The Turkish context is especially relevant due to recent institutional shifts in social security policy and the increasing politicization of social assistance. Employing data analysis at the regional level, this study assesses the effectiveness of social transfers and explores their structural role in poverty reduction. It also provides policy suggestions aimed at developing more inclusive and durable strategies. The results are intended to offer broadly applicable insights for other developing countries through the lens of Türkiye’s experience.

1. Introduction

As a critical tool in the fight against poverty, the social security system aims to provide social protection that enables individuals to meet basic needs such as health, education, and unemployment support. In Türkiye, the social safety net aims to protect the most vulnerable segments of society by offering various forms of support, particularly targeting the unemployed, disabled, elderly, and low-income groups. Complementing the social security system, transfer expenditures constitute another important mechanism in Türkiye’s anti-poverty strategy. These expenditures include direct cash transfers, food assistance, housing support, and minimum income programs provided through various state-led social assistance schemes. Such measures aim to offer temporary financial relief to the most disadvantaged, particularly during periods of high poverty. However, the impact of these interventions is often short-term and may fall short in addressing the structural causes of poverty. Moreover, in the long run, these supports may foster dependency, limiting individuals’ economic autonomy and potentially deepening social inequalities. Therefore, evaluating the effectiveness of transfer expenditures requires examining not only their immediate benefits but also their long-term impacts on poverty. Building directly on existing research on the poverty impact of social security in Southern Europe (Matsaganis et al. 2006, 2007), we undertake a parallel and related exercise in Türkiye.
Welfare reform is poised to remain a central topic of policy debate in the early decades of the 21st century, primarily because it intersects with the larger issue of how to sustain the European social model amid significant economic and societal shifts. Although discussions tend to concentrate on pensions and other major components of social protection, social assistance often receives less attention. Yet, the same pressures prompting broader welfare changes are also elevating the role of social assistance within welfare systems (Atkinson 1998). The stable foundations of the post-war era—often referred to as the “golden age of welfare capitalism”are no longer dependable. The decline of “Fordism” and the emergence of a “new economy” have substantially altered the labor market assumptions that underpin welfare institutions. Secure, long-term employment with a single employer has given way to increased job insecurity, more frequent employment transitions, unemployment spells, and the growth of precarious work. These labor market developments have eroded the basis of the traditional “male breadwinner model,” a trend that is compounded by shifting family dynamics. Rising ages at marriage, lower birth rates, the normalization of cohabitation without marriage, and other changes have challenged the conventional notion of a male provider and a homemaking spouse
In the context of Türkiye, the relationship between social policy and poverty has been a long-debated issue. Buğra and Keyder (2006) argue that social assistance in Türkiye tends to generate political dependency rather than resolving structural poverty. Social protection measures implemented during crisis periods in Türkiye have had positive effects, especially on vulnerable groups. However, most of the existing literature focuses on the short-term effects of social assistance, with insufficient discussion of its long-term implications. Studies like that of Nolan et al. (1999) examine the effects of social security transfers on the unemployed and their effectiveness in reducing income poverty, yet gaps remain concerning the long-term effects of social policies in Türkiye.
In other countries, the relationship between social policy and poverty is explored from a broader perspective. Hunter (1958), Wilensky (1974), Titmuss (1967, 2006), and Gilbert (2002) are now cited alongside Esping-Andersen (1999) to better ground the analysis in classic welfare state theory. Some authors for example, examine social policies through the framework of welfare state regimes, emphasizing their impact on market dependency and inequality. One of some authors, Moene and Wallerstein (2001) discuss how political support for welfare policies may be weaker in less egalitarian societies, using the social transfer model to investigate this issue. Dercon (2008) underlines the importance of expanding insurance services to protect the poor but cautions against viewing them as a cure-all solution. Studies in Asian countries also show that social protection policies can be effective, similar to comprehensive welfare state models (Barrientos 2011; Wagle 2017). Fiszbein et al. (2014) emphasize the role of social protection as a crucial tool in the global fight against poverty and inequality, offering comparative insights across diverse social policy experiences. These studies provide important perspectives for understanding the long-term effects of social policies and highlight both similarities and differences in their implementation across regions.
This study aims to evaluate the capacity of social security policies to reduce poverty in Türkiye. Türkiye is selected as the case study due to the significant expansion of social policies in the post-2000 period, the politicization of social assistance, and the transformation of its institutional framework. Moreover, Türkiye’s socioeconomic dynamics—including large income inequalities, regional development disparities, and rapid urbanization—make it an appropriate setting to observe the outcomes of social policy implementation.
In this context, the central research questions are as follows: Have the social policies implemented in Türkiye in the 21st century been effective in reducing poverty? Do these policies support long-term welfare improvement, or do they contribute to the reproduction of poverty by fostering dependency? If the latter is the case, how can this risk be managed, and how can a more inclusive social policy architecture be built? This study addresses these questions both theoretically and empirically. To strengthen the analysis, we briefly consider the life-cycle and risk-based foundations of social security. Following Barr (2020), we recognize that old-age pensions serve as life-cycle savings mechanisms, with insurance against longevity risk, while other transfers mitigate income volatility due to unemployment, illness, or family shocks. The method of financing—whether via contributory schemes or general taxation—also shapes redistributional outcomes.
The following section provides an overview of the development of the social security system in Türkiye. Section 3 discusses transfer expenditures within Türkiye’s social security system. Section 4 explains the microsimulation methodology used in this study. Section 5 addresses the scale of expenditure for social transfers in these countries and analyzes the impact of social assistance on poverty reduction. Section 6 concludes the study.

2. Literature Review: The Evolution of the Turkish Social Security System

The evolution of the Turkish welfare state, particularly its social security system, reflects broader socio-political and economic shifts, encompassing periods of state-led modernization, populist expansion, neoliberal restructuring, and Islamic-conservative reorientation. Social security, comprising health insurance, pensions, and unemployment benefits, has been central to the organization of Türkiye’s welfare provision. The development of Türkiye’s social security system has proceeded unevenly, shaped by both internal class and institutional dynamics as well as external imperatives of global economic integration and policy transfer. This literature review traces the historical trajectory and structural transformation of Türkiye’s social security system, emphasizing scholarly debates around its expansion, reform, and commodification.

2.1. Early Development and the Statist Phase

The foundations of Türkiye’s modern social security institutions were laid during the early Republican period, drawing heavily on European models, particularly those of Bismarckian inspiration (Buğra 2007). Social insurance for workers began with the Law on Occupational Accidents, Diseases and Maternity Insurance in 1945 and expanded with the establishment of the Social Insurance Institution (Sosyal Sigortalar Kurumu, or SSK) in 1946, targeting industrial workers (Buğra and Keyder 2006). These schemes were contributory and occupation-based, reflecting the labor-market-centered nature of Türkiye’s early welfare model. However, social protection remained limited in coverage, excluding large rural and informal sectors.
This period, often referred to as the “statist phase,” saw social security as an instrument of industrialization and nation-building. Services were organized around formal employment, with little attempt to create universalist welfare institutions (Çampınarı 2012). The fragmented structure of the system, divided among multiple schemes for public employees (Emekli Sandığı), self-employed (Bağ-Kur), and private-sector workers (SSK), created significant disparities in benefits and access (Buğra and Keyder 2006).

2.2. Populist Expansion and Institutional Fragmentation

The post-1960s period witnessed an expansion of social security coverage driven by the rise of populist politics and import substitution industrialization. Political parties increasingly used social policy to mobilize electoral support, leading to generous but fiscally unsustainable pension and health entitlements, especially in the 1970s and 1980s (Buğra and Candas 2011). This populist phase resulted in the rapid growth of the pension system and broader inclusion of rural and informal groups, albeit often through politically motivated rather than actuarially sound means.
Coverage grew in terms of enrolment, but the system remained fragmented and inefficient. By the 1980s, there were over 30 different types of pension schemes with varying rules, eligibility criteria, and benefit levels (Özdemir 2010). The lack of coordination and cross-subsidization created perverse incentives and mounting deficits, with pension spending exceeding 10% of GDP by the early 2000s (Ercan 2011).

2.3. Neoliberal Restructuring and Social Security Reform

The 1980 military coup and the subsequent adoption of neoliberal economic policies marked a significant turning point. While privatization and deregulation dominated the economic agenda, social security remained largely unreformed until the early 2000s. However, by this time, the fiscal crisis of the state, pressures from international financial institutions (notably the IMF and the World Bank), and the evident unsustainability of existing arrangements made reform imperative.
A major wave of reform culminated in the 2006 Social Security and General Health Insurance Law, which unified the three major social insurance institutions (SSK, Bağ-Kur, and Emekli Sandığı) under a single administrative body: the Social Security Institution (Sosyal Güvenlik Kurumu, SGK). The reform aimed to simplify administration, reduce deficits, and improve efficiency, while introducing a General Health Insurance (GHI) scheme designed to universalize health coverage (Çampınarı 2012).
Scholars have viewed this reform through different lenses. For Buğra and Keyder (2006), it represented a shift towards a more commodified and market-oriented welfare state, consistent with global neoliberal trends Yörük (2012), however, notes that while the reforms enhanced formal coverage, they also introduced exclusionary mechanisms by linking access to contribution histories, thereby reinforcing labor market inequalities.

2.4. AKP Era: Targeted Assistance and Dual Transformation

The rise of the Justice and Development Party (AKP) in 2002 brought new dynamics to social policy, including social security. Initially continuing the neoliberal reform agenda under IMF supervision, the AKP government embraced social assistance as a key governance strategy, particularly after exiting the IMF program in 2008. The AKP’s approach to social security has been characterized by two interrelated features: the consolidation of contributory systems and the expansion of non-contributory, targeted assistance (Buğra and Candas 2011).
The pension system, while unified, underwent further parametric reforms that increased the retirement age, reduced replacement rates, and tightened eligibility in line with fiscal sustainability goals (Ercan 2011). These reforms were criticized for undermining adequacy and equity, especially for low-income and informal workers
Concurrently, the AKP developed an expansive network of social assistance programs, including conditional cash transfers, housing subsidies, and food aid, often distributed through local municipalities and foundations. Scholars argue that this targeted model created a parallel, politically mediated system of welfare provision that blurred the boundaries between clientelism and entitlement (Yörük 2012). While these programs helped reduce extreme poverty, they did not address structural inequality or the precariousness of informal employment.
This dual transformation of commodified social insurance and politically mediated social assistancehas led some scholars to question the applicability of traditional welfare regime typologies. Türkiye’s social security system exhibits hybrid features: a Bismarckian core for formal workers, residual assistance for the poor, and selective universalism in health (Buğra and Keyder 2006).

2.5. Southern Welfare State Model

The literature on welfare regimes has expanded the traditional Southern European model (Ferrera 1996, 2001; Rhodes 1996) to include additional Mediterranean countries such as Cyprus, Israel, Malta, and Türkiye, alongside Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain (Gal 2010). These countries share certain structural and cultural characteristics that distinguish their welfare systems from both the conservative and liberal models. Common features include the dominance of family and religious institutions in welfare provision, low levels of social expenditure, weak public assistance programs, and limited female participation in the labor market. Political clientelism also plays a significant role in the allocation of welfare resources (Gal 2010).
Türkiye’s welfare regime, in particular, mirrors many of these characteristics, notably the fragmented structure of social security and the reliance on the male breadwinner model. This reflects a Bismarckian legacy shaped by informality and occupational segmentation, leading to inequality in social citizenship and access to benefits (Buğra and Candas 2011).
Karamessini (2007) identifies key traits of the Southern European model—such as labor market segmentation, high male employment protection, and patronage in welfare distribution—which also apply to the Turkish context. Recent reforms in Türkiye suggest a convergence with Southern European trends. The implementation of universal health coverage for all citizens under 18 marks a significant shift towards recognizing social rights beyond family responsibility (Grütjen 2007). Furthermore, policy changes under the AKP government have aligned with the Mediterranean model by increasing the roles of markets, local authorities, and civil society in welfare provision (Grütjen 2007).

3. Social Security Benefits in Türkiye

Türkiye’s Social Security System is a comprehensive structure that provides protection against social risks for employed citizens and foreign workers in the country. The system is primarily based on the Bismarck Model, which involves pooling contributions deducted from individuals’ income during their working life, along with employer contributions. The benefits provided against risks such as retirement, illness, and work accidents are determined based on individuals’ previous income levels and the contributions they have paid. The system is based on registered employment and is shaped by strict labor market rules and collective bargaining mechanisms. However, Türkiye’s social security system has not been limited to the Bismarck Model and has also contained certain structural challenges characteristic of the Mediterranean Model (Özmen 2017). Since the 1990s, early retirement policies, high informal employment rates, low premium collection ratios, and insufficient income replacement have disrupted the system’s financial balance. Additionally, the provision of services by multiple institutions has created inconsistencies in rights and obligations. The aging population has further deepened these problems. These benefits are financed partly through payroll contributions by employers and employees and partly via state budget subsidies, particularly for non-contributory and social assistance schemes. The financing structure has implications for intergenerational equity and redistribution.
Türkiye’s social security system has developed within a fragmented, corporatist structure that prioritizes formally employed individuals while largely excluding informal workers. Although Türkiye’s public social spending surpasses that of some more economically advanced countries like Mexico and Korea, it remains significantly lower than in wealthier OECD nations. This discrepancy reflects a dualistic welfare regime, where formal sector workers benefit from structured protections while others rely on informal networks, such as kinship and clientelism, for support (Buğra and Adar 2008).
This corporatist model, composed of institutions like the Social Insurance Institution (SSK), the Retirement Fund (ES), and Bag-Kur for the self-employed, became increasingly unsustainable due to demographic imbalances, mismanagement of funds, and the rising pressures of market-oriented reforms post-1980. Fiscal deficits and changes in labor and family structures weakened informal support mechanisms, prompting expenditures for comprehensive reform (Kılıç 2008b).
The 2006 Social Insurance and General Health Insurance Law (No. 5489) sought to unify these fragmented schemes to increase efficiency and standardize entitlements across groups. However, the reform encountered strong opposition, particularly over perceived reductions in acquired rights, and was partially annulled by the Constitutional Court, especially regarding civil servants’ entitlements (Kılıç 2008b).
Retirement policies also reflected shifting social values. Initially, women benefited from earlier retirement ages based on caregiving roles. However, reforms aimed to equalize retirement ages by 2048, citing increased life expectancy, especially for women, as justification (Ministry of Labour and Social Security 2004; Kılıç 2008b).
While these reforms signal a move towards more equitable and efficient systems, they also reflect a growing reliance on market mechanisms and a diminished role for the state. As a result, the capacity of the welfare state to ensure comprehensive social inclusion remains limited (Buğra and Adar 2008; Kılıç 2008a).

Challenges and Future Prospects

Despite formal coverage expansion under GHI, significant challenges remain. The persistence of informality—over 30% of the labor force—undermines the sustainability and inclusiveness of social insurance (OECD 2020). Moreover, the COVID-19 pandemic revealed the limits of contribution-based systems, as many workers lacked access to unemployment or sickness benefits (ILO 2021). The continued reliance on targeted assistance, without strengthening universal mechanisms, risks entrenching inequality and social stratification.
The literature also highlights a political dimension to social security provision. AKP’s use of welfare as a tool for electoral mobilization has created a system that is responsive to short-term political imperatives rather than long-term social investment (Yörük 2012). Meanwhile, the erosion of labor rights and the weakening of trade unions further constrain the redistributive potential of social security.
Recent policy discussions have focused on expanding universal basic income, digitizing benefit delivery, and integrating refugees into social insurance schemes. However, without addressing the structural issues of labor market segmentation, regressive financing, and political clientelism, such reforms may have limited impact.
To address these issues, Law No. 5510 on Social Insurance and General Health Insurance was enacted in 2008. This reform unified social security institutions under a single roof, increasing equality and accessibility in services. The main goal was to establish a social security system that is fair, accessible, financially sustainable, and more effective in combating poverty. This reform brought Türkiye’s social security system closer to international standards and strengthened its long-term resilience.
In Türkiye, transfer expenditures are considered financial support directed to various economic actors, unemployed individuals, and low-income groups (Ceylan 2020). These expenditures constitute part of the social security system’s costs (Cural 2016). Reducing poverty is one of the main objectives of the welfare state. In countries where the functions of the welfare state are strongly emphasized, transfer expenditures are considered a key and effective component of redistributive policies aimed at improving income distribution (Lorenz 2017). Below are the transfer expenditure categories used to describe disposable income in the 2022 Household Budget Survey, along with brief explanations:
  • Retirement Pension: Paid to retirees through the social security system, based on contribution payments made during their working life.
  • Old Age Pension: Income support from old age insurance provided for individuals after retirement.
  • Housing: Housing support provided for family members to meet shelter needs.
  • Scholarship: Financial support provided to students to help them continue their education.
  • Disability/Invalidity: Income support for disabled or invalid individuals, particularly those with reduced working capacity.
  • Illness: Temporary income support provided to individuals unable to work due to illness.
  • Widow/Orphan: Social assistance provided to orphans and widowed individuals.
  • Unemployment: Temporary financial assistance provided to unemployed individuals until they rejoin the labor force.
  • Severance Pay: Compensation received by employees upon dismissal or voluntary separation.
  • Agricultural Subsidies: State support programs for farmers to encourage agricultural production.
  • Other: General income support provided by the government.

4. Data and Methodology

4.1. Data

This analysis draws on up-to-date, credible, nationally representative data from Türkiye’s 2022 Household Budget Survey, collected using stratified sampling and weighted appropriately to ensure generalizability. Consistent in structure with previous iterations, the survey offers in-depth information on multiple dimensions of household economics. It includes detailed data on spending patterns, household structure, demographic and socio-economic profiles of household members, and levels of disposable income. Notably, the survey provides a comprehensive breakdown of social security benefits in Türkiye. The dataset comprises responses from 11,922 households, encompassing a total of 39,188 individuals.

4.2. Methodology

The objective of poverty { XE “Poverty” } measures is to quantify the size and extent of poverty { XE “Poverty” }. However, in policy analyses, we wish to assess the effectiveness of a policy or policy change in reducing poverty { XE “Poverty” }.
Beckerman (1979) proposed target efficiency and poverty { XE “Poverty” } reduction effectiveness indicators. Figure 1 describes the impact of transfers on disposable income { XE “Disposable income” }, reporting pre- and post-transfer { XE “Transfer” } income. A number of indicators can be produced on the basis of this figure:
  • The first measure is Vertical Expenditure Efficiency (VEE{ XE “VEE” }), meaning the share of total expenditure going to households who are poor before the transfer,{ XE “Transfer” } and it is equal to the area (A + B)/(A + B + C).
  • The next indicator of Poverty Reduction Efficiency (PRE{ XE “PRE” }) is the fraction of total expenditure allowing poor households to reach the poverty { XE “Poverty” } line without overcoming it and is defined as the area (A)/(A + B +C).
  • The Spillover Index (S) is a measure of the excess of expenditure with respect to the amount strictly necessary to reach the poverty { XE “Poverty” } line, (B)/(A + B). In combination, it can be seen that VEE{ XE “VEE” } (1 − S) = PRE{ XE “PRE” }.
However, these metrics alone are not adequate to assess the effectiveness of a transfer system in alleviating poverty. A program may be highly effective in targeting low-income individuals, yet if the allocated resources are insufficient, it may fail to bring about a meaningful improvement in the beneficiaries’ living standards. The Poverty Gap Efficiency (PGE{ XE “PGE” }) defined as (A)/(A + D) measures how effective a cash benefit is in filling the poverty { XE “Poverty” } gap.
The Beckerman (1979) method, however, weights all incomes below the poverty line in the same way. Foster et al. (1984), FGT, utilizes a method which allows for a differential weight α depending upon the distance between the poverty line z and the income y i
F G T α = 1 N i = 1 q z y i z α
where:
  • N = total population
  • q = number of poor individuals
  • z   = poverty line
  • y i = post-transfer income of individual i
  • α = sensitivity parameter
Utilizing a method described in the study by O’Donoghue and Can (forthcoming), we incorporate the FGT reweighting to evaluate the poverty efficiency of social security benefits in Türkiye with different weights:
where y i , p r e is the pre-transfer income of individual i who is poor before transfers; the Beckerman A ,   B ,   C ,   D become:
A α = i = 1 q m i n z , y i y i , p r e α
B α = i = 1 q y i z α
C α = i = q + 1 N y i z α
D α = i = 1 q z y i α

5. Results

In this section, we consider the expenditure for social security benefits. Table 1 highlights the demand for social security benefits by instrument, expressed as a percentage of total disposable income in the Türkiye. The table describes the average expenditure as a percentage of total household disposable income. We notice that, of all the benefits considered, retirement pensions have the highest share, accounting for 16.6% of disposable income or 79% of all transfers, followed by survivor’s benefits at 12.6% of all transfers. The remaining transfers account for less than 10% of the total. Expenditure on contributory pensions dwarfs the expenditure on social assistance in Türkiye; typical of the Conservative/Mediterranean type of welfare state (Ferrera 1996). Reflecting the focus on retirement pensions and survivor’s pensions in Türkiye, the benefit share of disposable income is highest for the over-60s at 60% (Table 2).

5.1. Poverty Headcount Rate and Poverty Gap

Although not the sole objective, with, for example, a focus on income smoothing for pensions (Barr 2020), one of the primary objectives of social security benefits is poverty prevention, particularly among older adults. Before measuring the impact of social security benefits on poverty, we clarify that ‘adequate living standards’ in this context align with the 60% median equivalized disposable income threshold, consistent with EU-SILC methodology. This threshold is used to operationalize poverty levels in Türkiye. We need to examine the differential extent of poverty for different benefits. By the extent of poverty, we measure the proportion of people in poverty, while we use the poverty gap or the average amount by which individuals who fall into poverty as our measure of the depth of poverty. Table 3 describes the degree of poverty for the benefits examined. As is quite standard in poverty comparisons of this nature, we use a relative poverty measure. Our poverty line is based on median equivalized disposable income, as it is more robust than mean income, which is quite sensitive to high-income outliers in the data. Given that poverty outcomes can vary significantly depending on the chosen poverty threshold, we adopt three distinct benchmarks in our analysis: our primary measure at 60% of the median income, complemented by alternative thresholds set at 70% and 50% of the median.
Table 4 describes the extent and depth of poverty in Turkiye in terms of three poverty lines and decomposed by age group. Taking 60% of the median poverty line as our starting point. Türkiye has a poverty rate of 19.1% and a poverty gap of 5.8% of the poverty line. The poverty headcount is similar to other Southern European Welfare states, Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain, but lower than France, which has more of a Central European welfare regime (Matsaganis et al. 2006, 2007). Turning to the 50% line, we see that of those below the poverty line, about a third are between the 50% and 60% similar to the former set of Southern countries in Matsaganis et al.’s study. This confirms the finding of the poverty gap, whereby the poor are likely to have incomes much lower. There is a similar percentage of households between the 60% and 70% poverty lines. The poverty gap tells a similar story.
Decomposing the poverty rate by age, we find that the poverty rate increases with age, reflecting labor market attachment and the structure of the transfer system. In addition to the higher poverty rate amongst older age groups, there is also a greater concentration in the 50–60 poverty line range among older persons.

5.2. Poverty Impact of Social Security Instruments

We now shift our focus to evaluating the effectiveness of current public policies in reducing poverty. To do so, we explore how both the incidence and severity of poverty would change in the absence of social benefits. While it is evident that individuals would adjust their behavior to cope in a world without such support, this analysis abstracts from those potential behavioral responses. Instead, it assesses the role of social transfers in alleviating poverty based on the current distribution of market incomes.
Table 3, using a threshold set at 60% of the median income. It includes both the baseline scenario detailed in Table 3 and the isolated impact of social security benefits. The poverty gap is calculated as the average shortfall from the poverty line, expressed as a percentage of the overall average disposable income—measured across the entire population, not just those classified as poor.
In the case of no benefits, we see that both the poverty rate and the poverty gap increase without transfers. In total, the poverty headcount rate would increase to 39.6% when measured at 60% of the median income poverty line, more than doubling, while the poverty gap would increase to 26.5%. Reflecting the difference in the importance of benefits, most of this is driven by retirement and survivor’s pensions. Again reflecting the nature of these instruments, the poverty headcount rate and gap would increase the most for older people, with the poverty headcount rate exceeding two- thirds for all age groups over 60 and in fact over 80% for the over-80s. Compared to younger age groups, the impact on the poverty gap is proportionally higher than the poverty headcount rate.

5.3. Distribution of Benefit Expenditure

In this section, we examine the efficiency of social security benefits as an anti-poverty instrument in different countries. To do this, we first investigate the distribution of public expenditure on benefits across the income distribution. Table 5 describes the distribution of expenditure on both social security benefits by equivalized disposable income decile. The columns report the share of the instrument relative to disposable income for each decile. Overall, social security benefits are more closely targeted at the bottom of the distribution. Meanwhile, other benefits, highlighting their income replacement rather than anti-poverty function, are targeted at the top of the distribution.
Benefits can be grouped into three components:
  • Little difference between the top and bottom of the distribution or skewed towards the top, with a 90:10 ratio of 1 or more
  • Moderately targeted at the bottom of the distribution, with a 90:10 ratio of 0.25–1
  • Strongly skewed towards the bottom of the distribution, with a 90:10 ratio of less than 0.25
Retirement pensions and housing benefits are in the first group, with the former exhibiting little difference between the top of the distribution and the bottom of the distribution, with the instrument in fact most concentrated at the middle of the distribution. Although relatively unimportant, housing benefits are strongly skewed towards the top of the distribution.
Survivor’s Benefits are the most important instrument in the middle group, although relatively skewed towards the bottom, reflecting lower other income sources of survivors, mainly women. Educational scholarships, except for the top decile, decrease with earnings, reflecting a combination of means testing for lower deciles and higher participation in education for the top decile. Except for the bottom decile, which has a higher share, there is not much variation across other deciles for agricultural support.
The remaining instruments are all relatively unimportant in terms of budget share and are heavily skewed towards the bottom of the distribution, reflecting their means-tested nature and/or the association with the risk category, such as disability or unemployment, with income.

5.4. Poverty Efficiency

A clearer and more detailed assessment of how effectively social transfers mitigate poverty is offered in Table 6, which reports standard indicators of targeting efficiency and poverty reduction performance, as established by Weisbrod (1969) and Beckerman (1979) and adapted in O’Donoghue and Can (forthcoming), for each of the previously discussed schemes.
Table 6 reports the poverty efficiency for the different instruments. Reflecting the distributional characteristics of the benefits in Table 6, when alpha has a value of 1, most instruments have high poverty reduction efficiency (PRE) of 80% or higher. These include Old Age Pension, Child Benefits, Sickness Benefits, Housing Benefits, and Social Assistance Benefits going to those who would be below the poverty line without the transfer. When alpha has a value of 2, these conclusions remain the same, with the PRE changing slightly. Consistent with the targeted nature of these instruments, the Spillover Index is low at 5% or less.
Grouped around a PRE of 60–80% are the main social insurance instruments, Disability Benefits, and Survivor’s Benefits. The Spillover Index is highest for the Survivor’s Benefit, with 22% percent of the transfer going to the poor when Alpha is 1, bringing them above the poverty line, while for the other, at 9%, brings people above the poverty line. This relates to the lower replacement rate of the latter. There is, however, a reasonably large difference when we set alpha to 2, with the PRE declining by a third in the case of Disability Benefits and a quarter for Survivor’s Benefits, with the degree of targeting decreasing when we weight households further from the poverty line more. The remaining benefits have a lower PRE of less than 60% with alpha set to 1, with most of these instruments targeted at those who are already above the poverty line, including Retirement Pensions, Agricultural Support, and Educational Scholarships. The PRE falls substantially for these when alpha is set to 2, consistent with the gainers being close to the poverty line.
Overall, the effectiveness of targeting is relatively weak. When examining the share of benefits that lift recipients up to, but not beyond, the poverty line, we find that, aside from the most precisely targeted program, the Post-Transfer Poverty Reduction Efficiency (PRE) remains below 40%. For the full set of benefits combined, it is about 47% when alpha is set to 1 and 40% when alpha is set to 2. This implies that more than 60% of total transfer resources are either allocated to individuals who were already above the poverty threshold prior to receiving benefits or to those who are lifted entirely out of poverty by the transfers.
Most instruments are social insurance-based and so require a work connection and indeed a formal sector work connection for eligibility. This means that individually, they may have other sources of income, or other members of their household may have other sources of income. Also, given the relative importance as an income source of Retirement Pensions and Survivor Pensions and the high Spillover Index, these incomes bring people above the poverty line.
This limited poverty efficiency can be partly explained by the fact that income-tested instruments are administered, often to smaller units within a larger household. For instance, elderly individuals may qualify for old-age means-tested benefits even if they reside with wealthier family members. Another contributing factor is the temporary nature of certain benefits, such as unemployment benefits, which may only be received during part of the year. Individuals like seasonal workers or those in receipt of short-term sickness benefits might receive earnings for part of the year and benefits during periods of unemployment. In these cases, it is possible for households that are relatively better off over the full year to receive assistance during certain months (Matsaganis et al. 2006, 2007).
When we consider the capacity of instruments to reduce the poverty gap, there is little relationship with the degree of targeting. Retirement Pensions and Survivor Pensions have by far the highest Poverty Gap Efficiency when alpha is set to 1, at 44% and 18%, respectively, increasing slightly to 52% and 21% when alpha is set to 2. The other instruments, regardless of their targeting, have minimal impact on the poverty gap due to the scale of expenditure on them.
To sum up the evidence provided by these indicators, it seems fair to say that the target efficiency of social security benefits is relatively low, so there would be room to redirect public assistance expenditures towards the truly poor, without violating the currently tight budget constraints. Given the vast amount of resources not targeted to the poor, this share could be significantly increased, with better means-testing criteria, without the need for additional funds.

6. Discussion and Conclusions

This study aimed to empirically evaluate the poverty-reducing impact and the efficiency of social transfers in reaching and supporting the poor with social security benefits in Türkiye. The findings reveal a dual picture: social transfers—especially contributory pensions and survivor’s benefits—play a significant role in reducing poverty, but the effectiveness varies across population groups and types of transfers. This paper contributes to the understanding of how social security benefits impact poverty in Türkiye.
Data from 2022 show that transfer expenditures from social security benefits constitute a significant portion of household income. Pensions alone account for 16.6% of disposable income and 79% of all transfers, underscoring the central role of this system. This aligns Türkiye’s welfare system closely with the Conservative/Mediterranean welfare regime defined by Ferrera (1996), wherein contributory social insurance mechanisms dominate and income support is largely directed towards the retirement phase. Supporting the assessment by Matsaganis et al. (2006, 2007) of poverty-fighting social benefits in Europe, Türkiye’s poverty profile closely resembles that of other Southern European welfare states, Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain, while differing from France. In France, the structure of the economy and tax-benefit system results in a lower poverty rate and a shallower poverty gap.
Poverty analysis shows that in a hypothetical scenario without social transfers, the poverty rate would increase from 19.1% to 39.6%, and the poverty gap would rise significantly. These findings clearly illustrate the poverty-reducing effect of transfers. The strongest protective impact is observed among the elderly; in the absence of social benefits, poverty among this group rises dramatically, with the poverty rate among those aged 80+ exceeding 80%. This indicates that the social security system significantly prevents elderly poverty, primarily through age-based income protection mechanisms. This counterfactual abstracts from potential behavioral adjustments, and the results should be interpreted as illustrative rather than predictive.
However, this structure has certain limitations. Firstly, the system appears less protective for younger and working-age populations. The concentration of transfer spending on the elderly may leave those who are not fully integrated into the labor market or working informally without sufficient protection. Furthermore, the dominance of contributory benefits may exclude individuals without a history of regular employment from future social safety nets. This strengthens criticisms that such systems may contribute to the reproduction of long-term poverty.
In light of these findings, we can more clearly answer the core questions: Social policies implemented in Türkiye in the 21st century have been quite effective in reducing poverty among the elderly, albeit with relatively poor targeting. However, the same policies are not sufficiently inclusive for younger, unemployed, or precariously employed individuals. As in the case of other Southern European models, there is a need to improve the delivery of social assistance to these groups that fall outside the more formal social insurance based safety net, as advocated by Buğra (2007), and to improve the capacity of the system to improve the severe gender equity issues in Türkiye, Kılıç (2008b). To manage this risk, social assistance policies need to be more targeted. This reflects the concern raised by Hunter (1958) that fragmented and selective systems often mirror labor market inequalities and echoes Titmuss’s (1967) critique that such systems fail to address deeper structural causes of poverty, i.e., inclusive and strengthened by non-contributory support mechanisms. In conclusion, although Türkiye’s social security system reduces poverty for certain segments, for it to function as a comprehensive welfare architecture, the scope of social assistance must be expanded. Policies targeting the young and employable population must be reinforced, and the system must be transformed into one that offers inclusive solutions without fostering dependency over the long term. It is also important to reiterate that in the absence of social transfers, individuals would not passively accept income loss but would seek alternatives, including increased labor participation or reliance on informal support. Our estimates do not account for these adaptive behaviors.

Funding

This research was funded by University of Galway.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article; further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Atkinson, A. B. 1998. Social exclusion, poverty and unemployment. In Exclusion, Employment and Opportunity. London: Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion (CASE), London School of Economics and Political Science, p. 4. [Google Scholar]
  2. Barr, N. A. 2020. The Economics of the Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  3. Barrientos, Armando. 2011. Social protection and poverty. International Journal of Social Welfare 20: 240–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Beckerman, Wilfred. 1979. The Impact of Income Maintenance Payments on Poverty in Britain, 1975. Economic Journal 89: 261–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Buğra, Ayse. 2007. Poverty and citizenship: An overview of the social-policy environment in republican Türkiye. International Journal of Middle East Studies 39: 33–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Buğra, Ayşe, and Aysen Candas. 2011. Change and continuity under an eclectic social security regime: The case of Türkiye. Middle Eastern Studies 47: 515–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Buğra, Ayşe, and Çağlar Keyder. 2006. The Turkish welfare regime in transformation. Journal of European Social Policy 16: 211–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Buğra, Ayşe, and Sinem Adar. 2008. Social policy change in countries without mature welfare states: The case of Türkiye. New Perspectives on Türkiye 38: 83–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Ceylan, Zeynep. 2020. Estimation of COVID-19 prevalence in Italy, Spain, and France. Science of The Total Environment 729: 138817. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Cural, Mehmet. 2016. Türk Sosyal Güvenlik Sisteminin Mali Yapisi ve Sisteme Yapilan Bütçe Transferlerinin Ekonomik Yansimalari. Süleyman Demirel Üniversitesi İktisadi ve İdari Bilimler Fakültesi Dergisi 21: 693–706. [Google Scholar]
  11. Çampınarı, Duygu. 2012. A Critical Analysis of the Transformation of the Social Security System in Turkey in the Context of New Constitutionalism and Europeanizatiion. Master’s thesis, Middle East Technical University, Ankara, Turkey. [Google Scholar]
  12. Dercon, Stefan. 2008. Fate and fear: Risk and its consequences in Africa. Journal of African Economies 17 S2: ii97–127. [Google Scholar]
  13. Ercan, Hakan. 2011. Occupa onal Outlook in Turkey. ILO Turkey. Available online: http://www.mdgfund.org/sites/default/files/YEM_STUDY_Turkey_Occupational%20Outlook%20in%20Turkey.pdf (accessed on 24 May 2025).
  14. Esping-Andersen, G. 1999. Politics without class: Postindustrial cleavages in Europe and America. In Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 293–316. [Google Scholar]
  15. Ferrera, Maurizio. 1996. The ‘Southern model’ of welfare in social Europe. Journal of European Social Policy 6: 17–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Ferrera, Maurizio. 2001. Targeting welfare in a “soft” state: Italy’s winding road to selectivity. In Targeting Social Benefits. International Perspectives & Trends. Edited by Gilbert Neil. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers. [Google Scholar]
  17. Fiszbein, Ariel, Ravi Kanbur, and Ruslan Yemtsov. 2014. Social protection and poverty reduction: Global patterns and some targets. World Development 61: 167–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Foster, James, Joel Greer, and Erik Thorbecke. 1984. A class of decomposable poverty measures. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 52: 761–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Gal, John. 2010. Is there an extended family of Mediterranean welfare states? Journal of European Social Policy 20: 283–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Gilbert, Neil. 2002. Transformation of the Welfare State: The Silent Surrender of Public Responsibility. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  21. Grütjen, Daniel. 2007. Social Security in Türkiye An Example of the Southern Model? The role of state, market, and the family in welfare provision. Turkish Policy Quarterly 7: 1. [Google Scholar]
  22. Hunter, Floyd. 1958. WILENSKY and LEBEAUX. Industrial Society and Social Welfare (Book Review). Social Forces 37: 84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. ILO. 2021. Social Protection Responses to COVID-19 Crisis around the World. Geneva: International Labour Organization. [Google Scholar]
  24. Karamessini, Maria. 2007. The Southern European Social Model: Changes and Continuities in Recent Decades. Geneva: International Institute for Labour Studies. [Google Scholar]
  25. Kiliç, Azer. 2008a. Continuity and change in social policy approaches toward women. New Perspectives on Türkiye 38: 135–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Kiliç, Azer. 2008b. The gender dimension of social policy reform in Türkiye: Towards equal citizenship? Social Policy & Administration 42: 487–503. [Google Scholar]
  27. Lorenz, Walter. 2017. European policy developments and their impact on social work. European Journal of Social Work 20: 17–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Matsaganis, Manos, Cathal O’Donoghue, Horacio Levy, Manuela Coromaldi, Magda Mercader-Prats, Carlos Farinha Rodrigues, Stefano Toso, and Panos Tsakloglou. 2006. Reforming family transfers in southern Europe: Is there a role for universal child benefits? Social Policy and Society 5: 189–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Matsaganis, Manos, Cathal O’Donoghue, Horacio Levy, Manuela Coromaldi, Magda Mercader-Prats, Carlos Farinha Rodrigues, Stefano Toso, and Panos Tsakloglou. 2007. Child poverty and family transfers in Southern Europe. In Microsimulation as a Tool for the Evaluation of Public Policies: Methods and Applications. Bilbao: Fundación BBVA, vol. 3, pp. 293–321. [Google Scholar]
  30. Ministry of Labour and Social Security. 2004. T. C. Sosyal Guvenlik Kurumu “Sosyal Sigortalar ve Genel Saglik Sigortası Kanunu”. Available online: https://www.mevzuat.gov.tr/mevzuat?MevzuatNo=5510&MevzuatTur=1&MevzuatTertip=5 (accessed on 24 May 2025).
  31. Moene, Karl Ove, and Michael Wallerstein. 2001. Inequality, social insurance, and redistribution. American Political Science Review 95: 859–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Nolan, Brain, Richard Hauser, and Jean-Paul Zoyem. 1999. The changing effects of social protection on poverty. In Welfare Regimes and the Experience of Unemployment in Europe. Mannheim: Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre. [Google Scholar]
  33. O’Donoghue, C., and Z. G. Can. Forthcoming. Adjusting the Beckerman Poverty Efficiency Method to Account for Differential Poverty Gap Weighting. New York: Mimeo. [Google Scholar]
  34. OECD. 2020. OECD Employment Outlook 2020. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar]
  35. Özdemir, S. 2010. The Pension System in Türkiye: Problems and Possible Solutions. Ankara University Journal of Social Sciences 67: 215–40. [Google Scholar]
  36. Özmen, Zeynep. 2017. Avrupa’da sosyal güvenlik sisteminin finansmanı: Farklı refah devletleri üzerine bir inceleme. Karabük Üniversitesi Sosyal Bilimler Enstitüsü Dergisi 7: 600–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Rhodes, Martin. 1996. Southern European welfare states: Identity, problems and prospects for reform. South European Society & Politics 1: 1–22. [Google Scholar]
  38. Titmuss, Richard. 2006. Universalism versus selection. In The Welfare State Reader. Cambridge: Polity Press, pp. 40–48. [Google Scholar]
  39. Titmuss, Richard. M. 1967. The welfare complex in a changing society. The Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly 45: 9–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Wagle, Udaya. R. 2017. How much do social protections matter to poverty and inequality? An insight from Asian experiences. Global Social Policy 17: 137–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Weisbrod, Burton. 1969. Collective action and the distribution of income: A conceptual approach. In The analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditure: The PPB System, a Compendum of Papers Submitted to The Subcommittee of the Joint Economic Committee. Madison: University of Wisconsin, Institute for Research on Poverty, pp. 177–97. [Google Scholar]
  42. Wilensky, Harold L. 1974. The Welfare State and Equality: Structural and Ideological Roots of Public Expenditures. California: University of California Press, vol. 140. [Google Scholar]
  43. Yörük, Erdem. 2012. The Politics of the Welfare State and the Neoliberal Poverty Regime in Türkiye. Ph.D. thesis, Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, MD, USA, October. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. The efficiency of social transfers. Source: Beckerman (1979).
Figure 1. The efficiency of social transfers. Source: Beckerman (1979).
Socsci 14 00421 g001
Table 1. Demand for social security benefits.
Table 1. Demand for social security benefits.
Instrument% of Total Disposable Income
Retirement Pension0.166
Old Age Pension0.004
Survivor’s Benefits0.027
Disability Benefits0.005
Sickness Benefits0.00020
Unemployment Benefits0.00060
Educational Scholarships0.00137
Agricultural Support0.00288
Child Benefits0.00079
Housing Benefits0.00143
Social Assistance0.002
Total0.212
Source: Türkiye HBS 2022.
Table 2. Expenditure for social security benefits by age group (as a percentage of total disposable income).
Table 2. Expenditure for social security benefits by age group (as a percentage of total disposable income).
Age GroupTotal
200.134
300.088
400.102
500.305
600.515
700.634
800.609
Total0.212
Source: Türkiye HBS 2022.
Table 3. Measuring the extent and depth of poverty.
Table 3. Measuring the extent and depth of poverty.
% of Median
Poverty Line506070
Poverty Headcount0.1260.1910.264
Poverty Gap0.0390.0580.083
Poverty Line by Age Group
Age Group% of Median
Poverty Line506070
200.1200.1800.242
300.1280.1930.266
400.1240.1830.253
500.1000.1480.210
600.1170.1900.268
700.1550.2480.369
800.2090.3410.443
Total0.1260.1910.264
Source: Türkiye HBS 2022. Notes: (1) Poverty Gap as a percentage of the poverty line. (2) Poverty Headcount as a percentage of the total population. (3) Poverty Line in terms of median equivalized disposable income. (4) Equivalence Scale, square root of household size.
Table 4. Public policy and poverty (poverty in the absence of benefits).
Table 4. Public policy and poverty (poverty in the absence of benefits).
Poverty HeadcountPoverty Gap
Pension0.3270.181
Old Age Pension0.1960.066
Survivor’s Benefits0.2220.086
Disability Benefits0.1970.062
Sickness Benefits0.1910.059
Unemployment Benefits0.1920.059
Education Scholarships0.1920.059
Agricultural Support0.1920.096
Child Benefits0.1920.096
Housing Benefits0.1910.095
Social Assistance0.1940.098
Total0.3960.265
Source: Türkiye HBS 2022. Notes: (1) Poverty Gap as a percentage of the poverty line. (2) Poverty Headcount as a percentage of the total population. (3) Poverty Line in terms of Median Equivalized Disposable Income. (4) Equivalence Scale, square root of household size).
Table 5. Distribution of benefits expenditure.
Table 5. Distribution of benefits expenditure.
Equivalent Disposable Income DecilePensionOld Age PensionSurvivor’s BenefitsDisability BenefitsSickness BenefitsUnemployment BenefitsEducational Scholar.Agricultural SupportChild BenefitsHousing BenefitsSocial AssistanceTotal
10.1240.0770.0570.0330.00190.00500.00310.00840.01400.00050.04020.365
20.1960.0290.0790.0100.00000.00170.00110.00200.00650.00080.01520.342
30.2060.0130.1000.0100.00050.00280.00130.00140.00260.00140.00890.348
40.2230.0070.0690.0070.00010.00110.00120.00250.00120.00240.00540.320
50.1830.0030.0580.0050.00050.00070.00050.00210.00150.00110.00210.258
60.1880.0020.0450.0060.00030.00060.00090.00220.00070.00220.00190.249
70.2150.0010.0320.0030.00020.00050.00050.00160.00040.00270.00080.257
80.1780.0010.0330.0030.00020.00050.00030.00210.00020.00200.00030.221
90.1340.0010.0240.0020.00050.00050.00030.00210.00000.00090.00030.166
100.1370.0000.0150.0010.00000.00010.00210.00300.00000.00130.00000.160
Total0.1660.0040.0350.0040.00020.00060.00110.00250.00090.00160.00240.219
90:10 ratio1.110.000.260.040.010.010.660.360.002.520.000.44
Source: Türkiye HBS 2022. Notes: (1) Deciles in terms of median equivalized disposable income. (2) Equivalence Scale, square root of household size.
Table 6. Poverty efficiency of social security benefits.
Table 6. Poverty efficiency of social security benefits.
α = 1 α = 2
VEEPREPGESVEEPREPGES
Agricultural Support0.5070.2800.0070.4460.5030.0270.0040.946
Educational Scholarships0.3930.3930.0030.0000.0900.0900.0010.000
Pension0.7700.4230.4430.4500.7170.1880.5210.738
Survivor’s Benefits0.8510.6620.1760.2210.8520.5050.2070.407
Disability Benefits0.8490.7750.0330.0870.5870.4950.0270.157
Sickness Benefits0.8040.8040.0010.0000.7580.7580.0000.000
Child Benefits1.0000.9680.0110.0311.0000.9480.0060.052
Social Assistance0.9970.9810.0290.0160.9970.9800.0130.017
Old Age Pension0.9990.9970.0550.0010.9990.9990.0370.001
Unemployment Benefits1.0000.9990.0040.0011.0001.0000.0030.000
Housing Benefits1.0001.0000.0010.0001.0001.0000.0000.000
Total0.8160.4710.5760.4230.7490.2010.6320.731
Source: Türkiye HBS 2022. Notes (1) VEE—Vertical Expenditure Efficiency; (2) PRE—Poverty Reduction Efficiency; (3) S—Spillover Index; (4) PGE—Poverty Gap Efficiency.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Can, Z.G. The Poverty Effectiveness of Social Security Benefits in Türkiye. Soc. Sci. 2025, 14, 421. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci14070421

AMA Style

Can ZG. The Poverty Effectiveness of Social Security Benefits in Türkiye. Social Sciences. 2025; 14(7):421. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci14070421

Chicago/Turabian Style

Can, Zeynep Gizem. 2025. "The Poverty Effectiveness of Social Security Benefits in Türkiye" Social Sciences 14, no. 7: 421. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci14070421

APA Style

Can, Z. G. (2025). The Poverty Effectiveness of Social Security Benefits in Türkiye. Social Sciences, 14(7), 421. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci14070421

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop