Next Article in Journal
High-Temperature Rheological Properties and Storage Stability of Bitumen Modified with the Char Produced from Co-Pyrolysis of Different Wastes
Previous Article in Journal
A Roadmap for the Design, Operation and Monitoring of Renewable Energy Communities in Italy
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Estimating Travel Choice Probability of Link-Based Congestion Charging Scheme for Car Commuter Trips in Jakarta

Faculty of Economics and Business, Universitas Padjadjaran, Bandung 40115, Indonesia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(10), 8104; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108104
Submission received: 19 April 2023 / Revised: 8 May 2023 / Accepted: 9 May 2023 / Published: 16 May 2023

Abstract

:
The likely effects on car commuters of enforcing congestion charging using the link-based corridor method include that they may shift to public transport, divert their route of travel, or decide not to travel to the related area. However, most recent research has focused mainly on the choice of modes. This paper examined the travel choices of private car commuters resulting from the congestion charging scheme set to be implemented in Jakarta, Indonesia. The scheme is intended to replace the current odd-even strategy. It is imperative to study all possible mutually exclusive alternatives faced by car commuters. A web-based e-survey was used for data collection, employing the stated preference method. The discrete choice multinomial logit model was chosen to analyze the data. A total of 401 of the 2125 respondents to the e-survey questionnaire link, evenly distributed to all areas of Greater Jakarta, were sampled in this study. The sample respondents who traveled by car, passing through the eight designated corridors, were analyzed. NLOGIT6 software was used to analyze the parameter of attributes, the probability of alternatives chosen, and the marginal effects of congestion charging on such corridors, employing the multinomial logit model (MNLM). One surprising finding was that the load factor and taxi fares were not significant, indicating that the level of in-vehicle overcrowding is not a concern of respondents, and taxi services are not a substitute for car travel. Another surprising finding was that income variables and job type do not significantly influence travel behavior. In terms of the probability of commuters to continue to travel by car when link-based congestion charging is imposed, only around half of the car travelers were willing to pay the congestion levy and pass through congestion charging corridors. The probability of car travelers diverting onto alternative roads is high, i.e., around 16.82% to 22.88%, while the probability of car travelers shifting to mass transportation is 17.69%. When interpreting direct marginal effects, there is a change in the probability of all travelers choosing to use private cars through the congestion charging corridor of −0.0338, or a decrease of −3.38% for every IDR 1000 increase in the congestion charging levy rate, ceteris paribus.

1. Introduction

In recent years, Jakarta has been suffering from severe traffic congestion. Data show that the average speed of traffic in the morning was 16.7 km/h, during the day, it was 15.4 km/h, and in the evening, it was 15.0 km/h [1]. In terms of the level of service, during the morning rush hour, 36% of roads were at service level C, 16% at service level D, 23% at service level E, and 12% at service level F [2]. The economic losses from this inefficient transportation system reached IDR 100 trillion annually, or around 4% of the Greater Jakarta GRDP, consisting of IDR 40 trillion in lost vehicle operating costs and IDR 60 trillion in lost travel time costs. This amount is equivalent to the cost of building two to three MRT lines in Jabodetabek. This amount is also equivalent to a loss of IDR 3 million per year for each Jabodetabek resident [1]. Through Regional Regulation No. 5 of 2014 [3], the Jakarta government intended to increase the traffic on Jakarta’s road network to 35 km/h by changing the odd-even scheme to a link-based congestion charging strategy.
Over the past three decades, there have been many studies on the implementation of congestion charging, but these focused only on certain responses from travelers. A study focusing on the effect of congestion charging on modal shifting, for example, was carried out by Agarwal and Koo [4] in Singapore with an intervention to increase ERP rates at several central business district (CBD) entry points using a quasi-experimental difference-in-differences design. Meanwhile, Nanang and Tamin [5] used a dual-model trip distribution and modal split, which is a choice model. Belgiawan et al. [6] used a random regret minimization model, while Ilahi et al. [7] used a logit model with a latent variable to examine the effects of congestion charging on modal shifting in Jakarta. In 2016, Rizki et al. [8] examined three link-based trial ERP corridors in Jakarta to understand the route diverting behavior. Meanwhile, the effect of congestion charging on WFA or teleworking/telecommuting was carried out by Dissanayake [9] in Bangkok using the nested logit model. Of the above studies on congestion charging, all of them partially examine the effect of congestion charging. Due to the effects of the implementation of congestion charging, including transportation mode shifting and route diversions, as well as choosing not to travel, but to work from anywhere (WFA) instead, research focusing on the simultaneous effects of congestion charging on modes, routes, and WFA is needed.

2. Literatures Review

2.1. The Idea of Congestion Charging

According to Lindsey [10], the idea of imposing congestion charging was first proposed by Arthur Pigou in 1920 and Knight in 1924. However, much earlier, Adam Smith proposed the idea of charging in his book The Wealth of Nations in 1776 [11], regarding both road financing and the equity of using it. Dupuit [12] argued that even if the road is a public facility, the government will need a budget to finance its operation. Many economists argue that this Pigouvian tax principle is the first best method for financing transportation [13,14,15]. The Pigouvian tax principle as a tax of negative externalities, including traffic congestion, is determined based on the level of road traffic congestion [16,17]. This is equal to the external cost of congestion, and also known as a marginal cost pricing [18]. The implementation of congestion charging is the most efficient way to reduce traffic congestion because it employs a price mechanism, along with all its advantages, such as clarity, universality, and efficiency [18,19]. Vickrey [20,21], promoted the introduction of congestion charges, both theoretically and practically. He proposed the employing the cost of using the road to influence the choice of route and mode of transportation, depending on the level of congestion, or varying according to time, location, and type of vehicle. Then, according to Lindsey and Verhoef [17], congestion charging is appropriate because people tend to make efficient choices when they are faced with all the social benefits and costs of their activities, including travel.

2.2. Discrete Choice Models

According to Moshe Ben-Akiva and Steven R. Lerman [22], McFadden [23], and Meyer [24,25], discrete choice models, such as multinomial logit (MLM) and nested logit models (NLM), are widely used. These models are used based on the concept of utility, which assumes that each traveler values the utility of each choice of transportation mode. McFadden [23] suggests that if it is assumed that each individual traveling is a rational economic consumer, then in the face of mutually exclusive alternatives, he or she will maximize its utility depending on individual budget constraints. This model directly measures the response and choice of each individual concerning the performance of the transportation system. Consumers try to maximize the commodities’ utility according to the attributes they consume. Commodity desirability or individual preferences will be determined by the commodity’s attributes. An important implication of this theory in the analysis of travel demand is that preferences do not depend on the alternative travel options available, but on what the consumer wants (desirability). Hensher, 2005, in the Applied Choice Analysis [26] further states that humans are born to be voters (sellers, traders). Individual preferences depend on the attributes and socio-demographic characteristics of the traveler. The challenge in the choice model analysis is how to maximize variability that can be measured or observed (observed heterogeneity) while minimizing variability that cannot be measured or observed (unobserved heterogeneity). The alternatives that can be chosen by each individual are limited to choosing one of the alternatives that are designed (mutually exclusive) and are as complete as possible (collectively exhaustive). In this case, each individual chooses only one alternative from a series of choice alternatives. Train [27] states that in choosing several alternatives, or so-called choice sets, in addition to mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive characteristics, the number of alternatives must also have a limit or a finite number). The first and second characteristics do not always have to be fulfilled. For example, choices can be a combination of the first and second choices (not mutually exclusive), and some people may not choose either of these alternatives (not collectively exhausted). However, there must be a certain limit for the third characteristic that must be fulfilled in order for the number of choices to be finite.

2.3. Recent Studies

The effect of congestion charging on modal shifting was studied by Agarwal and Koo in Singapore using the difference-in-differences method with the intervention of increasing ERP rates at several entry points of the central business district (CBD). The results of the study showed that there was a significant increase in public transportation passengers [4], Nanang and Tamin simulated all possible TDM technique types in Jakarta, such as the use of busways, school buses, activity time staggering, three-in-one, odd-even, and road pricing [5]. Yudhistira et al., 2017 [28], conducted a study on the public perception of traffic jams. Yudhistira used a non-probabilistic survey of 400 respondents in Jakarta regarding the Sudirman Thamrin corridor and found that 53.4% of the respondents chose a mode of transportation based on travel time, 19% for safety reasons, and 17% based on travel costs. Belgiawan et al. [6] researched the effect of congestion charging on the mode of transportation shiftingby using the random regret minimization model from stated preference data. Then, Ilahi et al.’s research tried to include modes of transportation-on-demand services in Jakarta. He included the anti-car and pro-public transport latent variables in the multinomial logit (MNL) and mixed logit (MXL) models in the modal selection analysis. Motorcycles are the main choice of travelers in Jakarta. Ilahi et al. [7] examine the response of the people of Jakarta to congestion charging.
There are four congestion charging methods, namely cordon based, area based, link based, and road network based methods [29]. The majority of European and Asian countries implement congestion charging on a cordon or area basis, while link based pricing is used in North America, using the characteristics of a concentric road network. Elena et al. [30] and Li et al. [31] examined the social benefits of the two methods for imposing road pricing. Yudhistira [32] researched the application of cordon-based road pricing in traffic restriction areas (cordon-based pricing) using the spatial general equilibrium (SGE) model method. In Jakarta, if the ERP replaces the odd-even scheme, link-based pricing will be implemented. Such a scheme will enable travelers to choose alternative routes that are not subject to congestion charging. Regarding the weakness of this link-based pricing, Rizki et al. [8], researched three ERP trial corridors in Jakarta, investigating the possibility of commuter trips choosing alternative routes (route selection behavior), based on the length of the commuter trip.
Working from home, telecommuting, or teleworking, as well as flexible work arrangements, have been practiced since 1975 [33]. Initially, these methods were implemented due to the demand for lower housing costs and the need for a balance between work life and family interests, to help those with disabilities, and to reduce traffic congestion [34]. This trend is reinforced by the rapid improvement of information and communication technology [33], including the possibility for virtual work. Initially, in some countries, teleworking was carried out by contract workers, or those working on an output basis. However, teleworking and similar work models, such as flexible work arrangements, are now utilized by many types of workers and companies, for various reasons. Recently, transportation issues, including time wasted during travel, the challenge of living far from the workplace, and stress during the trip, have become one of the main considerations for working from home. The choice of urban [9] workers to telecommute can reduce the volume of traffic, hence easing traffic congestion. In Indonesia, there is no well-structured academic research on telecommuting. Research linking teleworking with ERP was conducted by Dissanayake [9] in Bangkok using the nested logit model.
In the context of modeling the response of travelers to congestion charging, this research provides novelty in that it examines the response of commuter travelers using the multinomial logit model, including not only modes of transportation, but also route diversions and options not to travel, or WFA. In this study, commuters making trips by private vehicles in urban areas are considered choice riders because they can choose not to commute due to the fact that they can carry out their activities anywhere, at home or in co-working spaces around their neighborhoods.

3. Methods

3.1. Models

Considering the need to find out the car commuter responses to link-based congestion charging, the model chosen in this study is the probability choice model, specifically the logit model, as proposed by McFadden [35], which calculates the probability of the n traveler choosing alternative i:
Pni = Prob (Uni + εni > Unj + εnjji)
Pni = Prob (εnj < εni + UniUnjji)
If εni is given, then
F( ε n j ) = exp(−exp( ε n i + U n i U n j ))
After going through complex algebraic calculations, then
P n i = 1 j e U n i U n j
P n i = e U n i j e U n j
where Pni is between 0 and 1 and never has a value of exactly 0 or 1.
Ten mutually exclusive alternatives are developed. The utility functions of the alternatives are as follows:
U(Cal) = acal + btt TT + bsdc SDC + εcal
U(Cat) = acat + btt TT + btol Toll + bsdc SDC + εcat
U(Cac) = acac+ btt TT + bcc CC + bsdc SDC + εcac.
U(Mal) = amal + btt TT + bsdc SDC + εmal
U(Mcc) = amcc + btt TT + bcc CC + bsdc SDC + εmcc
U(Tjc) = atjc + btt TT + bfpub Fpub + blf LF + bsdc SDC + εtjc
U(Trc) = atrc + btt TT + bfpub Fpub + blf LF + bsdc SDC + εtrc
U(Txc) = atxc + btt TT + bcc CC + bftx Ftx + bsdc SDC + εtxc
U(Ojc) = aojc + btt TT + bcc CC + bftx Ftx + bsdc SDC + εojc.
U(WFA) = awfa + + bsdc SDC + εwfa.
where:
U(Cal): private vehicle via alternative roads
U(Cat): private vehicle via toll roads
U(Cac): private vehicle via congestion charging corridor
U(Mal): motorcycle via alternative roads
U(Mcc): motorcycle via congestion charging corridor
U(Tjc): TransJakarta Busway
U(Trc): railway (Commuterline, MRT, LRT)
U(Txc): taxi/online taxi via congestion charging corridor
U(Ojc): online motorcycle taxi via congestion charging corridor
U(WFA): WFH/WFA (no choice option)
SDC: socio-demographic characteristics, income level (Inc), car ownership (COwn), and dummy job type (d_JT)
In the model formulation, there is one generic variable, namely travel time (TT), which is the sum of the time in the vehicle and the waiting time. Travel time is considered generic for all alternatives. Then, the characteristics of congestion charging rates for the alternatives of choosing private cars passing through the congestion charging corridors (Cac) and taxis (Txc) are considered the same. Likewise, the characteristics of congestion charging rates for the alternatives of using motorcycles passing through the congestion charging corridor (Mcc) and online motorcycle taxis/ojek (Ojc) are considered the same. The characteristics of transportation fares for the alternatives of choosing the TansJakarta Busway (Tjc) or the train (Trc) are considered the same, as well as taxi/online taxi fares (Txc) and fares for the alternatives of using online motorcycle taxis/ojek (Ojc). As a result, there are six observed attribute coefficients (btt = travel time coefficient; btol = toll levy coefficient; bcc = congestion charging rate coefficient; bfpub = public transport fare coefficient; bftx = taxi fare coefficient; and blf = public transport load factor coefficient), nine ASC constants (acal, acat, acac, amal, amcc, atjc, atrc, atxc, awfa), and one SDC coefficient (binc = income coefficient; or bjt = job type dummy variable coefficient).

3.2. Stated Preference Scenarios Development

There are several ways to design scenarios, including orthogonal or factorial designs, fractional factorial designs, and efficient designs. According to Hess [36], in the last decade, research on discrete choice using the stated preference (SP) experimental design method in generating choice sets has shifted from orthogonality principles to efficient-design principles or techniques. According to Rose and Bliemer [37] some researchers questioned the suitability of orthogonal design, especially its practicality, because it requires too many situations of choice. Bliemer stated that researchers are switching to using efficient designs, even if this means that one or several attributes will appear unbalanced. In this case, the number of choice situations must exceed the estimated degrees of freedom of the coefficients. The efficient design not only tries to minimize the correlation between attributes, but also strives to make the standard error of the estimated parameters as small as possible.
In this study, scenarios were generated using Software Choice Metrics Ngene with efficient design. The Ngene Software makes it possible to create blocking or subset questions for each respondent so that it is not necessary to answer all the questions in that choice set or scenario, but rather only one block of questions. There are 40 different situations to choose from (exceeding the estimated coefficient of 16). The 40 sets of questions were divided into 10 blocks. Therefore, each respondent only answered 4 scenarios, with each choice set consisting of 10 alternatives. The respondents chose 1 out of 10 blocks based on the last digit of their cell phone number.

3.3. Survey and Sample Selection Procedures

The research objects were car travelers who passed through eight congestion charging corridors, which is the odd-even scheme, as shown in Figure 1.
The sampling method used purposive sampling by distributing questionnaire links through various social media sites of the Transportation Research Agency (website, Istagram, Facebook, Twitter, and WhatsApp) within a certain time to obtain the number of samples, according to the minimum target. The stated preference survey was conducted online and disseminated via social media and the internet. The survey was carried out for 30 days, from October to November 2021. The number of respondents was proportionally distributed in each study area. Respondents who did not meet the criterion, i.e., not usually passing through the odd-even corridors, did not continue to complete the questions about choice preferences in the choice sets. Meanwhile, private car travelers who usually drove through the congestion charging corridor continued to complete the questionnaire.
The e-survey method was selected due to a very high internet penetration rate at 2020, which is around 93.24% in Jakarta, 82.18% in West Java, and 84.07% in Banten [38]. The selection of an online survey also allows all those connected to the internet to have the same opportunity to fill out the questionnaire.

3.4. Sample Size

Following the methods of Jatnika et al. [39] the calculation of the minimum sample size for simple random sampling can be performed using the following formula:
N = (N × P × Q)/((N − 1) × D + P × Q)
N = population size;
B = bound of error (highest sampling error);
P = Q = moderate proportion estimate (0.5);
D = calculated based on B and the level of confidence.
Based on the formula, the sample can be calculated using the average daily number of travelers who usually passes through eight odd-even corridors, which will be converted into congestion charging corridors. This number is 304,213 private cars per day, or 456,319 people per day.
Ncar = 456.319
B = 5%
P = Q = 0.5
D = B2/4 = 0.000625
n c a r = ( 456.319 ) ( 0.5 ) ( 0.5 ) 456.319 1 0.000625 + ( 0.5 ) ( 0.5 ) = 399.65 = 400 car commuter sample

3.5. Attribute Levels

In the model formulation, there is one generic variable, namely travel time (TT), which is the sum of the time in the vehicle and the waiting time. Travel time is considered generic for all alternatives. Then, characteristics of congestion charging rates for the alternatives of choosing private cars passing through the congestion charging corridors (Cac) and taxis (Txc) are considered the same. Likewise, the characteristics of the congestion charging rates for the alternatives of using motorcycles passing through the congestion charging corridor (Mcc) and online motorcycle taxis/ojek (Ojc) are considered the same. The characteristics of transportation fares for the alternatives of choosing the TansJakarta Busway (Tjc) or the train (Trc) are considered the same, as well as taxi/online taxi fares (Txc) and fares for the alternatives of using online motorcycle taxis/ojek (Ojc). As a result, there are six observed attribute coefficients (btt, btol, bcc, bfpub, bftx, blf), nine alternative specific constants (acal, acat, acac, amal, amcc, atjc, atrc, atxc, awfa), and one SDC coefficient (binc, cown, or bjt).
By including only the main transportation impedances as vector attributes, the respondents can easily understand the choice sets in the stated preference questionnaire, even though in this study, there were ten alternatives in one choice set. Setting 40 choice sets is also challenging. However, the scenarios or choice sets can be divided into several blocks. To distribute the block of choice sets to be completed by the respondent, the last digit of the respondent’s cell phone can be used as block group of choice sets, because they are relatively evenly distributed in the ten blocks. The design alternatives can be multifaced, and they relate to all possible alternatives, but they are finite. A modal shifting alternative may be combined with route choices, as well as an alternative of not traveling. The alternative of not traveling is considered as a no choice option; therefore, it requires no attributes.
The attribute values of travel time, toll fees, and public transport fares, as well as the initial settings for congestion charging values based on the previous value of time survey, are used as initial setting values, which are then increased and decreased by 20–25% (pivoting). These values are shown in Table 1:

3.6. Data Cleaning

Data cleaning was performed by excluding the data that showed non-trading behaviors and inconsistency. Non-trading behavior is shown by always choosing the same option, regardless of the value of the attribute. Using non-trading behavior data will affect the estimated coefficients [40]. Of 2125 respondents, 1509 traveled to the center of Jakarta. A total of 447 respondents traveled to Jakarta by private car, which usually went through the eight corridors. A total of 46 respondents showed non-trader and inconsistent characteristics, resulting in 401 respondents included in the parameter estimates. Of the 401 respondents, the number of data points was 1608.

4. Results and Discussion

4.1. Socio-Demographic Data

The socio-economic characteristics of the respondents are shown in Table 2:

4.2. Estimating Parameters of the Models and Determining Goodness of Fit of the Models

4.2.1. Parameter Attributes Estimation

In the discrete choice model, the parameters of the models were estimated using the method of maximum likelihood estimation (MLE). For the MNL model, the maximum likelihood function that the probability of individual i choosing an alternative j can be expressed as:
j P i j ) y i j
where yij = 1 if individual i chooses j and zero if he or she chooses the another option.
By assuming that each individual decision is independent, the probability that each individual in the sample chooses an alternative is:
L β = i = 1 n j P i j ) y i j
where n is a sample of individuals making a decision, and β is the parameter vector in the model.
Then log likelihood function becomes:
L L β = i = 1 n j y i j l n ( P j )
NLOGIT6 econometric software estimates the value of β that maximizes the LL(β) function.
The results of the estimation of the parameters of the models are presented in Table 3.

4.2.2. Significance of Parameter Estimates

From the modeling results, the coefficients of travel time, congestion charging levy, toll rates, mass public transport fares, taxi fares, and load factors showed negative results, which indicates that the attribute is the main impedance of urban travel. Travel time, congestion charging levy rates, toll rates, and mass public transport fares significantly determine the utility of alternatives. However, the level of overcrowded onboard the transport modes (load factor) and taxi fares are not statistically significant. These findings indicate that the level of overcrowding in public transportation is not a variable that influences the choice of mode of travel in an urbanized area. Likewise, taxi fares are not significant, indicating that taxis are not the preferred mode of substitution, and taxi fares are not an attribute that determines the choice of the mode of transportation for commuters with private cars.
In Model 1, of the 15 parameters estimated, 13 were significant at α = 0.01 or 99% confidence level. Two parameter attributes are not significant, namely blf (load factor attribute or public transport occupancy rate coefficient) and bftx (online taxi and motorcycle taxi fare coefficient). The Wald statistics = z = β i s t a n d a r d   e r r o r i for blf and bftx are −0.03 and −1.47, respectively. Testing the significance of those two attributes, the Wald statistic is smaller than the critical value of 1.96; thus, the hypothesis that the estimated parameter is equal to zero is accepted, and the variables are concluded to be statistically insignificant. That is also the case when evaluating the p-value by setting the 95% confidence interval at the value α = 0.05. If the p-value is less than α = 0.05, then the estimated parameters are statistically not equal to zero, and the attribute is statistically significant. If the p-value exceeds α = 0.05, the estimated parameter is statistically equal to zero, and the variable is statistically insignificant. The Wald statistic and p-value at the same level of confidence will yield the same result. The p-value of blf and bftx with p-value are 0.9747 and 0.1409, respectively, greater than α = 0.05. Therefore, the hypothesis that the estimated parameter is equal to zero is acceptable, and the variable is statistically insignificant. When blf and bftx are excluded in Model 1a, all estimated parameters (9 ASC and 4 observed attributes) show significance at the 99% confidence interval at a value of α = 0.01.
Adding the Income variable and Job Type as dummy variables, the coefficient estimates in Models 2 and 4 do not show significance. The Wald statistic is −0.8946 for binc and 1.4644 for bjt, with p-values of 0.3710 for binc and 0.1431 for bjt. In this case, it can be stated that binc = 0 and bjt = 0, and we cannot reject the Ho hypothesis: βi = 0 because the absolute value of the Wald statistic is smaller than the critical value of 1.96, and the p-value is greater than α = 0.05. In other words, the hypothesis that the estimated parameters equal zero is accepted, and the variable is statistically insignificant.
Whereas for Model 3, by adding the Car Ownership (COwn) attribute, it shows significance at α = 0.05, with the Wald statistic of COwn as 1.98 and α = 0.0476. In other words, the hypothesis that the estimated parameters are equal to zero is rejected, and the variable (Car Ownership) is statistically significant.

4.3. Determining Goodness of Fit of the Models

4.3.1. Log Likelihood

The significance of the model was determined by comparing the log-likelihood function of the estimated model to the base model. Following the methods of McFadden [35], the base model used in this study was the log-likelihood at zero coefficient (LL at Zero) or (LL0). To measure the improvement of the goodness of fit model, if the estimated log-likelihood of the model is close to zero, the model is improving [26].
The value of LL0 is calculated by the formula:
L L 0 = N l n ( 1 N A l t t )
where N is the number of observations (1608 data points), and NAlt = 10, then LL0 = −3702.5568. The LL function of Model 1a. is −2429.58121, greater than LL0 = −3702.5568, and is close to zero. Therefore, Model 1a. is better than the model without the coefficients.

4.3.2. Log Likelihood Ratio Test

  • Comparing Model 1 and Model 1.a
The −2LL ratio obtained from the output model was then checked using the log-likelihood ratio formula to obtain the Chi-square model. The Chi-square result was then compared with the Chi-square table at α = 0.05 or the 95% confidence level.
2 L L r a t i o = 2 L L b a s e   m o d e l L L e s t i m a t e d   m o d e l χ n u m b e r   o f   n e w   p a r a m e t e r s   e s t i m a t e d   i n   t h e   e s t i m a t e d   m o d e l 2
In Model 1.a., the number of parameters estimated is k = 13, with k = 9 constants (ASC) and k = 4 variable coefficients. The log-likelihood of Model 1a regarding the convergent function estimated by the log-likelihood in the basic model log-likelihood is zero, the Chi-square (χ2) is 2545.95118, greater than the critical Chi-square result according to the table at a degree of freedom 13, which is 22.362. The p statistical value of χ2 is also 0.0000, which is lower than the value of α = 0.05 at the 95% confidence level. According to the −2LL ratio criterion, hypothesis H0 that the estimated model is not better than the base model is rejected. It can be concluded that Model 1a is statistically significant.
2.
Comparing Model 1.a, Model 2, Model 3, and Model 4
In Models 2, 3, and 4, the estimated coefficients are 14 each, higher than those in Model 1a, which is 13. According to Koppelman [41] and Hensher [26], selecting the best model can be achieved by comparing the −2LL in the same way, but not against the basic model. Model 2 was compared to Model 1a, while Model 3 was compared to Model 1a. In this case, the largest LL was subtracted from the smallest LL.
The −2LL test was formulated as −2LL ratio = −2(largest LL—smallest LL) ∼χ2 (the difference in the number of parameters estimated from the two models). The Pseudo R is
R 2 = 1 L L e s t i m a t e   d m o d e l L L b a s e   m o d e l
The Table 4 shows that the log-likelihood ratio of Model 2 was estimated by using base Model 1a, resulting in the Chi-square (χ2) of 0.7756, which was smaller than the critical Chi-squared result for the degree of freedom 1, namely 3.841. Meanwhile, the log-likelihood ratio of Model 3, gives a Chi-squared value of 4.25514, greater than the Chi-squared table at df 1, which is 3.841. Therefore, the hypothesis H0 that the estimated model is not better than the basic model (Model 1.a), is unacceptable, and it can be concluded that Model 3 is statistically significant. The log-likelihood ratio test for Model 4 to Model 1a is 1.10626, which is smaller than the critical Chi-squared value according to the table for the degree of freedom 1. Therefore, the hypothesis H0 that the estimated model is not better than the basic model (Model 1a), can be accepted. It can be concluded that Models 2 and 3 are not statistically significant. As a result, based on the goodness of fit criterion, only Model 1a and Model 3 are significant, while Models 2 and 4 are statistically insignificant.
For further analysis, Model 1a was used because it is better evaluated in terms of the measure of the goodness of fit and the significance of its parameter estimates.

4.4. Estimating Probability in Each Congestion Charging Corridor

The number of alternatives varies across the eight congestion charging corridors studied. This is because corridors 1, 2, 3, 4, 7, and 8 are not parallel to the toll road. Likewise, not all railway lines are parallel to the congestion charging corridors, i.e., corridors 4, 5, 6, and 8. Therefore, the alternative probability for each corridor is not the same.
Estimating of probability for each alternative is carried out by entering the initial setting values of the attributes, as depicted in Table 1, into the model. In this case, the initial setting of the congestion charging levy for cars is IDR16,000. On congestion-charging corridors where there are no toll roads, the probability of choosing a private car via congestion-charging (Cac) is around 49.05% and 53.48%. Around half of the car travelers were willing to pay the congestion levy and passed through congestion charging corridors. However, for corridors that are parallel to toll roads, the proportion of travelers who chose to pass through toll roads was around 36.06%. That is to say, if congestion charging is applied to corridors 5 and 6, then only 36.06% of travelers were willing to pay and used the congestion charging corridors.
Table 5 depicts the probability of car travelers diverting into alternative roads (Cal) accounts for a high probability, that is 16.82% to 22.88%. Link-based congestion charging opened the possibility of car travelers diverting their routes to alternative non-congestion charging routes. In terms of shifting to public transportation, 17.69% of car travelers would choose mass transportation. Those who shifted to TransJakarta busways (Tjc) and trains (Trc) were 9.40% and 8.29%, respectively, far higher than those using taxis/online taxis and online motorcycle taxis/ojek, at 0.93% and 0.05%, respectively. Meanwhile, on corridors that are not parallel to the railway lines, travelers with private cars will not automatically move to the TransJakarta busway, but are proportionally distributed to other alternatives. Car commuters shift their mode to motorcycles when passing through congestion charging with a probability of 3.50% (Mcc) and 4.69% for choosing alternative roads (Mal). The probability of those who chose not to travel and carried out their activities anywhere (WFA, working from anywhere) was still greater than the probability of choosing online taxis/taxi and online motorcycle taxis/ojek, at 1.23%. These were travelers with discretionary job types, or types of work that do not require them to be present in the office to work, but who telework instead. Of course, the probability of choosing an alternative depends on the congestion charging levy rate. The probability that car travelers will choose to pay the congestion levy and pass through the congestion charging corridor will be higher if the congestion levy is cheaper, and vice versa.
As hypothesized, congestion charging greatly affects urban travel behavior in Jakarta. From a model of a private car, the tendency for route diversions is very high, higher than that for switching modes to public transport. Therefore, choosing a corridor-based congestion charging scheme, even though the main road network is relatively concentric, still allows for diversions to alternative roads, which can reduce the effectiveness of traffic control. Although the results may not exactly reflect the distribution of traffic all over road networks; however, the estimated probabilities indicate the conditions under which this is likely to happen. Traffic assignment will dynamically change over time, redistributing depending on the generalized costs. Traffic may be redistributed from alternative roads to congestion charging corridors if severe traffic congestion occurs on alternative roads until equilibrium conditions are reached.
Understanding the value of time for travelers is also important for further analysis of traffic assignments. The model estimated value of time for car travelers is IDR 15,540 per hour.

4.5. Marginal Effects

The direct marginal effects, the change in the probability of the alternative Pi to the change in the attribute of the alternative Xi, is obtained by the differentiation of Pi to Xik at the k attribute level of alternative i, ceteris paribus. Meanwhile, the cross marginal effect expresses changes as a result of unit changes in a competing alternative variable, where the variable is not an attribute of the alternative, ceteris paribus, it is formulated where bjk is an attribute of k, Pi is the probability of alternative i, and Pj is the probability of alternative j.
Table 6 shows the marginal effects of congestion charging (CC) on private vehicle choosing congestion corridors (Cac). In terms of direct marginal effects, it can be interpreted that there is a change in the probability of all travelers choosing private vehicles through the congestion charging (Cac) corridor of −0.0338 or decreasing by −3.38% for every IDR 1000 increase in the congestion charging levy rate (CC) on Cac, assuming the other attributes do not change, ceteris paribus.
The summation of probability increases for all alternatives, as shown in the table, corresponding to the marginal effects of Cac, i.e., 3.38%. Every IDR 1000 increase in the congestion charging levy rate will result a 2.08% increase in route diversions, a 0.94% increase in the shift to public transportation, a 0.26% increase in the change of mode to motorcycles passing through the CC corridor, and a 0.09% increase in those not traveling and telecommuting instead.
The marginal effect is an important estimate to predict the likely effects of levy rate changes. The marginal effects reflect the sensitivity changes regarding the probability of the alternatives.

5. Conclusions

The findings are not surprising, due to the fact that the link-based system is not a closed system. There are still alternative roads for car travelers to choose from. When the congestion charging levy is set at IDR 16,000, around a half of the car travelers will choose to travel by car, being willing to pay the levy and pass through congestion charging corridors. However, that is not the case when there is a toll road parallel to the congestion charging route, in which case, the probability of choosing congestion charging is lower. In the same way, when there is an increase in congestion charging rates, according to the marginal effect, travelers with private cars are more likely to choose alternative routes. It is estimated that the marginal effects of increasing IDR 1000, ceteris paribus, will be a reduction in the probability by 3.38%, and vice versa. Surprisingly, car travelers prefer to divert their routes rather than switching to public transport. Other findings show that the load factor as a proxy of the overcrowded rate of public transport and taxi fares are not significant attributes for car travelers.
These findings on corridor-basis congestion charging may provide insights for policy makers and regulators, as well as road planners, network designers, and traffic management officers. Policy makers and regulators should consider integrating transportation demand policy measures by simultaneously employing push and pull policies, especially in improving public transport services and parking policies. Due to the probability that a high proportion of car travelers on link-based congestion charging schemes would divert their routes, it is imperative for policy makers and regulators to consider area-based or cordon-based congestion charging rather than link-based methods. For local transport management officials, it is essential to anticipate the controlling of traffic on alternative roads, as well as to guarantee a high service level regarding mass public transportation.
Those who interested in this subject might continue the study of congestion charging in Jakarta, including the use of cordon- or area-based schemes. These studies may include the sampling of car travelers passing through other alternative routes to account for the probability of them choosing congestion charging schemes.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.Y.; Methodology, M.Y.; Software, M.Y.; Validation, B.B., M.S. and A.K.H.; Formal analysis, M.Y.; Resources, M.Y.; Data curation, M.Y.; Writing—original draft, M.Y.; Writing—review & editing, M.Y.; Visualization, M.Y.; Supervision, B.B., M.S. and A.K.H. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding and the APC was funded by University of Padjadjaran Bandung Indonesia.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. JICA and ALMEC Corporation. JABODETABEK Urban Transportation Policy Integration Project Phase 2 in the Republic of Indonesia, October, 2019. Available online: https://openjicareport.jica.go.jp/pdf/12356366.pdf (accessed on 20 October 2022).
  2. Kementerian Perhubungan. Rencana Induk Transportasi Jabodetabek (RITJ), p. 54, 2015, PPID-Kemenhub. Available online: http://ppid.dephub.go.id/files/datalitbang/bptj/laporan_RITJ_30-6-2015_AR.pdf (accessed on 20 October 2022).
  3. Pemerintah Provinsi DKI Jakarta. Perda_No_5_Tahun_2014, p. 13, JDIH Provinsi DKI Jakarta; 2014. Available online: https://jdih.jakarta.go.id/dokumen/detail/8944 (accessed on 20 October 2022).
  4. Agarwal, S.; Koo, K.M. Impact of electronic road pricing (ERP) changes on transport modal choice. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2016, 60, 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Nanang, M.; Tamin, O.Z. Mode Shift Travel Demand Management Evaluation From Jakarta’s Experience. In Proceedings of the Eastern Asia Society for Transportation Studies, Surabaya, Indonesia, 16–19 November 2009; Volume 7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Belgiawan, P.F.; Ilahi, A.; Axhausen, K.W. Influence of pricing on mode choice decision in Jakarta: A random regret minimization model. Case Stud. Transp. Policy 2019, 7, 87–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Ilahi, A.; Belgiawan, P.F.; Axhausen, K.W. Influence of pricing on mode choice decision integrated with latent variable. In Mapping the Travel Behavior Genome; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2019; pp. 125–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Rizki, M.; Karsaman, R.H.; Santoso, I.; Frazila, R.B. Route Divert Behavior in Jakarta Electronic Road Pricing Policy Implementation. Int. J. Technol. 2016, 7, 571. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Dissanayake, D. Sustainable urban policies for developing countries by integrating center-based telecommuting with transit and road pricing case study of Bangkok, Thailand, metropolitan region. Transp. Res. Rec. 2008, 2067, 137–145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Lindsey, R. Do economists reach a conclusion? Do Economists Reach A Conclusion on Road Pricing? The Intellectual History of an Idea. Econ. J. Watch 2006, 3, 292–379. Available online: http://journaltalk.net/articles/5515 (accessed on 20 October 2022).
  11. Smith, A. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Books I, II, III, IV and V; Metalibri: Amsterdam, The Netherland, 2007; Available online: http://metalibri.incubadora.fapesp.br (accessed on 20 October 2022).
  12. Dupuit, J. On-the-Measurement-of-the-Utility-of-Public-Works; pp. 255–283; translated in International Economic Papers, 2(1952): pp. 83–110. English translation by R. H. Barback from “De la Mesure de l’Utilite des Travaux Publics”, Annales des Pants et Chaussees, 2d series, Vol. 8, 1844. Reprinted by courtesy of International Economic. Available online: https://competitionandappropriation.econ.ucla.edu/wp-content/uploads/sites/95/2016/08/On-the-Measurement-of-the-Utility-of-Public-Works-p.-255-283.pdf (accessed on 20 October 2022).
  13. de Borger, B.; Proost, S. A political economy model of road pricing. J. Urban Econ. 2012, 71, 79–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Ortega, A.; Vassallo, J.M.; Pérez, J.I. How varies optimal welfare pricing with income distribution? the case of the untolled alternative. Transp. Res. Procedia 2014, 3, 413–422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Tirachini, A.; Hensher, D.A. Multimodal Transport Pricing: First Best, Second Best and Extensions to Non-motorized Transport. Transp. Rev. 2012, 32, 181–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Verhoef, E.; Nijkamp, P.; Rietveld, P. Second-Best Regulation of Road Transport Externalities. J. Transp. Econ. Policy 1995, 29, 147–167. [Google Scholar]
  17. Lindsey, C.R.; Verhoef, E.T. Traffic Congestion and Congestion Pricing; Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper, No. 00-101/3; Tinbergen Institute: Amsterdam/Rotterdam, The Nethelrands, 2000; Available online: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/85524www.econstor.eu (accessed on 20 October 2022).
  18. Hau, T.D. Economic Fundamentals of Road Pricing. In Road Pricing; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 1992; p. 81. [Google Scholar]
  19. Spurling, D.J. Introduction to Transport Economics: Demand, Cost, Pricing, and Adoption; Universal-Publishers: Irvine, CA, USA, 2010; Available online: www.universal-publishers.com (accessed on 20 October 2022).
  20. Vickrey, W. Pricing in Urban and Suburban Transport; The American Economic Review, Volume 53, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Seventy-Fifth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. Am. Econ. Rev. 1963, 53, 452–465. [Google Scholar]
  21. Vickrey, W. Congestion Theory and Transport Investment. Am. Econ. Rev. 1969, 59, 251–260. [Google Scholar]
  22. Ben-Akiva, M.; Lerman, S.R. Discrete Choice Analysis: Theory and Application to Travel Demand. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 1987, 38, 370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Mcfadden, D. Disaggregate Behavioral Travel Demand’s RUM Side-A 30-Year Retrospective Discrete Choice Theory View Project Behavioral Finance and Investment Decision View Project. 2000. Available online: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/2331526 (accessed on 24 November 2022).
  24. Meyer, M.D. Demand management as an element of transportation policy: Using carrots and sticks to infuence travel behavior. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 1999, 33, 575–599. Available online: www.elsevier.com/locate/tra (accessed on 24 November 2022). [CrossRef]
  25. Meyer, M.D. Transportation planning handbook. In Transportation Planning Handbook, 4th ed.; John Wiley & Sons.: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Hensher, D.A.; Rose, J.M.; Greene, W.H. Applied Choice Analysis A Primer Almost; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  27. Train, K.E. Chapter 4—GEV. In Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation, 2nd ed.; Cambridge University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2009; pp. 76–96. Available online: http://www.cambridge.org/9780521747387 (accessed on 20 October 2022).
  28. Yudhistira, M.H.; Koesrindartono, D.P.; Harmadi, S.H.B.; Pratama, A.P. How Congested Jakarta is? Perception of Jakarta’s Citizen on Traffic Congestion. Econ. Financ. Indones. 2017, 62, 141. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Broaddus, A.; Litman, T.; Menon, G.; Replogle, M. Transportation Demand Management Training Document; Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development: Bonn, Germany, 2009; Available online: http://www.sutp.org (accessed on 24 November 2022).
  30. Safirova, E.; Gillingham, K.; Harrington, W.; Nelson, P.; Lipman, A. Choosing Congestion Pricing Policy Cordon Tolls Versus Link-Based Tolls. Transp. Res. Rec. 2005, 1932, 169–177. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Li, X.; Lv, Y.; Sun, W.; Zhou, L. Cordon- or link-based pricing: Environment-oriented toll design models development and application. Sustainability 2019, 11, 258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Yudhistira, M.H. On The Effects of The Electronic Road Pricing Plan in The Jakarta Metropolitan Area. Ph.D. Thesis, National Graduate Institute of Policy Studies, Tokyo, Japan, January 2015. [Google Scholar]
  33. Nilles, J.M. Traffic reduction by telecommuting: A status review and selected bibliography. Transp. Res. Part A Gen. 1988, 22, 301–317. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Handy, S.L.; Mokhtarian, P.L. The future of telecommuting. Futures 1996, 28, 227–240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Mcfadden, D. The Measurement of Travel Demand. J. Public Econ. 1974, 3, 303–328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Hess, S.; Rose, J.M. Some Lessons in Stated Choice Survey Design. European Transport Conference, 2009 Proceedings, London, UK; Association for European Transport: Noordwijkerhout, The Netherlands, 2009; Available online: https://aetransport.org/past-etc-papers/conference-papers-pre-2012/conference-papers-2009?abstractId=3235&state=b (accessed on 8 September 2022).
  37. Rose, J.M.; Bliemer, M.C.J. Constructing Efficient Stated Choice Experimental Designs. Transp. Rev. 2009, 29, 587–617. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Badan Pusat Statistik/BPS-Statistics Indonesia; Statistik Indonesia: Jakarta, Indonesia, 2020; p. 449.
  39. Jatnika, R.; Haffas, M.; Abidin, F.A.; Prathama, A.G. Belajar Sampling Dengan; UNPAD SAS Online: Sumedang, Indonesia, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  40. Rose, J.M.; Hess, S.; Collins, A.T. Impact of violations of model assumptions: The role of lexicography, inconsistent choices and changing preferences in model estimation. In Proceedings of the Transportation Research Board 90th Annual Meeting Location, Washington, DC, USA, 23–37 January 2011; pp. 1–18. [Google Scholar]
  41. Koppelman, F.S.; Bhat, C.; Sethi, V.; Subramanian, S.; Bernardin, V.; Zhang, J. A Self Instructing Course in Mode Choice Modeling: Multinomial and Nested Logit Models; U.S. Department of Transportation Federal Transit Administration: Washington, DC, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Odd-even scheme corridors.
Figure 1. Odd-even scheme corridors.
Sustainability 15 08104 g001
Table 1. Alternatives, attributes, and levels.
Table 1. Alternatives, attributes, and levels.
No.AlternativeAttributes
Travel Time
(min)
CC/Toll
(IDR‘000)
Fare
(IDR‘000)
LF
(Percent)
1Private vehicles via alternative roadCal45, 60, 75
2Private vehicles via toll roadCat22, 30, 3810, 13, 16
3Private vehicles via congestion charging corridorsCac15, 20, 2512, 16, 20
4Motorcycles via alternative roadsMal45, 60, 75
5Motorcycles via congestion charging corridorsMcc15, 20, 256, 7.5, 9
6TransJakarta busTjc15, 20, 25 3.5, 5, 6.550, 100, 150
7Trains (Commuterline, MRT, LRT)Trc10, 20, 30 3.5, 1050, 100, 150
8Online taxi/taxi via congestion charging corridorsTxc15, 20, 2512, 16, 2040, 50, 60
9Online motorcycle taxis via congestion charging corridorsOjc15, 20, 256, 7.5, 925, 35, 45
10WFAWFA
Table 2. Socio-demographic characteristics.
Table 2. Socio-demographic characteristics.
No.Socio-Demographic CharacteristicsRespondent
SamplePercent
Income Group
1<IDR 3 million143.49%
2IDR 4–7 million8019.95%
3IDR 8–13 million9824.44%
4IDR 14–20 million9724.19%
5IDR 21–30 million5714.21%
6>IDR 31 million5513.72%
Car Ownership
10 vehicles174.24%
21 vehicle24260.35%
32 vehicles11127.68%
4>2 vehicles317.73%
Job Type
1mandatory36791.52%
2discretionary348.48%
Table 3. Comparison of parameters and goodness of fit of Models 1, 1a, 2, 3, and 4.
Table 3. Comparison of parameters and goodness of fit of Models 1, 1a, 2, 3, and 4.
Constants and CoefficientsModel 1.
Alternative Specific Constants and Variables
Model 1a.
(Modified Model 1)
Alternative Specific Constants and Variables
Model 2.
Alternative Specific Constants, Variables, and Income
Model 3.
Alternative Specific Constants, Variables, and Car Ownership
Model 4.
Alternative Specific Constants, Variables, and Dummy Job Type
CoefficientStandard ErrorCoefficientStandard ErrorCoefficientStandard ErrorCoefficientStandard ErrorCoefficientStandard Error
Constants (alpha)
acal4.11112 ***0.271444.08239 ***0.263144.28864 ***0.356223.44977 ***0.395853.53986 ***0.44330
acat5.43918 ***0.553795.40774 ***0.549305.61304 ***0.599034.77833 ***0.622954.86432 ***0.65544
acac5.64952 ***0.332385.60874 ***0.328185.81549 ***0.406994.97487 ***0.442345.06437 ***0.48592
amal2.52555 ***0.277742.49974 ***0.271082.70611 ***0.362211.86688 ***0.401231.95741 ***0.44794
amcc1.84162 ***0.265151.81714 ***0.262582.02369 ***0.356041.18381 ***0.395801.27393 ***0.44346
atjc3.23920 ***0.472953.20394 ***0.332173.41018 ***0.409862.57112 ***0.444782.66195 ***0.48713
atrc3.82483 ***0.553633.78049 ***0.394223.98670 ***0.461583.14778 ***0.492773.23866 ***0.53127
atxc4.95097 ***1.805442.30513 ***0.441332.51172 ***0.502611.67157 ***0.531661.76085 ***0.56844
awfa−0.95098 ***0.28557−0.95098 ***0.28557−0.74454 **0.37323−1.58395 ***0.41117−1.49310 ***0.45671
Coefficients (beta)
btt−0.03559 ***0.00386−0.03509 ***0.00367−0.03509 ***0.00367−0.03510 ***0.00367−0.03509 ***0.00367
bcc−0.13745 ***0.01640−0.13550 ***0.01629−0.13552 ***0.01629−0.13544 ***0.01629−0.13537 ***0.01629
btol−0.13341 ***0.03730−0.13215 ***0.03720−0.13205 ***0.03720−0.13240 ***0.03720−0.13213 ***0.03720
bfpub−0.14584 ***0.04495−0.14408 ***0.04202−0.14406 ***0.04202−0.14408 ***0.04202−0.14414 ***0.04202
blf−0.006740.21217
bftx−0.051120.03472
Coefficients SDC
Inc −0.011630.01300
Cown 0.49347 **0.24906
d_JT 0.618320.42222
Goodness of Fits
N1608 1608 1608 1608 1608
K15 13 14 14 14
LL(β)−2428.4968 −2429.5812 −2429.1934 −2427.4536 −2428.6403
LL(0)−3702.5568 −3702.5568 −3702.5568 −3702.5568 −3702.5568
LL(C)−2495.256 −2495.2560 −2495.2560 −2495.2560 −2495.2560
Pseudo R2 wrt LL(0) 0.3441 0.3438 0.3439 0.3444 0.3441
Pseudo R2 wrt LL(C) 0.0268 0.0268 0.0265 0.0272 0.0267
χ2 wrt LL(0) 2548.12008 2545.95118 2546.72678 2550.20632 2547.83304
χ2 wrt LL(C)133.51855 131.34965 618.8744 622.35394 619.98066
Prob [χ2 > value ]0 0 0 0 0
χ2 Table at α = 0.05 CI 95%24.996 22.362 23.685 23.685 23.685
***, **==> significance at the 1%, 5% level.
Table 4. Comparison of the goodness of fit of Models 2 and 3 to Model 1a.
Table 4. Comparison of the goodness of fit of Models 2 and 3 to Model 1a.
Model 1a
(Base Model)
Model 2Model 3Model 4
Difference in the degree of freedom (Δk)13111
Log-likelihood function−2429.58121−2429.19341−2427.45360−2428.64028
Pseudo R square 0.34380.0001596160.0008757110.000387281
Chi-squared 131.349650.77564.25521.10626
Chi-squared table22.3623.8413.8413.841
Table 5. Probability of each alternative mode and route for each corridor.
Table 5. Probability of each alternative mode and route for each corridor.
Mode/
Route
Probability (Percent)
Corridor 1Corridor 2Corridor 3Corridor 4Corridor 5Corridor 6Corridor 7Corridor 8
Cac49.0549.0549.0553.4836.0636.0649.0553.48
CatNo Toll32.5832.58No Toll
Cal22.8822.8822.8824.9416.8216.8222.8824.94
Mal4.694.694.695.113.443.444.695.11
Mcc3.503.503.503.822.572.573.503.82
Tjc9.409.409.4010.256.916.919.4010.25
Trc8.298.298.29No Train8.29No Train
Txc0.930.930.931.010.680.680.931.01
Ojc0.050.050.050.050.030.030.050.05
WFA1.231.231.231.340.900.901.231.34
100.00100.00100.00100.00100.00100.00100.00100.00
Table 6. Marginal effects of CC on Cac.
Table 6. Marginal effects of CC on Cac.
AlternativesMarginal Effects CC on Cac
Private vehicles via congestion charging corridorsCac−0.0338
Private vehicles via alternative roadCal0.0172
Motorcycles via alternative roadsMal0.0036
Motorcycles via congestion charging corridorsMcc0.0026
TransJakarta busTjc0.0063
Trains (Commuterline, MRT, LRT)Trc0.0000
Online taxi/taxi via congestion charging corridorsTxc0.0007
Online motorcycle taxis via congestion charging corridorsOjc0.0024
WFAWFA0.0009
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Yugihartiman, M.; Budiono, B.; Setiawan, M.; Hidayat, A.K. Estimating Travel Choice Probability of Link-Based Congestion Charging Scheme for Car Commuter Trips in Jakarta. Sustainability 2023, 15, 8104. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108104

AMA Style

Yugihartiman M, Budiono B, Setiawan M, Hidayat AK. Estimating Travel Choice Probability of Link-Based Congestion Charging Scheme for Car Commuter Trips in Jakarta. Sustainability. 2023; 15(10):8104. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108104

Chicago/Turabian Style

Yugihartiman, Masrono, B. Budiono, Maman Setiawan, and Achmad Kemal Hidayat. 2023. "Estimating Travel Choice Probability of Link-Based Congestion Charging Scheme for Car Commuter Trips in Jakarta" Sustainability 15, no. 10: 8104. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108104

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop