Next Article in Journal
The Ultimate Safe System: Redefining the Safe System Approach for Road Safety
Next Article in Special Issue
Relating Social and Ecological Resilience: Dutch Citizen’s Initiatives for Biodiversity
Previous Article in Journal
Environmental and Socioeconomic Impacts of Shrimp Farming in the Philippines: A Critical Analysis Using PRISMA
Previous Article in Special Issue
Regional Cooperation in Waste Management: Examining Australia’s Experience with Inter-municipal Cooperative Partnerships
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Importance of a Natural Social Contract and Co-Evolutionary Governance for Sustainability Transitions

1
Governance of Sustainability Transitions, Maastricht Sustainability Institute (MSI), Maastricht University, 6200 MD Maastricht, The Netherlands
2
Social Innovation and Governance for Sustainability at the Research and Innovation Centre Agri, Food and Life Sciences (RIC-AFL), Inholland University of Applied Sciences, 2628 AL Delft, The Netherlands
3
Innovation and Sustainable Development, Maastricht Sustainability Institute (MSI), Maastricht University, 6200 MD Maastricht, The Netherlands
4
Maastricht Economic and Social Research Institute on Innovation and Technology (UNU-MERIT), United Nations University, 6200 MD Maastricht, The Netherlands
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2022, 14(5), 2976; https://doi.org/10.3390/su14052976
Submission received: 30 November 2021 / Revised: 23 February 2022 / Accepted: 25 February 2022 / Published: 3 March 2022
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Environmental Policy and Governance: Evolutionary Perspectives)

Abstract

:
The coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) pandemic offers an opportunity for dealing with persistent problems, through a transformative recovery process. It is a crisis that offers opportunities for dealing with three interrelated crises: the ecological crisis (climate change, loss of biodiversity, resource depletion, pollution and ecosystem destruction), the confidence crisis (people losing trust in government, politics, companies, regular news channels, science, each other and the future), and the inequality crisis (the widening of the gap between rich and poor). Our argument is that sustainability transitions will not succeed without a different economy and another social contract with rights and duties of care for the environment and the well-being of others, including future generations. A different social contract is not only desirable from the point of view of sustainability and fairness, and justice and equality, but it is also necessary to restore citizens’ trust in politics, government, companies and each other. In the paper we discuss mechanisms towards a Natural Social Contract: systemic leverage points for system transformations and possibilities for co-evolutionary governance by actor coalitions interested in transformative change. The combination of those three elements helps to synchronize different agendas and reduce the chance that they will work against each other.

1. Introduction

In the EU and many other countries in the world, the need for sustainability transitions and for making the economy more fair and just is widely accepted, but the need for synchronizing the different transitions (characterized by different directionality, knowledge/power constellations and values) is not well-considered. In this paper we argue that a new social contract is needed to serve the various sustainability transitions agendas (the energy transition, food transition and circular economy transition) alongside the socio-economic agenda and the safeguarding of democracy agenda, which is currently undermined by populists or (non-democratic) lobbyists who oppose the climate agenda and the food transition agenda, or even challenge the European rule of law principles (e.g., the challenge by Poland and Hungary).
Each of those agendas constitutes a formidable challenge because they call for transformative change, which is resisted by powerful actors by drawing attention to costs and imperfections of alternatives. A further complication is that sectoral change and change in governance is path-dependent and incapable of transforming itself through volition: “One cannot jump from each branch in the evolutionary tree to each imaginable other branch. Evolutions are marked by dependency” [1]. As an example, “one cannot simply redesign a capitalist democracy, nor any other regime, or any other linkage between economic and political domains [1,2,3].
In this paper, we discuss the need for an alternative social contract and the mechanisms through which this is possible, with special attention to possibilities for co-evolutionary steering of interrelated transitions. This may appear very utopian, but another social contract is already emerging, at various levels and often in a polycentric way, which seeks to counteract environmental degradation and rebalance society [4,5,6,7,8,9,10]. A Natural Social Contract caters to calls for making society more fair, more equal and more sustainable, and is practiced and carried by (prefigurative) practices at various levels, based on values of responsibility that are gradually developed within the hybrid sphere and an alternative economy.
New social contracts do not get collectively chosen, but they evolve out of problem agendas which cause actors to collaborate and introduce policies for transformative change, the details of which are open to adjustment. Social contract formation (or renegotiation) takes places in a polycentric way, tuned to the specific features of local geography, ecology, economies and cultures [8,11,12], and “the result of specific governance evolutions, of the interplay between path dependence, goal dependence and interdependence, and various discursive mechanisms” [1]. A Natural Social Contract is supported by the SDG agenda and Beyond GDP measurement activities by statistical offices and (locally rooted, internationally networked) social-ecological movements, but the transformative nature of change makes it difficult to achieve, even when the goals are backed by powerful agendas and widely shared. Transformative change typically develops in niches, but requires changing circumstances (e.g., in the form of shrinking markets for unsustainable or unhealthy products).
In the past two decades, many scholars have argued that social contracts should be renegotiated due to the societal risks of climate change [4,5,13] and the ongoing ecological crisis (Jennings 2016), in particular given the co-evolving nature of risks and multi-actor influences on change [14]). Some scholars argue that the nature of environmental problems we face today requires new roles for states [15], and more importance for the plural sector [8,16,17], while others stress that future generations are not represented [8]. Other limitations include the influence of non-democratic lobbying activities by powerful players [18], and the often unequal distribution of risks and burdens [8].
Looking ahead, our societies will need to rethink how we inhabit and cultivate our planet and keep it healthy for future generations. This constitutes a huge challenge as the changes needed involve profound, long-term, and systemic changes in society’s common practices, policies, and philosophies that will rely on new knowledge and skills. Four carriers of change are: the creation of new imaginaries (such as the Natural Social Contract and the well-being economy based on an ontology of interconnectedness and the elimination of irresponsible behaviour), coalitions between alternative economy actors and regime actors who find common ground (based on business models of multiple value creation), the SDG agenda and practices of co-evolutionary governance to synchronise different agendas.
The structure of the paper is as follows: In Section 2, we discuss the need for collaborative governance and co-evolutionary steering that is forward-looking, mindful of interaction effects and capable to fostering transformative change (in present-day democracies and polarized societies), initially as an add-on phenomenon (through institutional layering), but after gaining power capable of transforming sectors through policies that undermine the status quo. We also discuss evolutionary governance theory (EGT) as a theory of the intricacies of governance (its poly-centric nature, the power of stories in maintaining order and changing it and the important influence of structural differentiation). EGT holds that “all elements of governance are subject to evolution, they co-evolve, and most of them are the product of governance itself”. Although EGT is mindful of achieving predefined outcomes, it also holds that a governance system that is concerned with its own functioning, with regard to serving multiple agendas, can achieve more in the sense of breaking free from an exploitative economy and sectoral ways of thinking. A growing commitment to a Natural Social Contract (discussed in Section 3), can help to institute stronger policies for destabilising currently dominant regimes [19] while avoiding a backlash in democracy. Interdependencies can be made a source of innovation in governance, by leading certain actor coalitions to work towards institutional change (through institutional work). In Section 4, we present concrete proposals for transition policy for dealing with the following four problems: the sectoral focus of transition policy, the steering power of government, distrustful citizens, and the imperfection of the existing structures. We end the paper with conclusions (in Section 5).

2. Transformation Pleas and Governance Approaches for Achieving This

Many people consider transformative change necessary for dealing with persistent problems in the form of inequality, the exploitative economy and regenerating eco-systems. Prominent proposals are the donut model [20], the economy for the common good [21,22] and A Precariat Chapter [23]. All four proposals are based on principles to be adopted. A different approach is taken in the literature on sustainability transitions [24,25,26,27], by examining the actual mechanisms through which incumbent products and incumbent power will be decreased. Dynamics of adaptation and transformation in sectors are studied from a socio-technical perspective which gives due attention to the practices, aims and networks of (organized) actors in niches, regimes and niche-regimes.
Sustainability transitions research is based on an evolutionary ontology with attention being given to the co-evolution of developments, where co-evolution refers to processes of evolution that are linked with each other. Next to biological co-evolution the following models of co-evolution are being distinguished:
The co-evolution of:
  • Sociosystems and ecosystems [28,29];
  • Supply and demand [30];
  • Technology and users [31,32] (with von Hippel talking about co-dynamics and Leonard-Barton about mutual adaptation);
  • Technology, industry structure and institutions [32,33];
  • Technology and society [24,34,35,36];
  • Industry paths [37];
  • Technical, environmental and social systems [38];
  • Actor/institution configurations and power/knowledge configurations [1];
  • Policy mixes (policy subsystems) and socio-technical systems [39].
The word evolution is used in two ways: as a process of change which is evolving (instead of being implemented or controlled) and a process of change in which variation, retention and selection are important aspects [40]. Co-evolution refers to interlinked evolutionary processes that enjoy an element of autonomy but are also linked in important ways.
Nature does not leap (“natura non facit saltus”) and from the literature on innovation we know that the same is true for technology. Despite phrases of revolutionary technology, technical change is cumulative with occasional discontinuities [41,42]. The interaction of variation and selection gives rise to dominant technologies, designs, fuels, standards, practices and expectations which are not easily abandoned (especially not if the costs of changeover are large).
The view that variation and selection are coupled is nowadays widely shared among innovation scholars. The interaction may give rise to evolutionary patterns, based on variation and selection resulting in trajectories that exercise selective pressures on radical novelties that break away from those trajectories, and which, because of competition from well-developed alternatives, are able to exist and grow in niches, places where selection pressure and resources are congenial to the existence of an innovation [43,44].
Whereas in ecology, regime resilience is viewed in a positive light, to achieve sustainability goals the resilience of environmentally harmful regime practices and technologies acts as a great barrier to sustainable practices. The big question for steering is as follows: how do we initiate and accelerate system changes whose features are not perfectly clear and oftentimes underdeveloped compared to the existing systems?
In this section, we discuss three models for working towards transitions: collaborative governance, evolutionary steering and adaptive governance. All three deal with complexity, normativity and uncertainty in an action-oriented way and have mechanisms of self-correction and adaptation which are needed for achieving fairness in outcomes, avoiding unintended effects in order to remain legitimate and receive continued support from societal stakeholders.
Collaborative governance refers to a mode of interactive governance that is deliberative, multilateral, consensus-seeking and oriented towards joint production of results and solutions [45]. Collaborative governance works with the improvement perspectives of different actors. It often involves (and requires) social innovation in the form of cross-sector partnerships (resulting in new value networks) and new dependencies and roles [46,47]. Examples of collaborative governance are the Markemodel or the Midden-Delflandmodel. In both models, used in the Achterhoek and Midden-Delfland regions in the Netherlands, local authorities work together with the farmers and NGOs to determine on a subnational scale what achievable quality goals are in the field of water quality, biodiversity, ammonia and nitrate emissions, circularity, and agricultural nature management and search for economic mechanisms to make this possible. A system of stacked rewards, including payments for ecosystem services, is part of this. Both models are examples of collaborative governance and steering based on shared values and goals (e.g., by using key performance indicators) instead of more traditional top-down steering focused on measures. A value-based steering model increases the possibilities for multiple value creation and emphasizes interdependence, mutual trust and shared responsibilities.
In models of evolutionary steering, the focus is not so much on collaboration but on altering the dynamics of variation and selection [48]. This can be achieved by nurturing variation and fostering coordination and adaptation of the selection environment through innovation policies and environmental policies. Path dependencies are created in desirable ways through strategic niche management [44] and time-strategic policies [49]. This can be achieved for specific innovations. A more comprehensive policy for changing the dynamics of variation and selection is by setting long-term goals and to co-manage portfolios of options in a forward-looking and adaptive way. Same as collaborative governance, it is based on coalitions of the willing with government agencies and policies offering legitimacy and support. The role for governments is to mobilise actor networks, support research, and innovation activities in promising paths. It offers a framework for policy integration, helping different political actors and ministries to collaborate. Transition management is not conducted by a transition manager but consists of a set of principles informing transition endeavours by partnerships, involving public and private decision makers, NGOs and science [50,51,52].
The choice of official transition paths helps to work on long-term change (in a forward-looking, adaptive manner). This is done for the case of sustainable mobility through questions for innovation agencies and project managers such as:
  • Does the project offer a contribution to a societal problem (challenge)? Which challenge is this?
  • Is it informed by a vision of sustainable mobility? Is it designed to learn about this vision?
  • Is it part of a transition path? If so, what path?
  • Is it oriented towards demonstration or learning? Does it learn about sustainability aspects, markets, how various actors may be enrolled and how the project may be scaled up?
As an innovation support approach, the Dutch transition management model is a sophisticated approach which fits with modern innovation system thinking which says that policy should be concerned with (1) management of interfaces, (2) organizing (innovation) systems, (3) providing a platform for learning and experimenting, (4) providing an infrastructure for strategic intelligence and (5) stimulating demand articulation, strategy and vision development [53]. However, it is also criticised for being technocratic, undemocratic and insufficiently targeted at municipalities, regional authorities and NGOs [54,55].
From the early experiences with transition management (described in [52,56]) and evaluations by [57,58], it has become clear that transition policies have been pursued in a too sectoral way, with too little attention to other agendas, and too weak pressures on (environmentally problematic) regimes. A more integrated approach (aimed at multiple value creation through penta-helix models of innovation) will achieve more in serving multiple agendas. For this, the analytical framework for transformative social-ecological innovation (TSEI) can be used (see Figure 1), which includes attention to institutions, power, output, outcomes and impact. TSEI is defined as ‘systemic changes in established patterns of action as well as in structure, including formal and informal institutions and economies that contribute to sustainability, health, and justice in social-ecological systems’ [8].
Transformative Social-Ecological Innovation (TSEI) refers to innovations with explicit transformative goals and attention to mutual gains. Originating from political sciences, and negotiation theory more in particular, the mutual gains approach (MGA) offers valuable insights for complex multi-party problem solving. It has been successfully used in many negotiations, mainly related to trade, labour, and environmental negotiations [59,60,61], while also applied in citizen engagement, process facilitation, mediation, and conflict resolution [12,62,63], for instance, to mediate in the Israeli–Palestinian water conflict [64].
The mutual gains approach is highly valuable in situations where two or more people are negotiating to reach an agreement that may be of benefit to both or all of them (Consensus Building Institute 2014). In the search for mutual gains, participants are encouraged to explore more ways to create more value (i.e., to increase the pie) and generate a broader vision on sharing benefits. To illustrate, whenever action is taken to remedy environmental problems, the benefits also cascade: for instance, nurturing wildlife and flora in a wetland can also reduce water pollution and soil erosion, and protect crops against storm damage, alleviating water scarcity and allowing for more food production. In other words, working on one aspect of human security (i.e., environmental security in above example) may contribute to other aspects of human security (i.e., water and food security in above example). During mediation in the Israeli–Palestinian water conflict, this aspect of multiple value creation was demonstrated by a multifunctional usage approach, in which the same cubic meter of water is being used by multiple users at different points in time before it flows into the river, thanks to, among other factors, wastewater treatment and water recycling [65]. A central tenet of the MGA-approach is that a vast majority of negotiations in the real world involve parties who have more than one goal or concern in mind and more than one issue that can be addressed in the agreement they reach.
In the case of Rondeel eggs, five functionalities are being combined: animal well-being, compact use of space, the collection of eggs should be labor-extensive, efficient removal of chicken manure, and affordable price for consumers. With the help of design thinking and multi-actor management, the five requirements were all met. Animal well-being had to be determined, which was done on the basis of animal behaviour studies and discussions with environmental groups about animal well-being. The support of animal well-being groups helped to win over support from consumers and the higher retail price for the eggs paid for the extra costs in connection to the newly built system and use of more healthy chicken feed. The eggs are packaged in compostable package material based on potato flour, in an eye-catching design. The eggs are sold directly to a big retailer (AH) where they are part of the AH “pure and fair” product line, in which they are sold for an extra price of 10 cents per egg [45]. The experiences with the Rondeel egg (which was largely publicly funded in terms of design) through a market introduction exclusively at AH supermarkets, have now led to the design by market parties of a completely new Kipster barn system exclusively introduced at LIDL supermarkets. This shows that private parties are often so successful with system-changing innovations because they step in exactly at the moment when the difficult process financed with public funds comes to a breakthrough, as argued by [65].
The outcome in the Rondeel eggs example emerged from a transdisciplinary research project based on reflexive interactive design [65]. RIO is an approach for doing reflexive modernisation “that adopts design of both the technical and social features of societal systems for production and consumption as its central activity and focus of deliberation”. The wide scope of value creation helps to bring a wide range of stakeholders in the project: “The definition of both the problem and the solution takes place in a reciprocal and iterative argumentative exchange between stakeholders including the people and people needed for implementation”. This helps to find radical solutions that are feasible. Benefits for society are safeguarded by NGOs and authorities, who are invited to adopt a cooperative approach. Responsibility is secured via responsiveness (to environmental, social justice and well-being organisations) and design activities of a socio-technical nature. Interdependent activities and practices are made a subject of discussion and negotiation. Because of such elements, it can be expected to achieve more than CSR projects that are taken up as an internal company matter and whose results have been disappointing [66].
For dealing with complexity and uncertainty, adaptive planning and forms of governance aimed at social learning are advocated: “social learning builds upon well-established traditions from participatory development, but puts learning and collective change at the centre of engagement” [67]. Attention to social learning is part of a broad and diverse field of governance studies that propose adaptive governance (e.g., [68,69,70,71,72,73,74,75], reflexive governance (e.g., [52,76,77,78,79,80], and deliberative governance as new pathways to sustainability. These concepts share a focus on addressing ambivalence, complexity, uncertainty, and distributed power in societal change. Beyond attention to social learning, it is desirable to give attention to issues of fairness (in terms of the distribution of benefits, risks and costs), the monitoring of outcomes and policy learning about policy effects and conflict resolution mechanisms. In Huntjens [8], such aspects are referred to as “institutional design principles” (Table 1), relevant for TSEI and aimed at the sustainable management of shared resources (based on [72,81]).
In reality, issues of fairness and anger get expressed in a less deliberative way, via protests and politics. In France, a fuel tax resulted in a revolt by people wearing yellow jerseys. However, it also led to the creation of a citizens’ assembly called “The Citizens Convention for Climate” which produced 149 proposals, many of them with near universal support. Of those proposals, French parliament adopted 40% of the proposals by the convention. The Citizens Convention for Climate did not replace existing forms of governance, but changed the system of pluri-centric governance.
As noted before, governance is subject to evolution, with adaptive, reflexive and deliberative approaches gaining influence. In general, adaptive management and transition management provide a number of important insights for Transformative Social-Ecological Innovation, of which the importance of collective learning processes and social networks for coping with uncertainty and enabling change stands out. Such new approaches are often additional to existing approaches and one challenge for sustainable development is to adjust or replace sectoral approaches which offer a barrier to integrative solutions. Co-evolutionary steering requires attention to interaction effects of different agendas, which helps to avoid negative interaction effects and achieve positive ones. An example of a negative interaction is that between energy transition management and the liberalization of the energy market in the Netherlands, with the second agenda working against the first one [57].
A valuable reflection on governance is provided by evolutionary governance theory [1]. EGT understands governance as radically evolutionary and is mindful of limitations of any form of governance:
All elements of governance are subject to evolution, they co-evolve, and most of them are the product of governance itself. The perspective creates new spaces of analysis and new spaces for and modes of intervention. It also envisions new limitations to intervention. The dichotomy between market and state might dissolve and new variations are likely to occur. Yet, one cannot simply redesign a capitalist democracy, nor any other regime, or any other linkage between economic and political domains [2,3]. One cannot jump from each branch in the evolutionary tree to each imaginable other branch. Evolutions are marked by dependency [1].
EGT considers “everything a product of evolution, both elements and structures, their interaction and the rules of transformation” (p. 9), and holds that actors in a governance path cannot freely change the course of governance because of three dependencies: path dependence, interdependence and goal dependence [1,82]. Path dependence refers to legacies from the past, interdependencies to interdependence between actors and institutions in a governance process, goal dependence is dependence on the future: the influence of shared visions or plans, in the form of ideas of what is needed, desirable and possible.
EGT gives attention to actor/institution dialectics and power/knowledge dialectics and is mindful of the discursive dimension in the transformation and non-transformation of institutions of governance: “governance paths connect sites of narration, of narrative reconstruction, and of discursive migration and transformation”. The discourse dimension includes metaphors, open concepts and master signifiers. An example of a metaphor for connectedness is mycelium. Open concepts are seemingly vague concepts that nevertheless play crucial roles in the reproduction of governance. Examples are sustainability, spatial quality, the knowledge economy and innovation. Open concepts can act as a master signifier: “a signifier of a totality, a wholeness and completeness that cannot exist in reality, but is nevertheless desirable [1,83].
Master signifiers are ideologically charged and give meaning and unity to dispersed actions. They may also fall apart as a result of severe criticisms. The neoliberal view that says that markets and competition are good for society is currently under heavy attack, by those who are anti-capitalism and those who want a capitalism with a human face. However, as the authors of Evolutionary Governance Theory [1] make clear, an alternative cannot be implemented from the outside by collective will but will emerge from processes of co-evolution of actor/institution configurations and power/knowledge configurations.
In policy, the need for sustainability transitions and the need for an alternative economy (one that is more inclusive, fair and environmentally responsible) is accepted but the need for synchronizing the various transitions is not well-considered. Because of this, innovation actors are likely to run up against dominant institutions of modernity: sectoral thinking, a focus on efficiency, sectoral laws and permits, and a reliance on markets and triple helix arrangements for innovation (in which NGOs are absent).
For dealing with problems of pollution, climate change and improving resource efficiency, governments often rely upon the efforts of regime players to contain negative effects through voluntary action and through soft forms of regulation. This usually does not bring much because the root causes behind unsustainability are left intact: the overriding importance to earn profits for shareholders and low prices for consumers.
A few quotes:
The imaginaries of a green economy (UNEP) and green growth (OECD) help governments to do more in terms of supporting green businesses but are bound to result in a slow and gradual greening. The response of the old economy to societal challenges is heavily influenced by old logics, which differ from logics from an alternative economy based on a Natural Social Contract. Alternative economy practices based on transformative social innovation have problems of going to scale. A possible way out is via penta-helix networks. Repurposing capitalism via special partnerships with NGOs and governments can achieve more by aligning individual gains with collective gains. Such an approach is advocated by Henri Mintzberg [84] and by the authors of Accountable [85] in the form of a call for citizenship: citizen buyer, citizen worker, citizen saver and citizen voter. Citizenship is viewed (by those actors and ourselves) as key to making capitalism more responsible. New business models are part of this, but they depend on special partnerships and a facilitating context.
Truly repurposing and re-orienting capitalism depends on institutions that go against exploitation of people and nature. The process of creating those institutions can be taken up in a reformist way but also in a more transformative way under the name of a Natural Social Contract. Social contract theory says that people live together in society in accordance with views on moral and political rules of behaviour, which serve as a point of orientation for stakeholders. It is partly contained in law and policy but not limited to this. Attention to a Natural Social Contract draws attention to negative effects to be avoided and the need for transformative governance: how governance can become more oriented to transformative change. In the next section, such issues will be discussed further.

3. Quest for a New Social Contract

The duties and rights of citizens towards each other and the state constitute a social contract. In this section, we describe and discuss social contract theory and its relevance for the environmental and social agenda.
“The core philosophy of a social contract, as articulated by Aristotle, Hobbes, Rousseau, Locke, Kant, Rawls and other political philosophers, emphasizes an implicit arrangement between citizenry, their respective societies, and legitimate government to create a healthier and safer society together. Social Contract theory states that legitimate, collective governance arrangements should be informed by the consent of the people (Weale, 2004), and this theory, therefore, informs our modern concepts of democracy. The question remains, however, if a social contract focused on individualism, materialism, privatisation, short-termism, the free market, and with a singular focus on economic growth, while paying little attention to social and ecological values, can adequately respond to the challenges of the 21st century. As Albert Einstein said, “we cannot solve our problems with the same thinking we used when we created them”. The fact that ecological vulnerability translates into social and economic vulnerability, and a complex set of security and justice challenges, is an important omission in Social Contract theory, and political theory and economics more in general” [8].
“Nature has had little or no intrinsic value for most (but not all) Social Contract theorists” [14].
“Increasing wealth inequality, financial crises, ecological crisis, climate change, trade wars, migration issues, and even vulnerabilities to the coronavirus pandemic (related to global dependencies and interconnectedness), can be traced back to two common denominators: First, the schism between humans and nature and the dominant anthropocentric worldview that arose during the Enlightenment era. Additionally, second, the capitalist economic logic and in particular the unsustainability of infinite economic growth in a finite world and belief in the infallibility of the free market that arose after the Second World War” [8].
Until recently, it seemed that society and government should serve a well-functioning market economy. This is based on the idea that if the market economy functions well, all layers of society could lead, at least tendential, a meaningful (in terms of work) and liveable (in terms of income) existence. That myth has been debunked by academics [86,87] and the lived experiences of precariat workers (i.e., lacking job security), which increasingly include substantial parts of the former middle class). According to Paul Collier, we are living in a new era, where “capitalism’s core credential of steadily rising living standards for all has been tarnished: it has continued to deliver for some, but has passed others by” [88,89,90].
“Since the 1970s, many Western countries have too easily subscribed to an economic model that if the market arranges it, then it is better and more efficient. However, this has left us with market-based societies characterized by individualism and self-interest, materialism, privatisation, short-termism, and a dogmatic focus on profit and economic growth. The result diminishes social and ecological values and instead prioritizes excessive production, consumption and depletion of our natural resources and raw materials. This decades-long focus has resulted in loss of biodiversity and key ecosystem functions, as well as environmental degradation, and the depletion of natural resources and raw materials. We now experience first-hand that ecological vulnerability translates into economic and social vulnerability, and a complex set of security and justice challenges.” [8].
Looking ahead, our societies will need to rethink how we inhabit and cultivate our planet and keep it healthy for future generations. Making these changes involve profound, long-term, and systemic changes in society’s common practices, policies, institutions and philosophies that will rely on new knowledge and skills, a rebalancing of society which are problem-driven and based on alternative master narratives.
The nature of the societal, environmental, and economic problems we face today requires a new social contract, coined as a Natural Social Contract, as extensively described and substantiated in ‘Towards a Natural Social Contract’ [8]. It concerns a society that is more humane and fairer and above all less destructive to people and nature. ‘A Natural Social Contract does justice to a human being’s natural state (human life is group life) and to the natural position of humankind and society within a larger ecosystem, that of planet Earth. It regards society as a social-ecological system, focusing on people as members of a community and as part of a natural ecosystem. A Natural Social Contract emphasizes long-term sustainability, and general welfare by combining human and nature, and recalibrating while at the same time putting an end to unlimited economic growth, overconsumption and over-individualisation, for the benefit of ourselves, our planet and future generations’ [8]. A Natural Social Contract includes missions for making society more fair, more equal and more sustainable. However, there is a danger that such policies run counter to each other or are perceived in such a way. Sustainability policies meet with resistance from incumbents and populist leaders and may run into opposition from poor and disadvantaged people (who are angry about their own economic prospects and are strongly opposed to measures that affect their income and living standards negatively, as shown by the revolt to a diesel tax in French). Social contract theory helps to recognize duties and rights of citizens and consider issues of rebalancing society, and approaches and mechanisms for achieving this.
The development of a Natural Social Contract is a multifaceted transition process. Thinking about this is still in its infancy. It will involve a different balance between the market, government, and the ‘plural’ sector [84] that is gradually developed via partnerships and institutions of responsibility. The plural sector is home to citizens acting individually and collectively, who can ‘propel’ the processes organized in the public and private sectors towards a constructive social impact, including through citizens’ initiatives and introducing the citizen perspective into those other sectors. It includes not only civil society organizations and activist NGOs, but also, for example, associations, clubs, cooperatives, foundations, religious bodies, social enterprises, volunteers, and citizens’ initiatives. A greater role for the plural sector means that the roles and playing fields of the state, market and citizen are redefined, and therefore also that the citizen will have to define his/her own role in the social transition differently. Accepting social responsibilities (of paying taxes and being a good employer) makes business organizations more hybrid. Collaboration with other parties contributes to this and leads to the formation of a ‘hybrid sphere’ [88,89,90,91] (shown in Figure 2).
The outline of a Natural Social Contract serves as a counter-proposal to existing social contracts. A Natural Social Contract implies an existential change in the way humankind lives in and interacts with its social and natural environment. To navigate this transformation, we will have to find new ways to inhabit and cultivate our planet and keep it healthy for future generations. In this paper, we argue that the social-economic, ecological and political transitions (to fair and decent pay, ecological sound practices, and the safeguarding and deepening of democracy) must be synchronized with each other so that they constructively reinforce and accelerate each other. This synchronization requires transformative governance based on co-evolution across several interrelated dimensions, i.e., social, economic, ecological and institutional dimensions of a social contract. Possible leverage points for a societal transformation towards a Natural Social Contract, through transformative governance based on co-evolution across several interrelated dimensions, have been visualized in Figure 3 below.
Figure 3 shows a compilation of possible systemic leverage points, each of which is difficult to achieve since it involves coordination of a wide range of actors and institutional change. Within each systemic dimension there is a multitude of interconnected heterogeneous components. All issues are getting some attention (by certain government and non-government actors), but the links and need for achieving progress in multiple dimensions are not well-understood and considered. Given that these dimensions are often intertwined in practice, changes or problems in one dimension thus affect all dimensions. Finding leverage points alone is not enough; systemic change also requires good insight into the interrelationships and how the desired outcome can be achieved with maximum synergy effects and minimal ‘trade-offs’. The connections between the dimensions must enable permanent coevolution, when working on transformative change. This explains, among others, why major societal transformations take on average about 30 years, which is also a realistic timespan for some of the fundamental systemic changes required for a Natural Social Contract [8].
The goals and leverage points themselves (in Figure 3) are not controversial; many people will consider them lofty and desirable, but making progress along those lines in a co-evolutionary way is difficult and often an uphill battle. Figure 4 shows “The Transition Flower” as a tool for supporting co-evolutionary governance through connecting actor-coalitions and interdependent systemic leverage points. In particular, this tool could be used as a systemic tool for agenda-setting during a TSEI-process as shown in Figure 1. The transition path in question is always context-specific, path-dependent and goal-dependent. A transition path is the form that a transition takes as a result of coordinated and uncoordinated actions, changing circumstances and interaction effects with other change processes (especially institutional change occurring outside the transition). As a context-dependent, goal-dependent, path-dependent generative process, a transition path will differ with respect to the degree in which it is planned and goal-oriented.
An example of such an application for a specific transition path is provided in Figure 5, detailing possible leverage points and key variables for the transition to nature-inclusive agriculture in the Netherlands (based on [82]). The transition path to nature-inclusive agriculture is part of the transition towards a sustainable food production system, which itself is part of a larger transformation in the food system as a whole, which includes the transition to sustainable and fair supply chains and sustainable and healthy food consumption). By taking such a broad, systemic perspective, another important advantage becomes clear when using the Transition Flower in practice. It is not only a tool for identifying options for co-evolutionary steering, but also a tool for supporting multiple value creation, in particular when parties are stuck in zero-sum thinking and fighting for the same piece of cake. The Transition Flower shows that more perspectives and interests can be served by enlarging the pie. In the example of Nature-inclusive agriculture a mutual gains approach is visible in multifunctional land use where various public and private interests are served by the same piece of land, i.e., when farmers in addition to sustainable food production work on short food supply chains, better soil and water quality, animal welfare, biodiversity restoration and/or increasing water retention capacity; it also serves (additional) interests of local authorities, environmental NGOs and the wider public by providing ecosystem services. In return, these parties become (more) willing to pay the farmers for the ecosystem services they facilitate, e.g., through a system of stacked rewards for the farmers. Adopting a whole-of-systems approach helps recognize synergies and trade-offs, moving beyond linear forms of production and consumption, towards more circular, inclusive systems (SAPEA 2020). ‘Systems thinking is about seeing life in motion, recognizing that the big picture is rarely static, but almost always a web of factors that interact to create patterns and change over time’ [90]. Complexity is increased due to attention to interdependence with other agendas (e.g., on water, energy, spatial planning, housing), but it helps to work on those agendas in new ways. An interesting observation by [81] is that clear differences emerge between the scale levels (i.e., local, subnational, national and international level). For example, where more key variables can be found in the economic dimension at company level, this picture is different at subnational level, where fewer key variables can be found in the economic dimension, while there are more key variables in the social, ecological and institutional dimensions. This means that an actionable agenda per dimension, and between dimensions, may differ depending on the scale level at which action is taken (ibid).
The case of climate change mitigation is a good example of the difficulties of altering the course of development, and an illustration of a policy instruments journey. If we use the Kyoto protocol of 1997 as a starting point, we have 24 years of climate policies. In those 24 years, big energy users have been able to defer strong policies against fossil fuel use. In the European Union, energy users were able to make money from the emission trading system in carbon emission rights (estimated at 30 to 50 billion euros). (https://www.nrc.nl/nieuws/2021/06/07/onderzoek-industrie-maakte-winst-op-gratis-co2-uitstootrechten-a4046363; see also https://www.groene.nl/) (accessed on 21 September 2021). Over the last two years, thanks to a number of policy changes, the price of a carbon right has been rising to EUR 30 per ton in Dec 2020 and further up to EURO 73 per ton on 25 November 2021. The prospect of high carbon prices and COPs in the wake of the Paris Agreement tells the financial industry that fossil fuels are a possible liability and telling electricity producers that their future is not in fossil fuels. In 2021, the announcement of the new IPPC report (after a summer of flooding in Europe and drought-related fires in America and Asia) silenced climate deniers and boosted the view that quick and drastic action is needed. Governments are also accepting the need to reform the labour market and deal with poverty and provide social care in different ways. In addition, the 2008 global credit crisis and the COVID-19 pandemic (since March 2020) have highlighted the painful vulnerabilities of today’s world and the need for fundamental change in the form of a more sustainable, healthy and just society.
Hence, a crucial issue is as follows: through what generative mechanisms can a transition to a Natural Social Contract occur given: (i) the orientation to a for-profit market economy and interests in its continuation, (ii) political parties who are unwilling to find common ground (because of ideological differences and desires for dominating others), (iii) the evolutionary nature of change and distributed nature of power?
Whereas the obstacles to transformative change are formidable, we think that the following factors contribute to a shift to a Natural Social Contract: (i) the inability of the exploitative economy to cater to equality and environmental responsibility in a big way, (ii) the growing dissatisfaction with exploitative modes of production, (iii) the creation of new imaginaries and the creation of an alternative economy based on values of responsibility, mutual care and human flourishing, (iv) growing attention in each of these transitions to issues of justice, social learning, co-creation and collective action from a systemic perspective, acting as stepping stone for further change, including the institutionalization of transformative change and the co-evolutionary governance aspects (discussed in the previous section). Each of these developments will cause governance to change, through the actions of coalitions for transformative change.
Governance that does not have transformative goals will achieve little in this regard, obviously. However, we are now seeing the formulation of transformative goals for sectors and the economy by policy actors and elites. Towards this aim, a number of steering approaches have been developed, such as transition management, adaptive planning and co-evolutionary governance. The recognition of a Natural Social Contract and the need for changing economic institutions can be expected to make more progress to transforming sectors and the economy. A change to a Natural Social Contract comes down to a transformative process in the sense of a transition from the existing economy (with instances of sustainability) to a well-being economy where the concern for people and nature is a central concern for business, consumers, government and science who are all devoted to this in some way. The European Green Deal and the Building back better approach of the Biden administration in the have transformative elements but they are relatively weak. Making transformative change more pronounced over time, requires a reconsideration of basic economic institutions and social institutions with which the economy is connected.
Calls for a citizen capitalism and rebalancing society are attempts to consider the link between economy and society, but they fall short in terms of explaining how an economy oriented to well-being differs from a neoliberal economy. In an attempt to explore this better, Table 2 puts the well-being economy based on a Natural Social Contract next to the existing economy, with respect to the overarching goal of the social contracts on which they are based, the hegemonic worldview, the role for individualism, the development paradigm, core policy concerns, response to climate change, innovation models, basis for social relations, vision of society, and view on of the natural environment.
Several of the institutions for an “economy for the common good” (as a new type of economy based on human flourishing and environmental stewardship) already exist, but they are insufficiently recognised as transformative and as viable/attractive alternatives, which restricts their growth. The big question is how to get rid of the old economy or how to transform it. Achieving this transition is beyond the ability of everyday politics and business, but it can be made a joint concern in the same way as the SDGs are a joint concern. In the literature on sustainability transitions, policy mixes are advocated as the way to foster transitions [91,92]. Policy mixes should go beyond the stimulation of alternatives in niches but also include policies of control and the phasing out of fossil fuels. Thus far, policies of control have been weak, but the Paris accord and EU ambitions about climate mitigation and sustainable agriculture have made clear that more is needed in terms of the discouragement and discontinuation of fossil fuel technologies and unsustainable agricultural practices. More control may come from international obligations but also from the creation of a Natural Social Contract which aligns the energy transition with goals of making the economy more circular, social and fair.
In the transitions literature, too little attention is given to the need for a different social contract and the importance of social innovation for creating a more responsible, inclusive society and economy. Social innovation (based on self-organisation) defies instrumentation by government and is unsuited for a measurement and management approach. In the Technology Innovation System literature and most of the transition literature, social innovation is primarily studied in relation to technological innovation (not as a focal phenomenon itself). In so doing, important aspects of change (those having to do with ethics, government responsibilities, trust, and procedural and distributional justice) are backgrounded. For this reason, ref. [1] introduced the concept of Transformative Social-Ecological Innovation (TSEI), which is defined as “systemic changes in established patterns of action and in structure, including formal and informal institutions and economies, that contribute to sustainability, health and justice in all social-ecological systems” (ibid, page 86).
TSEI requires special programmes and partnerships (with involvement of science, NGOs, government people and institutions). Intermediation is likely to be needed to align and modulate the different views and logics [46]. Knowledge tools which make decisions of collaboration transparent and decidable are very useful for the managerial governance of collaborative projects, but insufficient for achieving external institutional change. Since system innovation requires changes in the orientation and practices of actors and changes in (sector-specific) rule systems (and perhaps even in meta-governance), an important question is how to deal with the external institutional context which is in need of change. Doing an institutional analysis is not enough. The crux for achieving institutional change via institutional work lies in involving institutional actors (regional authorities, NGOs and standard-setting bodies) in projects of change and in deliberations about institutional barriers, to enrol them in such processes and to make them think about (necessary and achievable) enabling conditions. This is especially important for projects that have to deal with the institutional frameworks of two sectors (for example, energy and waste) and that aim to create value for society next to value for the actors involved. A co-evolutionary perspective is useful for this, through the attention for interaction effects. Coordination is needed on two fronts, that of socio-technical agency and (external) institutional structure. The first concerns the development of novel practices in a partnership for innovation, the second is about achieving structural change in a coordinated. Bos and Grin (2012) [64] coined the term ‘Dual Track governance’ for the coordination of distributed agency of actors in activities that are also focused on structural change. Dual Track governance is part of what we call co-evolutionary governance. Co-evolutionary governance is a form of governance that is explicitly concerned with the co-evolution, through the use of integrated thinking, cross-sectoral partnership and attention to macro-issues next to meso-issues. The SDG agenda is a macro institution, championed by the UN. Without meso-institutions and momentous developments it will achieve very little. An NSC can be expected to gain power because of the need for structural change to deal with persistent problems. It will take different forms and will be pursued under different names: just transition, a more inclusive economy, the economy of the common good, economic development within planetary boundaries and the donut economy.
One of the greatest challenges for an NSC and a wellbeing economy (based on the institutions in Table 2) is the creation of policies that destabilise dominant (socio-technical) regimes [19], because such policies meet with resistance from incumbents (which is a big enough barrier), but another formidable barrier is the power of populist parties who are anti-elite and wish to discredit transition agendas as statist, anti-democratic and totally against the interests of “the people”. This is why we attest such strong importance to the hybrid sphere [17,89], as an open space for social innovation and transformative socio-ecological innovation. The hybrid sphere may encourage companies to abandon existing logics with the help of partnerships that hold them to higher standards and customers and workers willing to buy goods and work in companies that are more ethical and more oriented to their well-being as workers. The articulation of models for a more responsible economy by intellectuals and social movement leaders make such an economy more salient and compelling. However, ultimately there have to be economic benefits for companies and consumers in a more responsible economy [45]. This cannot be engineered from the top but will emerge in a bottom-up manner, guided by visions of a better world and partnerships for this (which means that it is a multi-level process). This is a huge challenge for a world in which getting rich is an important aim. However, the realization that this is not possible for all and comes at a great cost may encourage and sustain collective efforts. There is a recursive relation between citizen capitalism and a Natural Social Contract: they support each other. Thus far, citizen capitalism is not an important point of orientation. Attention to a Natural Social Contract (about obligations and wishes to create a better world) may make a different economy a goal for society. The recommendations of Mintzberg [84] about rebalancing society, those of O‘Leary and Valdmanis [83] about citizen capitalism, and the recommendations of Ostrom [93] and Raworth [21] about the commons and regenerative economy can act as foundational elements.
In our vision, the hybrid sphere based on citizenship plays an important role. The expansion and deepening of this, helps to find do-able projects and engage in dual track governance. It consists of a pluralistic endeavour based on different concepts and shaped by different circumstances. This fits with EGT, which contends that governance is always multi-level governance, with each path of governance always embedded in other paths and slow evolutions incorporating faster evolutions. Recognition of this could help to create institutions that promote integrated thinking and transformative social-ecological innovation and foster institutional work that is oriented at the replacement and adjustment of existing institutions next to the creation of new ones [94,95].
The process of change towards a well-being economy is partly ideologically driven (based on lofty ideals) but also is problem-driven. The interaction of different (transition) agendas in a world that is functionally differentiated creates problems for each of the agendas. A fuel tax (and speed limit) caused a revolt in France and in the Netherlands the top-down implementation of renewable energy is leading to local opposition. The problems can be addressed in a reactive manner, and they can be addressed through Dual Track Governance and institutional change at higher levels. In Dutch physical planning, the sectoral planning system is replaced by an integral planning system (Omgevingswet) which facilitates integrated thinking and collective action from stakeholders (which are needed for a well-being economy), but requires a good deal of collaborative governance and tools for integrated decision making. A Natural Social Contract may foster collaboration with actors and changes in governance (in and around projects of change and beyond these) but the governance system will remain complex and geared against many changes. However, the non-disappearance of sustainability problems and continuous demand for deeper democracy and justice will foster change in governance and a social contract. Backlashes in democracy are happening and can be expected to occur in the future, but there is also the growth of a new consciousness about human responsibility and tools for multiple value creation. Two examples of such tools are the boundary work of [96] for cross-sectoral cooperation and Theory U, an awareness-based social change methodology called Presencing [97,98,99] both of which are developed for making business more purposeful with the help of business models for sustainability.

4. Four Proposals for Transition Policy

In this section, we address four problems with transition policy and policy more generally: the sectoral focus of transition policy, the weak steering power of government, distrustful citizens, and the need for changing socio-economic structures (as an important issue for politics and society). For those problems we offer suggestions based on co-evolutionary governance.
  • Transition policy is often too sectoral, so that it does not take sufficient advantage of other agendas. Dutch policy between 2001 and 2009 was judged to be inconsistent [56] and not very democratic [53]). Attention to the contradictions between various agendas (sustainability, liberalization and democracy) helps to achieve better results, with the help of interministerial coordination, evaluative research into policy interaction effects [100] and integrated approaches for regional development based on multiple value creation (such as the Markemodel or Midden-Delflandmodel).
  • Choices of instruments, direction and implementation matters receive too little attention. The Netherlands has high policy ambitions about a circular economy. Provinces have a circular agenda, but there is little power and money behind it. There are five ‘transition agendas’ and agreements such as the Plastic Pact and the Concrete Agreement, but voluntary action is paramount. Current innovation policies and mission-driven agendas are illustrative of the old-fashioned and blind belief that everything can be solved by stimulating technology, and therefore do not provide a sufficient basis for social innovation. A positive example is this regard is the Integrated Circular Economy Report (ICER), which provides an overview of the state of play of the transition to a circular economy in the Netherlands. The report describes actions by social parties and provides guidelines for government policy. As noted by EGT and transition management scholars, transition endeavours have to be institutionalized (via laws, agencies responsible for monitoring and evaluation) and should go beyond a push strategy by giving attention to strategic uncertainty, complex mutual dependence and a polyarchic power distribution in which partial interests have de facto veto power.
  • Too little attention is paid to the unrest that transitions entail. Many voters do not like the unrest inherent in transitions. Marc Oosterhout says that “Voters don’t like change; they are conservative by nature. They are for safety and security. You see this, for example, with technological innovations. They only succeed if innovations are in line with recognizable routines. Of course, you can change people and move them to new behavior, but that almost always goes through the way of certainty and trust.” (https://www.volkskrant.nl/columns-opinie/opinie-de-kiezer-houdt-niet-van-verandering-dus-moet-links-juist-vertrouwen-bieden~b2bfef86/) (accessed on 14 March 2021) A commitment to a just transition helps to win support and pre-empt resistance. This can be achieved through projects of co-creation and (de facto) regulations that the benefits of renewable energy projects (solar panels and wind turbines on farmers land) are distributed fairly. However, even that may not be enough to take away feelings of anxiety. According to research by Kennedy and Givens [101]: “participants in higher social classes experience environmental concern in a way that is consistent with a broader sense of competency and control to positively shape the world around them, including the natural environment”, whereas “those in lower social classes experienced environmental concern in a way consistent with their broader sense of lacking power to influence their surroundings”. This shows that there are also limits to an anxiety-reducing approach.
  • More attention is needed for the adaptation of structures. Sustainable development can never be achieved through technology alone. Structures need to be overhauled [66], all innovation and transition researchers agree on this, but little is done with this insight. The triple helix model (cooperation between governments, knowledge institutions and companies for (open) innovation) works excellently for high-tech innovations but is not a good model for sustainability transitions [45], because it makes little or no use of civil society organizations and citizens, who are active in the hybrid sphere. Involvement of civil society organizations ensures that moderately sustainable options (such as biomass for energy production) are identified as such and that the capacity for change of civil organizations is used. Stimulating interdisciplinary research ensures that social science knowledge is used more and better.
The above recommendations not only aid sustainability but also contribute to a Natural Social Contract (NSC). The focus on multiple value creation helps companies and other organizations do things that are in accordance with elements of a Natural Social Contract and contribute to a further articulation and realization of an NSC (or elements thereof). Problems associated with managed change are taken up more proactively and adaptively.

5. Conclusions

In this paper, we discussed possibilities for achieving transformative change via co-evolutionary governance (forms of governance that are mindful of interaction effects and work simultaneously on agency and structure). Our argument is that sustainability transitions (in the energy system, agriculture and in making the economy more circular) will not succeed without a different economy and another social contract: a different alliance between citizens, society, economy and government, with the associated rights and duties of care (for the environment and the well-being of others, including future generations). A different social contract is not only desirable from the point of view of sustainability and fairness, justice and equality, but is also necessary to restore citizens’ trust in politics, government, companies and each other. Drawing on evolutionary governance theory, which says that governance is poly-centric and path-dependent, and insights from innovation/transition studies about systemic change (which is mindful of the recursive elements in stability and change), we discussed mechanisms towards a Natural Social Contract and offered recommendations for transition policy.
The paper is motivated by our observation that the sustainability transitions in many countries are running into difficulties: the energy transition is slow due to the high costs of replacing fossil-based industry and households, the transition to sustainable agri-food system, meets great resistance from angry farmers (who feel unduly blamed for environmental problems), and the transition to a circular economy mainly consists of recycling. The sustainability transitions suffer from “consumer capitalism” (driven by financial capitalism) that allows cost shifting; inequality means that the weak will suffer rather than benefit from energy transition policy unless they are explicitly considered; network control favours regime players, and social innovation is mainly seen as a means and not as a valuable goal. We argue that the challenges related to sustainability transitions and social transitions should be considered more in relation to each other, and that each of these transitions should focus on social learning, co-creation and collective/connective action from a systemic perspective, with specific attention to multiple value creation, social and environmental stewardship, inclusivity and social justice, ultimately aimed at realizing broad welfare and prosperity for the benefit of ourselves, our planet and future generations.
Although a Natural Social Contract offers a narrative of change on collective issues, in the form of a plea for the synchronization and co-evolution of the sustainability transition and social transitions, it can clash with the urge in politics to emphasize differences for the sake of identity and power. Hence, overcoming this dichotomy requires parties in politics and society that can rise above their differences and place more emphasis on similarities and finding common ground, for example by exploring and highlighting shared values and looking for opportunities for multiple value creation and connective action (such as the Markemodel or Midden-Delflandmodel). By doing so, the attention will shift to interdependence, mutual trust and shared responsibilities. This makes it easier for parties to arrive at a narrative of change on collective issues, one that brings people together. A narrative of change on collective issues is dependent on the values underlying people’s perspectives on what the goals of a transition should be (e.g., see [100] on a values-based approach to climate change adaptation). Therefore, a value-driven ‘whole-of-systems’ transition approach should be explicit about these underlying values, which could be differentiated in system values (e.g., driving the way a food system or economic system works), intrinsic values (e.g., nature, animals, biodiversity and ecosystems have value in their own right, independent of human uses), personal values that steer our individual behavior, and societal values that show what a society finds important. Finding a common value base and the use of attractive imaginaries for innovation and development and the macro-concepts of a well-being economy and citizen capitalism offer opportunities to steer the system in the desired direction, through co-evolutionary steering, a form of steering which takes into account positive and negative interaction effects (through partnerships and less sectorial ways of thinking).
Mutual gains can be sought through agency but also through institutions for this. Various approaches that provide useful insights for this, such as shared value creation [101], integrated value creation [102], mutual gains approach [59,60,61,103]), multiple value creation [17], and co-creation [8]. In the search for mutual gains, participants are encouraged to explore more ways to create more value (i.e., to increase the pie) and generate a broader vision on sharing benefits [8,99,104,105,106] in ways that contribute to institutional change. Attention to a Natural Social Contract helps to institute structural change through formal and informal institutions.
Attention to the systemic leverage points for a transformation towards a Natural Social Contract is necessary for inserting responsibility and integrated thinking in existing forms of governance. The transition to a just society in which sustainability, dignity, well-being, and prosperity is certainly not an easy and peaceful process (although its desirability is widely shared). However, the persistence of problems will encourage regime players to become part of the solution, when external circumstances impel this (as is happening in the energy transition now and to a lesser extent in agriculture and the circularity of the economy).
Both the EU and US have programmes for green recovery which have transformative elements, but which may restore the old economy unless transformative change is actively supported [101]. As such, COVID-19 is not a ‘game changer’ but a crisis that, together with the political crisis (of citizens losing trust in government and the political system), can be used to restore confidence in politics, government, and companies. In our view, there is an alternative to the neoliberal economy, which partly already exists, in the form of cooperatives, Teal companies, purpose-driven leadership and a greater orientation of investors towards social value creation. Another social contract is emerging, but this emergence can be enhanced by making it an explicit goal for societal development, because it serves multiple agendas: the ecological agenda, social agenda and restoring confidence agenda (which is about regaining trust in government, science and business)
The need for change is paramount. We need a more inclusive economy, with better pay and working conditions for workers, and access to health care services. Ecosystem protection and regeneration is needed for avoiding a resource crisis and for enhancing the well-being of those who live now. There is a big chance that the multi-trillion euro investment programmes for restoring the economy will simply restore the old economy. This is why attention to a Natural Social Contract is so important (next to the formulation of concrete policies and institutional reforms). Transition policy based on co-evolutionary governance can contribute to transformative change, via mechanisms identified in this paper, but such efforts meet with lots of problems, notably the power of incumbents and sectoral ways of thinking. The exploitative economy will continue to exist (within every conceivable time frame), but the grip it has on government, science, consumers, workers and the financial system is bound to decline, through the rise of an economy that caters to demands for responsible action and human thriving. The transformation of society into a market society [107,108] was a long-term transformation process, the same is true for making societies more fair, inclusive and less disruptive to nature and human beings. The task of achieving this cannot be postponed and is best taken up in a proactive, evolutionary manner to create transformative change in an experiential (time-honoured) way, by testing ideas of progress and alternative economies.
Our ideas of co-evolutionary governance are based on the assumption that a Natural Social Contract is needed and that attention to interaction effects between different agendas for sustainability and those for reducing inequality and deepening democracy will lead to better outcomes through more reflexive, collaborative and adaptive forward-looking forms of steering which deal with the social and ecological agenda and in so doing also deal with the confidence crisis (by synchronising the different agendas). This paper is partly a manifesto, in the form of a call for the creation of a Natural Social Contract and for transformation-oriented forms of governance, but the governance approaches advocated have been tried and tested, and subjected to evaluation that yielded insights for future use. We are not denying that every governance approach is subject to limitations and acceptance [1,109,110], but the focus of this paper is on forms of governance that are concerned with dynamics and interaction effects through a broad scoped mutual gains approach which is forward-looking, yet adaptive. The systemic leverage points for transformation offered can be used for achieving change through questions about interdependencies which can be utilised by actor coalitions interested in transformative change through sustainability transitions which are not unduly sectoral but also pay attention to issues of just transition, resilience and the overarching goal of instituting a Natural Social Contract. Achieving this requires and involves a rebalancing of society and new imaginaries (as master signifiers), such as the well-being economy and a Natural Social Contract.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization of NSC, P.H., discussion of co-evolutionary governance, R.K. and P.H.; methodology, P.H. and R.K.; writing—original draft preparation plus review and editing, P.H. and R.K.; visualization, P.H. and R.K. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was part-funded by Platform31. Earlier work on the conceptual development of NSC and TSEI [7,8] was funded by the Netherlands Ministry of Economic Affairs and Climate, as part of the ‘Impact Programme: Transition in the green sector’.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

We acknowledge the influence of Ger Jonkergouw in discussions about the topic of this paper, which sparked [17] and this paper. The authors are grateful to the guest editor and reviewers for providing excellent comments which helped us to improve the paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Van Assche, K.; Beunen, R.; Duineveld, M. Evolutionary Governance Theory: An Introduction; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2014; p. 5. [Google Scholar]
  2. Allina-Pisano, J. Post Soviet Potemkin Villages. Politics and Property Rights in the Black Earth; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  3. Verdery, K. The Vanishing Hectare: Property and Value in Postsocialist Transylvania; Cornell University Press: Ithaca, NY, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  4. O’Brien, K.; Hayward, B.; Berkes, F. Rethinking Social Contracts: Building Resilience in a Changing Climate. Ecol. Soc. 2009, 14, 12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Schellnhuber, H.J.; Messner, D.; Leggewie, C.; Leinfelder, R.; Nakicenovic, N.; Rahmstorf, S.; Schlacke, S.; Schmidt, J.; Schubert, R. World in Transition: A Social Contract for Sustainability; Flagship Report; WBGU: Berlin, Germany, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  6. Jennings, B. Ecological Governance: Toward a New Social Contract with the Earth; West Virginia University Press: Morgantown, WV, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  7. Huntjens, P. Sociale Innovatie voor een Duurzame Samenleving: Op weg naar een Natuurlijk Sociaal Contract; Lectorale boek, IMPACT Lectoraat Sociale Innovatie in het Groene Domein; Hogeschool Inholland: Delft, The Netherlands, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  8. Huntjens, P. Towards a Natural Social Contract: Transformative Social-Ecological Innovation for a Sustainable, Healthy and Just Society, 1st ed.; Springer Nature: Cham, Switzerland, 2021; ISBN 978-3-030-67129-7. [Google Scholar]
  9. Omtzigt, P.H. Een Nieuw Sociaal Contract; Prometheus: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  10. Shafik, M. What We Owe Each Other; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  11. Ostrom, E. Understanding Institutional Diversity; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  12. Huntjens, P.; Lebel, L.; Pahl-Wostl, C.; Camkin, J.; Schulze, R.; Kranz, N. Institutional design propositions for the governance of adaptation to climate change in the water sector. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2012, 22, 67–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Adger, W.N.; Quinn, T.; Lorenzoni, I.; Murphy, C.; Sweeney, J. Changing social contracts in climate-change adaptation. Nat. Clim. Chang. 2012, 3, 330–333. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. O’Brien, K. Global environmental change II: From adaptation to deliberate transformation. Prog. Hum. Geogr. 2012, 36, 667–676. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Dryzek, J.S.; Hunold, C.; Schlosberg, D.; Downes, D.; Hernes, H.-K. Environmental Transformation of the State: The USA, Norway, Germany and the UK. Political Stud. 2002, 50, 659–682. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Mintzberg, H. Time for the Plural Sector, Stanford Social Innovation Review. 2015. Available online: https://ssir.org/articles/entry/time_for_the_plural_sector (accessed on 25 November 2021).
  17. Kemp, R.; Huntjens, P.; Jonkergouw, G. Transitiebeleid na Corona: Het Belang van een Natuurlijk Sociaal Contract’. Coronapapers. 2 July 2021. Available online: https://coronapapers.nl/nieuws-1/nieuws/transitiebeleid-na-corona-het-belang-van-een-natuurlijk-sociaal-contract (accessed on 12 October 2021).
  18. Weale, A. Contractarian theory, deliberative democracy and general agreement. In Justice and Democracy: Essays for Brian Barry; Dowding, K., Goodin, R., Pateman, C., Barry, B., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2004; pp. 79–96. [Google Scholar]
  19. Kivimaa, P.; Kern, F. Creative destruction or mere niche support? Innovation policy mixes for sustainability transitions. Res. Policy 2016, 45, 205–217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Raworth, K. Doughnut Economics. Seven Ways to Think Like a 21-Century Economist; Random House Business: London, UK, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  21. Felber, C. Change Everything. Creating an Economy for the Common Good; Bloomsbury Publishing: London, UK, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  22. Mason, P. Post-Capitalism. A Guide to Our Future; Allen Lane: London, UK, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  23. Standing, G. A Precariat Chapter. From Denizens to Citizens; Bloomsbury Academic: London, UK, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  24. Geels, F. Processes and patterns in transitions and system innovations: Refining the co-evolutionary multi-level perspective. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2005, 72, 681–696. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Geels, F.W.; Schot, J. Typology of sociotechnical transition pathways. Res. Policy 2007, 36, 399–417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Grin, J.; Rotmans, J.; Schot, J. Transitions to Sustainable Development; Routledge: London, UK, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  27. Rosenbloom, D.; Meadowcroft, J.; Cashore, B. Stability and climate policy? Harnessing insights on path dependence, policy feedback, and transition pathways. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2018, 50, 168–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Norgaard, R.B. Coevolutionary Development Potential. Land Econ. 1984, 60, 160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Norgaard, R. Development Betrayed: The End of Progress and a Co-Evolutionary Revisioning of the Future; Routledge: London, UK, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  30. Nelson, R.R. The Co-evolution of Technology, Industrial Structure, and Supporting Institutions. Ind. Corp. Chang. 1994, 3, 47–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Von Hippel, E. The Sources of Innovation; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1988. [Google Scholar]
  32. Leonard-Barton, D. Implementation as Mutual Adaptation of Technology and Organisation. Res. Policy 1988, 17, 251–267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Rosenkopf, L.; Tushman, M. The Coevolution of Technology and Organization. In Evolutionary Dynamics of Organizations; Baum, J., Singh, J., Eds.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1994; pp. 403–424. [Google Scholar]
  34. Rip, A.; Kemp, R. Technological Change. In Human Choice and Climate Change; Rayner, S., Malone, L., Eds.; Resources and Technology; Batelle Press: Washington, DC, USA, 1998; Volume 2, pp. 327–399. [Google Scholar]
  35. Van de Ven, A.H.; Garud, R. The Co-evolution of Technical and Institutional Events in the Development of an Innovation. In Evolutionary Dynamics of Organizations; Baum, J.A., Singh, J.V., Eds.; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 1994; pp. 425–443. [Google Scholar]
  36. Von Tunzelmann, N. Historical Coevolution of Governance and Technology in the Industrial Revolutions. Struct. Chang. Econ. Dyn. 2003, 14, 365–384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Aarset, B.; Jakobsen, S.-E. Path dependency, institutionalization and co-evolution: The missing diffusion of the blue revolution in Norwegian aquaculture. J. Rural. Stud. 2015, 41, 37–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  38. Kemp, R.; Rotmans, J. The management of the co-evolution of technical, environmental and social systems. In Towards Environmental Innovation Systems; Weber, M., Hemmelskamp, J., Eds.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2005; pp. 33–55. [Google Scholar]
  39. Edmondson, D.L.; Kern, F.; Rogge, K.S. The co-evolution of policy mixes and socio-technical systems: Towards a conceptual framework of policy mix feedback in sustainability transitions. Res. Policy 2018, 48, 103555. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Kemp, R.; Turkeli, S. Sustainable Development as Redirected Evolution. Insights from Innovation Studies and Ecological Humanities. In Cultures and Local Practices of Sustainability; Valdivieso, G., Casals, A., Vélez, A.E.B., Eds.; UPB: Medellín, Colombia, 2021; Available online: https://repository.upb.edu.co/handle/20.500.11912/9748 (accessed on 25 October 2021).
  41. Basalla, G. The Evolution of Technology; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1988. [Google Scholar]
  42. Ziman, J. (Ed.) Technological Innovation as an Evolutionary Process; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  43. Schot, J. The Usefulness of Evolutionary Models for Explaining Innovation. The Case of the Netherlands in the Nineteenth Century. Hist. Technol. 1998, 14, 173–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Kemp, R.; Schot, J.; Hoogma, R. Regime Shifts to Sustainability through Processes of Niche Formation. The Approach of Strategic Niche Management. Technol. Anal. Strateg. Manag. 1998, 10, 175–195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Ansell, C.; Gash, A. Collaborative Governance in Theory and Practice. J. Public Adm. Res. Theory 2008, 18, 543–571. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  46. Diepenmaat, H.; Kemp, R.; Velter, M. Why Sustainable Development Requires Societal Innovation and Cannot Be Achieved without This. Sustainability 2020, 12, 1270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  47. Velter, M.; Bitzer, V.; Bocken, N.; Kemp, R. Sustainable business model innovation: The role of boundary work for multi-stakeholder alignment. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 247, 119497. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Nill, J.; Kemp, R. Evolutionary Approaches for Sustainable Innovation policies: From niche to paradigm? Res. Policy 2009, 38, 668–680. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Sartorius, C.; Zundel, S. (Eds.) Time Strategies, Innovation and Environmental Policy; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  50. Rotmans, J.; Kemp, R.; van Asselt, M. More evolution than revolution: Transition management in public policy. Foresight 2001, 3, 15–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Kemp, R.; Loorbach, D.; Rotmans, J. Transition management as a model for managing processes of co-evolution towards sustainable development. Int. J. Sustain. Dev. World Ecol. 2007, 14, 78–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  52. Kemp, R. The Dutch energy transition approach. Int. Econ. Econ. Policy 2010, 7, 291–316. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Smits, R.; Kuhlmann, S. The rise of systemic instruments in innovation policy. Int. J. Foresight Innov. Policy 2004, 1, 4–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Hendriks, C.M.; Grin, J. Contextualizing Reflexive Governance: The Politics of Dutch Transitions to Sustainability. J. Environ. Policy Plan. 2007, 9, 333–350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Voß, J.-P.; Smith, A.; Grin, J. Designing long-term policy: Rethinking transition management. Policy Sci. 2009, 42, 275–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Van der Loo, F.; Loorbach, D. The Dutch Energy Transition Project (2000–2009). In Governing the Energy Transition. Reality, Illusion or Necessity? Verbong, G., Loorbach, D., Eds.; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  57. Kern, F.; Howlett, M. Implementing transition management as policy reforms: A case study of the Dutch energy sector. Policy Sci. 2009, 42, 391–408. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Smith, A.; Kern, F. The transitions storyline in Dutch environmental policy. Environ. Politics 2009, 18, 78–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Susskind, L.; Field, P. Dealing with an Angry Public: The Mutual Gains Approach to Resolving Disputes; Simon and Schuster: New York, NY, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  60. Rodríguez-Carvajal, R.; Moreno-Jiménez, B.; de Rivas-Hermosilla, S.; Álvarez-Bejarano, A.; Vergel, A.I.S. Positive psychology at work: Mutual gains for individuals and organizations. Rev. Psicol. Trab. Organ. 2010, 26, 235–253. [Google Scholar]
  61. Ryan, L.; Wallace, J. Mutual Gains Success and Failure: Two Case Studies of Annual Hours in Ireland. Ir. J. Manag. 2019, 38, 26–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Islam, S.; Madani, K. Water Diplomacy in Action: Contingent Approaches to Managing Complex Water Problems; Anthem Press: New York, NY, USA, 2017; Volume 1. [Google Scholar]
  63. Yasuda, Y.; Hill, D.; Aich, D.; Huntjens, P.; Swain, A. Multi-track water diplomacy: Current and potential future cooperation over the Brahmaputra River Basin. Water Int. 2018, 43, 642–664. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Huntjens, P. Mediation in the Israeli-Palestinian water conflict: A practitioner’s view. In Water Diplomacy in Action: Contingent Approaches to Managing Complex Water Problems; Anthem Press: New York, NY, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  65. Mazzucato, M. The entrepreneurial state. Soundings 2011, 49, 131–142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Bos, A.P.; Grin, J. Reflexive interactive design as an instrument for dual track governance. In System Innovations, Knowledge Regimes, and Design Practices towards Sustainable Agriculture; Barbier, M., Elzen, B., Eds.; INRA: Paris, France, 2012; pp. 132–153. [Google Scholar]
  67. Visser, W. CSR 2.0: Transforming the Role of Business in Society. (Social Space. 26–35. Social Space). 2011. Available online: https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/lien_research/87 (accessed on 25 October 2021).
  68. Kristjanson, P.; Harvey, B.; Van Epp, M.; Thornton, P.K. Social learning and sustainable development. Nat. Clim. Chang. 2013, 4, 5–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Folke, C.; Hahn, T.; Olsson, P.; Norberg, J. Adaptive Governance of Social-Ecological Systems. Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour. 2005, 30, 441–473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  70. Huitema, D.; Mostert, E.; Egas, W.; Moellenkamp, S.; Pahl-Wostl, C.; Yalçin, R. Adaptive Water Governance: Assessing the Institutional Prescriptions of Adaptive (Co-)Management from a Governance Perspective and Defining a Research Agenda. Ecol. Soc. 2009, 14, 26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Termeer, C.J.; Dewulf, A.; Lieshout, M.V. Disentangling Scale Approaches in Governance Research: Comparing Monocentric, Multilevel, and Adaptive Governance. Ecol. Soc. 2010, 15, 29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Huntjens, P. Water Management and Water Governance in a Changing Climate. Experiences and Insights on Climate Change Adaptation in Europe, Africa, Asia and Australia; Eburon: Delft, The Netherlands, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  73. Huntjens, P.; Pahl-Wostl, C.; Rihoux, B.; Schlüter, M.; Flachner, Z.; Neto, S.; Koskova, R.; Dickens, C.; Kiti, I.N. Adaptive Water Management and Policy Learning in a Changing Climate: A Formal Comparative Analysis of Eight Water Management Regimes in Europe, Africa and Asia. Environ. Policy Gov. 2011, 21, 145–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Ison, R.; Blackmore, C.; Iaquinto, B.L. Towards systemic and adaptive governance: Exploring the revealing and concealing aspects of contemporary social-learning metaphors. Ecol. Econ. 2013, 87, 34–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Chaffin, B.C.; Gosnell, H.; Cosens, B.A. A decade of adaptive governance scholarship: Synthesis and future directions. Ecol. Soc. 2014, 19, 56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Rip, A. A co-evolutionary approach to reflexive governance—And its ironies. In Reflexive Governance for Sustainable Development; Voss, J.P., Bauknecht, D., Kemp, R., Eds.; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 2006; pp. 82–100. [Google Scholar]
  77. Leach, M.; Bloom, G.; Ely, A.; Nightingale, P.; Scoones, I.; Shah, E.; Smith, A. Understanding Governance: Pathways to Sustainability. 2007. Available online: https://opendocs.ids.ac.uk/opendocs/handle/20.500.12413/2440 (accessed on 25 October 2021).
  78. Voß, J.P.; Bornemann, B. The politics of reflexive governance: Challenges for designing adaptive management and transition management. Ecol. Soc. 2011, 16, 9. Available online: https://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol16/iss2/art9/ (accessed on 25 October 2021). [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  79. Voß, J.-P.; Kemp, R. Sustainability and reflexive governance: Introduction. In Reflexive Governance for Sustainable Development; Voß, J.-P., Bauknecht, D., Kemp, R., Eds.; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 2015; pp. 3–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  80. Feindt, P.H.; Weiland, S. Reflexive governance: Exploring the concept and assessing its critical potential for sustainable development. Introduction to the special issue. J. Environ. Policy Plan. 2018, 20, 661–674. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  81. Huntjens, P.; Smits, M.; van den Akker, J. Literatuurstudie voor het Identificeren van Succes- en Faalfactoren voor Natuur-inclusieve Landbouw; SIA-Project Gebiedsgerichte Kansen voor Natuur-Inclusieve Landbouw: Delft, The Netherlands, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  82. Shtaltovna, A.; Van Assche, K.; Hornidge, A.-K. Where Did This Debt Come from? Organizational Change, Role Ambiguity and Development in Rural Khorezm, Uzbekistan. Int. Asienforum 2012, 43, 179–197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Stavrakakis, Y. Lacanian and the Political; Routledge: London, UK, 1999. [Google Scholar]
  84. Mintzberg, H. Rebalancing Society: Radical Renewal beyond Left, Right, and Center. 2015. Available online: http://www.mintzberg.org/sites/default/files/page/rebalancing_full.pdf (accessed on 25 October 2021).
  85. O’Leary, M.; Valdmanis, W. Accountable. How We Can Save Capitalism; Penguin Business: London, UK, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  86. Atkinson, A.B. Inequality: What Can Be Done? Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  87. Van Bavel, B. The Invisible Hand? How Market Economies Have Emerged and Declined since AD 500; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  88. Collier, P. The Future of Capitalism: Facing the New Anxieties; HarperCollins: New York, NY, USA, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  89. Avelino, F.; Wittmayer, J.M. Shifting Power Relations in Sustainability Transitions: A Multi-Actor Perspective. J. Environ. Policy Plan. 2015, 18, 628–649. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Martella, J.; Rendon, T.; Schilder, D. System Leaders and System Thinkers. Available online: http://ceelo.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/06/PLI_System_Thinking2019.pdf (accessed on 25 October 2021).
  91. Kern, F.; Rogge, K.S. Harnessing theories of the policy process for analysing the politics of sustainability transitions: A critical survey. Environ. Innov. Soc. Transit. 2018, 27, 102–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Rogge, K.S.; Reichardt, K. Policy mixes for sustainability transitions: An extended concept and framework for analysis. Res. Policy 2016, 45, 1620–1635. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Ostrom, E. Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems. Am. Econ. Rev. 2010, 100, 641–672. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  94. Mahoney, J.; Thelen, K. A Theory of Gradual Institutional Change. In Explaining Institutional Change. Ambiguity, Agency, and Power; Mahoney, J., Thelen, K., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2010; pp. 1–37. [Google Scholar]
  95. Lawrence, T.B.; Suddaby, R. Institutions and institutional work. In Handbook of Organization Studies, 2nd ed.; Clegg, R., Hardy, C., Lawrence, T.B., Nord, W.R., Eds.; SAGE: London, UK, 2006; pp. 215–254. [Google Scholar]
  96. Velter, M.G.E.; Bitzer, V.; Bocken, N.M.P. A Boundary Tool for Multi-Stakeholder Sustainable Business Model Innovation. Circ. Econ. Sustain. 2021, 1–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. Scharmer, O. The Essentials of Theory U: Core Principles and Applications. 2018. Available online: https://www.amazon.com/Essentials-Theory-Core-Principles-Applications/dp/1523094400 (accessed on 25 October 2021).
  98. Dijk, M.; Iversen, E.; Klitkou, A.; Kemp, R.; Bolwig, S.; Borup, M.; Møllgaard, P. Forks in the Road to E-Mobility: An Evaluation of Instrument Interaction in National Policy Mixes in Northwest Europe. Energies 2020, 13, 475. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  99. Kennedy, E.H.; Givens, J.E. Eco-habitus or Eco-powerlessness? Examining Environmental Concern across Social Class. Sociol. Perspect. 2019, 62, 646–667. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  100. O’Brien, K.L.; Wolf, J. A values-based approach to vulnerability and adaptation to climate change. Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Clim. Chang. 2010, 1, 232–242. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  101. Porter, M.E.; Kramer, M.R. The competitive advantage of corporate. Harv. Bus. Rev. 2002, 80, 56–68. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
  102. Visser, W.; Kymal, C. Integrated value creation (IVC): Beyond corporate social responsibility (CSR) and creating shared value (CSV). J. Int. Bus. Ethics 2015, 8, 29–43. [Google Scholar]
  103. Susskind, L.; Cruikshank, J. Anticipate the problems of following through. In Breaking Robert’s Rule: The New Way to Run Meetings, Build Consensus, and Get Results; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2006; pp. 130–132. [Google Scholar]
  104. Huntjens, P.; de Man, R. Water Diplomacy: Making Water Cooperation Work. Policy Brief. 2017. Available online: https://www.planetarysecurityinitiative.org/sites/default/files/2017-04/PB_Water_Diplomacy_WG_4.pdf (accessed on 25 October 2021).
  105. Velter, M.; Bitzer, V.; Bocken, N.; Kemp, R. Boundary work for collaborative sustainable business model innovation: The journey of a Dutch SME. J. Bus. Models 2021, 9, 36–66. [Google Scholar]
  106. Ashford, N.A.; Hall, R.P.; Arango-Quiroga, J.; Metaxas, K.A.; Showalter, A.L. Addressing Inequality: The First Step beyond COVID-19 and towards Sustainability. Sustainability 2020, 12, 5404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  107. Polanyi, K. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time, 2nd ed.; Beacon Press: Boston, MA, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  108. Sandel, M. Niet Alles Is te Koop: De Morele Grenzen van Marktwerking; Uitgeverij Ten Have: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  109. Mayntz, R. Governing Failures and the Problem of Governability: Some Comments on a Theoretical Paradigm. In Modern Governance. New Government-Society Interactions; Kooiman, J., Ed.; SAGE: London, UK, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  110. Peter, B.G.; Pierre, J. Multi-Level Governance and Democracy: A Faustian Bargain? Bache, I., Flinders, M., Eds.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2004; pp. 75–92. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Conceptual framework for Transformative Social-Ecological Innovation (TSEI) [8].
Figure 1. Conceptual framework for Transformative Social-Ecological Innovation (TSEI) [8].
Sustainability 14 02976 g001
Figure 2. The Hybrid Sphere is a societal space for cooperation between, e.g., governments, market, knowledge institutes and civilians. A Natural Social Contract is established in such space. The top figure is from [91], the below figure based on [17].
Figure 2. The Hybrid Sphere is a societal space for cooperation between, e.g., governments, market, knowledge institutes and civilians. A Natural Social Contract is established in such space. The top figure is from [91], the below figure based on [17].
Sustainability 14 02976 g002
Figure 3. Possible systemic leverage points for a societal transformation towards a Natural Social Contract, through transformative governance based on co-evolution across several interrelated dimensions (this figure is a synthesis of Table 3.4 in [8]).
Figure 3. Possible systemic leverage points for a societal transformation towards a Natural Social Contract, through transformative governance based on co-evolution across several interrelated dimensions (this figure is a synthesis of Table 3.4 in [8]).
Sustainability 14 02976 g003
Figure 4. The Transition Flower as a tool for identifying options for co-evolutionary steering and multiple value creation through connecting actor-coalitions and interdependent systemic leverage points. The transition path in question is always context-specific, path-dependent and goal-dependent.
Figure 4. The Transition Flower as a tool for identifying options for co-evolutionary steering and multiple value creation through connecting actor-coalitions and interdependent systemic leverage points. The transition path in question is always context-specific, path-dependent and goal-dependent.
Sustainability 14 02976 g004
Figure 5. Possible leverage points and key variables for a transition to nature-inclusive agriculture (NIA) in the Netherlands (at subnational level) [81].
Figure 5. Possible leverage points and key variables for a transition to nature-inclusive agriculture (NIA) in the Netherlands (at subnational level) [81].
Sustainability 14 02976 g005
Table 1. Institutional design principles relevant for TSEI [8].
Table 1. Institutional design principles relevant for TSEI [8].
Institutional Design PrincipleExplanation
Adaptive, reflexive and deliberative approaches to governanceGovernance taking account of ambivalence, complexity, uncertainty, and distributed power in societal change.
Equal and fair (re-)distribution of risks, costs and benefitsThrough the involvement and strong representation of groups and stakeholders who will be affected or are particularly vulnerable.
Arrangements for collective decision-makingTo enhance the participation of groups and stakeholders in decision-making processes.
Reflexive monitoringThis provides a foundation for reflection and social learning, while at the same time supporting accountability.
Conflict prevention and resolution mechanismsPrevention and resolution of conflicts is possible through a variety of mechanisms, such as appropriate benefit sharing arrangements, mutual gains approach, timing and careful sequencing, transparency, building trust, and sharing or clarifying tasks, powers and responsibilities.
Embedded activities/polycentric governanceGovernance and management at a level of scale that does the most justice to the complexity of socio-ecological systems. For example, in European law this is similar to the principle of subsidiarity: social and political issues should be addressed at the most immediate or local level.
Policy learningBy exploring uncertainties, considering alternatives and ‘reframing’ problems and solutions, as well as policy experimentation: a deliberate and coordinated activity (e.g., pilot projects) to develop and test new policy alternatives.
Table 2. The old economy/social contract and the well-being economy with a Natural Social Contract.
Table 2. The old economy/social contract and the well-being economy with a Natural Social Contract.
Key CharacteristicsOld Economy/Social ContractWell-Being Economy/Natural Social Contract
Overarching goal of the social contractProtection (e.g., of property rights), maintenance of order, individual freedomBroad welfare, through human security, social and environmental justice and planetary health. Well-being is pursued in less materialistic ways.
WorldviewAnthropocentric. People work for pay which allows us to consume. Ecocentric or Earth-centric (people and society as part of larger ecosystem, that of planet Earth). Labour is a source of uplifting instead of a drag.
Vision of individualHomo Economicus: a rational person who pursues wealth
for his own self-interest; individual isolated from others.
Homo Ecologicus: a model of human behaviour that is characterised by ecological consciousness and care for the well-being of others and the natural environment. It does not deny that people can be selfish and driven to material gains (Homo Economicus) but says that this denies another reality, of people being social and dependent on nature for their well-being.
Development paradigmNeoliberalism: government is responsible for creating the underlying conditions that the free market requires in order to flourishHybrid sphere: collaboration between governments, businesses, knowledge institutions, civil society, and an important role for citizenship, characterized by penta-helix models and based on multiple value creation.
Policy concernsSecurity and economic opportunityEmpowerment, social justice based on equity, environmental security and justice, planetary health
Response to climate changeGreen growth and green technology (mostly large scale). Carbon capture and storage as important solution. Cooperatives and platforms to ensure that costs and benefits of energy transition are fairly distributed
Innovation modelsTriple Helix, shared value creationPenta helix models based on multiple value creation, and Presencing/Theory U (Based on the work of Claus Otto Scharmer.)
Basis for social relationsUtilitarianMutual respect, solidarity, togetherness, social and environmental stewardship
Vision of societyIndividualisticSociety is a social-ecological system, and individual considered in relation to social environment (human life is group life) and natural environment
View on the natural environmentEcosystem is a black box; Natural resources to be used exclusively by humans, to serve the needs of humanityEarth is the whole of which humans are subservient (but impactful) parts. Institutional and economic design based on natural design principles.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Huntjens, P.; Kemp, R. The Importance of a Natural Social Contract and Co-Evolutionary Governance for Sustainability Transitions. Sustainability 2022, 14, 2976. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14052976

AMA Style

Huntjens P, Kemp R. The Importance of a Natural Social Contract and Co-Evolutionary Governance for Sustainability Transitions. Sustainability. 2022; 14(5):2976. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14052976

Chicago/Turabian Style

Huntjens, Patrick, and René Kemp. 2022. "The Importance of a Natural Social Contract and Co-Evolutionary Governance for Sustainability Transitions" Sustainability 14, no. 5: 2976. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14052976

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop