Next Article in Journal
Sustainable Alternatives for Tertiary Treatment of Pulp and Paper Wastewater
Previous Article in Journal
Exploring the Spatiotemporal Impacts of the Built Environment on Taxi Ridership Using Multisource Data
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Tripartite Evolution Game of Environmental Governance under the Intervention of Central Government

1
Department of Management Engineering, Zhengzhou University, Zhengzhou 450001, China
2
School of Marxism, Zhengzhou University, Zhengzhou 450001, China
3
Department of Development and Planning Off, Zhengzhou University, Zhengzhou 450001, China
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
This author is the primary corresponding author.
Sustainability 2022, 14(10), 6034; https://doi.org/10.3390/su14106034
Submission received: 14 April 2022 / Revised: 12 May 2022 / Accepted: 14 May 2022 / Published: 16 May 2022
(This article belongs to the Topic Climate Change and Environmental Sustainability)

Abstract

:
Environmental pollution management is about the sustainable development effects of enterprises and the quality of life of people. However, the frequent occurrence of various types of enterprises polluting the environment in recent years has revealed many problems, such as the lack of monitoring by relevant central agencies, the ineffective supervision by local governments, and the failure of public complaints. This paper considers the rent-seeking phenomenon of enterprises in pollution prevention and control, constructs a tripartite evolutionary game model between enterprises, local governments and central government, analyzes the evolutionary stability of each participant’s strategy choice, explores the relationship between the influence of each factor on the strategy choice of the three parties, and further analyzes the stability of the equilibrium point in the tripartite game system. The results show that there is no evolutionary equilibrium strategy in the current Chinese environmental governance system; the reward and punishment policies of the local government and central government have a guiding effect on the strategy choices of enterprises in a short period of time, but the guiding effect will gradually weaken after a period of time, and cannot completely curb the irregular strategies of enterprises; the dynamic reward scheme can effectively alleviate the fluctuation of the game system and make the strategy choices of enterprises converge to the ideal state.

1. Introduction

After 1978, China’s GDP was known as the “Chinese miracle” with an average annual growth rate of nearly 10% [1], but behind the rapid economic development was the scale investment of resources and energy and the traditional emergency rescue development mode with high investment, high consumption, and high pollution. On the one hand, according to the “2020 Eco-Environmental Quality Profile”, the average proportion of light pollution, moderate pollution, heavy pollution, and serious pollution in 337 cities above the prefecture level in 2020 will be 13%, and 135 cities still have air pollution. Hebei Province, Henan Province, Shanxi Province, and Shandong Province are the provinces with the highest concentrations of non-standard and severely polluted areas. China ranks 12th from the bottom according to the data of the 2020 Global Urban Air Pollution Survey Report; the air quality of the majority of domestic cities still exceeds the standard; 32 cities are on the list. In addition, according to a document from the Ministry of Ecology and Environment of the People’s Republic of China, water pollution in the central and southern regions is severe, and the carrying capacity of resources and the environment in certain regions is nearing its limit [2], which means that the need for a shift in the social and economic development model has become increasingly apparent. On the other hand, as China’s economy enters the new normal, the contradiction between economic development and environmental protection is increasingly intensified [3], which objectively requires China to constantly innovate its economic development model and achieve green and sustainable economic development. It also means that green development has become an inevitable trend. To this end, the Chinese government has issued a large number of relevant environmental regulation policies [4,5,6]. The report of the 19th National Congress of the Communist Party of China identified pollution prevention and control as one of the three major battles of the new era, and proposed that air, water, soil, and agricultural non-point source pollution should be the primary objectives of future governance, aiming to guide and urge resource-based enterprises to actively implement green transformation, and further form a green development system of “central government monitoring, local government regulation and corporate implementation”. In other words, the central government entrusts and authorizes the Ministry of Ecology and Environment of the People’s Republic of China to supervise the implementation of the environmental policies of local governments and the green development of enterprises [7], and local governments are responsible for carrying out the supervision and enforcement of the green development of enterprises in their regions [8], so as to ensure the consistency of the top and bottom, and make joint efforts to stifle and reverse the trend of increasing resource depletion and ecological degradation in the country at source [9]. Similarly, a similar three-level management system exists in certain nations, such as the “EPA-state government-enterprise” structure in the United States and the “AGDA-state/local government-enterprise” structure in Australia, etc. Under this system, even though it helps to improve the effectiveness of environmental governance, the phenomenon of companies ignoring the environment in pursuit of their greatest interests is still prevalent [10], according to information reported by the Ministry of Ecology and Environment from January to December 2021. There were 132,800 environmental administrative penalty decisions issued at the national level, with a total of CNY 11,687 billion in fines and confiscations and an average fine of CNY 88,000 per case. This exposed the extent of environmental pollution caused by certain businesses as well as numerous problems, such as the ineffectiveness of local government oversight mechanisms and the failure of central government oversight. Governance of these issues is crucial for the development of the nation, the well-being of the population, and the sustainable growth of businesses.
Nowadays, the majority of research on environmental governance focuses on the underlying causes of environmental pollution, the formulation and implementation of environmental policies, and the study of the game relationship between environmental governance subjects. In research on the causes of pollution, on the one hand, scholars examine the impact on the polluted environment in terms of economic development [11], technological development [12], and industrial structure [13]. For instance, Tian [14] believes that excessive pursuit of the economy will lead businesses to disregard environmental protection and cause environmental pollution; the environmental pollution caused by technological development is reflected in daily life, such as automobile exhaust emissions and waste cosmetics and cleaning products. The disposal of supplies exerts some pressure on the environment [15]; the impact of industrial structure changes on the environment is mainly reflected in the energy industry. Shi et al. [16] believed that as coal resources are depleted, the energy- and resource-intensive industrial structure will accentuate and exacerbate environmental pollution issues. In this regard, some scholars believe that effective pollution reduction can be achieved through the implementation of appropriate environmental protection policies.
From an environmental policy perspective, in recent years, countries have developed environmental policies centered on a low-carbon economy, pollution prevention and control, energy conservation, emission reduction, and cleaner production. For instance, the Chinese government’s “14th Five-Year Plan for Soil, Groundwater and Rural Ecological Environmental Protection,” the United States’ “National Environmental Policy Act” and “Oil Pollution Act,” and Australia’s “Clean Air Regulations,” etc. On the basis of distinct policy characteristics, these policies can be categorized as command-and-control, market-incentivized, or public participation. The command-and-control type refers to the government’s direct control [17]; the market-incentive type is a policy that encourages enterprises to conduct cleaner production through the formulation of various reward and punishment policies [18]; and the public-participation type refers to public participation and encourages public participation in the form of reporting and supervision [19]. Environmental governance policies are aimed at enhancing the efficiency of environmental governance. According to the various ways that policies are initiated, they are typically divided into two categories: “central initiation-local application” and “central initiation.” The “central initiation” policy is typically a non-local, normative policy that lacks local characteristics. The second is to require the local government to develop a local policy based on the interpretation of the central policy and to combine local characteristics with a strong sense of individuality.
In the study of environmental governance subject behavior, some scholars have indicated enterprise industrial activities are the primary factor leading to environmental deterioration [20], arguing that Chinese enterprises are capital intensive, and green development must bear high adjustment costs and sunk costs [21], under huge cost pressure enterprises will inevitably lead to the local government “rent-seeking” to seek interest exchange [22]. Some local governments with local protectionism are afraid of the threat of interest damage and take the opportunity to exchange interests with “rent-seeking” enterprises, and to achieve “win-win” [23]. Due to information asymmetry [24], it is difficult for the central government to grasp local environmental behaviors in time, leading to the long-term existence of such “cooperation” between enterprises and the local government [25]. The state has also introduced environmental tax [26] and other governance measures, but has still failed to fundamentally solve the environmental pollution problem, which has brought great losses to the society. Game analysis is helpful to simulate and predict the implementation effect of environmental tax regulations and reward and punishment measures. Using evolutionary game theory, Xiu [27] and Aubert [28] discussed the complexity of rare earth mining areas and water resource environmental governance. Sun et al. [29] used evolutionary games to demonstrate that central government regulation positively affects the strategies chosen by local municipal governments and businesses. Wang [30] analyzed the effect of market regulation on economic and environmental performance using evolutionary game theory; Luo [31] and Wang et al. [32] used evolutionary game theory to analyze the environmental governance strategy game between local governments or environmental regulatory departments and enterprises and found that the cost of government supervision and the punishment of illegal enterprises are the key factors affecting the behavior of both sides.
To sum up, the existing studies have affirmed the enterprise, local government, and national ecological environment role in environmental governance, but these studies have mostly analyzed enterprises, local government, and central government as a separate individual, lacking in environmental governance interests between the interests and quantitative considerations of behavior interaction. Given that evolutionary games are an effective method to study the dynamics of multi-actor strategies with limited rationality, they are also applicable to the study of environmental governance. This paper constructs a three-party evolution game model of enterprises, local government, and central government, and analyzes the interactive behaviors of the three parties in environmental governance from the perspective of game theory. By solving the equilibrium strategy, the evolution law of enterprise behaves differently under different situations and the interaction mechanism between enterprises, local governments, and central government provides a factual basis for the governance role of the local government and central government; lastly, relevant countermeasures and suggestions are proposed based on the game derivation and numerical analysis results.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 constructs a three-party evolutionary game model; Section 3 introduces the evolutionary stability strategies in different situations through numerical simulation and illustrates the impact of parameter changes on these strategies; Section 4 discusses the simulation results of Section 3; and finally, Section 5 discusses the conclusions of this study and proposes corresponding policy recommendations.

2. Materials and Methods

Numerous variables come into play when it comes to environmental governance. This paper, in accordance with Chinese policy, draws on Ioppolo’s point of view [25] and selects enterprises, local governments, and central government as game participants from various administrative levels in China. Each of the three will consider how to make the best use of available resources in order to maximize their own benefits, and each participant will have two strategies to choose from.
There are two environmental management strategies available to businesses: “Cleaner Production” and “Non-cleaner production.” Cleaner Production: On the one hand, businesses must incorporate environmental management into their planning and decision-making processes, actively fulfill their corporate social responsibility, optimize resource allocation, and reduce waste and pollution emissions. On the other hand, they must invest human and financial resources in order to acquire or develop cutting-edge technological products, optimize the use of secondary energy, and achieve energy conservation and consumption reduction, among other environmental goals. Non-cleaner production: Negative treatment of environmental management, including inaction on environmental management, in production and operations focuses exclusively on the costs and benefits directly related to their own interests, ignoring the social and environmental costs associated with their operations.
Local governments employ two strategies in the environmental governance process: “Regulation” and “Non-regulation.” Regulation: Enforcing environmental protection laws and standards at the national level, developing guidelines for regional environmental governance, establishing limits on the total amount of pollution in the area under their jurisdiction, and rigorously approving construction, renovation, and other projects involving various enterprises within their jurisdiction. Non-regulation: focuses exclusively on economic development within the jurisdiction’s boundaries, ignores sustainable green development, and takes no action against enterprises’ environmentally irresponsible behavior.
Central government employs two strategies in the process of environmental governance: “Monitoring” and “Non-monitoring.” Monitoring includes developing and improving policies related to ecological and environmental protection, assessing the extent to which provincial and municipal governments implement their policies, supervising the implementation of national emission reduction targets, and so forth. Non-monitoring entails failing to pay attention to provincial and municipal environmental development, failing to investigate the implementation of provincial and municipal policies, and ignoring public demands for a greener living environment, among other things.

2.1. Model Assumptions

This section may be divided by subheadings. It should provide a concise and precise description of the experimental results, their interpretation, as well as the experimental conclusions that can be drawn.
Hypothesis 1 (H1).
Assume that the probability of an enterprise choosing a “Cleaner Production” strategy is x and 0 ≤ x ≤ 1, and that the probability of an enterprise choosing a “Non-cleaner production” strategy is 1 − x. The enterprise’s primary benefit is R1. When an enterprise opts for the “Cleaner Production” strategy, it incurs the cost C1. Simultaneously, the local government andcentral government will provide enterprises with E1 subsidies and E2 rewards for their behavior. When enterprises prioritize profit maximization over environmental protection and cause excessive environmental pollution, they will face punishment Q from the local government. However, if the local government adopts a strict supervision strategy during this time period, it will not only confiscate the rent-seeking cost K (K < C1), but also punish the enterprise S1. Additionally, regardless of the strategy employed by an enterprise, it must pay an environmental tax. The tax rate is α, but the amount of pollutants discharged under various strategies varies. When an enterprise is committed to cleaner production, the amount of pollutants discharged is M1, but when it is not, the amount is M2 (M2 > M1).
Hypothesis 2 (H2).
Assume that the probability of the local government adopting the “Regulation” strategy is y and 0 ≤ y ≤ 1; and that the probability of the local government adopting the “Non-regulation” strategy is 1 − y. The local government’s basic income is R2. When local governments exercise strict oversight, they incur time, energy, and other costs C2. If the local government is carefully supervised bycentral government, and if the local government is properly supervised, the local government will receive E1. If it is determined that the local government was negligent, punitive measures will be taken against it, which will be recorded as S2. If the enterprise is found to have violated environmental protection laws during this time period,central government will also hold the local government accountable H.
Hypothesis 3 (H3).
Assume thatcentral government chooses the “Monitoring” strategy with a probability of z and 0 ≤ z ≤ 1; the probability of choosing the “Non-monitoring” strategy with a probability of 1 − z. Bear in mind thatcentral government’s basic income is R3, and the cost of monitoring is C3. Whencentral government chooses not to supervise, and local governments and enterprises “combine with the same stream,” their own credibility is diminished, resulting in social losses D.
On the basis of the foregoing assumptions, the strategic combination between the enterprise, the local government, and central government can be obtained, as shown in Table 1 and Table 2.

2.2. Model Analysis

2.2.1. Replication Dynamic Equation and Equilibrium Points of Enterprise

Note that the expected value of a company adhering to cleaner production is V11 and the expected value of adopting a neglectful approach to environmental development is V12, with an average expected value of   V x ¯ .
V 11 = y z ( C 1 + R 1 + E 1 + E 2 α M 1 ) + ( 1 y ) z ( C 1 + R 1 + E 2 α M 1 )   + y ( 1 z ) ( C 1 + R 1 + E 1 α M 1 ) + ( 1 y ) ( 1 z ) ( C 1 + R 1 α M 1 ) V 12 = y z ( R 1 S 1 Q K α M 2 ) + ( 1 y ) z ( R 1 S 1 K α M 2 )   + y ( 1 z ) ( R 1 Q K α M 2 ) + ( 1 y ) ( 1 z ) ( R 1 K α M 2 ) V x ¯ = x V 11 + ( 1 x ) V 12
Then, the replication dynamics equation for cleaner production in companies is:
F ( x ) = d x d t = x ( 1 x ) ( V 11 V 12 )   = x ( 1 x ) [ ( E 1 + Q ) y + ( E 2 + S 1 ) z + α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 ] G ( z ) = ( E 1 + Q ) y + ( E 2 + S 1 ) z + α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1
According to the differential equation stability theorem, for an enterprise’s probability of choosing cleaner production to be stable, it must satisfy the following conditions: F ( x ) = 0 and d F ( x ) / d x 0 . G ( z ) is an increasing function with respect to z due to G ( z ) / z 0 .
Thus, when z = [ C 1 K α ( M 2 M 1 ) ( E 1 + Q ) y ] / ( S 1 + E 2 ) = z * , G ( z ) = 0 , d F ( x ) / d x 0 , and F ( x ) 0 , all x are in the evolutionary stable state; when z < z * , G ( z ) < 0 , d F ( x ) / d x | x = 0 < 0 , then x = 0 is the enterprise’s evolutionary stable strategy; otherwise, x = 1 is the enterprise’s evolutionary stable strategy.

2.2.2. Replication Dynamic Equation and Equilibrium Points of Local Government

Note that the expected value of a local government to regulation is V21, the expected value of a local government to no-regulation is V22, with an average expected value of   V y ¯ .
V 21 = x z ( C 2 + R 2 E 1 + E 3 + α M 1 ) + x ( 1 z ) ( C 2 + R 2 E 1 + α M 1 )   + ( 1 x ) z ( C 2 + R 2 + Q + K + E 3 + α M 2 )   + ( 1 x ) ( 1 z ) ( C 2 + R 2 + Q + K + α M 2 )
V 22 = x z ( R 2 S 2 + α M 1 ) + x ( 1 z ) ( R 2 + α M 1 )   + ( 1 x ) z ( R 2 + K S 2 H + α M 2 ) + ( 1 x ) ( 1 z ) ( R 2 + K H + α M 2 )
V y ¯ = y V 21 + ( 1 y ) V 22
Then, the replication dynamic equation for strict local government regulation is
F ( y ) = d y d t = y ( 1 y ) ( V 21 V 22 )   = y ( 1 y ) [ ( E 3 + S 2 ) z ( E 1 + H + Q ) x + H + Q C 2 ]
J ( z ) = ( E 3 + S 2 ) z ( E 1 + H + Q ) x + H + Q C 2
According to the differential equation stability theorem, the probability of local governments exercising strict supervision in a stable state must satisfy the following conditions: F ( y ) = 0 and d F ( y ) / d y 0 . As a result of J ( z ) / z 0 , J ( z ) is an increasing function in terms of z. Thus, when z = [ ( E 1 + H + Q ) x H Q + C 2 ] / ( E 3 + S 2 ) = z * , J ( z ) = 0 , d F ( y ) / d y 0 and F ( y ) 0 , all y are in an evolutionary stable state; when z < z * , J ( z ) < 0 , d F ( y ) / d y | y = 0 < 0 , y = 0 is the local government’s evolutionary stability strategy; otherwise, y = 1 is the local government’s evolutionary stability strategy.

2.2.3. Replication Dynamic Equation and Equilibrium Points of Central Government

The expected value of monitoring by central government of the People’s Republic of China is V31, and the expected value of non-monitoring is V32, the average expected value is   V z ¯ .
V 31 = x y ( R 3 C 3 E 3 E 2 ) + x ( 1 y ) ( R 3 C 3 + S 2 E 2 )   + ( 1 x ) y ( R 3 C 3 E 3 + S 1 ) + ( 1 x ) ( 1 y ) ( R 3 C 3 + S 1 + S 2 )
V 32 = x y R 3 + x ( 1 y ) R 3 + ( 1 x ) y ( R 3 D ) + ( 1 x ) ( 1 y ) ( R 3 D )
V z ¯ = z V 31 + ( 1 z ) V 32
Then, the replication dynamic equation for central government is
F ( z ) = d z d t = z ( 1 z ) ( V 31 V 32 )   = z ( 1 z ) [ ( E 3 + S 2 ) y ( E 2 + S 1 + D ) x + S 1 + S 2 + D C 3 ]
L ( y ) = ( E 3 + S 2 ) y ( E 2 + S 1 + D ) x + S 1 + S 2 + D C 3
According to differential equations’ stability theorem, the probability that central government chooses to monitor in a stable state must satisfy the following conditions: F ( z ) = 0 and d F ( z ) / d z 0 . L ( y ) is a decreasing function with respect to y due to L ( y ) / y 0 . Thus, when y = [ S 1 + S 2 + M 1 + D C 3 ( E 2 + S 1 + D ) x ] / ( E 3 + S 2 ) = y * , L ( y ) = 0 , d F ( z ) / d z 0 and F ( z ) 0 , then all y are in an evolutionary stable state; when y < y * , L ( y ) > 0 and d F ( z ) / d z | z = 0 > 0 , then z = 0 is central government’s evolutionary stabilization strategy; otherwise, z = 1 is the evolutionary stabilization strategy.
While the evolution process of a game system composed of enterprises, local governments, and central government can be described by their respective replication dynamic equations, it is still impossible to predict the equilibrium point to which the system will tend during the evolution process. We obtain eight pure-strategy equilibrium solutions and multiple mixed-strategy equilibrium solutions using the differential equations’ stability principle [33]. However, as Ritzberger’s research [34] indicates, the mixed strategy equilibrium solution cannot be an evolutionary stable strategy (ESS); this game system requires only the analysis of eight pure strategy equilibrium solutions. The three-party evolutionary game has a different stability analysis than the two-party evolutionary game. Friedman’s positive and negative determination of the Jacobian matrix determinant and trace to discuss the ESS is no longer applicable, and the Lyapunov first judgment method is used in this paper to carry out the ESS’s judgment. The necessary and sufficient condition for the system to be asymptotically stable is that all eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix have negative real parts; if at least one of the eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix is positive, the equilibrium point is the evolutionary unstable point; if the eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix contain both zero and negative values, the equilibrium point is in a critical state, and its stability depends on the following sections, which will examine the stability of each strategy combination. The game system’s Jacobian matrix is as follows:
J = [ F ( x ) / x F ( x ) / y F ( x ) / z F ( y ) / x F ( y ) / y F ( x ) / z F ( z ) / x F ( z ) / y F ( z ) / z ]
F ( x ) / x = ( 1 2 x ) [ ( E 1 + Q ) y + ( E 2 + S 1 ) z + α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 ]
F ( x ) / y = x ( 1 x ) ( E 1 + Q )
F ( x ) / z = x ( 1 x ) ( S 1 + E 2 )
F ( y ) / x = y ( 1 y ) ( B z S 3 )
F ( y ) / y = ( 1 2 y ) [ ( E 3 + S 2 ) z ( E 1 + H + Q ) x + H + Q C 2 ]
F ( y ) / z = y ( 1 y ) ( E 3 + S 2 )
F ( z ) / x = z ( 1 z ) ( E 2 + S 1 + D )
F ( z ) / y = z ( 1 z ) ( E 3 + S 2 )
F ( z ) / z = ( 1 2 z ) [ ( E 3 + S 2 ) y ( E 2 + S 1 + D ) x + S 1 + S 2 + D C 3 ]
To obtain the corresponding eigenvalues, substitute each equilibrium solution into the above Jacobian matrix, as shown in Table 3.
As an example, the point (0,0,0,) is used to discuss the conditions for satisfying the evolutionary stabilization strategy. The eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix of the system at (0,0,0) are λ 1 = α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 , λ 2 = H + Q C 2 , λ 3 = S 1 + S 2 + D C 3 . If λ 1 < 0 , λ 2 < 0 , λ 3 < 0 are also satisfied, then this point is a stable point for the evolution of this conditional system. By analogy, the conditions for the remaining conditional asymptotically stable points are shown in Table 4.
As shown in Table 4, when central government does not monitor both local and enterprise-level activities, there is only one stable strategy for enterprise-level cleaner production with a value of No.2 (1,0,0), (cleaner production, no-regulation, no-monitoring), which corresponds to the replicated dynamic phase diagram shown in Figure 1. In combination 2, conditions C 2 E 1 < 0 , C 1 K α ( M 2 M 1 ) < 0 and E 2 + S 2 C 3 < 0 must be met, namely that the cost of green development to the firm is less than the sum of the firm’s rent-seeking costs and environmental taxes, and that the cost of strict monitoring by central government is greater than the difference between the fines it collects from local governments for poor regulation and the rewards it gives to firms.
When central government chooses to monitor the local as well as the enterprise, there exists a stable strategy combination of enterprise cleaner production with one value of No.3 (1,0,1), i.e., (green development, no regulation, monitoring), which corresponds to the replicated dynamic phase diagram shown in Figure 2. In combination 3, the conditions C 1 K S 1 E 2 α ( M 2 M 1 ) < 0 , E 3 + S 2 C 2 E 1 < 0 , E 2 S 2 + C 3 < 0 need to be satisfied, that is, the cost paid by enterprises to choose cleaner production is lower than the sum of rent-seeking costs, environmental taxes, fines for rent-seeking behavior, and the state’s incentives for environmental behavior of enterprises; the sum of the cost of local government supervision and the amount of subsidies paid to enterprises is lower than the sum of the incentives and penalties for proper supervision of local governments by central government; the cost of strict monitoring by central government is lower than the difference between the fines it charges local governments for poor supervision and the incentives it rewards companies for their cleaner production practices.

3. Simulation Analysis

In a three-party game, the changes of various parameters will have varying effects on the game’s strategic choices, which will in turn influence the dynamic changes of the evolutionary process. Through simulation analysis, the validity of the game system’s stability can be confirmed, and the evolution trend and speed of the game system in various scenarios can be analyzed. This study analyzes the effect of changes in pollutant emissions, environmental taxes, and static and dynamic reward and punishment measures on the game system by assigning parameter values and utilizing Matlab tools to simulate the behavior evolution process of the central government, local governments, and businesses. To more accurately reflect the current state of environmental governance, we use relevant cases (the Ministry of Ecology and Environment’s third batch of typical cases of ecological environmental law enforcement) and parameter settings from the relevant literature [35] to assign values to various variables, so let C1 = 4, C2 = 2, C3 = 4, R1 = 8, R2 = 5, R3 = 3, S1 = 4, S2 = 2, D = 6, Q = 2, K = 1, H = 1, E1 = 1.5, E2 = 2, E3 = 1.

3.1. Simulation Analysis of Environmental Taxes and Emissions on Enterprises’ Strategy Choices

In reality, enterprise quality awareness is generally low, and their behaviors are typically a mix of self-discipline and non-self-discipline, implying hypothesis x = 0.5; local governments are constrained by limited regulatory resources, and while they can investigate and deal with illegal enterprises quickly through special governance and other methods, they cannot be normalized, implying hypothesis y = z = 0.5. According to the existing research, the emission value and corresponding environmental tax coefficient are changed before and after the enterprise pollutes, while the other parameters remain constant, and the simulation is run with x = 0.5 as the enterprise’s initial strategy choice.
As illustrated in Figure 3, corporate strategy is influenced by both its own external pollutant discharge and the external environment, such as changes in environmental tax rates. If cleaner production can significantly reduce an enterprise’s pollutant emissions and even partially offset the additional costs of cleaner production, businesses will be more receptive to environmental protection. When the amount of pollutants discharged under the two strategies remains constant, it is clear that environmental taxes have an effect on business behavior. Increased tax rates will encourage businesses to prioritize environmental stewardship over self-interest. Similarly, when the tax rate is constant, businesses can effectively reduce pollution emissions by implementing green technology and other environmental tools. The more emissions are reduced, the more businesses will pursue cleaner production strategies.

3.2. Simulation Analysis of Incentives and Subsidies on Enterprises’ Strategy Choices

This section investigates the effect of local subsidies E1 and state incentives E2 on corporate strategy selection. On the basis of the preceding section, the difference in pollutant discharge between disregarding environmental protection decisions and pursuing cleaner production is fixed at 4, that is, M1M2 = 4 and = 0.5. With E1 = 1, 2, 3, 4, and E2 = 2, 3, 4, 5, and all other data remaining constant, examine the local government and central government under various initial strategy choices, with local subsidy E1 and state reward E2. The impact on enterprise strategy selection is illustrated in Figure 4 and Figure 5.
As illustrated in Figure 4 and Figure 5, the local government’s subsidy policy for cleaner production and the state’s incentive policy for cleaner production both contributed to the enterprise’s strategic choice. Increased subsidies and incentives will encourage businesses to pursue a “cleaner production” strategy. Simultaneously, when subsidies and incentives are identical, businesses are more susceptible to state-level incentives. Similarly, the likelihood of central government’s participation and the likelihood of strict oversight by the local government both have a propelling effect on corporate strategy selection. As the probability of supervision increases, the likelihood of businesses shifting to “cleaner production” as an initial strategy increases, but it will still show a downward trend over time, demonstrating that despite increased participation and the amount of incentive subsidies, enterprises’ “non-cleaner production” behavior cannot be completely eradicated.

3.3. Simulation Analysis of Punishment on Enterprises’ Strategy Choices

This section examines the effects of the local penalty Q on rent-seeking behavior and the state penalty S1 on an enterprise’s non-cleaner production behavior on its strategic choice. With Q = 1, 2, 3, 4, S1 = 3, 4, 5, 6, and all other data remaining constant, examine the local government and central government under various initial strategy choices, including the punishment Q from local governments and punishment S1 from central government. The impact on enterprise strategy selection is illustrated in Figure 6 and Figure 7.
As illustrated in Figure 6 and Figure 7, both local governments and central government have aided in the promotion of positive strategy selection by businesses. Businesses will become more receptive to the “cleaner production” strategy as punishment increases. Simultaneously, when subsidies and incentives are equal, businesses will initially respond more to relevant local policies, but will eventually succumb to central government. Additionally, the likelihood of participation by central government and the likelihood of strict oversight by local governments both factor into the selection of corporate strategies. A “cleaner production” strategy is more likely to be adopted when there is more monitoring and regulation, but this trend changes over time, which shows that a single punitive measure has little effect on long-term decisions by businesses.

3.4. The Impact of Dynamic Reward and Punishment Subsidies on Enterprises’ Strategy Choices

The analysis of central government’s and local government’s incentive, subsidy, and penalty measures on enterprise strategic choice reveals that both incentive and penalty factors can promote positive enterprise strategic choice over a short period of time, but as the game cycle progresses, this driving effect weakens, and the ideal evolutionary state becomes impossible to achieve, indicating that the static reward and punishment strategy cannot satisfy the ideal effect. This is because the static scheme ignores the degree of participation of subjects across time periods, leaving the problem of game system oscillation unresolved. Therefore, under the dual premise of demonstrating that the reward and punishment strategy is effective for corporate behavior and demonstrating that the company is more receptive to incentive measures, optimize the above reward scheme such that E 11 = y 2 + E 1 y , and E 22 = z 2 + E 2 z , respectively, to replace the original E1 and E2. At this point, the copied dynamic equation is transformed into the following:
F ( x ) = x ( 1 x ) [ ( y 2 + E 1 y + Q ) y + ( z 2 + E 2 z + S 1 ) z + α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 ] F ( y ) = y ( 1 y ) [ ( E 3 + S 2 ) z ( y 2 + E 1 y + H + Q ) x + H + Q C 2 ] F ( z ) = z ( 1 z ) [ ( E 3 + S 2 ) y ( z 2 + E 2 z + S 1 + D ) x + S 1 + S 2 + D C 3 ]
Simultaneously, using the given data, the simulation analysis was repeated, this time considering the direction of enterprise evolution for the three parties under various initial probabilities (y, z equal to 0.1, 0.3, 0.5, 0.7, and 0.9, respectively), the results of which are shown in Figure 8:
As illustrated in Figure 8, when dynamic incentives and subsidies are used, enterprises tend to choose the “cleaner production” strategy when the initial probabilities are different. This demonstrates that, as the game progresses, central government and local governments should adjust the corresponding incentive and subsidy policies to reflect the real-time situation of enterprises, which can not only effectively reduce the cost of supervision and supervision, but also assist enterprises in selecting the appropriate strategy.

4. Discussion

This article employs game theory to construct a game model with three dimensions: national, local, and enterprise, and then uses simulation experiments to verify the effect of environmental taxes, pollution emissions, static reward and punishment policies at various administrative levels, and dynamic reward and punishment measures on corporate strategic behavior choices. From a model-building perspective, the three game players chosen in this paper in accordance with China’s “State Council Institutional Reform Plan” reflect the current state of China’s environmental management while also providing a framework for environmental governance in other countries. This is because the majority of other countries also have a three-tiered governance structure, such as the “EPA-state government-enterprise” structure in the United States and the Australian “AGDA-state/local government-enterprise” structure etc.
In terms of the impact of pollutant discharge and environmental taxes on corporate decision making, Weitzman [36] has theoretically demonstrated that government departments’ use of taxation plays a significant role in promoting cleaner production enterprises. According to Pearce [37], environmental taxes can both compel businesses to conserve energy and reduce emissions and encourage businesses to improve their manufacturing technology, thereby benefiting environmental development. The simulation results presented in this article on environmental taxation and pollutant discharge corroborate these assertions. At the same time, this paper believes that businesses are the primary source of environmental pollution, and that different types of businesses emit pollution at varying levels. For example, manufacturing enterprises emit more pollution than other types of businesses, and they are more sensitive to changes in environmental taxes. Environmental pollution is relatively low for Internet companies, and changes in environmental taxes have little effect on the development of businesses.
The simulation results in this paper confirm the viewpoints of Olubum [38] and Devlin [39] regarding the impact of static reward and punishment policies on corporate behavioral decision making. This effect is only temporary. It could be because the likelihood of local governments and national departments participating changes over time, and the sensitivity of enterprises to policies decreases over time. The incentive effect brought by the static reward and punishment policy gradually declines and it may even induce enterprises to take risks, engage in rent-seeking behavior, and achieve complicity [40], all of which are consistent with the psychological characteristics of greed [41]. On the other hand, existing research on the effects of reward and punishment policies on corporate behavior has failed to account for the difference in corporate sensitivity to the two types of decision making. The simulation results indicate that businesses are more sensitive to state and local government incentive policies than to punishment policies, which is consistent with economics’ fundamental assumption—the bounded rational person who “seeks benefits and avoids disadvantages [42],” because the purpose of the enterprise is to maximize benefits. When incentive and punishment policies are sensitively compared, enterprises are more sensitive to the state’s and government’s incentive policies.
The impact of dynamic reward policies on corporate behavior is more stable and continuous than the simulation results of static reward and punishment policy. Scholars in the financial industry [43], agriculture [44], the Internet [45], and other industries have reached similar conclusions, but there are few studies on environmental protection. This conclusion is psychologically consistent with the characteristics of classical conditioning theory, namely “acquisition, extinction, recovery, and generalization [46].” When a static reward and punishment policy is implemented, businesses are stimulated to engage in the corresponding behaviors, but only for a limited time. This effect fades and fades over time, reverting to unfriendly behavior. When an enterprise adopts a dynamic reward and punishment policy, as the policy’s effect fades, the dynamic policy can cause the enterprise to adjust the policy in response to changes in the environment over time, generate new incentives for the enterprise, and keep the enterprise’s decision-making choice. Any decision made by the decision maker in the long-term development process of an enterprise is made after a detailed analysis of the business environment of the enterprise, and the policy environment determines the enterprise’s development in the external environment. Changes in policies determine the development direction of an enterprise in the future. As a result, if the reward and punishment policy does not change for a long time, the company will make haphazard strategic decisions and will gradually tend to make decisions that are unfriendly to the environment. Therefore, when the reward and punishment policy have not changed for a long time, the enterprise will make tentative decisions on strategic choices, and will gradually tend to make decisions that are not environmentally friendly.

5. Conclusions and Suggestions

This paper analyzes the strategic choices made by enterprises, local governments, and central government under various tax systems, and reward and punishment programs, and discusses the systematic dynamic evolution trends and stability strategies. The evolution path of the game between enterprises, local governments, and central government, as well as the position changes of equilibrium points, are numerically calculated using MATLAB software. The following conclusions are drawn from this paper: there is no ideal evolutionary equilibrium state in the game system under static policies; in comparison to the punishment policy, the company is more sensitive to the reward policy, and while both punishment and reward have a guiding effect on the company’s strategic choice in the short run, the guiding effect gradually fades over time and cannot completely curb the company’s irregular strategy; the dynamic reward scheme can effectively mitigate the game system’s fluctuation and make enterprise strategy selection tend to be ideal. Based on the above analysis, the following suggestions are made:
Firstly, strengthen government–enterprise exchanges and encourage technological innovation and enterprise transformation. Relevant government policies will have an impact on a variety of business decisions. Strengthening communication between the government and businesses can help businesses understand their future development directions, which is beneficial to the development of strategic decisions for cleaner production. In terms of communication, it has the potential to accelerate the transformation of enterprises’ technological innovation while also lowering the cost of cleaner production.
Secondly, broaden the methods of supervision and increase the visibility of corporate wrongdoing. Local government supervision and supervision by central government influences enterprise strategic decision making, enriches supervision forms, and increases the rate of violations by companies that violate regulations, which can not only improve supervision effectiveness, but also have a deterrent effect on other companies. As a result, it is necessary to make effective use of social channels, such as the media, increase the frequency of public communication, and improve the local governments’ and central government’s supervision and supervision effects.
Thirdly, use dynamic incentive measures to increase the incentive effect of enterprises’ cleaner production. Static reward and punishment policies can only guide enterprises toward more environmentally friendly production in the short term, but their guiding role will gradually fade away as the development process progresses. To achieve the best incentives, central government and local governments should adjust incentive measures in response to changes in corporate behavior.
This paper also suffers from the following flaws, which warrant future research: due to the numerous variables that influence the effectiveness of environmental governance, this paper only selects three game subjects based on their administrative levels and other factors. Future research can further enrich the game subjects, such as third-party polluting businesses, the public, internal employees, etc., thereby improving the game model’s accuracy. Furthermore, during the assumption process, this paper makes assumptions based on the behavioral interaction logic of the three parties and only considers the gains and losses of interest, which does not accurately reflect the actual game situation. In the future, theories from various disciplines can be incorporated to further enrich the assumptions. For example, prospect theory and public game theory. Finally, in the process of simulation analysis, this paper refers to the third batch of typical ecological and environmental law enforcement cases announced by the Ministry of Ecology and Environment in 2020 and the related literature to set basic values. Although it has a certain degree of authenticity, due to the small number of cases, each country’s policies are also different, so the applicability to other countries will be affected to some extent.

Author Contributions

The authors contributed to each section of the paper by conceptualization, Y.Z.; methodology, Z.Z.; software, J.L.; validation, J.L.; formal analysis, Y.Z.; investigation, Z.Z.; resources and data curation, J.L.; writing—original draft preparation, J.L.; writing—review and editing, Y.Z.; supervision, L.N.; project administration and funding acquisition, L.N. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was supported by the National Research Foundation of China (Grant No. 2020-ZD-18-5) and the Ministry of Education Foundation of China (Grant NO. 20YJA6301010).

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Chen, M.; Kwok, C.L.; Shan, H.; Yip, P.S. Decomposing and predicting China’s GDP growth: Past, present, and future. Popul. Dev. Rev. 2018, 44, 143–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Liu, J.; Raven, P.H. China’s environmental challenges and implications for the world. Crit. Rev. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2010, 40, 823–851. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Li, J.; Shi, X.; Wu, H.; Liu, L. Trade-off between economic development and environmental governance in China: An analysis based on the effect of river chief system. China Econ. Rev. 2020, 60, 101403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Yu, X.; Wang, P. Economic effects analysis of environmental regulation policy in the process of industrial structure upgrading: Evidence from Chinese provincial panel data. Sci. Total Environ. 2021, 753, 142004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Gu, G.; Zheng, H.; Tong, L.; Dai, Y. Does carbon financial market as an environmental regulation policy tool promote regional energy conservation and emission reduction? Empirical evidence from China. Energy Policy 2022, 163, 112826. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Zhou, C.; Xie, H.; Zhang, X. Does fiscal policy promote third-party environmental pollution control in China? An evolutionary game theoretical approach. Sustainability 2019, 11, 4434. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Guttman, D.; Young, O.; Jing, Y.; Bramble, B.; Bu, M.; Chen, C.; Furst, K.; Hu, T.; Li, Y.; Logan, K.; et al. Environmental governance in China: Interactions between the state and “nonstate actors”. J. Environ. Manag. 2018, 220, 126–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Gao, X.; Teets, J. Civil society organizations in China: Navigating the local government for more inclusive environmental governance. China Inf. 2021, 35, 46–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Shen, Y.; Lisa Ahlers, A. Local environmental governance innovation in China: Staging ‘triangular dialogues’ for industrial air pollution control. J. Chin. Gov. 2018, 3, 351–369. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Qadri, R.; Faiq, M.A. Freshwater pollution: Effects on aquatic life and human health. In Fresh Water Pollution Dynamics and Remediation; Springer: Singapore, 2020; pp. 15–26. [Google Scholar]
  11. Shah, S.A.R.; Naqvi, S.A.A.; Riaz, S.; Anwar, S.; Abbas, N. Nexus of biomass energy, key determinants of economic development and environment: A fresh evidence from Asia. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2020, 133, 110244. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Cheng, Z.; Li, L.; Liu, J. The effect of information technology on environmental pollution in China. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2019, 26, 33109–33124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  13. Muhammad, S.; Pan, Y.; Agha, M.H.; Umar, M.; Chen, S. Industrial structure, energy intensity and environmental efficiency across developed and developing economies: The intermediary role of primary, secondary and tertiary industry. Energy 2022, 247, 123576. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Tian, Z.; Tian, Y.; Chen, Y.; Shao, S. The economic consequences of environmental regulation in China: From a perspective of the environmental protection admonishing talk policy. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2020, 29, 1723–1733. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Magazzino, C.; Mele, M.; Morelli, G.; Schneider, N. The nexus between information technology and environmental pollution: Application of a new machine learning algorithm to OECD countries. Util. Policy 2021, 72, 101256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Shi, J.; Huang, W.; Han, H.; Xu, C. Pollution control of wastewater from the coal chemical industry in China: Environmental management policy and technical standards. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2021, 143, 110883. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Shen, C.; Li, S.; Wang, X.; Liao, Z. The effect of environmental policy tools on regional green innovation: Evidence from China. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 254, 120122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Agarwal, S.; Deng, Y.; Li, T. Environmental regulation as a double-edged sword for housing markets: Evidence from the NOx Budget Trading Program. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2019, 96, 286–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Leng, X.; Zhong, S.; Kang, Y. Citizen participation and urban air pollution abatement: Evidence from environmental whistle-blowing platform policy in Sichuan China. Sci. Total Environ. 2022, 816, 151521. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Karim, R.; Muhammad, F.; Qureshi, J.A.; Latip, N.A.; Marzuki, A.; Nilofar, M. The Effects of Industrial Value Addition and Energy Consumption on Environmental Deterioration: New Evidence from Islamic Countries. Int. J. Econ. Environ. Geol. 2020, 11, 56–58. [Google Scholar]
  21. Baboukardos, D. The valuation relevance of environmental performance revisited: The moderating role of environmental provisions. Br. Account. Rev. 2018, 50, 32–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Costa Junior, C.J.; Garcia-Cintado, A.C. Rent-seeking in an emerging market: A DSGE approach. Econ. Syst. 2021, 45, 100775. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Chen, Y.; Zhang, J.; Tadikamalla, P.R.; Gao, X. The relationship among government, enterprise, and public in environmental governance from the perspective of multi-player evolutionary game. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 3351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  24. Schiemann, F.; Sakhel, A. Carbon disclosure, contextual factors, and information asymmetry: The case of physical risk reporting. Eur. Account. Rev. 2019, 28, 791–818. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Ioppolo, G.; Cucurachi, S.; Salomone, R.; Saija, G.; Shi, L. Sustainable local development and environmental governance: A strategic planning experience. Sustainability 2016, 8, 180. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Li, G.; Zhang, R.; Masui, T. CGE modeling with disaggregated pollution treatment sectors for assessing China’s environmental tax policies. Sci. Total Environ. 2021, 761, 143264. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Wang, X.-l.; Zhang, Z.-y.; Li, H.-k. Research on Environmental Governance and Supervision Strategy of Rare Earth Mining Area Based on Game Theory. Oper. Res. Manag. Sci. 2022, 31, 46–51. [Google Scholar]
  28. Aubert, A.H.; Medema, W.; Wals, A.E.J. Towards a framework for designing and assessing game-based approaches for sustainable water governance. Water 2019, 11, 869. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Sun, T.; Feng, Q. Evolutionary game of environmental investment under national environmental regulation in China. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2021, 28, 53432–53443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Wang, M.; Cheng, Z.; Li, Y.; Li, J.; Guan, K. Impact of market regulation on economic and environmental performance: A game model of endogenous green technological innovation. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 277, 123969. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Luo, M.; Fan, R.; Zhang, Y.; Zhu, C. Environmental governance cooperative behavior among enterprises with reputation effect based on complex networks evolutionary game model. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2020, 17, 1535. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  32. Wang, H.; Cai, L.; Zeng, W. Research on the evolutionary game of environmental pollution in system dynamics model. J. Exp. Theor. Artif. Intell. 2011, 23, 39–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Weinstein, M.I. Lyapunov stability of ground states of nonlinear dispersive evolution equations. Commun. Pure Appl. Math. 1986, 39, 51–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Ritzberger, K.; Weibull, W.J. Evolutionary selection in normal-form games. Econometrica 1995, 63, 1371–1399. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Xu, L.; Di, Z.; Chen, J. Evolutionary game of inland shipping pollution control under government co-supervision. Mar. Pollut. Bull. 2021, 171, 112730. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Weitzman, M.L. Prices vs. quantities. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1974, 41, 477–491. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Pearce, D. The role of carbon taxes in adjusting to global warming. Econ. J. 1991, 101, 938–948. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Olubunmi, O.A.; Xia, P.B.; Skitmore, M. Green building incentives: A review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 59, 1611–1621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Devlin, S.M.; Kudenko, D. Dynamic potential-based reward shaping. In Proceedings of the 11th International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems (AAMAS 2012), Valencia Spain, 4–8 June 2012; IFAAMAS: Richland, SC, USA, 2012; pp. 433–440. [Google Scholar]
  40. Zhang, Y.; Jin, P.; Feng, D. Does civil environmental protection force the growth of China’s industrial green productivity? Evidence from the perspective of rent-seeking. Ecol. Indic. 2015, 51, 215–227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Hessing, D.J.; Elffers, H.; Robben, H.S.J.; Webley, P. Needy or Greedy? The Social Psychology of Individuals Who Fraudulently Claim Unemployment Benefits. J. Appl. Soc. Psychol. 1993, 23, 226–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  42. Ackerman, F.; Heinzerling, L. Pricing the priceless: Cost-benefit analysis of environmental protection. Univ. Pa. Law Rev. 2002, 150, 1553–1584. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  43. Lu, L.; Zhang, J.; Tang, W. Optimal dynamic pricing and replenishment policy for perishable items with inventory-level-dependent demand. Int. J. Syst. Sci. 2016, 47, 1480–1494. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Qureshi, M.I.; Awan, U.; Arshad, Z.; Rasli, A.M.; Zaman, K.; Khan, F. Dynamic linkages among energy consumption, air pollution, greenhouse gas emissions and agricultural production in Pakistan: Sustainable agriculture key to policy success. Nat. Hazards 2016, 84, 367–381. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Shan, D.; Jiang, W.; Ren, F. Absorbing micro-burst traffic by enhancing dynamic threshold policy of data center switches. In Proceedings of the 2015 IEEE Conference on Computer Communications (INFOCOM), Hong Kong, China, 26 April–1 May 2015; IEEE: New York, NY, USA, 2015; pp. 118–126. [Google Scholar]
  46. Prokasy, W.F.; Kumpfer, K.L. Classical conditioning. In Electrodermal Activity in Psychological Research; Academic Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1973; pp. 157–202. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. (1,0,0) Copy dynamic phase diagram.
Figure 1. (1,0,0) Copy dynamic phase diagram.
Sustainability 14 06034 g001
Figure 2. (1,0,1) Copy dynamic phase diagram.
Figure 2. (1,0,1) Copy dynamic phase diagram.
Sustainability 14 06034 g002
Figure 3. Impact of changes in emissions and taxes on the evolution of enterprise strategy choices. (a) M1M2 = 2; (b) M1M2 = 4; (c) M1M2 = 6.
Figure 3. Impact of changes in emissions and taxes on the evolution of enterprise strategy choices. (a) M1M2 = 2; (b) M1M2 = 4; (c) M1M2 = 6.
Sustainability 14 06034 g003
Figure 4. Impact of local subsidies on enterprises’ strategy choices. (a) E1 = 1; (b) E1 = 2; (c) E1 = 3; (d) E1 = 4.
Figure 4. Impact of local subsidies on enterprises’ strategy choices. (a) E1 = 1; (b) E1 = 2; (c) E1 = 3; (d) E1 = 4.
Sustainability 14 06034 g004
Figure 5. Impact of central government incentives on enterprises’ strategic choices. (a) E2 = 2; (b) E2 = 3; (c) E2 = 4; (d) E2 = 5.
Figure 5. Impact of central government incentives on enterprises’ strategic choices. (a) E2 = 2; (b) E2 = 3; (c) E2 = 4; (d) E2 = 5.
Sustainability 14 06034 g005
Figure 6. Impact of local governments’ penalties on enterprises’ strategy choices. (a) Q = 1; (b) Q = 2; (c) Q = 3; (d) Q = 4.
Figure 6. Impact of local governments’ penalties on enterprises’ strategy choices. (a) Q = 1; (b) Q = 2; (c) Q = 3; (d) Q = 4.
Sustainability 14 06034 g006
Figure 7. Impact of central government’s penalties on enterprises’ strategic choices. (a) S1 = 3; (b) S1 = 4; (c) S1 = 5; (d) S1 = 6.
Figure 7. Impact of central government’s penalties on enterprises’ strategic choices. (a) S1 = 3; (b) S1 = 4; (c) S1 = 5; (d) S1 = 6.
Sustainability 14 06034 g007
Figure 8. Impact of dynamic incentive subsidy schemes on enterprises’ strategy choices. (a) x = 0.1; (b) x = 0.3; (c) x = 0.5; (d) x = 0.8.
Figure 8. Impact of dynamic incentive subsidy schemes on enterprises’ strategy choices. (a) x = 0.1; (b) x = 0.3; (c) x = 0.5; (d) x = 0.8.
Sustainability 14 06034 g008
Table 1. The benefit matrix of the tripartite game between enterprises, local governments, and central government.
Table 1. The benefit matrix of the tripartite game between enterprises, local governments, and central government.
Game ParticipantsLocal Government
Regulation (y)Non-Regulation (1 − y)
EnterpriseCleaner Production
(x)
Central GovernmentMonitoring (z)−C1 + R1 + E1 + E2αM1;
−C2 + R2E1 + E3 + αM1;
R3C3E3E2
−C1 + R1 + E2αM1;
R2S2 + αM1;
R3C3 + S2E2
Non-
Monitoring (1 − z)
−C1 + R1 + E1αM1;
−C2 + R2E1 + αM1;
R3
−C1 + R1αM1;
R2 + αM1;
R3
Non-cleaner Production
(1 − x)
Central GovernmentMonitoring (z)R1S1QKαM2;
−C2 R2 + Q+K + E3 + αM2;
R3C3E3 + S1
R1KS1αM2;
R2 + K + S2H;
R3C3 + S1 + S2
Non-
Monitoring (1 − z)
R1QKαM2;
−C2 + R2 + Q + K + E3 + αM2;
R3D
R1KαM2;
R2 + KH + αM2;
R3D
Note: The relationships of all formulas in the table are derived from the above assumptions.
Table 2. Definition of variables within the model.
Table 2. Definition of variables within the model.
SymbolsDefinition
C1The cost of cleaner production
C2The cost of regulation
C3The cost of regulation
R1Corporate basic income
R2Local basic benefits
R3Central government’s basic income
S1When corporate rent-seeking is found to be punished
S2When local governments do not supervise, they are punished
DSocial losses when central government does not monitor
QLocal government punishes companies for not being environmentally friendly
KCorporate rent-seeking costs
HLocal governments are punished with additional governance costs additional treatment costs
E1Local government subsidies to enterprises
E2Central government rewards enterprises
E3Central government awards local governments
αEnvironmental tax rate
M1Pollution emissions of enterprises during cleaner production
M2Pollution emissions when companies ignore the environment
Note: The variables in the table are derived from the above assumptions and correspond to the formulas in Table 1.
Table 3. Stability analysis of balancing points.
Table 3. Stability analysis of balancing points.
Balancing Point Eigenvalue   λ 1 , λ 2 , λ 3 Stability
(0,0,1) E 2 + S 1 + α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 ,
E 3 + S 2 + H + Q C 2 ,
C 3 S 1 S 2 D
Conditional
(0,1,1) E 1 + E 2 + Q + S 1 + α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 ,
C 2 H Q E 3 S 2 ,
E 3 S 1 D + C 3
Conditional
(0,1,0) E 1 + Q + α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 ,
C 2 H Q ,
E 3 + S 1 + D C 3
Conditional
(1,0,0) C 1 K α ( M 2 M 1 ) ,
C 2 E 1 ,
E 2 + S 2 C 3
Conditional
(1,0,1) C 1 K S 1 E 2 α ( M 2 M 1 ) ,
E 3 + S 2 E 1 C 2 ,
E 2 S 2 + C 3
Conditional
(1,1,0) C 1 K Q E 1 α ( M 2 M 1 ) ,
C 2 + E 1 ,
C 3 E 2 E 3
Unstable
(0,0,0) α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 ,
H + Q C 2 ,
S 1 + S 2 + D C 3
Conditional
(1,1,1) C 1 K S 1 E 2 E 1 Q α ( M 2 M 1 ) ,
C 2 + E 1 S 2 E 3 ,
C 3 + E 2 + E 3
Unstable
Note: The eigenvalues are obtained by the matrix. Since C2 + E1 > 0 and C3 + E2 + E3 > 0, the points (1,1,0) and (1,1,1) are Unstable. Furthermore, based on the actual situation, the rent-seeking cost of an enterprise must be less than the cost of cleaner production, that is, K < C1, or it fails to meet the practical significance.
Table 4. Stability conditions at each balancing point. (Unstable points excluded).
Table 4. Stability conditions at each balancing point. (Unstable points excluded).
Balancing PointConditionsNumber
(0,1,0) E 1 + Q + α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 < 0 ,
C 2 H Q < 0 ,
E 3 + S 1 + D C 3 < 0
1
(1,0,0) C 1 K α ( M 2 M 1 ) < 0 ,
C 2 E 1 < 0 ,
E 2 + S 2 C 3 < 0
2
(1,0,1) C 1 K S 1 E 2 α ( M 2 M 1 ) < 0 ,
E 3 + S 2 E 1 C 2 < 0 ,
E 2 S 2 + C 3 < 0
3
(0,0,0) α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 < 0 ,
H + Q C 2 < 0 ,
S 1 + S 2 + D C 3 < 0 .
4
(0,0,1) E 2 + S 1 + α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 ,
E 3 + S 2 + H + Q C 2 ,
C 3 S 1 S 2 D
5
(0,1,1) E 1 + E 2 + Q + S 1 + α ( M 2 M 1 ) + K C 1 ,
C 2 H Q E 3 S 2 ,
E 3 S 1 D + C 3
6
Note: Unstable points have been removed from this table. In addition, for the convenience of discussion, the possible stable points are marked with numbers, and the numbers have no practical significance.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zhu, Y.; Niu, L.; Zhao, Z.; Li, J. The Tripartite Evolution Game of Environmental Governance under the Intervention of Central Government. Sustainability 2022, 14, 6034. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14106034

AMA Style

Zhu Y, Niu L, Zhao Z, Li J. The Tripartite Evolution Game of Environmental Governance under the Intervention of Central Government. Sustainability. 2022; 14(10):6034. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14106034

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zhu, Yongming, Lanxiao Niu, Zheyun Zhao, and Jing Li. 2022. "The Tripartite Evolution Game of Environmental Governance under the Intervention of Central Government" Sustainability 14, no. 10: 6034. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14106034

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop