Next Article in Journal
Congruence Effects on the Effectiveness of Sponsorship of Sport Event Websites: An Experimental Approach
Next Article in Special Issue
Determining the Competitiveness of Spa-Centers in Order to Achieve Sustainability Using a Fuzzy Multi-Criteria Decision-Making Model
Previous Article in Journal
Thermal Analysis and Experimental Validation of Environmental Condition Inside Greenhouse in Tropical Wet and Dry Climate
Previous Article in Special Issue
Sustainability of the Motivation Policy Model for Employees in State Administration
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Will Ending the One-Child Policy and Raising the Retirement Age Enhance the Sustainability of China’s Basic Pension System?

1
China Institute for Actuarial Science/School of Insurance, Central University of Finance and Economics, Beijing 102206, China
2
Department of logistics, University of Defence, 11000 Belgrade, Serbia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2020, 12(19), 8172; https://doi.org/10.3390/su12198172
Submission received: 12 September 2020 / Revised: 30 September 2020 / Accepted: 30 September 2020 / Published: 3 October 2020

Abstract

:
The sustainability of China’s Basic Pension System (CBPS) has been challenged by the ageing of the population and the decline in economic growth. This article establishes a Markov model for CBPS to examine whether the reforms, including ending the one-child policy and raising retirement the age, will shrink the negative income–expenditure gap. We find that the negative income–expenditure gap will destroy CBPS in the future in the absence of fiscal transfer or reform. Ending the one-child policy will increase the number of contributors and then reduce the gap in the short term but will worsen the gap in the long term. Raising the retirement age will have several positive effects overall while increasing expenditures in certain periods. The contributions of this article are describing CBPS in detail and establishing a precise model to analyze the effectiveness of reforms.

1. Introduction

After several decades of development and reforms, China has established a three-pillar old-age security program comprising China’s Basic Pension System (CBPS), Supplementary Pension System, and Personal Saving. Sponsored by the Government, CBPS plays the most important role because of the history of the planned economy. CBPS contains several sub-systems for different groups of people: an urban employees’ basic pension system for workers in urban areas, an urban residents’ basic pension system for workers who are not employed, and a rural residents’ basic pension system for people in rural areas (now urban residents and rural residents are combined in the urban and rural residents’ basic pension system). The urban employees’ basic pension system was the benchmark system, which began in 1997 and included all employees in China (see [1]). Therefore, it is the focus of this article.
A mixed scheme was designed for China’s urban employees’ basic pension system, comprising a public account and a private account, for example [1,2,3]. The public account holds funds from the pay-as-you-go plan contributed by all employers at a rate of 20% (the ratio was decreased to 16% to reduce the burden of employers in 2019) of employees’ wages and benefiting all the retirees. The benefit for public accounts is calculated at the base of an individual’s history of contributions (related to the historical wages) and the average wages in retirement, awarding 1% for 1 year’s contribution. The private account holds the funded plan contributions by individuals at a rate of 8% of wages and benefiting the individuals after retirement. The benefit for private accounts is calculated by dividing the planned periods from individuals’ cumulative value at retirement.
China’s urban employees’ basic pension system does not work very well because there was no fiscal transfer into the start-up fund at the outset, but the system paid benefits to retirees at that time (see [2]). Consequently, the money in the private account was embezzled. With the aging of the population, a gap appeared and has grown. In the 2000s, the problem was not apparent because of the high economic growth, thus providing ample public revenue and millions of subsidies. In fact, the government awarded large bonuses to retirees by increasing their public account benefits during 2005 to 2015 (the annual average growth rate was above 10% during 2005 to 2015).
Alarm bells rang in the early 2010s. The sustainability of China’s urban employees’ basic pension system was eroded by the population’s aging, particularly the sudden reduction in new labor because of the one-child policy beginning in 1978. In addition, economic growth has continued to decline, thus resulting in a decrease in fiscal subsidies. Therefore, there is an understanding that the income–expenditure gap not is inevitable and reforms are necessary, for example [1,2,4,5].
The government issued several measures quickly. The one-child policy was ended in 2016, and couples are now allowed to have two children (see [6]). In addition, the compulsory retirement age will be increased by 5 years gradually over the course of several years, to 65 and 60 for males and females (see [7]). In addition, parts of stated-owned assets have been transferred to China’s urban employees’ basic pension system, thereby allowing the assets’ return to complement the benefits. Furthermore, a disbursement mechanism allows surplus provinces to subsidize provinces with deficits.
Will these measures enhance CBPS sustainability? The third measure will help because the transfer will result in cash inflow, whereas the fourth measure will not help because it is only a rebalancing among provinces. However, what about ending the one-child policy and raising the retirement age? This is an interesting question because of its details: CBPS income and expenditure are not actuarial-balanced. Therefore, there may be a surplus or a deficit for each individual, and the surplus or the deficit may accumulate if the number of contributors increases. Furthermore, raising the retirement age will shorten the benefit period but increase the benefit level. Thus, whether the expenditure will decrease is unclear.
This article established a Markov model to simulate CBPS cashflows according to detailed rules and then analyzed the impacts of population policies and reforms on the sustainability of CBPS. We found that first, the negative income–expenditure gap will destroy CBPS in the future if there is no outside transfer or reform; second, ending the one-child policy will increase the number of contributors and reduce the gap in the short term but will worsen the gap in the long-term; and third, raising the retirement age will have some positive effects overall while increasing the expenditures in certain periods.
The remainder of the article is organized as follows. The Section 2 reviews the literature and summarizes the innovations of this article. The Section 3 establishes an actuarial model of cash inflow and expenditure, assuming that the contribution is not always continuous and the contributor could take early retirement. The Section 4 calibrates the parameters in the model. The Section 5 tests the model and parameters with the data from 2009 to 2015, forecasts CBPS cashflows from 2018 to 2058, and then discusses how policies and reforms affect the cashflows. The Section 6 describes the conclusions.

2. Literature Review

The prediction of income and expenditure for pension systems has attracted substantial interest. Some official models have been established to forecast the impacts of reform on sustainability. For example, the Office of the Chief Actuary of the US Social Security Administration has built an actuarial model (the OCA Stochastic Model, OSM) to forecast the income and expenditure of the US Social Security Fund in the next 75 years. The Congressional Budget Office also predicts the cashflows with a micro-stochastic model. A special report on the short-term and long-term cashflows of Social Security Funds in the UK has been released by the Government Actuary’s Department. Unfortunately, similar modeling is not conducted in China, although many researchers have made attempts to do so, for example [1,2,3].
The aging of the population has led to many studies of the pension system’s sustainability; ref. [8] has proposed the Aaron condition, based on the Samuelson model, in which intergenerational equilibrium for a pay-as-you-go pension system occurs when the growth rates of the population and wages exceed the interest rates. However, the pension system will inevitably have a deficit because of the low fertility rate in an aging society, for example [9,10,11]. Using an OLG model to calculate the gap in Slovenia, ref. [12] has shown that the gap increases as the population ages, and ref. [13] believes that pension system reforms are essential to solving the aging problem, e.g., delaying retirement and increasing the fertility rate and the contribution rate. Delayed retirement is generally accepted to enhance a pension system’s sustainability: see [14,15,16]. In addition, on the basis of an endogenous fertility model, ref. [17] has suggested that a pension system’s sustainability will be enhanced if the fertility rate is increased; ref. [18] have claimed that financial sustainability of unfunded pension systems will be eroded by population ageing and analyzed the impact of immigration flows on the financial sustainability, taking Spain as a test case.
Some studies have focused on the sustainability of CBPS. For an aging population with a pay-as-you-go system, ref. [1] have claimed that CBPS will have a current deficit in 2025 if there are no reforms; ref. [9] believes that the income and expenditure will be balanced if the compulsory retirement age is 65 years; ref. [4] analyzes the sustainability of China’s basic pension fund under two macroeconomic scenarios and indicates that China’s present basic pension system faces insolvency crisis; ref. [6] has claimed that if more than 54% of qualified couples have a second child, the accumulated deficit of pension insurance fund will not appear before 2090; ref. [19] has suggested that China’s pension plan is expected to finish the transition in 2081. Postponing the retirement age will delay the peak time of debt, but the total debt will increase substantially. Ref. [20] has assessed the effects of rates on enterprises’ incentive to participate in CBPS. The findings suggest that a lower contribution rate motivates enterprises to participate in CBPS and increases the fund’s revenue; ref. [21] explores the financial self-balancing ability of the individual accounts of China’s urban enterprise employees’ pension plan and indicates that the self-balancing ability of individual accounts will be improved if a stochastic bookkeeping rate is adopted; ref. [5] studies the effect of poverty alleviation policy on the sustainability of China’s basic pension funding for urban and rural residents in the short term (2020–2025) and medium term (2025–2050) and suggests that the sustainability of the fund will inevitably face challenges.
Various aspects of CBPS have been studied, but some problems have yet to be solved. No micro-stochastic actuarial model has been developed for CBPS. Although many models have been established for CBPS, they do not consider break-off and early retirement. Moreover, CBPS is not a standard pay-as-you-go system, and it includes many additional bonuses. Existing studies have ignored the particularities of CBPS, thus potentially resulting in ineffectiveness in delaying retirement and increasing the fertility rate.
Our article introduces CBPS, describes a Markov actuarial model built to predict the income and expenditure of CBPS in the future, and discusses the impact of delaying retirement and increasing fertility rate.

3. Model and Assumption

3.1. Population Model

3.1.1. Markov Model for Contributors and Retirees

Figure 1 shows the state space and the transitions for the contributors and the retirees.
All CBPS participants are divided into two groups: contributors and retirees. There are four states for each contributor: “normal” describes the state in which the contributor contributes to CBPS (including the contribution of the employer and employee). “Break-off” describes the state in which the contributor belongs to CBPS but does not contribute to the system, for example, because of unemployment. Break-off is a serious problem for CBPS, and the official data show that the break-off rate is 20%. However, a break-off contributor can re-contribute to CBPS. “Dead” and “retirement” are two absorbing states. Although there are compulsory retirement ages for men and women, many contributors have reason to apply for retirement before the compulsory age. Early retirement is taken by 40% of men and 50% of women. There are two states for each retiree: “retirement” and “dead”. “Retirement” means that the retiree is alive and receives pension from CBPS.
According to the state transition diagrams, it is easy to construct the transition probabilities matrix for the contributor, i.e.,
P x ( t ) = ( p x l l ( t ) p x l s ( t ) p x l r ( t ) p x l d ( t ) p x s l ( t ) p x s s ( t ) p x s r ( t ) p x s d ( t ) 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 )
where P x ( t ) denotes the matrix of an x-year-old contributor at period t and p x i j ( t ) denotes the probability of an x-year-old contributor transitioning from state i to state j at period t.
The matrix for the retiree is
Q x ( t ) = ( q x r r ( t ) q x r d ( t ) 0 1 )
where Q x ( t ) denotes the matrix of an x-year-old retiree at period t and q x i j ( t ) denotes the probability of an x-year-old retiree transitioning from state i to state j at period t.
For simplicity, we assume that the Markov models are time homogeneous. Thus, the transition probabilities depend only on age. Therefore,
P x = ( p x l l p x l s p x l r p x l d p x s l p x s s p x s r p x s d 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 ) ,   Q x = ( q x r r q x r d 0 1 )

3.1.2. The Number of Participants in the Future

We forecast the number of participants in the future on the basis of the present population structure and the transition probability matrix.
Participants in the future comprise two groups. The first is those who have already participated in CBPS at period 0. Let L A x i denote the number of contributors who are x years old and are in state i, and let L R y denote the number of retirees who are y years old. The second is those who enter CBPS afterward. We assume that all new participants are c years old and contribute to CBPS at the beginning. Let N L A c ( t ) denote the number of new participants at period t.
With those assumptions, the expected number of “normal” contributors at period t is:
x = x s x f L A x l · p t x l l + x = x s x f L A x s · p t x s l + k = 1 t N L A c ( k ) · p t k c l l
where x s and x f represent the minimum and maximum age of the contributor, respectively.
The expected number of “retirement” retirees at period t is
y = y s y = y f L R y · q t y r r + x = x s x = x f [ L A x l · t r = 1 t P ( R x l = t r ) q t t r x + t r r r ] + x = x s x = x f [ L A x s · t r = 1 t P ( R x s = t r ) q t t r x + t r r r ] + k = 1 t [ N L A c ( k ) · t r = k t P ( R c ( s ) = t r ) q t t r c + t r k r r ]
where P ( R x l = t r ) (or P ( R x s = t r ) ) denotes the probability of an x-year-old “normal” (or “break-off”) contributor retiring at period t r , P ( R c ( s ) = t r ) denotes the probability of new participants at period s retiring at period t r , and y s and y f represent the minimum and maximum ages of retirees, respectively.

3.2. Inflow Model of CBPS

CBPS specifies that the contribution base is an individual’s average wage in the previous year. However, if a person’s wage exceeds 300% of the social average wage, the contribution base is restricted to 300% of the social average wage, and if a person’s wage is less than 60% of the social average wage, the contribution base is restricted to 60% of the social average wage. In addition, we assume that there is no difference in wages for people at the same age. The individual contributes λ (8%) of the contribution base to the private account, while the employer contributes η (20%) of the base to the public account. Therefore, the cash inflows for the public account T I N t and the private account P I N t at period t are:
T I N t = x = x s x = x f ( η B x + t t · L A x l · p t x l l ) + x = x s x = x f ( η B x + t t · L A x s · p t x s l ) + k = 1 t ( η B c + t s t N L A c ( k ) · p t k c l l )
P I N t = x = x s x = x f ( λ B x + t t · L A x l · p t x l l ) + x = x s x = x f ( λ B x + t t · L A x s · p t x s l ) + k = 1 t ( λ B c + t s t N L A c ( k ) · p t k c l l )
respectively, where B x t is the contribution base of an x-year-old contributor at period t.
Either T I N t or P I N t contains three parts. The first part of the inflow is contributed by those who are “normal” at the beginning and are “normal” at period t. The second part is contributed by those who are “break-off” at the beginning and are “normal” at period t. The third part is contributed by those who entered in CBPS from period 1 to period t and are “normal” at period t.

3.3. Expenditure Model of CBPS

CBPS specifies that the expenditure of the private account includes individual pensions and unfinished amounts in the plan-month, and the expenditure of the public account includes the public pension, individual pension out of the plan-month, and the funeral favor, a bonus covering the funeral expenses of retirees. The structure of expenditures is shown in Figure 2.
In addition, the retirees at period t come from three groups of people:
  • Type I: those retired at period 0;
  • Type II: those employed at period 0;
  • Type III: those who will join CBPS from period 1 to period t.

3.3.1. Expenditure Models for Type I

For participants in type I, their benefits at period 0 have already been determined. Therefore, we take the living status and the growth rate of public pension into consideration. The expenditures of the private account and public account for type I are as follows.
P R C t = y = y s y f [ q t y r r · A V P y · ( 1 I { t > G y } ) + q t 1 y r r q y + t 1 r d · A V P y · max ( G y t , 0 ) ] · L R y
T R C t = y = y s y f [ q t y r r · A V B y · s = 1 t ( 1 + α s ) + q t 1 y r r q y + t 1 r d · D · s = 1 t ( 1 + β s ) + q t y r r · A V P y · I { t > G y } ] · L R y
where q t y r r denotes the survival probability of retirees from y years old to y + t years old, A V P y and A V B y are the average individual pension and public pension of y-year-old participants at period 0, respectively, I { · } is the indicator function, G y is the average remaining years in the planned period, α t denotes the growth rate of the public pension at period t, D is the funeral favor, and β t is the growth rate of the funeral favor at period t.

3.3.2. Expenditure Models for Type II

Among participants in type I, the benefits are partially determined by their contribution history but still depend on their contributions in the future. Therefore, we must forecast their benefits on the basis of assumptions regarding their wages and status. Before that, we will review the rules of CPBS. CPBS specifies that the individual pension equals the accumulated amount of an individual’s private account divided by the length of the planned period, which is set by the government, i.e.,
  • Individual pension = accumulated amount of private account/length of planned period
  • In addition, the public pension is calculated as follows:
  • Public pension = (years of contribution/100) × …
  • (Average wage of individual contribution + average wage of all employees)/2
With these specifications, the expenditures of the private account and public account for type II are as follows:
P L C t = i = l , s { x = x s x = x f [ L A x i · t r = 1 t P ( R x i = t r ) P L C x t , t r , i + L A x i · P ( T x i = t ) P A x t , i ] }
T L C t = i = l , s { x = x s x = x f [ L A x i · t r = 1 t P ( R x i = t r ) T L C x t , t r , i ] }
where P ( R x i = t r ) is the probability that an i-status x-year-old individual retires at period t r , P ( T x i = t ) is the probability that an i-status x-year-old individual dies at period t , P L C x t , t r , i and T L C x t , t r , i are the expenditures at period t of the private account and public account for an i-status x-year-old individual who retires at period t r , and P A x t , i is the accumulated amount in the private account for an i-status x-year-old individual at period t. P L C x t , t r , i is calculated by
P L C x t , t r , i = q t t r x + t r r r P L C x t r , i ( 1 I { t t r g ( x + t r ) } ) + q t 1 x + t r r r q x + t r + t 1 r d P A S x t , t r , i
P L C x t r , i = k = 0 t r ( 1 + r ) t r k λ B x + k k p k x i l + P A Y x i ( 1 + r ) t r g ( x + t r )
P A S x t , t r , i = P L C x t r , i max ( g ( x + t r ) ( t t r ) , 0 )
where P L C x t r , i is the individual pension of an i-status x-year-old individual who retires at period t r , g ( x + t r ) is the length of the planned period for those who retired at age x + t r , P A Y x i is the accumulated amount at period 0 of an i-status x-year-old individual, and P A S x t , t r , i is the unfinished amount at period t for an individual account of an i-status x-year-old individual who retires at period t r .
T L C x t , t r , i is calculated by
T L C x t , t r , i = q t t r x + t r r r · T L C x t r , i · s = t r t ( 1 + α s ) + q t 1 x + t r r r q x + t r + t 1 r d · D · s = 1 t ( 1 + β s ) + q t t r x + t r r r · P L C x t r , i · I { t t r g ( x + t r ) }
T L C x t r , i = W ¯ t r 1 × z x e q u , i × n x e q u , i × 1 % + W ¯ t r 1 × z x r e a l 92 98 , i × n x r e a l 92 98 , i × 1 % + 1 % × 0.5 ( W ¯ t r 1 + W ¯ t r 1 × ( z x r e a l 99 08 , i + E Z x r e a l 09 16 , i + E Z x r e a l 17 t r , i ) × ( n x r e a l 99 08 , i + E N x r e a l 09 16 r , i + E N x r e a l 17 t r , i )
where T L C x t r , i is the public pension of an i-status x-year-old individual who retires at period t r and Equation (15) is the calculation of T L C x t r , i .
P A x t , i is calculated by
P A x t , i = k = 0 t ( 1 + r ) t k λ B x + k k p k x i l

3.3.3. Expenditure Models for Type III

The expenditure models for new participants (type III) are similar to those for type II, except that the participants are aged c at period s instead of x at period 0. Therefore, we omit the explanations for these formulas. The expenditures of the private account and public account for type III are as follows.
P L N C t = s = 1 t [ N L A c ( s ) · t r = s t P ( R c ( s ) = t r ) P L C c t , t r ( s ) + N L A c ( s ) · P ( T c d ( s ) = t ) P A c t ( s ) ]
T L N C t = s = 1 t [ N L A c ( s ) · t r = s t P ( R c ( s ) = t r ) T L C c t , t r ( s ) ]
where
P L C c t , t r ( s ) = q t t r c + t r s r r P L C c t r ( s ) ( 1 I { t t r g ( x + t r ) } ) + q t 1 c + t r s r r q c + t r s + t 1 r d P A S c t ( s )
P L C c t r ( s ) = k = s t r ( 1 + r ) t k λ B c + k k p k s c l l g ( c + t r s )
P A S c t ( s ) = P L C c t r ( s ) max ( g ( c + t r s ) ( t t r ) , 0 )
P A c t ( s ) = k = s t ( 1 + r ) t k λ B c + k k p t s c l l
and
T L C c t , t r ( s ) = q t t r c + t r s r r · T L C c t r ( s ) · m = t r t ( 1 + α m )
T L C c t r ( s ) = 1 % × 0.5 ( W ¯ t r 1 + W ¯ t r 1 × E Z x r e a l s t r ) × E N x r e a l 09 t r

3.4. Balance Model of CBPS

With the population model, inflow model, and expenditure model, the balance models at period t for private account and public account are
T B t = T I N t T R C t T L C t T L N C t
T P t = P I N t P R C t P L C t P L N C t

4. Calibration

4.1. Participants in the Future

The population structure in the future depends on the population structure at period 0 and the mortality and fertility rates. Let L y t denote the population of y-year-old people at period t. Then, L 0 t + 1 = n t y L y t and L y + 1 t + 1 = L y t · p y , where n t is the fertility rate of the total population, and p y is the probability of an individual y years old surviving to y + 1 years old. Therefore, we must estimate the population structure at period 0 and the mortality and fertility rates.
We calculate the population structure at period 0, { L y 0 } , according to the tabulation of the 2010 Population Census of China.
We must estimate a national life table because one is not currently available. According to the China Life Insurance Mortality Table (2010–2013) and the actual population and fertility rate issued by the China National Bureau of Statistics, the actual mortality rate is 1.2 times that in Table 1, China Life Insurance Mortality Table (2010–2013). The comparison of the actual population and the estimated population is shown in Table 1.
Estimating the fertility rate in the future in China is highly difficult. The one-child policy was issued in 1978, and couples were allowed to have only one child. However, the policy was ended in 2016, and a new policy allows couples to have two children. The reform of the one-child policy has attracted great interest. At the beginning of the new policy, many studies claimed that the total fertility rate would increase rapidly in the short term, e.g., [22,23]. However, those expectations did not come true. According to data from China National Bureau of Statistics, the total fertility rate was 1.094, which is the lowest in the history of China. In this study, we sought to examine the impact of the increasing population on the sustainability of CBPS. Therefore, we assume that the fertility rate will increase in the short term and then decline in the long term. According to the data from a population sample survey released by the National Bureau of Statistics, we assume a fertility rate of 1.4 from 2019 to 2022 and 1.25 after 2022.
With these assumptions, the population will increase first and then decrease after the 2038 peak, as shown in Figure 3.
As described before, only employees participate in CBPS, and the populations who join in CBPS must be estimated.
Step 1: estimating the structure of populations that have already joined CBPS. We obtained the number of contributors and retirees from the China Labor Statistical Yearbook 2018. From the unpublished social security database of Beijing, we obtained the proportions of participants of all ages. Then, we estimated the number of participants of all ages in China, which are L A x i and L R y at period 0.
Step 2: estimating the numbers of new participants in all periods. We assumed that the number of new participants is the product of the new workforce, urbanization rate, and employment rate. The numbers of the new workforce come from the population in China. According to the China National Population Development Plan (2016–2030), the urbanization rate in 2030 will be 70%. Given that the urbanization rate in 2018 was 58.52%, we assume that the urbanization rate will increase 1% per year from 2019 to 2030 and then remain unchanged after 2030. In addition, the unemployment rate in China was between 4% and 4.3% from 2002, according to the China National Bureau of Statistics. Thus, we assume that the unemployment rate in the future will be 4.14%, and the employment rate will be 95.86%.
Step 3: estimating the transition probability matrix. We collected the unpublished social security database of Beijing, stratified the data by age and status, and then estimated the probabilities (Appendix A).

4.2. Wages

Following [24], we assume the following rules for wages:
  • W x + t t = W x t e x + t . The human capital e x + t determines the difference in wages of individuals who are x years old and x + t years old in the same period.
  • W y t = W y t 1 ( 1 + ε ) . The wages of individuals of the same age increase ε per year.
Therefore, we have W x + t t = W x 0 e x + t ( 1 + ε ) t , where e x + t and ε will be estimated.
According to the unpublished social security database of Beijing, we calculated the average wages for all ages and then obtained e x + t , which is shown in Figure 4.
The average growth rate of wages ε reached to 13.83% during 2000–2014. However, the subsequent growth rate will not be as high because of the decline of economic growth in China. According to [2], we assume that ε = 7.7 % for 2018–2020, ε = 6.6 % for 2021–2025, and ε = 5.7 % for 2026–2068.

4.3. Parameters in CBPS

We assume that the age of the youngest employees is 21, and the maximum age of retirees is 100, according to the social security database of Beijing. CBPS specifies an individual contribution rate of 8% and an employer contribution rate of 20% (the employer contribution rate has been decreased to 16% to reduce the employer’s burden and promote the development of the private sector in China. However, the policy is temporary because of the large CBPS gap. Therefore, we still assume 20% but perform a sensitivity test for the parameter.). The length of the planned period depends on the age at which the participant retires; for example, the length of the planned period for an individual retiring at 60 years is 139 months (approximately 12 years). Appendix B shows the relationship between the length of the planned period and age.
Official documents regulated the interest rate of the private account in 2017, and the interest rate was above 8%. We assume an interest rate of 8.13% after 2017, according the Annual Report of National Council of Social Security Funds. Before 2017, the money in the private account was embezzled. The return of the private account was not recovered and for bookkeeping purposes was considered to have accrued at the lowest interest rate. Therefore, we assume that the interest rate was 2.84% before 2017.
The public pension increases every year after individuals retire. The increases are a bonus to retirees to ensure that the standard of living of retirees is not affected by inflation. However, the growth rate of the public pension was much higher than the inflation rate during 2006–2015, reaching 10% per year. However, the growth rate began to fall in 2016 and was 6.5%, 5.5%, 5%, and 5% in 2016, 2017, 2018, and 2019, respectively. Therefore, we assume a 5% future growth rate.
The funeral favor, another bonus, differs among provinces. For example, the funeral favor is 5000 CNY in Beijing and four times the average wage in Chengdu. According to [25], we assume that the funeral favor is 60% of the national average wage.
All parameter values are shown in Table 2.

5. Model Testing and Policy Analysis

5.1. Model Testing

We used the data from 2009 to 2017 to test our model to ensure that the model, parameters, and codes are correct. The comparison of the actual data and simulated data is shown in Table 3.
Table 3 shows that our model fits CBPS well. The error rate of income is 4.62% and that of expenditure is 4.19%. Our model appears to be reliable.

5.2. Forecasting

Taking 2017 as period 0, we predict the income and expenditure of CBPS from 2018 to 2058. The results are shown in Table 4.
Table 4 shows that the contributions are less than the benefits every year from 2018, and CBPS is unsustainable if there are no reforms or external transfers. In addition, the gap grows in the future.
As there is a positive accumulated balance at the end of 2017, the accumulated balance will not become negative in 2018. The accumulated balances from 2018 to 2028 are shown in Table 5.
Table 5 shows that the accumulated balance of CBPS will become negative in 2022, and the deficit is 76.9 billion CNY. Subsequently, the deficits grow, reaching 24,073.2 billion CNY in 2028, which is 27% of the GDP in 2018.

5.3. Policy Analysis

5.3.1. The Decline in Employer Contribution Rate

As described before, the government decreased the employer contribution rate from 20% to 16% in 2019, to ease employer burden and promote economic growth. However, this change is not beneficial for the unsustainable CBPS. There is no doubt that the deficits will become larger than before. The results are shown in Figure 5.
As expected, the deficits grow. Owing to the decrease in the employer contribution rate from 20% to 16%, the time at which the accumulated balance will become negative becomes 2021 instead of 2022. In addition, the deficit will be 1192.8 billion CNY, instead of 76.9 billion CNY.
However, the impact of the decline in the employer contribution rate may be substantial. The decline will increase employer profit and then increase the wages and employment rate, which in turn, will increase the income of CBPS. However, this topic is beyond the scope of our article.

5.3.2. The End of One-Child Policy

China is getting older faster than anywhere else worldwide. Ending the one-child policy was one measure taken to alleviate the aging problem. Simultaneously, an increase in fertility rate will also enhance the sustainability of CBPS, according to the experience of other countries. Here, we study the impact of ending the one-child policy on the sustainability of CBPS.
We examine three situations:
  • High fertility rate: 2 from 2019 to 2022 and 1.8 after 2022.
  • Moderate fertility rate (baseline situation): 1.4 from 2019 to 2022 and 1.25 after 2022.
  • Low fertility rate: 1.4 from 2019 to 2022 and 1.1 after 2022.
Changes in fertility will affect the income and expenditure of CBPS for more than 100 years. Therefore, we must extend the prediction period from 2018–2057 to 2018–2107. The results are shown in Figure 6.
Figure 6 shows that fertility rate have no effects in the short term because the new generation does not participate in CBPS until 2038. After these individuals are employed and contribute to CBPS during 2038–2078, the income will increase, and the gap between expenditure and income will decrease if the fertility rate increases. Therefore, the increase in fertility rate will also enhance the sustainability of CBPS in the short to medium term.
However, Figure 6 shows that the sustainability will substantially decrease when the new generation retires. This conclusion is contrary to those of many other researchers, who have claimed that the increase in fertility rate will enhance the sustainability of CBPS at all times, e.g., [6]. The reason for this discrepancy is that CBPS is not actuarially balanced. In other words, every participant receives more than his/her contributions, as shown in Table 6. Therefore, CBPS has a greater deficit if there are more participants.
In conclusion, ending the one-child policy may enhance the sustainability of CBPS in the short to medium term but will erode the sustainability of CBPS in the long term.

5.3.3. The Increase in Retirement Age

Raising the retirement age is another way to enhance the sustainability of the pension system. China also issued a delayed retirement policy specifying that the retirement age will increase 1 year every 2 years, and the final compulsory age will be 65 for men and 60 for women. We consider the policy as the experimental group and the baseline situation as the control group. The results are shown in Figure 7.
Figure 7 shows that the income will increase because individuals will contribute longer if the retirement ages are increased. However, the change in expenditure is slightly more than we expected. We expected that the expenditure would decrease if the retirement age increased. Although this is true in most years, the expenditure increases between 2049 and 2055, although the gap decreases in all years because of delayed retirement.
We sought to determine why the expenditure increases between 2049 and 2055. Taking a male participant who enters the system in 2018 as an example, we calculated the actuarial present value of his total contributions and benefits with different retirement ages. The results are shown in Figure 8. Although delayed retirement results in a delay in pension payment for part of the working staff, the amount of pension payment for this part of the insured staff will increase in the future, thus potentially leading to an increase in the total amount of pension funds paid in the future, and in contrast, increasing the pressure on pension funds to pay.

5.3.4. Comprehensive Analysis

There are interactions if the above policies are simultaneously affected. Therefore, we comprehensively analyzed the effects of the decline in employer contribution rate, the end of the one-child policy, and the increase in retirement age. The results are shown in Figure 9.
Figure 9 shows that the income will increase if all policies go into effect simultaneously. There will be many more participants because of the ending of the one-child policy. All participants will contribute for longer times because of delayed retirement. Although the income will decrease because of the decline in the employer contribution rate, it will be offset by the increases resulting from the other two policies.
However, the change in expenditure is not consistent. The impacts on expenditure of ending the one-child policy and increasing the retirement age are opposite. Moreover, the decline in the employer contribution rate does not affect the expenditure. Therefore, the expenditure will decrease because of fewer participants, whereas the expenditure will increase when the population exceeds a threshold, which will occur in 2078.
The changes in income and expenditure determine the gap. Our results show that the gap will shrink before 2088 and subsequently increase rapidly.

6. Conclusions

This article describes CBPS and discusses the effectiveness of reforms on its sustainability. It provides a description of the pension system in China. In addition, a Markov actuarial model, which had not previously been developed for China, was established and verified for CBPS.
This article found that: (1) The contributions are less than the benefits every year from 2018, and the accumulated balance will be negative from 2022. (2) Ending the one-child policy may enhance the sustainability of CBPS in the short to medium term but will erode the sustainability of CBPS in the long term. (3) Raising the retirement age will shrink the gap of CBPS although the expenditure increases in a certain period. (4) Comprehensively, the gap will shrink before 2088 and subsequently increase rapidly if all of the policies are implemented.
From the above results, we believe that CBPS will not be sustainable in the long term if there are no subsidies or other financial transfers, even with delayed retirement and the increase in fertility. Moreover, the rise in fertility will shrink the gap of CBPS in the medium to short term but will increase the gap in the long term. In addition, raising the retirement age may not help, because the benefits depend on the length of contributions. It is the system itself that is not sustainable. In other words, the system is not actuarially balanced, by giving everyone extra money. Therefore, thorough reform is necessary to make the system self-financed, such as the methods to calculate the benefits of the public and private account.
There are two limitations of the article. Firstly, there are a lot of parameters and assumptions when forecasting the future cashflows of CBPS. Because of the uncertainties in future, the actual parameters and assumptions may be different with the settings in the paper. Secondly, the implementation of some reforms will not only directly affect the sustainability of CBPS but also have indirect impacts by changing macroeconomic variables. It is an interesting topic for future works. In addition, our model can also be applied to projecting the cashflows of other pension systems.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, resources, and writing—original raft preparation, P.L.; investigation, data curation, H.S.; writing—review and editing, D.P. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by China National Social Science Fund, grant number 17CSH018, and Program for Innovation Research in Central University of Finance and Economics.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. The transition probability matrix of contributors.
Table A1. The transition probability matrix of contributors.
Agelllslrldslsssrsd
210.854630.145270.000000.000100.757940.240430.000000.00163
220.877590.122320.000000.000090.782860.215650.000000.00149
230.880400.119520.000000.000080.776700.221530.000000.00177
240.869350.130540.000000.000110.739360.258170.000000.00247
250.860490.139400.000000.000110.698700.298150.000000.00315
260.861770.138100.000000.000130.642150.353400.000000.00445
270.867050.132820.000000.000130.590160.403700.000010.00613
280.876790.123040.000000.000160.551090.440930.000000.00798
290.881090.118740.000010.000170.526660.465340.000040.00796
300.888770.111020.000000.000210.509920.482110.000000.00797
310.895590.104210.000020.000180.498170.493610.000080.00814
320.902430.097390.000020.000160.496030.493780.000080.01010
330.908650.091060.000050.000230.503050.485580.000210.01116
340.916900.082780.000120.000190.497490.489790.000490.01222
350.925980.073610.000110.000300.502500.483560.000470.01347
360.931140.068320.000220.000320.493640.489950.001000.01542
370.936250.063160.000250.000340.496800.484320.001160.01772
380.939060.060150.000370.000410.499650.477970.001790.02059
390.940390.058640.000500.000470.495560.479920.002610.02191
400.933090.065740.000680.000490.493820.479410.003600.02316
410.938500.060110.000820.000570.509500.462980.004450.02307
420.940050.058200.001130.000620.509800.458160.006250.02579
430.937810.060390.001200.000600.507340.454190.007260.03121
440.934270.063330.001570.000830.481470.468660.010780.03910
450.833490.072780.092730.000990.276210.275160.422430.02619
460.913940.060670.024380.001010.405220.392190.159310.04328
470.930320.061330.007240.001120.451300.436570.056950.05517
480.939770.053640.005400.001190.450800.440980.044250.06396
490.940590.053730.003940.001750.436470.460800.034960.06777
500.651880.058000.288440.001670.096610.124110.757410.02187
510.905940.064680.027520.001860.319750.416710.185880.07767
520.927730.061630.008790.001840.343890.497630.065970.09250
530.928940.060800.007890.002370.320100.516060.063320.10052
540.918430.072750.006670.002150.306720.535970.056900.10040
550.509850.054350.433900.001890.052140.091470.832710.02368
560.844290.052710.100770.002230.193730.294320.423430.08851
570.920970.048980.026840.003220.261670.438470.163130.13673
580.944140.036710.015980.003170.252100.500300.108680.13892
590.946200.040170.009690.003940.240760.532570.073140.15352
600.031960.043420.921530.003100.006170.047150.927280.01940
610.172450.182530.641660.003360.030690.357780.428890.18263
620.530000.145000.320000.005000.034880.630810.093020.24128
630.581820.118180.300000.000000.037950.642860.073660.24554
640.555560.138890.305560.000000.026090.743480.095650.13478
650.000000.000001.000000.000000.000000.000001.000000.00000
“l”, “s”, “r”, “d” denote “Normal”, “Break-off”, “Retirement” and “Dead”, respectively. And “ij” denotes the 1-year transition probability from state i to state j. For example, “ll” denotes the the 1-year transition probability from Normal to state Normal.
Table A2. The transition probability matrix of retirees.
Table A2. The transition probability matrix of retirees.
AgerrrdAgerrrd
410.975750.02425710.968060.03194
420.988300.01170720.963100.03690
430.982090.01791730.956970.04303
440.977020.02298740.953180.04682
450.995740.00426750.947760.05224
460.995250.00475760.942790.05721
470.993950.00605770.938710.06129
480.994970.00503780.931380.06862
490.993200.00680790.921540.07846
500.997220.00278800.910880.08912
510.995330.00467810.905270.09473
520.995190.00481820.897490.10251
530.995430.00457830.882680.11732
540.994360.00564840.865530.13447
550.995080.00492850.857740.14226
560.993100.00690860.837060.16294
570.992230.00777870.819140.18086
580.991530.00847880.799040.20096
590.990920.00908890.788320.21168
600.991630.00837900.775970.22403
610.989480.01052910.733680.26632
620.987790.01221920.714700.28530
630.985770.01423930.714480.28552
640.984970.01503940.683110.31689
650.983560.01644950.676880.32312
660.981340.01866960.655870.34413
670.979790.02021970.701860.29814
680.975930.02407980.568420.43158
690.975660.02434990.464290.53571
700.970870.029131000.000001.00000
“l”, “s”, “r”, “d” denote “Normal”, “Break-off”, “Retirement” and “Dead”, respectively. And “ij” denotes the 1-year transition probability from state i to state j. For example, “ll” denotes the the 1-year transition probability from Normal to state Normal.

Appendix B

Table A3. The relationship of the length of planned period and the age.
Table A3. The relationship of the length of planned period and the age.
Retirement AgeThe Length of Planned
Period (in Months)
Retirement AgeThe Length of Planned
Period (in Months)
4023353180
4123054175
4222655174
4322356164
4422057158
4521658152
4621259145
4720860139
4820461132
4919962125
5019563117
5119564109
5218565101

References

  1. McCarthy, F.D.; Zheng, K. Population aging and Pension Systems: Reform Options for China (May 1996). Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=636131 (accessed on 4 September 2020).
  2. Yang, Z.; Shi, C. Financial burden on pensions for employees in urban enterprises in China. Econ. Sci. 2016, 2, 42–52. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  3. Zheng, S.; Liao, P. Actuarial model for urban public pension fund in China. Syst. Eng. Theory Pract. 2017, 31, 10–17. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  4. Yu, H.; Shen, H. Analysis on the sustainability of China’s basic pension fund. In Proceedings of the 2011 2nd International Conference on Artificial Intelligence, Management Science and Electronic Commerce (AIMSEC), Zhengzhou, China, 8–10 August 2011; pp. 6553–6556. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Sun, L.; Su, C.; Xian, X. Assessing the Sustainability of China’s Basic Pension Funding for Urban and Rural Residents. Sustainability 2020, 12, 2833. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Zeng, Y.; Zhang, X.; Liu, L. From “selective two-child policy” to universal two-child policy: Will the payment crisis of China’s Pension System be solved? China Financ. Econ. Rev. 2017, 5, 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Fan, R. The Path to Select Chinese Progressive Delay Retirement Age Policy. Stud. Asian Soc. Sci. 2015, 2, 19–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Aaron, H. The social insurance paradox. Can. J. Econ. Political Sci. 1966, 33, 371–374. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Corbo, V. Policy challenges of population aging and pension systems in Latin America. Proc. Econ. Policy Symp. Jackson 2004, Aug, 257–280. [Google Scholar]
  10. Sin, Y. China: Pension Liabilities and Reform Options for Old Age Insurance; The World Bank Working Paper; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  11. Grech, A.G. Assessing the sustainability of pension reforms in Europe. J. Int. Comp. Soc. Policy 2013, 29, 143–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Verbič, M.; Majcen, B.; Nieuwkoop, R.V. Sustainability of the Slovenian Pension System: An analysis with an overlapping generations general equilibrium model. East. Eur. Econ. 2006, 44, 60–81. [Google Scholar]
  13. Barr, N.; Diamond, P. The economics of pensions. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 2006, 22, 15–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Samwick, A.A. New evidence on pensions, social security, and the timing of retirement. J. Public Econ. 1998, 70, 207–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Breyer, F.; Hupfeld, S. On the fairness of early retirement provisions. Ger. Econ. Rev. 2010, 11, 60–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Fehr, H.; Kallweit, M.; Kindermann, F. Pension reform with variable retirement age: A simulation analysis for Germany. J. Pension Econ. Financ. 2012, 11, 389–417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Conde-Ruiz, J.I.; Giménez, E.L.; Pérez-Nievas, M. Endogenous fertility-pension programs and intergenerational welfare. In Modeling and Control of Economic Systems 2001; Neck, R., Ed.; Elsevier Science: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2003; pp. 157–161. [Google Scholar]
  18. Serrano, F.; Eguía, B.; Ferreiro, J. Public pensions’ sustainability and population ageing: Is immigration the solution? Int. Labour Rev. 2011, 150, 63–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Zhao, Y.; Bai, M. Stressing testing the transition debt of pension plan in China. J. Quant. Tech. Econ. 2018, 4, 80–96. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  20. Han, J.; Meng, Y. Decreased contribution rates increase public pension fund revenue: Evidence from China. J. Aging Soc. Policy 2019, 1–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Chen, X.; Yang, Z. Stochastically Assessing the Financial Sustainability of Individual Accounts in the Urban Enterprise Employees’ Pension Plan in China. Sustainability 2019, 11, 3568. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Zhai, Z.; Zhang, X.; Jin, Y. Demographic consequences of an immediate transition to a universal two-child policy. Popul. Res. 2014, 38, 3–17. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  23. Qi, M.; Dai, M.; Zheng, Y. Discuss the impact and tendency of the universal two-child policy on China’s birth rate fluctuation. China Popul. Resour. Environ. 2016, 9, 1–10. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  24. Kulish, M.; Kent, C.; Smith, K. Aging, retirement, and savings: A general equilibrium analysis. BE J. Macroecon. 2010, 10, 1–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Liao, P. Does China’s social pension system enhance the participants’ welfare? J. World Econ. 2016, 11, 147–171. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Markov model for contributors and retirees.
Figure 1. Markov model for contributors and retirees.
Sustainability 12 08172 g001
Figure 2. The expenditure structure of China’s Basic Pension System (CBPS).
Figure 2. The expenditure structure of China’s Basic Pension System (CBPS).
Sustainability 12 08172 g002
Figure 3. The future population in China. (a) The population in China (2018–2058). (b) The population structure in China (2038).
Figure 3. The future population in China. (a) The population in China (2018–2058). (b) The population structure in China (2038).
Sustainability 12 08172 g003
Figure 4. Human capital for all ages ( e x = 1 ).
Figure 4. Human capital for all ages ( e x = 1 ).
Sustainability 12 08172 g004
Figure 5. Accumulated balance when the employer contribution rate is decreased to 16%.
Figure 5. Accumulated balance when the employer contribution rate is decreased to 16%.
Sustainability 12 08172 g005
Figure 6. CBPS gap with different fertility rates (2018–2078).
Figure 6. CBPS gap with different fertility rates (2018–2078).
Sustainability 12 08172 g006
Figure 7. Income and expenditure of CBPS with different retirement ages. (a) The income of CBPS (2018–2068). (b) The expenditure of CBPS (2018–2068). (c) The gap of CBPS (2018–2068).
Figure 7. Income and expenditure of CBPS with different retirement ages. (a) The income of CBPS (2018–2068). (b) The expenditure of CBPS (2018–2068). (c) The gap of CBPS (2018–2068).
Sustainability 12 08172 g007aSustainability 12 08172 g007b
Figure 8. The actuarial present value of the benefits and contributions of a male participant who enters the system in 2018 with different retirement ages (assuming an interest rate of 7%).
Figure 8. The actuarial present value of the benefits and contributions of a male participant who enters the system in 2018 with different retirement ages (assuming an interest rate of 7%).
Sustainability 12 08172 g008
Figure 9. Income and expenditure of CBPS with reforms. (a) The income of CBPS (2018–2088). (b) The expenditure of CBPS (2018–2088). (c) The expenditure of CBPS (2018–2098).
Figure 9. Income and expenditure of CBPS with reforms. (a) The income of CBPS (2018–2088). (b) The expenditure of CBPS (2018–2088). (c) The expenditure of CBPS (2018–2098).
Sustainability 12 08172 g009
Table 1. Comparison of the actual population and estimated population in China from 2010 to 2018.
Table 1. Comparison of the actual population and estimated population in China from 2010 to 2018.
201020112012201320142015201620172018
Actual population13,40913,47413,54013,60713,67813,74613,82713,90113,954
Estimated population13,32813,40613,48213,56013,63213,71513,78813,83813,908
Accuracy rate99.4%99.5%99.6%99.7%99.7%99.8%99.7%99.6%99.7%
Table 2. Parameter values.
Table 2. Parameter values.
DescriptionValue
Mortality rate1.2 times the value in Table 1, China Life Insurance Mortality Table (2010–2013)
Fertility rateThe fertility rate is 1.4 from 2019 to 2022 and 1.25 after 2022
Population structure at period 0The tabulation on the 2010 Population Census of China
Urbanization rateThe urbanization rate in 2018 was 58.52%, which will increase 1% per year from 2019 to 2030 and then remain unchanged.
Unemployment rate4.14%
Average growth rate of wages7.7% for 2018–2020, 6.6% for 2021–2025, and 5.7% after 2025
Interest rate2.84% before 2017 and 8.13% after 2017
Funeral favor60% of the national average wage
Public pension growth rate5% after 2018
Table 3. Comparison of actual data and simulated data (2009–2017).
Table 3. Comparison of actual data and simulated data (2009–2017).
(0.1 Billion CNY)Actual
Income 1
Simulated
Income
RatioActual
Expenditure
Simulated
Expenditure
Ratio
20099534.010,924.7114.59%8894.48965.7100.80%
201011,110.012,211.2109.91%10,554.910,888.1103.20%
201113,956.014,199.8101.75%12,765.013,249.9103.80%
201216,467.016,184.898.29%15,561.816,049.5103.10%
201318,634.018,324.398.34%18,470.419,644.0106.40%
201420,434.020,844.6102.01%21,754.723,435.2107.70%
201523,016.023,617.4102.61%25,812.728,030.7108.60%
201626,768.027,158.3101.46%31,853.832,310.4101.40%
201733,403.031,453.294.16%38,051.537,027.497.30%
1 Data source: China Labor Statistical Yearbook 2018; the actual income does not contain the subsidies.
Table 4. Income and expenditure forecasting of CBPS (2018–2058).
Table 4. Income and expenditure forecasting of CBPS (2018–2058).
(0.1 Billion CNY)IncomeExpenditureGap in Single Year
201835,288.442,417.6−7129.2
202359,106.180,415.9−2,1309.8
202888,826.7152,188.6−6,3361.8
2033126,820.4274,725.0−147,904.7
2038177,121.9459,464.7−282,342.9
2043246,078.1729,378.4−483,300.3
2048336,225.51,076,058.5−739,833.0
2053452,095.01,534,990.1−1,082,895.1
2058617,958.42,093,026.2−1,475,067.9
Table 5. Accumulated balance of CBPS (2018–2028).
Table 5. Accumulated balance of CBPS (2018–2028).
Accumulated Balance (0.1 Billion CNY)
201840,323.2
201934,605.7
202026,469.1
202114,911.0
2022−769.2
2023−22,079.0
2024−49,565.3
2025−83,610.6
2026−125,697.6
2027−177,370.3
2028−240,732.2
Table 6. The actuarial present value of the benefits and contributions of a male participant who enters the system in 2018 (assuming an interest rate of 7%).
Table 6. The actuarial present value of the benefits and contributions of a male participant who enters the system in 2018 (assuming an interest rate of 7%).
Entry YearContributions (CNY)Benefits (CNY)
201861,71079,420

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Liao, P.; Su, H.; Pamučar, D. Will Ending the One-Child Policy and Raising the Retirement Age Enhance the Sustainability of China’s Basic Pension System? Sustainability 2020, 12, 8172. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12198172

AMA Style

Liao P, Su H, Pamučar D. Will Ending the One-Child Policy and Raising the Retirement Age Enhance the Sustainability of China’s Basic Pension System? Sustainability. 2020; 12(19):8172. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12198172

Chicago/Turabian Style

Liao, Pu, Hui Su, and Dragan Pamučar. 2020. "Will Ending the One-Child Policy and Raising the Retirement Age Enhance the Sustainability of China’s Basic Pension System?" Sustainability 12, no. 19: 8172. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12198172

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop