Next Article in Journal
Analysis of the Influence of Socio-Economic Factors on Occupational Safety in the Construction Industry
Next Article in Special Issue
Investigating the Impact of Critical Factors on Continuance Intention towards Cross-Border Shopping Websites
Previous Article in Journal
The Opportunities of Sustainable Biomass Ashes and Poultry Manure Recycling for Granulated Fertilizers
Previous Article in Special Issue
An Assessment of the Impact of Spatial Agglomeration on the Quality of China’s Wood Processing Industry Products
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

A Study of the Feasibility of International ETS Cooperation between Shanghai and Korea from Environmental Efficiency and CO2 Marginal Abatement Cost Perspectives

Global E-governance Program, Inha University, Inharo100, Nam-gu, Incheon 402-751, Korea
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2019, 11(16), 4468; https://doi.org/10.3390/su11164468
Submission received: 24 June 2019 / Revised: 10 August 2019 / Accepted: 15 August 2019 / Published: 18 August 2019

Abstract

:
With the worldwide spread of emissions trading schemes (ETSs) and the need for international cooperation on climate change, there is growing interest in linking ETSs. Along with sustainable development, preventing and controlling pollution, is now regarded as an urgent priority by China and Korea. In the context of the willingness of the Chinese and Korean governments to cooperate on ETS, this paper examines the feasibility of a pilot ETS cooperation between Shanghai and Korea from environmental efficiency and CO2 marginal abatement cost (MAC) perspectives. We apply a directional distance function (DDF) and stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) to estimate the environmental efficiency and the CO2 MAC of coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai and Korea using cross-sectional data from 2015. The results indicate that the group frontier environmental efficiency of Shanghai and Korea reached a similarly high score. However, as to meta-frontier environmental efficiency, the coal-fueled power plants in Korea performed better than those in Shanghai. The CO2 MAC results indicate that, despite the small gap in efficiency performance, the CO2 MAC of coal-fueled power plants is much higher than that in Shanghai due to the big feed-in tariff difference. This is because the MAC not only relates to the environmental efficiency, but also to the feed-in tariff. A higher feed-in tariff leads to higher MAC. To tackle this serious problem, which has also been addressed in previous studies, we suggest that policymakers should focus on the huge CO2 MAC differences caused by feed-in tariff differences to avoid equity problems when building the structure of the Shanghai-Korea ETS cooperation. For instance, compared with power plants in Shanghai, policymakers should set a looser cap and a higher offset for Korean plants. To reduce the impact of feed-in tariff on carbon trading in the market, it would also be effective to arrange a higher quota or a lower carbon tax for coal-fueled power plants in Korea. In addition, policymakers should fill the gaps of 85.15% and 67.6% between the realistic market price and the MAC results of coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai and Korea, respectively, by introducing stricter regulations.

1. Introduction

From 30 November to 12 December 2015, more than 180 countries of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) met in Paris to deal with greenhouse gas-emissions mitigation, adaptation, and finance in the 21st Conference of the Parties (COP21). As of March 2019, 195 members of the UNFCCC have signed the agreement, and 185 countries have become parties. The long-term goal of the Paris Agreement is to keep the rise in average global temperatures well below pre-industrial levels of 2 °C and to limit warming to 1.5 °C, as this will greatly reduce the risk and impacts of climate change.
As to whether the Paris Agreement will bring about positive results, relevant studies are still inconclusive, especially concerning the specific implementation of the agreement in various countries. On the one hand, some studies suggest that the signing of the agreement alone represents a political success [1,2,3]. On the other hand, some studies have argued that the agreement is incomplete in some respects, due to the lack of enforcement mechanisms and provisions to compensate for losses caused by extreme weather events [4,5].
Since the global atmosphere is a public interest, regardless of national boundaries, addressing climate change requires effective international cooperation that needs to be integrated into a combination of strategic policy tools that include command-and-control (regulatory) and market-based policies. Carbon pricing and trade has become the preferred policy tool for reducing greenhouse gases (GHG) in many developed countries, and developing countries have also considered this kind of mechanism.
The European Union’s emissions trading system, the first in the world, came into operation in 2005. After just 10 years, by 2015, 17 carbon trading systems have emerged around the world, covering 40% of the world’s total GDP.
With the worldwide spread of ETS and the need for international cooperation on climate change, there is growing interest in linking ETSs. From this perspective, although the Paris Agreement did not set the rules of international carbon trading, it laid a foundation for the establishment of a carbon trading market mechanism, especially through international cooperation. The linkage of international ETSs can not only reduce the total emissions reduction cost of a linkage system and increase market liquidity and carbon price stability, but also promotes the integration of a separate carbon market, which is a bottom-up way to establish a global carbon market [6].
In 2014, a joint auction between California and Quebec became the world’s first direct bilateral connection of ETSs, providing a good example for other regions to cooperate on carbon markets.
Under this climate strategy, there is an interaction of regional carbon regulations to reduce or eliminate the marginal cost differences between participants. The EU and Switzerland have signed an agreement to link their systems. Once the agreement has entered into force, linking would result in the mutual recognition of EU and Swiss emissions allowances. The EU and Australia have also considered the possibility of linking their systems. However, due to the repeal of the Australian system in 2014, linking negotiations have not been pursued [7]. In this way, a wider range of mitigation options can be obtained, thus improving overall efficiency [8,9]. International cooperation is expected to create a larger international market, which could increase market liquidity [10] and price stability [11].
There are different ways of cooperation through ETS at the international level. In a bilateral ETS connection, a carbon quota can be tradable between countries at a perfectly balanced price. If a country cannot reduce emissions at a lower cost, it can invest in new technologies for mitigation or buy an additional quota of emissions from another country that possesses a lower cost of emissions. Financial flows would go from the former country to the latter one that invests in emissions abatement technology [6].
Some factors may lead to technical barriers to the realization of international cooperation, including cap stringency, price management measure [12], and the recognition of offsets [8,13]. Cap stringency requirements, including cap setting, depend on the environmental and economic profile, or the level of development. In this sense, well-functioning cooperation also depends on how the strategy benefits the participants, without losing sight of the particularities, which include system compatibility, the nature of the system, and the existence of an absolute cap on emissions [14].
In order to solve economic and equity problems, comparable plans, climate policies, and long-term emissions trends should be considered, because these factors reflect the environmental plans and aggregate goals of the cooperation. Inadequate planning and unequal policies can lead to environmentally inefficient policies [8,15,16,17,18].
In principle, technical barriers do not include design scope, coverage, and other differences such as regulatory points and opt-in and opt-out provisions. In fact, two separate ETS markets cannot be identical in terms of different conditions [10,19]. Therefore, caution is necessary when linking two ETS markets from different sectors because it may lead to competition.
In line with this, the choice of the right partner is also an important consideration in the coordination of climate issues. In most cases, the chosen partner depends on geographical proximity, legal compatibility, potential distributional effects, respective ETS elements, and other factors [20]. Both EU&Switzerland ETS and California&Quebec ETS serve as good benchmarks for other regions that plan to collaborate in ETS.
In September 2016, China’s national development and reform commission, Korea’s Ministry of Strategy and Finance, and Japan’s Ministry of the Environment held a meeting in Beijing and decided to hold a regular meeting on carbon emissions trading every year, through which they will discuss the establishment of a long-term unified market for carbon emissions trading and unified emissions testing methods, and seek a scheme for the exchange of carbon emissions among the three countries. As a more specific and substantive step, Korean ETS has signed a memorandum of understanding with China’s Beijing Environment Exchange. Under this agreement, China and Korea will exchange market information and share experience on ETS operations. They agreed to expand cooperation on ETS, including joint efforts to link ETS in these two countries. ETS cooperation between these two countries can be expected in the future.
The intense interest in ETS cooperation between China and Korea, in addition to the geographical proximity, is mainly due to their large international trade volume. Korea’s carbon market is the first ETS among developing countries, while China is the world’s largest carbon trading market. Both the China ETS and the Korea ETS received technological and institutional support from the EU ETS, which provided the favorable conditions for compatibility between these two ETS markets [7].
China is the second-largest economy and the country with the largest population in the world. It is also the largest emitter of carbon dioxide, accounting for 27% of the world’s emissions. In order to fulfill its commitment to the Paris Agreement and improve the environment, China has set a target of reducing its carbon dioxide emissions by 60–65% (from the 2005 levels) by 2030. As a stepwise measure, China set up seven pilot carbon markets in 2011, including five cities of Shanghai, Beijing, Tianjin, Chongqing, and Shenzhen, and two provinces of Guangdong and Hubei. Furthermore, in December 2017, China released a plan for a nationwide carbon emissions market, using the power generation industry as a pilot industry. Note that power generation, especially coal-fired power plants, accounts for 47% of China’s total coal consumption and 34% of its carbon dioxide emissions [21]. China has shown willingness to explore cooperation and docking of regional international ETS systems after the successful establishment of the nationwide ETS system. China has great potential to play a leading role in the international ETS market [6]. In July 2018, China and EU released the China-EU leaders’ statement on climate change and clean energy that will exchange experience and promote cooperation on ETS. In June 2017, Chinese government and the governor of California discussed the possibility of linking their ETS. Both sides promised that they would study and overcome the obstacles and complexities of the cooperation constantly. Similarly, China and Korea have exchanged in-depth views on ETS cooperation issues.
A neighbor of China, Korea is the 11th largest economy in the world, accounting for about 2.2% of the world’s total primary energy consumption in 2017, making it the eighth largest energy consumer in the world. In addition, Korea accounted for 2.3% of global coal consumption, ranking sixth in the world in 2017 [22]. In 2017, the CO2 emissions of Korea were 679.7 million tons, ranking fourth among the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) nations after the United States (5.0877 billion tons), Japan (1.1766 billion tons), and Germany (763.8 million tons), and representing an increase of y 24.6% from the 2007 level. The speed of CO2 emissions increase of Korea ranked second among the OECD countries after Turkey’s (50.5%). According to the analysis, South Korea’s high dependence on coal is the main reason for its high carbon dioxide emissions, as well as the main cause of air pollution and haze [23]. In 2009, the Korean government enacted a “low-carbon green growth” national carbon emissions reduction policy. In 2015, Korean government passed a law requiring to reduce Korea’s carbon dioxide emissions by 37% below business as usual (BAU) levels by 2030. Moreover, in the same year as the Paris Agreement was signed, Korea formally launched a national ETS as a concrete measure to reduce CO2 emissions.
Due to the huge differences in economic scale, population size, economic development stage, and social and legal systems between China and Korea, it is unrealistic to pursue international ETS cooperation at a national level in the short term. Following China’s approach of establishing pilot regions and pilot industries in the development of a carbon market, China and Korea should conduct pilot international cooperation in areas of similar economic scale and development stage.
Shanghai is one of the pilot regions for a carbon trading market and the largest city in China. In addition, the national carbon market trading center of China was established in Shanghai because of its developed financial industry base, as well as its special status in China’s political and economic arena, and its good performance as a pilot carbon market. In terms of carbon market maturity, economic development level, and market size, Shanghai is closest to Korea, and thus the most appropriate region to cooperate with Korea on ETS. Moreover, given that the charcoal power industry plays the most important role in the carbon market in both China and Korea, the coal industry is the first choice for the regional cooperation pilot project.
As of 2015, there are systems operating in jurisdictions that vary largely in terms of their geographical scope, economic profile, and energy mix. Indeed, when it comes to ETS, there is no one-size-fits-all approach; rather, the variability and individuality of the ETS are the key to its success. As a pilot international ETS cooperation, the Shanghai-Korea ETS market should explore an adaptable mechanism.
Table 1 describes the transaction situation of the Shanghai and Korea ETSs in 2015 [24,25]. In terms of transaction sums, the Korea ETS is 19.32% higher than the Shanghai ETS, but in terms of transaction volume, the Shanghai ETS is about three times higher than the Korean ETS. Accordingly, in terms of average market price, the Korean ETS is about four times higher than the Shanghai ETS. Regardless of which ETS is being discussed, the power industry plays an important role in the dominant position, accounting for 50.2% and 48.8%, respectively, of total transaction volume. Note that in both Shanghai and Korea, although there are no separate transaction data on coal-fired power plants, they occupy an important position in the entire power generation industry, accounting for 67.9% and 42%, respectively, of the total power generation in 2016 [26].
Over the past two decades, many empirical studies have examined the efficiency and pollutant MAC of coal-fueled power plants in China and Korea, on account of the important global position of these two countries and the key role of coal-fueled power plants in the power industry [27,28,29,30,31,32].
In this paper, we make a contribution to the literature by extending the approach of previous studies. We introduce DDF and SFA, which not only seek to maximize desirable outputs while reducing undesirable outputs, but also can differentiate the inefficiencies and random errors. Moreover, we introduce Meta-frontier to solve group heterogeneity problems. Through environmental efficiency and pollutant MAC perspectives, we first attempt to make an analysis of the feasibility of the international ETS cooperation between China and Korea.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 summarizes the trend of the method to estimate efficiency and pollutants’ MAC and related studies on international ETS cooperation. Section 3 then describes the methodology. Section 4 uses the proposed approach to empirically analyze the environmental efficiency and pollutants’ MAC results and the feasibility of international ETS cooperation between China and Korea, and Section 5 concludes with some policy implications.

2. Literature Review

In the early stages of pollutants’ MAC studies, Aigner et al. and Schmidt estimated pollutants’ MAC by the deterministic production function [33,34]. Since then, Pollak et al. and Gollop et al. have begun to estimate pollutants’ MAC by the deterministic cost function [35,36]. After Pittman creatively estimated pollutants’ MAC by Shephard distance function, this kind of method based on distance function (DF) begun to be used broadly [37,38]. Compared with DF, the directional distance function (DDF) is a relatively new methodology for pollutants’ MAC or environmental efficiency estimation that seeks to maximize desirable outputs while simultaneously reducing undesirable outputs. For instance, Fare et al. estimated U.S. coal-fueled power plants’ efficiency performance. Zhang et al. estimated the CO2 emissions performance of Korean coal-fueled power plants. Both of them used DDF [30].
The approaches to solving distance functions include non-parametric methods and parametric methods. DEA is the most widely used non-parameter method and is a quantitative analysis method based on multiple inputs and output indexes, in which linear programming method is used to evaluate the relative efficiency among comparable units. The advantage of the DEA method is that it does not need to set a specific functional form for the underlying technology in advance [39]. By the DEA approach, Wang et al. measured the CO2 MACs for 28 Chinese provinces. Liu et al. measured the CO2 MACs for 30 Chinese provinces from 2005 to 2007, and Zhang et al. measured the CO2 MACs for 29 Chinese provinces from 2006 to 2010 [39,40,41]. However, the DEA method can only be applied when the function is differentiable everywhere. Moreover, there are different slopes of the efficient observation located on the frontier, and a different choice of slope will lead to different results [42].
The linear programming (LP) method is one of the parametric approaches to solve distance functions. By the LP approach, Du et al. measured the CO2 MACs for 29 Chinese provinces from 1995 to 2007 [43]. However, the LP method ignores random error and statistical noise [39].
In order to avoid the weaknesses of the DEA and LP approaches, we introduce the stochastic frontier approach (SFA). The SFA not only differentiates between inefficient parts and random error, but also considers statistical noise. For instance, Wei et al. estimated the CO2 MACs among China’s coal-fueled power plants by the SFA approach [44]. Choi and Qi estimated the MAC of 50 coal-fueled power plants in Korea by the SFA approach [45]. Table 2 summarizes some representative studies on MAC estimation in recent years.
Previous studies estimating the pollutants’ MAC or efficiency performance of power plants have focused on specific groups. However, if the group heterogeneity of coal-fuel power plants is not taken into account, the estimated efficiency score or MAC results may be biased as the heterogeneity may lead to differences in production techniques.
O’Donnell et al. indicated that efficiency under meta-frontier technology can be decomposed into group efficiency and meta-technology ratio (MTR). Group efficiency measures the relative efficiency of observation under specific group-frontier technology, while MTR (also known as the technology gap ratio) measures the distance between the group-frontier technology and the meta-frontier technology [46]. O’Donnell et al. pointed out that meta-frontier technology does not exceed group technology, so the meta-technology ratio is not greater than 1. The higher the meta-technology ratio, the closer the group frontier technology is to the meta-frontier technology. If the meta-frontier technology value equals1, there is no gap between the two technologies. That is, the two technologies overlap completely [47]. Following O’Donnell, we divided the coal-fueled power plants of Shanghai and Korea into two groups to solve the group heterogeneity problem.
The issue of international ETS cooperation has attracted an enormous amount of research, especially after the Paris Agreement. The EU ETS, the first international emissions trading system in the world, was set up in 2005. It is also the biggest one, accounting for over three-quarters of international carbon trading [48]. Therefore, most previous empirical studies focused on EU ETS. For instance, Chapman, Zetterberg, and Marschinski estimated the impact of the ETS cooperation between EU and USA [13,49]. They found that system stringency is a serious sticking point, as market realities will prevent offsets from stymieing linking negotiations. However, the opportunity should be seized by the USA to engage in massive efforts to take part in the EU’s firm stance on emissions reductions through tighter caps, less offset use, and a lower price ceiling. Marschinski et al. and Hubler et al. investigated a proposal for the cooperation between the EU ETS and the China ETS [50,51]. They revealed that linking the Chinese ETS to the European ETS and restricting the transfer volume to one-third of the EU’s reduction effort creates at best a small benefit for China, yet with smaller sectoral output reductions than auctioning. These results are evidence of the importance of designing the Chinese ETS wisely. By simulating autarky and linkage scenarios, Gavard et al. estimated a sectoral ETS on energy-intensive industries in the EU, the USA, and China [52]. They found that the limit results in different carbon prices between China and Europe or the USA. Although the impact on low-carbon technologies in China is moderate, global emissions reductions are more significant than in the absence of international trading due to reduced carbon leakage. If China captures the rents associated with limited permit trading, they show that it is possible to find a limit threshold that makes both regions better relative to carbon markets operating in isolation. In addition, Xu et al. implemented a different scenario analysis and simulated the establishing of a conceivable multi-region integrated emissions trading scheme with China, the USA, Europe, Australia, Japan, and South Korea by utilizing a computable general equilibrium model [53]. They found that the integration of ETS results in the redistribution of clean energy in the participating countries. In addition, it is worth noting that the multi-region integrated ETS would have significant impacts on the role each region plays in international trade, leading to an 11% decline in net exports for China in the MR scenario compared with the SR scenario. After summarizing the above previous studies, we find that, by optimizing the allocation of emissions permits, the integration of ETS will have complex economic and energy implications for different participants. For some countries, economic benefits are expected, while their expansion into the clean energy industry will slow down. On the other hand, such integration may also promote the development of clean energy in other countries, while adversely affecting their international competitiveness. It is worth noting that, before participants join the multi-regional comprehensive ETS mechanism, in addition to addressing political, institutional, and technical barriers, they need to clarify their roles and balance the interests of all participants.
To date, considering that they are important countries in terms of their economy and CO2 emissions, the international ETS cooperation between China and Korea has not attracted adequate attention in empirical studies. Therefore, we will fill this gap from environmental efficiency and pollutants’ MAC perspectives by the DDF and SFA methods; meanwhile, we will introduce a meta-frontier analysis to differentiate the group heterogeneity.

3. Methodology

According to Chung et al., the pollution problem in SFA can be expressed such that desirable outputs are often accompanied by undesirable outputs [54]. In our case, when a coal-fueled power plant produces electricity as a desirable output, CO2 will also be produced as an undesirable output. We assume that inputs are denoted as x R + N , with desirable outputs as y R + N and undesirable outputs as b R + N , so the meta-frontier can be defined by the output sets as follows:
S = { ( x , y , b ) : x   c a n   p r o d u c e   ( y , b ) } .
The meta-frontier S is defined as a boundary that envelopes all the observations, which describes how the input vector x can produce a set of desirable output and undesirable output (y, b).
Following Fare et al., we assume that the desirable output y and undesirable output b are produced jointly [55]. This assumption also satisfies the following three properties:
(i)
The desirable outputs and the undesirable outputs are null-joint. If (y, b) P(x) and b = 0 then y = 0, which indicates that the desirable and undesirable outputs are produced simultaneously; in other words, if there are no undesirable outputs, there will be no desirable outputs.
(ii)
If (y, b) P(x) and 0 ≤ θ ≤ 1 then (θy, θb) P(x), which indicates that the desirable and undesirable outputs are jointly produced under the weak disposability. In other words, if the undesirable outputs decrease, the desirable outputs will decrease proportionately and simultaneously. The reduction of undesirable outputs is costly.
(iii)
If x’ ≥ x then P(x’) P(x), which implies that the inputs and the outputs increase simultaneously, that is to say, the inputs represent strong disposability.
Then we can define the meta directional output distance function as
D ( x , y , b ; g y , g b ) = max { λ : ( y + λ g y , b λ g b ) S } ,
where g = (gy,gb) represents the directional vector. By this function, the desirable outputs can be expanded maximally on the direction gy while contracting the undesirable outputs on the direction gb. Additionally, here λ implies the technical cap between observations and the meta-frontier.
In our study, constrained by resources and regulatory or other environmental factors, coal-fueled power plants in China and Korea are divided into two groups due to the existence of sub-technology sets, where the group-frontier can be defined as
S k = { ( x , y , b ) : x   c a n   p r o d u c e ( y , b ) } , k = 1 , 2 .
Thus the kth group directional output distance function can be represented as:
D k ( x , y , b ; g y , g b ) = max { λ : ( y + λ g y , b λ g b ) S k } .
Furthermore, according to Zhang et al. and Du et al., we assume all group production sets belong to S, and define S = (S1∪S2), which is demonstrated in Figure 1 [30,32]. We assume that AB is the group environmental efficiency (GEE) measured by group frontier, and AC is the meta-frontier environmental efficiency (MEE), measured by the meta-frontier; BC is the meta-technology ratio (MTR) between the group frontier and the meta-frontier.
According to Bai et al. (2016), the aforementioned meta and group directional output distance function have five properties [56]:
(i)
D ( x , y , b , g ) 0     ( y , b ) S ( x ) , if the directional output distance is greater than 0, the observation is inefficient; if the observation is located on the frontier S(x), the directional distance value is 0.
(ii)
D ( x , y , b ; g ) D ( x , y , b ; g )   f o r   ( y , b ) ( y , b ) S ( x ) , if a power plant produces more desirable outputs and the same undesirable outputs with the same inputs, the inefficiency will not increase.
(iii)
D ( x , y , b ; g ) D ( x , y , b ; g )   f o r   ( y , b ) ( y , b ) S ( x ) , similarly if a power plant produces more undesirable outputs and the same desirable outputs with the same inputs, the inefficiency will not increase.
(iv)
D ( x , θ y , θ b ; g ) 0   f o r   ( y , b ) S ( x )   a n d   0 θ 1 . implies that the desirable outputs and the undesirable outputs are have joint weak disposability.
(v)
D ( x , y , b ; g ) is concave in ( y , b ) S ( x ) . This property determines the sign of the output elasticity of substitution.
Additionally, the meta-directional distance function satisfies the translation property below, which is convenient for calculation:
D 0 ( x , y + α g y , b α g b ; g ) = D 0 ( x , y , b ; g ) α .
On the production frontier, the inefficiency value is 0, so we set 0 as the dependent variable. We get the equation below if we put DDF into the SFA model:
0 = D 0 ( x , y , b , g ) + v u .
As for the meta-frontier, the concavity property should be satisfied. The concavity implies that, under fixed inputs, if the desirable outputs increase by αgy and the undesirable outputs decrease by αgb, then the value of the function will be reduced by α.
As depicted in Figure 1, there is a meta-technology ratio (MTR) between the meta-frontier inefficiency (AC) and group frontier inefficiency (AB) because the efficiency estimated by the meta directional output distance function is based on all groups.
M T R k = ( 1 D ( x k , y k , b k ; g ) ) / ( 1 D ( x k , y k , b k ; g ) )
The MTR measures the ratio of the environmental efficiency of a certain group stochastic function relative to the potential environmental efficiency that is defined by the meta-frontier function. The MTR implies the technology difference for the given group according to the currently available technology for power plants in that group, and can be expressed as follows:
M T R k = G E E k M E E .
To solve the SFA problems, we need a specific functional form. In our study, we estimate the directional output distance function by the quadratic functional, which satisfies the translation property. By expanding Equation (6), we get the equation below:
D 0 ( k i t , l i t , e i t , b i t ; g ) = β 0 + β k k i t + β e e i t + β y y i t + β c b i t + β k l k i t l i t + β k e k i t e i t + β k y k i t y i t + β k c k i t b i t + β l e l i t e i t + β l y l i t y i t + β l c l i t b i t + β e y e i t y i t + β e c e i t b i t + β y c y i t b i t + 1 2 β k k ( k i t ) 2 + 1 2 β l l ( l i t ) 2 + 1 2 β e e ( e i t ) 2 + 1 2 β y y ( y i t ) 2 + 1 2 β c c ( b i t ) 2 + v i + u i
By taking the undesirable output b as the dependent variable, we get the following equation:
b i = β 0 + β k k i + β l l i + β e e i + β y ( y i + b i ) + β k l k i l i + β k e k i e i + β k y k i ( y i + b i ) + β l e l i e i + β l y l i ( y i + b i ) + β e y e i ( y i + b i ) + 1 2 β k k ( k i ) 2 + 1 2 β l l ( l i ) 2 + 1 2 β e e ( e i ) 2 + 1 2 β y y ( y i + b i ) 2 + v i u i
β y β b = 1 , β y y = β b b = β y b , β k b = β k y , β l b = β l y , β e c = β e y ,
where y and b represent the desirable output (electricity) and the undesirable output (CO2 emissions), respectively. In addition, k, l, and e represent capital input, labor input, and energy input, respectively. g represents the direction vector, i = 1, 2, ..., N represents each power plant. vi represents the random errors and ui represents the inefficiency.
Following Fare et al. and Chung, we estimate the MACs of each power plants by the equation that follows [54,55]:
q i = p i D i ( k i , l i , e i , y i , b i ; 1 , 1 ) / b i D i ( k i , l i , e i , y i , b i ; 1 , 1 ) / y i ,
where qi represents the value of MACs and pi represents the feed-in tariff.
We get Equations (12) and (13) if we put the specific form of the directional distance function into Equation (11):
D i ( k i , l i , e i , y i , b i ; 1 , 1 ) b i = β b + β k b k i + β i b l i + β e b e i + β y b y i + β b b c i
D i ( k i , l i , e i , y i , b i ; 1 , 1 ) y i = β y + β k y k i + β l y l i + β e y e i + β y b c i + β y y y i .
Thus, the equation for estimating MAC can be denoted as:
q i = p i β b + β k b k i + β l b l i + β e b e i + β y b y i + β b b c i β y + β k y k i + β l y l i + β e y e i + β y b c i + β y y y i .
By calculating the coefficient value of each variable in the above equations, the environmental efficiency and emissions reduction cost of each power plant can be estimated.

4. Empirical Results

4.1. Data and Variables

As shown in Table 1, we selected 92 coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai and 53 coal-fueled power plants in Korea as our study sites. These cover all the coal-fueled power plants with an installed capacity above 10 MW in Shanghai and Korea. The data came from the Shanghai electric power corpus (2015) and the Korea Electric Power Corporation’s Statistics of Electric Power (2015) [21,57]. We used the installed capacity as capital input (k), the coal consumption as the energy input (e), the number of employed staff as the labor input (l); these were our three input variables. Additionally, we used each power plant’s gross electricity generation as the desirable output (y) and carbon dioxide emissions as the undesirable output (b); these were our two output variables. The data on electricity prices (P) are collected from the feed-in tariff of each coal-fired power plant of Shanghai and Korea in 2015.
However, there are no carbon dioxide emissions data available. Therefore, by following the criteria published on the website of the International Panel on Climate Change and the NRDC’s National Coordination Committee Office on Climate Change and Energy Research Institute, we calculated CO2 as follows [58]:
C O 2 = E × C F × C C × C O F × ( 44 / 12 )
where E indicates the amount of consumption of coal, CF indicates the transformation factor (tons of carbon/TCE), CC indicates the carbon content, and COF indicates the carbon oxidation factor, which estimates the percentage of actual carbon when combustion happens. The figure “44/12” indicates the ratio of the weight of one carbon atom combined with two oxygen atoms to the weight of a carbon atom. The ‘CF’ reported by the Korean Ministry of Knowledge Economy is used to estimate the CO2 emissions.
All data are based on the year 2015 and thus the empirical experiment is a cross-sectional comparative analysis between Korea and Shanghai. As shown in Table 3, the average scale of coal-fueled power plants in Korea is larger than that in Shanghai, while the standard deviation is similar.

4.1.1. Empirical Results and Discussion

Based on Equation (10), we solved the SFA problem by incorporating all the parameter estimate coefficients, as shown in Table 4, into the Stata software program (College Station, TX, USA). We used the maximum likelihood method to estimate the stochastic frontier. All the variables obtained are consistent with expectations and passed the statistical test. If the sign is negative, the negative effect of the variable in the production process is greater than the positive effect; on the contrary, if the sign is positive, the positive effect of the variable in the production process is greater than the negative effect.
Table 5 shows the results for environmental efficiency under group frontier technologies and meta-frontier technologies. As shown in this table, the average GEE value of coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai is 0.9289, indicating that, on average, coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai can increase their environmental efficiency by approximately 7.11% if all of them operate by group production technologies. Similarly, the average GEE value of coal-fueled power plants in Korea is 0.9218, which indicates that, on average, coal-fueled power plants in Korea can increase their environmental efficiency by approximately 7.82% if they operate by group production technologies. We found that the group environmental efficiency results of coal-fueled power plants in both Shanghai and Korea reached a high score. Their good performance in terms of environmental efficiency is a result of the sustainable development policies in these two countries and the exploration of new technology for improving production efficiency. From 2007, the shift of economic growth mode toward green growth or sustainable development became one of the most important national policies of China, and the power industry, as the key sector of pollutant emissions, started to heavily invest in key technologies for ultra-low emissions. In 2009, the Korean government set up the “green economic growth strategy” and in 2005 Korea established ETS, which was the first ETS among developing countries. Because coal-fueled power plants play an important role in total CO2 emissions, this sector has been under considerable pressure to improve its environmental efficiency.
The MEE value of the coal-fueled power plants in Korea is 0.8023, 2.22% higher than in Shanghai. The TGR value of coal-fueled power plants in Korea is 0.8704, 3% higher than in Shanghai. This indicates that the environmental efficiency of coal-fueled power plants in Korea is closer to the meta-frontier technology. Given the different stages of development in Korea and China, there is a gap of the environmental efficiency between the coal-fueled power plants in these two regions, but the gap is not huge. Because the coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai have benefited from heavy investments in ultra-low emissions technology over the last decade.
Table 6 shows the CO2 MAC results of coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai and Korea. The average MAC result is $17.04 and $29.6 in Shanghai and Korea, which is much higher than the real market price shown in Table 2. In other words, the market price only reflected 14.85% and 32.4%, respectively, of the CO2 MAC results. In both ETSs, coal-fueled power plants frequently act as a buyer in the market because they can purchase quotas at a very low price; this means that they can emit CO2 at a very low cost. So, as a matter of fact, the extremely low market price cannot stimulate the coal-fueled power plants to invest further in technology and improve environmental efficiency. The standard deviation of the MAC results of coal-fueled power plants in Korea is higher than that in Shanghai. These results indicate that, theoretically, coal-fueled power plants in Korea can reduce CO2 emissions more efficiently. We also found that there is a considerable overlap between the MAC range of coal-fueled power plants in these two regions, which makes the power plants in both countries act as quota sellers or quota buyers, rather than all of the power plants in one region acting as quota sellers while all of the power plants in another region act as quota buyers. This fact will stimulate their efficiency performance and help ensure effective carbon emissions reductions for power plants in both regions, with no one-sided benefits. In addition, although the gap in environmental efficiency between coal-fired power plants in Shanghai and those in Korea is small, the MAC results’ difference reaches 73.7%. Obviously, this significant difference in the MAC result is not due to the gap in environmental efficiency, but to the difference in feed-in tariffs between the two regions. The MAC not only relates to the environmental efficiency, but also to the feed-in tariff. A higher feed-in tariff leads to a higher MAC. If international ETS cooperation is to be achieved, differences in feed-in tariffs must be taken into account to avoid equity problems. For instance, policymakers should arrange a higher quota or lower carbon tax for coal-fueled power plants in Korea to reduce the impact of feed-in tariffs on carbon trading in the market.

5. Conclusions

Along with the sustainable developmental strategy, the question of preventing and controlling pollution is regarded as urgent by both China and Korea. Indeed, how to effectively protect the environment has become one of the thorniest issues of this century.
The Paris Agreement, signed in 2015, laid the foundation for the establishment of carbon trading market mechanisms, especially through international cooperation. Compared with sectoral or domestic ETS, international coordination can improve the efficiency of ETS, while substantially reducing emissions, to compensate for sector-specific costs of ETS and ultimately improve political acceptability. Harmonization may have the potential to avoid distributional effects and contribute to the environmental and economic benefits.
China and Korea are two major CO2 emitters, together accounting for about 30% of the total CO2 in the world. The two countries are not only geographically close, but also have a huge amount of trade volume with each other. In addition, both governments have shown willingness to cooperate on ETSs. Therefore, it is necessary to investigate the feasibility of international ETS cooperation between them. To avoid differences in economic scale, population size, and economic development stage, we selected Shanghai as a pilot region to cooperate with Korea. First of all, Shanghai is the most developed region in China and the closest to the stage of Korea’s economic development. Second, the formation of Shanghai’s metropolitan area is of special importance in China. It not only promotes economic development and the district integration in the Yangtze Delta, but also serves as a model for the development of the whole country. Third, the national carbon market trading center of China was established in Shanghai, because of its developed financial industry base, as well as its special status in China’s political and economic arena, and its good performance as a pilot carbon market.
The environmental efficiency results from coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai and Korea revealed that the group environmental efficiency is at a high level in both Shanghai and Korea, reaching 0.9289 and 0.9218, respectively, indicating that green economic policies and the establishment of ETS have played a positive role in these two regions and the exploration and application of new technology have been very successful. However, as to the meta-frontier environmental efficiency results, the value of coal-fueled power plants in Korea is 0.8023, which is higher than that in Shanghai. This result indicates that coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai are more likely to improve their environmental efficiency through benchmarks in international ETS cooperation. Large-scale ultra supercritical pressure units have been put into operation in Korea; meanwhile, the government and companies in Korea have invested significantly in carbon capture and storage technology.
This study also estimated the CO2 MAC of coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai and Korea. The results revealed that the real market price is much lower than our MAC results. In the Shanghai-Korea international ETS market, policymakers should impose a carbon tax, adjust their carbon emissions quotas, and introduce more regulatory measures—especially for coal-fueled power plants—to fill the gaps of 85.15% and 67.6%, respectively, of coal-fueled power plants in Shanghai and Korea. Otherwise, coal-fueled power plants will frequently act as buyers in the ETS market because the extremely low market price cannot stimulate coal-fueled power plants to further invest in pollution-reducing technology and improve environmental efficiency. In addition, although the difference in environmental efficiency between coal-fired power plants in Shanghai and in Korea is not large, the MAC difference reaches 73.7% due to the large difference in feed-in tariffs between these two regions. We suggest that policymakers should focus on the CO2 MAC differences caused by huge feed-in tariff differences to avoid equity problems when building the structure of the Shanghai-Korea ETS cooperation. For instance, compared with power plants in Shanghai, policymakers should set a looser cap and a higher offset for Korean plants. To reduce the impact of feed-in tariffs on carbon trading in the market, it would also be effective to arrange a higher quota or lower carbon tax for coal-fueled power plants in Korea.
However, long-term trends cannot be identified in our study because we used cross-sectional data instead of panel data. Both Shanghai ETS and Korea ETS have been established for less than five years. When more panel data have been collected, future studies may be possible for more precise and valuable results.

Author Contributions

The authors are contributed each part of a paper by Conceptualization, Y.C.; Methodology,C.Q.; Software, C.Q.; Validation, Y.C.; Formal Analysis, C.Q.; Investigation, Y.C.; Resources & Data Curation, C.Q.; Writing-Original Draft Preparation, C.Q.; Writing-Review & Editing, Y.C.; Visualization, C.Q.; Supervision, Y.C.; Project Administration, Y.C.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Dimitrov, R.S. The Paris Agreement on Climate Change: Behind Closed Doors Glob. Environ. Politics 2016, 3, 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Sirkis, A. Avaliando a COP-21: Quão Cheio Ficou o Copo? Revista ECO-21: Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  3. Soto, J. A Direção Está Mais do Que Clara na COP-21; Revista ECO-21: Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  4. Barata, P.M.; Kachi, A. Study on Approaches to Incoporation of Mitigation Contribution in International Market Mechanisms, Including through Development Standards for Setting Emissions Reference Levels: International Emission Transfers after 2020; Report to European Commission 2016; Publications Office of the European Union: Luxembourg, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  5. Vieira, L.; Vernet, E. COP-21: Sucesso Diplomático, Fracasso Climático; Revista ECO-21: Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  6. Li, M.; Weng, Y.; Duan, M. Emissions, energy and economic impacts of linking China’s national ETS with the EU ETS. Appl. Energy 2019, 235, 1235–1244. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. European Commission Homepage. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/clima/index_en/ (accessed on 12 February 2019).
  8. Kachi, A.; Unger, C.; Böhm, N.; Stelmakh, K.; Haug, C.; Frerk, M. Linking Emissions Trading Systems: A Summary of Current Research; ICAP: Berlin, Germany, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  9. Anger, N. Emissions trading beyond Europe: Linking schemes in a post-Kyoto world. Energy Econ. 2008, 30, 2028–2049. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Ranson, M.; Stavins, R. Post-Durban climate policy architecture based on Linkage of Cap-and-trade systems. Chic. J. Int. Law 2013, 13, 403–438. [Google Scholar]
  11. Flachsland, C.; Marschinski, R.; Edenhofer, O. To link or not to link: Benefits and disbenefits of linking cap-and-trade systems. Clim. Policy Spec. Issue Link. 2009, 9, 358–372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Comendant, C.; Taschini, L. Submission to the Inquiry by the House of Commons Select Committee on Energy and Climate Change on ‘Linking Emissions Trading Systems’; Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy: London, UK, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  13. Zetterberg, L. Linking the Emissions Trading System in EU and California; Swedish Environmental Research Institute: Stockholm, Sweden, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  14. Oliveira, T.D.; Gurgel, A.C.; Tonry, S. International market mechanisms under the Paris Agreement: A cooperation between Brazil and Europe. Energy Policy 2019, 129, 397–409. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Green, J.F.; Sterner, T.; Wagner, G. A balance of bottom-up and top-down in linking climate policies. Nat. Clim. Chang. 2014, 4, 1064–1067. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Haites, E. Lessons Learned from Linking Emissions Trading Systems: General Principles and Applications; Technical Note 7; Partnership for Market Readiness: Washington, DC, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  17. Edenhofer, O.; Flachsland, C.; Marschinski, R. Towards a Global CO2 Market—An Economic Analysis; Potsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research: Potsdam, Germany, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  18. Burtraw, D.; Palmer, K.; Munnings, C.; Weber, P.; Woerman, M. Linking by Degrees: Incremental Alignment of Cap-and-Trade Markets; Discussion Paper; RFF: Washington, DC, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  19. Baron, R.; Bygrave, S. Towards International Emissions Trading: Design Implications for Linkages; OECD: Paris, France, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  20. Metcalf, G.; Weisbach, D. Linking policies when tastes differ: Global climate policy in a heterogeneous world Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2012, 6, 110–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Shanghai Electric Power Corpus. 2015. Available online: https://shanghaipower.com/ (accessed on 3 January 2019).
  22. The Statistical Review of World Energy 2017. Available online: https://www.bp.com/ (accessed on 1 January 2019).
  23. Lee, H.; Choi, Y. Environmental Performance Evaluation of the Korean Manufacturing Industry Based on Sequential DEA. Sustainability 2019, 11, 874. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Shanghai ETS Annual Report 2015. Available online: http://www.cneeex.com/ (accessed on 14 February 2019).
  25. Korea ETS Annual Report 2015. Available online: http://www.energy.or.kr/web/kem_home_new/new_main.asp (accessed on 19 February 2019).
  26. Statistics Review of World Energy 2018. Available online: https://www.bp.com/en/global/corporate/energy-economics/statistical-review-of-world-energy.html (accessed on 8 February 2019).
  27. Oh, S.K.; Won, C.Y. Estimation of the marginal abatement costs of airborne pollutants in Korea’s power generation sector. Energy Econ. 1999, 21, 547–560. [Google Scholar]
  28. Park, H.; Lim, J. Valuation of marginal CO2 abatement options for electric power plants. Energy Policy 2009, 37, 1834–1841. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Lee, M. Potential cost savings from internal/external CO2 emissions trading in the Korean electric power industry. Energy Policy 2010, 39, 6162–6167. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Zhang, N.; Zhou, P.; Choi, Y. Energy efficiency, CO2 emission performance and technology gaps in fossil fuel electricity generation in Korea: A meta-frontier non-radial directional distance function analysis. Energy Policy 2013, 56, 653–662. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Zhang, N.; Wang, B. A deterministic parametric metafrontier Luenberger indicator for measuring environmentally-sensitive productivity growth: A Korean fossil-fuel power case. Energy Econ. 2015, 51, 88–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Du, L.; Mao, J. Estimating the environmental efficiency and marginal CO2 abatement cost of coalfired power plants in China. Energy Policy 2015, 85, 347–356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Aigner, D.; Lovell, C.; Schnidt, P. Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models. J. Econom. 1977, 6, 21–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Schmidt, P. On the statistical estimation of parametric frontier production functions. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1978, 58, 238–239. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Pollak, R.A.; Sickles, R.C.; Wales, T.J. The CES-translog: Specification and estimation of a new cost function. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1984, 66, 602–607. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Gollop, F.M.; Roberts, M.J. Cost-mininizing regulation of sulfur emissions regional gains in electric power. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1985, 67, 81–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Pittman, R.W. Issues in pollution control: Interlant cost differences and economics of scale. Land Econ. 1981, 57, 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Shephard, R.W. Theory of Cost and Production Function; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1970. [Google Scholar]
  39. Zhang, N.; Choi, Y. A note on the evolution of directional distance function and its development in energy and environmental studies 1997–2013. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 33, 50–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Wang, Q.; Cui, Q.; Zhou, D.; Wang, S. Marginal abatement costs of carbon dioxide in China: A nonparametric analysis. Energy Procedia 2011, 5, 2316–2320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  41. Liu, M.L.; Zhu, L.; Fan, Y. Evaluation of carbon emission performance and estimation of marginal CO2 abatement costs for provinces of China: A non-parametric distance function approach. China Soft Sci. 2011, 3, 106–114. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  42. Lee, M.; Zhang, N. Technical efficiency, shadow price of carbon dioxide emissions, and substitutability for energy in the Chinese manufacturing industries. Energy Econ. 2012, 34, 1492–1497. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Du, L.; Wei, C.; Cai, S. Economic development and carbon dioxide emission in China: Provincial panel data analysis. China Econ. Rev. 2012, 23, 371–384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Wei, C.; Löschel, A.; Liu, B. An empirical analysis of the CO2 shadow price in Chinese thermal power enterprises. Energy Econ. 2013, 40, 22–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Yongrok, C.; Chao, Q. Is the Korean ETS performance effective? Based on the MAC of coal-fueled power plants in Korea. Sustainability 2019, 11, 2504. [Google Scholar]
  46. O’Donnell, C.J.; Prasada Rao, D.S.; Battese, G.E. Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios. Empir. Econ. 2008, 34, 231–255. [Google Scholar]
  47. European Commission Website. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/ets_enhttps://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/ets_en (accessed on 21 March 2019).
  48. Jotzo, F.; Betz, R. Australia’s emissions trading scheme: Opportunities and obstacles for linking. Clim. Policy 2009, 9, 402–414. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Chapman, J. Linking a United States Greenhouse Gas Cap-and-trade system and the European Union’s emissions trading scheme. Vt. J. Environ. Law 2009, 11, 45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Marschinski, R.; Flachsland, C.; Jakob, M. Sectoral linking of carbon markets: A trade-theory analysis Resour. Energy Econ. 2012, 34, 585–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Hübler, M.; Voigt, S.; Löschel, A. Designing an emissions trading scheme for China: An up-to-date climate policy assessment. Energy Policy 2014, 75, 57–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Gavard, C.; Winchester, N.; Paltsev, S. Limited trading of emissions permits as a climate cooperation mechanism? US–China and EU–China examples. Energy Econ. 2016, 58, 95–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Zhang, X.; Qi, T.-Y.; Ou, X.-M.; Zhang, X.-L. The role of multi-region integrated emissions trading scheme: A computable general equilibrium analysis. Appl. Energy 2017, 185, 1860–1868. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Chung, Y.; Fare, R.; Grosskopf, S. Productivity and Undesirable Outputs: A Directional Distance Function Approach. J. Environ. Manag. 1997, 3, 229–240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Fare, R.; Grosskopf, S.; Noh, D.; William, W. Characteristics of a polluting technology: Theory and practice. J. Econom. 2005, 126, 469–492. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Bai, Y.; Deng, X.; Zhang, Q.; Wang, Z. Measuring environmental performance of industrial sub-sectors in China: A stochastic metafrontier approach. Phys. Chem. Earth Parts A/B/C 2017, 101, 3–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Korea Electric Power Corporation’s Statistics of Electric Power. 2015. Available online: http://epsis.kpx.or.kr/epsisnew/selectEkccIntroEn.do?menuId = 110100 (accessed on 5 January 2019).
  58. International Panel on Climate Change. Available online: https://www.ipcc.ch/data/ (accessed on 18 January 2019).
Figure 1. Relationship between meta-frontier and group frontier.
Figure 1. Relationship between meta-frontier and group frontier.
Sustainability 11 04468 g001
Table 1. The transaction situations of the Shanghai and Korea ETSs in 2015.
Table 1. The transaction situations of the Shanghai and Korea ETSs in 2015.
ShanghaiKorea
Sums (millions of U.S. dollars)46.1855.01
Volume (KT) 5734
Average market price (U.S. dollars/ton)2.539.59
Volume of power industry91562800
Volume ratio of power industry50.2%48.8%
Source: Shanghai ETS annual report 2015 (http://www.cneeex.com/). Korea ETS annual report 2015 (http://www.energy.or.kr/web/kem_home_new/new_main.asp).
Table 2. Studies on MAC estimation.
Table 2. Studies on MAC estimation.
StudiesYearMethodObjective
Wang et al.2011DDF/DEACO2 MAC of 28 provinces in China
Liu et al.2011DF/DEACO2 MAC of 30 provinces in China
Du et al.2012DF/LPCO2 MAC of 29 provinces in China
Zhang et al.2014DDF/LPCO2 MAC of 29 provinces in China
Wei et al.2013DDF/SFACO2 MAC of the coal-fueled power plants in China
Oh et al.1999DF/LPAirborne pollutants MAC of Korea’s power plants
Lee2010DF/LPCO2 MAC of Korea’s coal-fueled power plants
Choi and Qi2019DDF/SFACO2 MAC of 50 coal-fueled power plants in Korea
Table 3. Descriptive statistics.
Table 3. Descriptive statistics.
VariableObsMeanStd. Dev.
RegionSHKOTotSHKOTotSHKOTot
Capital (MW)9253145182.33399.47261.69221.81150.97224.35
Energy (KT)9253145280.022811.091205.16380.25971.561388.62
Labor (Per Person)9253145104.27297.55174.91104.16101.67138.97
Electricity (kMWh)9253145791.973889.351924.121261.281403.681989.27
CO2 (KT)9253145672.062815.581455.55912.59966.671391.65
Table 4. Parameter estimates.
Table 4. Parameter estimates.
ParameterCoef. (Std. Err.)
Group Frontier (Shanghai)Group Frontier (Korea)Meta-Frontier
β l 4.23 × 10−6 (1.22 × 10−6) ***−0.0009125 (0.0003922) ***0.0004164 (0.0000958) ***
β k −2.41 × 10−6 (2.11 × 10−6)0.0041788 (0.0011684) ***0.0003978 (0.0001042) ***
β e −1.000032 (0.0000229) ***−0.3308924 (0.1548403) **0.1499747 (0.0252257) ***
β y 0.000014 (0.0000107)−0.4943289 (0.1222343) ***−0.5134027 (0.0146761) ***
β l l 9.91 × 10−7 (2.90 × 10−7) ***4.38 × 10−6 (6.47 × 10−6)−9.88 × 10−7 (3.71 × 10−7) ***
β k l 0.0000124 (2.50 × 10−6) ***−0.000015 (6.69 × 10−6) ***−6.47 × 10−7 (3.50 × 10−7) **
β l e −0.0001162 (0.0000233) ***−0.0000787 (0.0019222) ***0.0006612 (0.0001256) ***
β 0 1.49 × 10−6 (1.03 × 10−6)−0.0269538 (0.0137456) **−0.0549784 (0.0063817) ***
β k k 3.41 × 10−6 (8.35 × 10−6)−8.71 × 10−6 (2.68 × 10−6) *−5.29 × 10−6 (5.78 × 10−7) ***
β k e −0.0000471 (0.0000204) ***0.0087048 (0.006622) **−0.000929 (0.0002616) ***
β e e 0.0008673 (0.0002042) ***2.425098 (1.49435)−1.160946 (0.0957935) ***
β y y 0.0001582 (0.0000413) ***0.8976776 (0.53042) **−0.1145199 (0.0274249) ***
β l y 0.00005 (0.0000101) ***0.0009055 (0.001164)−0.0002271 (0.0000555) ***
β k y 0.0000196 (7.86 × 10−6) ***−0.0029704 (0.0024377)0.0005836 (0.0001162) ***
β e y −0.0003704 (0.0000918) ***−1.644005 (0.9839597) **0.375444 (0.051916) ***
Note: The standard deviation is provided in parentheses; * p < 0.1; ** p < 0.05; *** p < 0.01.
Table 5. Environmental efficiency results.
Table 5. Environmental efficiency results.
ShanghaiKorea
GEETGRMEEEETGRMEE
0.92890.84500.78490.92180.87040.8023
Table 6. CO2 MAC results (in U.S. dollars/ton).
Table 6. CO2 MAC results (in U.S. dollars/ton).
CoefficientShanghaiKoreaTotal
Obs9253145
Mean17.0429.6021.63
Std. Dev.5.357.738.59
Min7.3218.967.32
Max37.6351.4551.45

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Qi, C.; Choi, Y. A Study of the Feasibility of International ETS Cooperation between Shanghai and Korea from Environmental Efficiency and CO2 Marginal Abatement Cost Perspectives. Sustainability 2019, 11, 4468. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11164468

AMA Style

Qi C, Choi Y. A Study of the Feasibility of International ETS Cooperation between Shanghai and Korea from Environmental Efficiency and CO2 Marginal Abatement Cost Perspectives. Sustainability. 2019; 11(16):4468. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11164468

Chicago/Turabian Style

Qi, Chao, and Yongrok Choi. 2019. "A Study of the Feasibility of International ETS Cooperation between Shanghai and Korea from Environmental Efficiency and CO2 Marginal Abatement Cost Perspectives" Sustainability 11, no. 16: 4468. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11164468

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop