Given these outcomes, the paper checks the cointegration properties of variables using the Fourier ADL cointegration estimator. By testing for cointegration, it is possible to determine how ETAX, LGDP, LPEC, and GELEC jointly affect LCO2 in the case of France.
4.1. Interpretation of Outcomes and Discussions
The long-run non-linear ARDL (N-ARDL) estimates indicate that variables have varied coefficients with significant statistical values depending on the economic shock period. First, the results of the N-ARDL long-run cointegration estimates (
Table 5) show that, for LGDP, there is a long-term positive and negative non-linear causal effect on LCO
2, with both positive and negative coefficients (−0.484297 and −0.234380, respectively) that are significant.
First, as they move in opposite directions in France, a 1% increase in LGDP causes LCO2 to fall by roughly 48.42% during its positive shock periods, while a 1% decrease in LGDP causes a surprise rise in LCO2 by −0.234380% during its negative shock periods, all other things being equal. A negative GDP shock can disrupt the long-term trend of decoupling economic growth from emissions. In many developed countries, CO2 emissions have been falling even as GDP has risen, thanks to improvements in energy efficiency, a shift to cleaner energy sources, and the transition from heavy industry to a service-based economy. For instance, a negative economic shock can interrupt this progress. When a recession hits, companies may cut back on investment in new, more efficient, and cleaner technologies. They may also defer or cancel plans to upgrade old, polluting equipment. This pause in “green” investment can halt the downward trajectory of emissions, and as the economy recovers, the use of older, less-efficient technology could lead to a sudden surge in emissions. Similarly, a recession reduces tax revenue for governments. This can lead to cuts in public spending, including funding for green infrastructure, research into clean technology, and environmental monitoring and enforcement. Additionally, the EKC hypothesis claims, at a certain point (high GDP), as the economy becomes wealthier, it can afford to invest in cleaner technologies and prioritize environmental protection, leading to a decline in pollution; this makes it correct to claim that a negative GDP shock could push a country back down the “cleaner” side of the curve, potentially causing a temporary increase in emissions as a result of a decline in environmental investment and focus. While this is a broad theoretical framework, it helps explain why a drop in GDP would not automatically lead to an environmental improvement.
In contrast to negative shock periods, positive shock periods for LGDP contribute to a decrease in carbon emissions in France. This outcome corroborates the hypothesis established for this study on the effect of LGDP on LCO
2 in the case of France. It is noteworthy to recognize that the decomposition factor power of the N-ARDL estimator helps to establish the need to implement policies for the decoupling of LGDP from LCO
2 in France during shock periods. This result supports the recent study by [
73] in the case of China. Theoretically, rising economic growth simultaneously results in more demand for energy and material resources for production, producing a worsening quality of the environment. This is the claim of the EKC framework, which underlines that the first stage of economic expansion results in environmental degradation until environmental regulations and technological advancements intervene to rectify the anomaly. With reduced LCO
2 during positive economic shocks in France, the outcome suggests the economy has reached the EKC peak, with high levels of technological and innovation progress.
In sum, economic growth had a mixed effect on the quality of the environment in France, following a pattern often described by the Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC). It must also be noted that France, as a high-income economy, had reached the declining curve of the EKC framework for many traditional pollutants during the period under study. Its economic growth was more closely associated with policies aimed at improving environmental quality. In practical terms, the mixed effect of economic growth on environmental quality for the case of France indicated that the economy of France needed to ensure that economic policies and environmental goals were aligned. In this case, a combination of carbon taxes, subsidies for green investment, and regulations targeted towards steering the economy were geared towards a truly sustainable path. For corporate strategy, managers could ensure regulatory policies on production equally influenced consumption patterns towards reducing waste generation and avoided a “race to the bottom” on corporate environmental footprint.
Second, the N-ARDL long-run cointegration estimates (
Table 5) show a positive and negative non-linear causal effect on LCO
2 for GELEC with coefficients −0.005098 and 0.000097 at positive and negative shocks, respectively. These imply that a 1% increase in GELEC causes a decrease in LCO
2 by approximately 0.005098% at positive shock periods, while a 1% decrease in GELEC during negative shock periods leads to a reduction in LCO
2 by 0.000097% as they move in a similar direction. This finding corroborates the hypothesis established on GELEC on LCO
2 for the case of France. Theoretically, investments in green electricity lead to a reduction in CO
2. It is important to recognize that France is committed to transforming its energy system by curbing fossil fuel consumption, being energy efficient, and relying on green electricity with huge budgetary allocations. It is also worth noting that for a robust transition to net zero to occur, huge investments in green innovation projects matter. For the case of France, the outcomes indicate that periods of no or reduced investments in green energy technologies result in rising carbon emissions. By aligning with the Green Solow Model [
74], which emphasizes possible emission reductions from exogenous technological development in the pollution diminution process, the outcome helps to prescribe the need to invest in technologies that help to control pollution.
In totality, it must be noted that the country’s (i.e., France) current over-reliance on nuclear power indicates its low-carbon electricity mix. It is, however, worth stressing that the country’s successes over the period in reducing carbon dioxide emissions were a combined result of both its green electricity policies and historical reliance on nuclear power. It is proper to remark that the low-carbon nature of the nuclear fleet provided a strong foundation for green electricity policies to build on, although this was a unique energy context that could not be easily replicated by other countries.
Given this result, it is instructive to remark that the development of green electricity (such as wind, solar, and hydro) could further reduce the need for fossil fuel-based electricity generation in the country, particularly during peak demand of electricity, or periods when nuclear plants are being maintained. In effect, current policy directions to transition to green electricity in the energy sector support France’s commitment to achieving carbon neutrality by 2050 (i.e., policies promoting green electricity, such as subsidies for renewables and grid-integration targets). This is crucial for meeting national and European climate targets. Additionally, developing a robust green electricity sector has significant geopolitical and economic implications for France, since by increasing its domestic renewable energy production, the country reduces its dependence on imported fossil fuels (such as natural gas and oil) and improves its energy security—making it less vulnerable to international price shocks and supply disruptions. These notwithstanding, experts warn that the intermittent nature of solar and wind power pose a significant challenge for the electricity grid, requiring heavy investments in smart grid technologies and energy storage solutions that can ensure a stable and reliable electricity supply [
75], despite their inherent challenges [
76].
Third, the findings of the N-ARDL long-run cointegration estimates (
Table 5) show that the long-term coefficient of LCO
2 is affected by LPEC in both positive and negative non-linear ways. The coefficients are both significant, at 0.882688 and 1.341291, respectively. These show that, in the context of France, all other things being equal, a 1% increase in LPEC causes an increase in LCO
2 of about 88.26% during its positive shock periods, while a 1% decrease in LPEC causes an unexpected decrease in LCO
2 of 1.34% during its negative shock periods. In contrast to positive shock periods, negative shock periods for LPEC contribute to a decrease in carbon emissions in France, confirming the theory developed for this French investigation. It is instructive to observe that primary energy use in France reached a total of 8.66 exajoules in 2023, representing a rise of five percent compared to the previous year. Although the state of France’s PEC is low compared to other EU economies, France’s economy slowed down significantly from 2022 until the second half of 2023, when it was expected to recover, due to supply bottlenecks and rising energy costs leading to increased coal use in electricity production. However, during the year 2000, the European nations’ primary energy consumption decreased by 2.7 exajoules, reaching a peak of around 11.4 exajoules in 2004. Before being converted into electricity or other secondary or tertiary energy forms, primary energy is defined as energy that is directly extracted from natural resources, including both fossil fuels and renewable resources.
In effect, France’s primary energy consumption mix has led to both significant decarbonization of its electricity sector, but also resulted in certain environmental challenges. For instance, by avoiding coal and gas for electricity, France has largely bypassed the air pollution issues (which negatively affect public health, reducing respiratory and cardiovascular diseases) currently plaguing several other industrialized nations. Notwithstanding, while nuclear power is clean in terms of air emissions, it presents unique environmental challenges such as the generation of radioactive waste, thermal pollution, and has potential for a catastrophic nuclear accident (such as those which occurred in Chernobyl or Fukushima), representing an immense environmental risk to the economy of France. Additionally, the use of nuclear power by France makes its electricity mix low-carbon, but the development of green electricity (such as wind and solar) is viewed as an important step to further reduce fossil fuel consumption, and facilitate the achievement of its carbon neutrality goals by 2050. Despite the fact that nuclear-based energy mixes have been effective in generating low-carbon electricity, their generalizability to fossil-dependent economies and policy actions is limited due to the country’s unique historical, political, and economic contexts. Researchers have argued that the effectiveness of France’s green electricity policies is more limited in other key sectors that are not easily electrified, such as the transport and agriculture sectors [
77,
78]. While policies like bonuses for electric vehicles have shown some success, they have not fully offset the rise in emissions from transportation due to increased consumption and a reliance on internal combustion engine vehicles. The agricultural sector also continues to be a major source of emissions, which green electricity policies do little to address.
Fourth, the N-ARDL long-run equilibrium estimates (
Table 5) point to a positive and negative non-linear causal impact on LCO
2 as ETAX has coefficients −0.043468 and 0.064726 during positive and negative economic shocks, respectively. These imply that a 1% increase in ETAX causes a decrease in LCO
2 by approximately −0.043468% at positive shock periods, while a 1% decrease in ETAX during negative shock periods leads to a reduction in LCO
2 by 0.064726% as they move in a similar direction. This finding corroborates the hypothesis established on ETAX on LCO
2 for the case of France. Theoretically, investments in environmental tax tend to cause a reduction in CO
2 by affecting a fall in fossil fuel consumption [
5]. The economy pledged to enact environmental tax laws to meet the Paris Climate Agreement and Kyoto Protocol’s carbon emission reduction targets. Theoretically, if the production or consumption of specific goods results in a negative externality, then ecological taxes are justified as enhancing social welfare [
17]. Theoretically, it proves that environmental pollution is a social concern because of emissions dependent on consumption or on the failure of prices in production costs. Given the difference between the private and social costs of pollution, Ref. [
12] argued that taxing pollution ensures efficient market outcomes while equating private costs and social marginal damage. It is important to recognize that France committed to transforming its energy system by curbing fossil fuel consumption with an environmental tax with the aim of realizing a transition to net zero.
In sum, environmental taxes for the economy of France have a mixed effect on environmental quality: by successfully reducing some pollutants, but with significant economic and social challenges that limit their overall impact. In practical terms, environmental taxes are generally based on the “polluter pays” principle, which creates a financial incentive for companies and individuals to change their behavior. However, experts argue environmental taxes, especially on energy and transport, tend to be regressive, disproportionately affecting lower-income households [
7,
8]. Since a larger share of their income is spent on necessities like heating and fuel for commuting, they bear a heavier burden from these taxes than wealthier households. Similarly, there are other scholars who have found environmental taxation to differ across economies for various context-specific factors [
79,
80]. In the case of France, recent environmental tax policy was limited in effectiveness due to the “Yellow Vests” protests that began in late 2018 as a direct response to a planned increase in fuel taxes (specifically on diesel) intended to fund green initiatives and reduce fossil fuel demand. However, it was perceived to disproportionately impact low- and middle-income households (particularly those in rural and suburban areas) who rely on cars for commuting and daily life. The protests forced the government to suspend and eventually cancel the planned tax hikes, demonstrating a significant political and social limitation on the effectiveness of environmental tax policies for reducing CO
2 emissions. Through these mechanisms, we find that the asymmetric response in France’s environmental taxation responses was generally not a chemical mechanism but motivated by both socio-behavioral and economic factors.
Figure 3 shows the summary of the estimated nonlinear model.
Our asymmetric results for environmental taxes suggest that policy reversals during negative shocks—often driven by distributional concerns and social resistance—can reduce their effectiveness. This underlines the need to strengthen public acceptance and equity considerations in tax design, consistent with recent debates on the regressive nature of energy taxes in France.