2.1. Overview of the Model
The E-Sector under the methodology we will be using goes beyond the traditional energy industries, encompassing every single physical process involved in the transformation of primary energy (extracted from the environment and including the extraction itself), into final energy (the final output of the traditional energy industries) and into the useful energy (measured as exergy) actually used to perform a given end-use in the economy. This includes not only the machines used in the traditional energy industries, such as boilers and turbines in a coal-fired power plant, but also devices used in households and firms, such as appliances, vehicles and computers. The output from this E-Sector corresponds to the useful exergy flows used to perform economic activities and generate economic value.
As we can see in
Figure 1, exergy enters the economy through the E-Sector at the primary stage (
) and is transformed into its final stage (
) in traditional energy industries and then into its useful stage (
) by end-use devices. The production of useful exergy output from the E-Sector is powered by capital and labour inputs to this sector (
and
, respectively) in exchange for payments to capital, known as “gross operating surplus”, and payments to labour, known as “compensation of employees” (
and
, respectively).
The useful exergy output from the E-Sector will be either used as an input in the production of non-energy goods and services in the NE-Sector (), alongside inputs of capital and labour to this sector ( and , respectively, paid for through and , respectively) and in exchange for an intermediate consumption payment from the NE-Sector to the E-Sector (), or consumed directly by households and government () through their expenditure on energy-converting goods and services (). This exchange of exergy for money between the E-Sector and the households and government is represented in the diagram by the point where the green arrow transforms into the red arrow . The output from the NE-Sector constitutes either consumption expenditure of non-energy goods and services () or investment expenditure allocated between the NE-Sector and the E-Sector ( and , respectively).
Both the E-Sector and the NE-Sector also take into account the trade balance between exports ( and , respectively) and imports ( and , respectively).
2.2. Reclassification of National Accounts
The central identity in national accounts expressed by Equation (
1) equates the economic output (i.e., the Gross Domestic Product or GDP, represented by
Q), calculated through the income approach, with the economic output calculated through the expenditure approach [
21].
In Equation (
1), the l.h.s. (expenditure approach) represents the sum of consumption (
C), investment (
I) and the trade balance between exports (
X) and imports (
M), while the r.h.s. (income approach) represents the sum of payments to capital, measured as gross operating surplus (
), payments to labour, measured as compensation of employees (
) and taxes minus subsidies on production and imports,
.
In the two-sector model, each term in Equation (
1) is disaggregated in an E-Sector and an NE-Sector component, according to the previously established criteria for these sectors. In particular, this means that investment, exports and imports in energy-related goods and industries are allocated to the E-Sector, while investment, exports and imports in all other goods and industries are allocated to the NE-Sector. This reclassification, however, takes into account the fact that expenditure in energy-converting end-use devices (such as appliances) that is listed in national accounts as consumption is actually a form of investment expenditure in the E-Sector under our two-sector model, and so it is reclassified as such, while its associated imputed rents—estimated from average depreciation—are added to consumption expenditure. This is because consumption expenditure on energy-converting end-use devices contributes to the E-Sector’s capacity to generate useful exergy from final exergy. The consumption of energy-carriers is also allocated to the E-Sector, while the consumption of non-energy-converting goods is allocated to the NE-Sector. A similar disaggregation is employed for
,
and
, leading to the equality in Equation (
2) from Santos et al. [
18].
As was the case for
Q in Equation (
1),
in Equation (
2) represents the total economic output. This will be different from GDP as reported in national accounts because it will include the imputed rents associated with the reclassification of consumption expenditure as investment on the l.h.s, but since it will also include its respective payments to capital (which have the same value) on the r.h.s, the equality still holds.
A detailed diagram of the extended energy sector is presented in
Figure 2. Following the Statistical Classification of Economic Activities in the European Community (NACE, from the French “
Nomenclature statistique des Ativités économiques dans la Communauté Européenne”), the industry standard classification system used in the European Union, this E-Sector is made up of the traditional energy sector (NACE categories “Mining & quarrying” and “Electricity, gas, steam & AC supply”) and supplementary economic activities ultimately responsible for energy transformation but not typically classified as part of the energy sector (NACE categories “Agriculture, forestry & fishing”, “Manufacture of food, beverages, & tobacco products” and “Manufacture of coke & refined petroleum products”).
The gross value added () of both the conventional and these supplementary economic activities, combined with the value of the end-use devices converting exergy at the final-to-useful stage (), forms the total GVA for the extended energy sector ().
In addition to the identity expressed in Equation (2), the disaggregation and reclassification of national accounts in the two-sector model must satisfy the sector-specific accounting identities illustrated in the circular flow diagram of
Figure 3.
These identities can be represented by the following equations from Santos et al. [
18]:
For Equations (
3)–(
8), the l.h.s represents money flows going out of that specific sector while the r.h.s represents money flows going into that specific sector.
and represent private consumption expenditure made by the Households in the NE-Sector and the E-Sector, respectively, represents Household savings (which will go to the Banks) and represents taxes minus subsidies on household consumption (which will be paid to the Government).
is the gross operating surplus of the NE-Sector and
is the compensation of employees in the NE-Sector. Together, these two factors, which come from Firms (E) (Equation (
7)), make up the gross value added (GVA) of the NE-Sector, which reverts back to the Households. The same is true for the gross operating surplus and the compensation of employees in the E-Sector (
and
, respectively), which make up the GVA of the E-Sector and come from Firms (NE) (Equation (
8)).
Similarly, on the r.h.s of Equation (
4), in addition to the taxes minus subsidies from the Households,
(taxes minus subsidies from production in the NE-Sector) and
(taxes minus subsidies from production in the E-Sector) are paid to the Government and are spent on
and
(government consumption in the NE-Sector and the E-Sector, respectively). The balance between income to the Government and expenses by the Government,
, is the government surplus (which will go to the Banks).
The Banks spend the savings and government surplus money they receive from the Households and the Government in (net external lending to the rest of the world, or ROW), (net internal lending to the NE-Sector) and (net internal lending to the E-Sector).
In the trade balance of Equation (
6), on the l.h.s.,
and
are the exports in the NE-Sector and in the E-Sector, respectively, and
and
are the imports in the NE-Sector and in the E-Sector, respectively.
In addition to the payments to capital and labour and the taxes minus subsidies on production, which both Firms in the E-Sector (Equation (
7), l.h.s.) and in the NE-Sector (Equation (
8), l.h.s.) pay to their specific sector, Firms in the E-Sector also invest in the NE-Sector (
) in exchange for a payment in intermediate consumption (
). Both sectors are financed by private and government consumption, as well as net internal lending and trade balance.
2.3. Expenditure Approach
Each of the expenditure approach terms in Equation (
1) was disaggregated into an E-Sector component and an NE-Sector component, as can be seen in Equation (
2). The criteria for this disaggregation will be explained for each of these components in the following sections.
National accounts data were collected throughout this work from databases and official sources. The sources for the datasets used can be seen in
Table A1 in
Appendix A. Each data entry was allocated to either the E-Sector or the NE-Sector according to the criteria outlined in the following sections.
2.3.1. Consumption
The total consumption expenditure (C) is the sum of private (P) and government (G) consumption expenditure. Each of these subcomponents of consumption expenditure is disaggregated, in most databases, by type of good or purpose.
The Classification of Individual Consumption According to Purpose (COICOP) is a classification system for individual consumption expenditures published by the United Nations Statistics Division (UNSD). It is structured in four levels: Divisions (two-digit), Groups (three-digit), Classes (four-digit) and Subclasses (five-digit). COICOP data for private expenditure will be used in this work at the three-digit level. A detailed list of all COICOP Divisions and Groups is presented in
Appendix B.1.
For government expenditure, the classification system used by the UNSD is the Classification of the Functions of Government (COFOG), which follows a structure similar to that of COICOP. COFOG data for government expenditure will be used in this work at the three-digit level. A detailed list of all COFOG Divisions and Groups is presented in
Appendix B.2.
Annual time series for aggregate private (
P) and government (
G) consumption for the USA in the period 1960–2020 were obtained from the AMECO database [
22] with nominal value.
Annual time series for disaggregate private consumption for the USA in the period 1960–2020 were obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) [
23] with nominal value. A correspondence was established between the BEA categories and those of COICOP. This correspondence can be seen in
Appendix B.3. The time series for each category in this dataset was then allocated to either the E-Sector or the NE-Sector according to the rule established in
Table A2,
Appendix A. The consumption data in Division 1 (“Food and non-alcoholic beverages”), for example, were allocated to the E-Sector, as per
Table A2, while the consumption data in Division 3 (“Clothing and footwear”), for example, were allocated to the NE-Sector, again as per
Table A2.
Annual time series for disaggregate government consumption for the USA in the period 1970–2020 were obtained from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) database [
24] in COFOG categories, but only at the Division level. The time series for each category in this dataset was allocated to either the E-Sector or the NE-Sector according to the rule established in
Table A3,
Appendix A, similarly to what was carried out in the case of private consumption. For cases where a given Division included Groups corresponding to multiple variables, a decision was made to attribute
of the total expenditure in the Division to each Group within it, with
N being the total number of Groups within the Division. For instance, as Division 4 (“Economic affairs”) includes a Group allocated to
and another Group allocated to
, 50% of government consumption in Division 4 was allocated to
and the remaining 50% was allocated to
.
The correspondence between disaggregate COICOP and COFOG consumption expenditure categories and each of the two-sector model’s variables is established according to the following criteria:
Expenditure on any type of energy-carrier good (e.g., food, fuels, electricity) is classified as consumption expenditure in the E-Sector (, );
Expenditure on any type of non-energy related good or service (e.g., clothing, services) is classified as consumption expenditure in the NE-Sector (, );
Expenditure on any type of good that actively participates in the conversion of final-to-useful exergy (e.g., vehicles, domestic appliances) is reclassified as investment expenditure in the E-Sector (, ).
The reclassification of consumption expenditure on energy-converting goods as investment expenditure in the E-Sector is explained by the fact that these consumer goods are, in fact, acting in the economy to improve the E-Sector’s capacity to generate useful exergy from final exergy, meaning that their purchase constitutes an investment expenditure in the E-Sector to increase its useful exergy output. There will be imputed rents associated with this investment, which will be added to the private consumption expenditure in the E-Sector (
). These imputed rents will be equal to the gross operating surplus corresponding to each of these reclassified investment expenditure categories (see
Section 3.2.4), thus representing their gross value added to the E-Sector (
, see
Section 2.2):
Table A2 and
Table A3 show the correspondence between COICOP/COFOG expenditure categories and the two-sector model’s variables, respectively. For cases in which a given COICOP or COFOG category might contain goods corresponding to more than one of the two-sectors’ variables, a decision is made to split that category in half.
After disaggregating consumption expenditure, we end up with the following identity, where
is the total consumption expenditure in the two-sector model:
2.3.2. Investment
Investment expenditure is measured in national accounts as gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) and is generally disaggregated by type of asset. The breakdown of GFCF by type of asset used by the United Nations’ System of National Accounts (SNA) is shown in
Table A4. GFCF data can also sometimes be found disaggregated by sector according to the Statistical Classification of Economic Activities in the European Community (NACE). A list of NACE categories is presented in
Appendix B.4.
Annual time series for aggregate GFCF for the USA in the period 1960–2020 were obtained from the AMECO database [
22] with nominal values.
Annual time series for GFCF disaggregated by type of asset according to
Table A4 and by sector according to
Table A5 were obtained for the USA for the years 1995–2020 from the Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies (wiiw, from the German “
Wiener Institut für Internationale Wirtschaftsvergleiche”) [
25].
The correspondence between disaggregate GFCF investment expenditure categories and each of the two-sector model’s variables is established according to the following criteria:
Expenditure on any type of asset that actively participates in the conversion of final-to-useful exergy (e.g., transport, machinery) is classified as investment expenditure in the E-Sector ();
All expenditure on a sector that actively participates in the conversion of final-to-useful exergy (e.g., agriculture, forestry and fishing, coke and refined petroleum products) is classified as investment expenditure in the E-Sector (), regardless of asset type.
Expenditure on any type of asset that does not actively participate in the conversion of final-to-useful exergy and is not in a sector that actively participates in the conversion of final-to-useful exergy (e.g., research and development in the construction sector) is classified as investment expenditure in the NE-Sector ().
The reclassification of all investment expenditure on energy-converting sectors as investment expenditure in the E-Sector, regardless of asset type, is explained by the fact that all investment in these sectors ultimately contributes to their goal of generating useful exergy from final energy/exergy.
Table A4 in
Appendix A shows the correspondence between asset type expenditure categories and the two-sector model’s variables. For cases in which a given category might contain expenditure corresponding to more than one of the two-sector model’s variables, an estimate of how much of that category contributes to each variable is made using other economic data (see
Section 3.1.2).
Table A5 in
Appendix A shows the correspondence between NACE categories and the two-sector model’s variables.
Finally, we must add to the investment expenditure in the E-Sector the reclassified consumption expenditure in this sector from
Section 2.3.1, and so the total investment expenditure in the two-sector model (
) is given by
2.3.3. Exports and Imports
Exports and imports are usually disaggregated between goods and services. Exported and imported goods can also be found further disaggregated by type of good. One such form of disaggregation is the World Integrated Trade Solution (WITS), whose categories can be seen in
Table A6 in
Appendix A.
Annual time series for aggregate exports (
X) and imports (
M) for the USA in the period 1960–2020 were obtained from the AMECO database [
22] with nominal values.
Annual time series for exports and imports disaggregated by WITS categories were obtained from the World Bank for the period 1991–2020.
The correspondence between disaggregate export and import categories and each of the two-sector model’s variables is established according to the following criteria:
Any type of energy-carrier good (e.g., food products, fuels) is classified as an export/import from/to the E-Sector.
Any type of non-energy-related good (e.g., footwear, metals) is classified as an export/import from/to the NE-Sector.
Any service is classified as an export/import from/to the NE-Sector.
Table A6 in
Appendix A shows the correspondence between WITS categories and each of the two-sector model’s variables.
2.6. Final and Useful Exergy Balances
Besides components from national macroeconomic accounts, exergy flows were also disaggregated and allocated to the two-sector model’s variables, namely at their final and useful stages.
Exergy balances disaggregated by sector are available for the USA. In our work, we will be focusing on the useful stage and the final-to-useful conversion of exergy flows, and so we will also consider the disaggregation of exergy balances by (useful) end-use in the economy. We adopt the useful exergy accounting procedure developed in Serrenho et al. [
30]:
Conversion of existing final energy data to final exergy values;
Allocation of final exergy of each final use sector to useful exergy categories;
Calculation of overall useful exergy by summing the total values from each useful exergy category.
In the approach by Serrenho et al. [
30], useful exergy (
U) is calculated for each year (
t), energy carrier (
i), economic sector (
j) and end-use category (
k) with Equation (
20), where
is the thermodynamic second-law efficiency for each end-use,
is an exergy factor (defined as the ratio of exergy to energy in the form of enthalpy, internal energy or others) and
is final energy consumption data.
Annual time series data on the flows of final and useful exergy disaggregated by sector are taken directly from the useful work accounting procedure performed in the Country-Level Primary-Final-Useful (CL-PFU) database [
31], which extends the International Energy Agency (IEA) World Extended Energy Balance data from the final energy stage to the useful exergy stage. This database includes exergy flow data from more than 150 different countries, disaggregated by sector and final energy carrier, for the period 1960–2020. We will use the data related to the US.
The correspondence between traditional institutional sectors, two-sector model sectors and end-uses can be seen in
Table A12 in
Appendix A. Once final/useful exergy balances are disaggregated according to this approach, they are allocated to the following components:
E-Sector own-uses correspond to all exergy consumption by the traditional energy sector (energy industry own-uses), as well as consumption by the “Agriculture and forestry” and “Food and tobacco” sectors. Part of the “Mining and quarrying” sector is also allocated to E-sector own-uses, in particular the share corresponding to coal mining and oil and gas extraction, as well as the fraction of the “Chemical and petrochemical” sector corresponding to coke and refined petroleum products.
The remaining final/useful exergy flows, excluding the E-Sector own-uses, correspond to the total output from the E-Sector, which is allocated either to inputs to production in the NE-Sector, or direct consumption.
The “Residential” and “Roads” sectors are allocated towards direct consumption, while every other sector within the E-Sector output is allocated as an input to the NE-Sector.