1. Introduction
The switch to decentralized renewable energies and the increasing electrification of various economic sectors (e.g., mobility, heating) call for expansion in many power grids. The need for additional grid capacity depends heavily on installed technologies and user behavior which, in turn, is influenced by the incentives resulting from grid tariffs. However, the development of demand response (DR) as an alternative to grid expansion is currently limited due to the chicken-egg problem explained in [
1]. As current levels of DR are low, grid operators tend to over-size the grid to prevent bottlenecks. This, in turn, means that there is a limited need to develop DR beyond today’s levels. Efficient grid tariffs that minimize the sum of dispatch and investment costs for the total system, including the grid and flexibility options, could resolve this problem. By ensuring that the grid tariffs that prosumers pay correspond to the grid costs that result from their consumption behavior, efficient grid tariffs could incentivize the development of local flexibilities.
Most electricity consumers pay a regulated tariff for their electricity consumption. As illustrated in
Figure 1, the electricity bill of households in Europe includes costs, ranging from the cost of electricity production (“Energy”), transmission and distribution grids (“Network”), cost of renewables (“RES”) and different types of taxes (“Taxes” and “VAT”).
Within this paper, we focus on the efficient design of tariffs for the recovery of grid costs. However, as we will discuss the same principles could also be applied to other cost components.
The three main tariff approaches that are used are lump sum payments (per time period), energy charges (per kWh) and capacity charges (per kW and time period). As illustrated in
Figure 2, a variety of different combinations of these charges are used in EU countries. In addition to that, the share of costs that are allocated to each component, and the detailed design for each of these charging components vary greatly among different countries.
The great variety in approaches and designs raises the question regarding optimal tariff design. As a result of the increasing electrification of transport and heat sectors, short-term elasticity of demand is rapidly growing. At the same time, the rollout of smart meters is providing new opportunities for the smart control of these devices. Future-proof tariffs should thus be designed in a way that leverages these opportunities to send optimal dispatch and investment signals.
Analyses of grid tariff designs are often limited to the tariff impact on grid peak load and the resulting grid investment need. Within this paper, we include an assessment of additional criteria such as the tariff impact on electricity generation cost, profitability of different technologies and cost-redistribution between households from different income brackets, which are also relevant for the choice between different tariff approaches.
The structure of this paper is as follows. In
Section 2, we summarize the approaches that were suggested and the main relevant findings from the literature on optimal tariff design. In
Section 3, we describe the tariff scenarios and in
Section 4 the data used in the analyses for this paper. The results of our analysis are reported in
Section 5 and discussed in
Section 6. In
Section 8 we describe our conclusions and policy implications.
2. Literature
To date, a substantial body of literature has explored different optimization strategies for home energy management systems (HEMS), particularly for appliance scheduling. Many decentralized approaches use linear optimization to determine households’ responses to external price signals. Ref. [
4] uses mixed-integer linear programming (MILP) to minimize household electricity costs by adjusting appliance load profiles in a time-dynamic pricing scheme. They model prosumer households with various adaptable appliances and devices such as EVs, ESS, thermal storage systems, and household appliances. Ref. [
5] minimizes electricity bills over a multi-day time horizon, incorporating a penalty term into the objective function to account for the prosumers’ comfort. In addition to time-dynamic electricity tariffs, [
6] employ MILP to investigate prosumers’ short-term adaption under five distinct electricity tariffs, which include a capacity tariff and multiple bidirectional tariffs. They find that these two concepts significantly reduce grid interaction. Ref. [
7] introduces a multi-objective optimization problem to study the balance between minimizing electricity costs and enhancing households’ comfort under two different power-based electricity contracts.
Taking into account that individual optimal appliance scheduling is not necessarily beneficial to the grid operation, several studies propose frameworks that coordinate DR. Ref. [
8] uses a bi-level optimization problem to investigate coordinated DR. At the lower level, they optimize the electricity bills of households, while in the upper level, they minimize the overall system load. Ref. [
9] proposes an optimization approach at the neighborhood level to coordinate DR.
One of the main findings from this literature is that with increasing levels of automation, discontinuous price signals, such as time-of-use tariffs and critical peak prices could not reduce the peak load, and lead to an even higher rebound peak at the beginning of low-price periods. The solutions proposed to this problem include the introduction of a protection period after the high-tariff hours [
10], the introduction of different price signals for different consumer groups [
11] and the imposition of binding power limits during scarcity [
4,
9,
12]. However, while the resulting dispatch may be effective in achieving a lower peak demand, these studies do not distinguish between the tariff approaches for recovering energy cost, grid cost or residual cost, and do not analyze how the suggested proposals affect other tariff design criteria, such as cost-recovery, welfare, equity and other dimensions of acceptability (i.e., fairness, transparency) [
13,
14,
15]. In addition to that, only two of the studies assess the suitability of capacity tariffs [
6,
7], and none of them evaluate the impact of using a continuous tariff signal, instead of a discrete step-function.
In our paper, we will fill this gap, by exploring the impact of both a capacity tariff and a novel continuous tariff signal proportional to grid load and compare their performance to the performance of other approaches for avoiding rebound peaks along all the above-mentioned tariff design criteria and calculate the overall efficiency of tariffs including impacts on grid peak-load, grid and energy cost, technology profitability and equity.
3. Methodology
To simulate the behavior of consumers and prosumers in response to dynamic electricity prices and to analyze the effects of the resulting load profiles on the grid infrastructure and consequently grid costs, we use a linear optimization model. An overview of the model structure is provided in
Figure 3. The inputs for this model include the “infrastructure scenario” and the “tariff scenario”.
The “infrastructure scenario” outlines the number, types, and equipment of households being simulated. We define 13 distinct consumer and prosumer types based on variations in asset equipment and household characteristics. Consumers can have different combinations of heat pumps (HP), electric vehicles (EV), or neither of these assets, while prosumers are additionally equipped with photovoltaic (PV) systems and potentially Battery Electric Storage Systems (BESS). We model BESS, EVs and HPs as shiftable in time since these devices offer the required flexibility and are likely to be the largest contributors to demand peaks by 2035 [
16]. Other household loads, such as wet goods, stoves, consumer electronics, etc., are considered inflexible in the model.
We will analyze the effects of nine different “tariff scenarios” by comparing two distinct incentive mechanisms: capacity tariffs (type 2) and time-differentiated tariffs (tariff type 3–8) which are price-based mechanisms, along with a “direct load control” scheme (tariff type 9) which operated as an incentive-based mechanism.
flat: constant price per kWh during all hours
capacity: constant price per kW individual annual consumption peak
tou: time-of-use tariff, with a daily high- and low tariff period
cpp-h: critical-peak-price tariff, with a high tariff during those hours when load reaches its annual maximum and a low tariff otherwise
cpp-d: critical-peak-price tariff, with a high tariff during all high-tariff hours of the tou tariff on days, when load reaches its annual maximum and a low tariff otherwise
grid load: a tariff that is proportional to the projected grid load prior to load shifting
spot: a tariff that is proportional to spot prices
grid load and spot: a combination of 5 and 6.
dlc: direct load control tariff
The simulation model consists of three stages. In the first stage, system costs are calculated based on the exogenous infrastructure scenario. The electricity tariff levels are calibrated following the cost recovery principle which ensures that grid, energy and residual costs are fully recovered by each tariff scheme. The second stage models households’ operational decisions on the electricity tariffs using a linear optimization model. After calculating the optimal household dispatch, the third and last stage of the model adjusts tariff levels according to the optimized load profiles to ensure grid cost recovery. Re-calibrated tariff levels are then used as input for calculating the impact metrics. The mathematical notation and further details regarding the dispatch model, the method for tariff calibration and calculation of the impact metrics are provided in the
Appendix A,
Appendix B,
Appendix C,
Appendix D and
Appendix E.
4. Data
The model was utilized to simulate a synthetic subset of a distribution grid, encompassing a single transformer station that serves 300 households. These households exhibit variations in terms of device equipment and consumption patterns. The simulation is conducted for two distinct years, 2020 and 2050, with an hourly resolution. Synthetic load profiles were employed for households, electric vehicles, heat pumps, and photovoltaic systems.
The simulation model is calibrated for a case study in the canton of Aargau, Switzerland. Within the model, two complete years are simulated with hourly resolution, differing in the distribution of flexible electrical appliances and installations. The electricity tariffs are aligned with the average electricity cost proportions from the year 2021, corresponding to an electricity cost of 20.01 Rp./kWh. Between the two simulated years, household appliance equipment varied based on survey data and forecasts. For the 2020 appliance equipment, data from the Swiss Household Energy Demand Survey (SHEDS) conducted from 2016 to 2020 were utilized. The survey encompassed 5000 Swiss households and gathered information about their appliance equipment and consumption behavior. Appliance equipment estimation for the year 2050 was performed using forecasts from the Swiss Federal Office of Energy [
17]. These forecasts expect that by 2050 around 68% of all households will have a heat pump, 78% an EV, 47% a BESS and 67% a PV module. Household counts were estimated by adjusting household counts for each type from 2020 in a way that achieves this marginal diffusion of the different technologies while minimizing the sum of squared deviations between the household share in 2020 and the household share in 2050.
The resulting number of household types for each scenario year and node is presented in
Table 1. We differentiate between 12 different types of households, depending on whether the household is equipped with HP, EV, BESS or PV. For example, for 2020 we assume that 1 of the 300 households (0.3%) which we simulate is equipped with HP, EV and PV (type9), while during 2050 we assume that this number rises to 60 households (20%).
We assume that only the load from HPs, EVs or BESSs responds to flexibility incentives. The remaining portion of residential load and PV system generation is considered non-flexible.
Simulations were based on synthetic load profiles from the LoadProfileGenerator (LPG) [
18]. PV production profiles and heat pump load profiles were calculated based on building-level data from a distribution grid operator in the canton of Aargau. Further details on the load profiles can be found in the
Appendix F.
5. Results
This section presents the findings of the case study. First, in
Section 5.1, we display the model results for the current scenario, where 28% of households possess one of the flexible technologies. Additionally, 8% of households in this scenario are equipped with a PV system. Moving on to the 2050 future scenario, the share of prosumers in the grid area rises to 67%, while the share of households with flexible technologies increases to 78%. The outcomes of this scenario are elaborated upon in
Section 5.2.
5.1. Scenario 2020
5.1.1. Effectivity
We assess the effectiveness of the tariffs based on the change in peak load incentivized by each tariff compared to the load under a flat tariff (Status Quo—SQ) within the considered network area.
Figure 4 illustrates the change in load at the time when the peak load occurred in the SQ scenario (blue) as well as the change in the overall peak load (red).
The time-variable tariffs with two distinct price levels (TOU, CPP_h, and CPP_d) effectively decrease the load at the time of the peak load in SQ, but they result in a new peak load occurring at a different time, which is even higher than the original peak load. The effect of increased peak loads due to new tariff structures is recognized in the existing literature as a “rebound peak” [
11,
12]. This effect stems from the step-like nature of price signals in time-varying tariffs with fixed, predefined price levels. This leads to a cumulative shift in flexible loads from high-tariff periods to the first subsequent low-tariff time slot. As these subsequent times often exhibit high load levels in comparison to the daily average, the shifted load can result in a peak load surpassing the original magnitude (
Figure 5a).
Capacity tariffs (capacity) and direct load control (DLC) can avoid the rebound peak. However, the capacity tariff only achieves very small peak-load reductions of a few percentages, as the peaks of individual customers often do not coincide with the peak load of the total grid. The DLC tariff obtains the strongest peak-load reduction, as it assumes a central optimization with the objective of minimizing the peak load. In the 2020 scenario, the DLC tariff achieves a peak load reduction of around 20%. However, because of unbundling restrictions, DLC typically does not account for the energy costs as part of the optimization. Conceptually, it is, therefore, less suitable for minimizing the sum of grid and energy costs (see next section).
The tariff signal proportional to total load (grid load) achieves a lower peak-load reduction than DLC. However, in the 2020 scenario, it can avoid rebound peaks as it prompts flexible loads to shift to a period when the system load is comparatively lower (
Figure 5b). Compared to capacity tariffs and DLC, an important advantage of the grid-load tariff is, that it may be combined with an energy component that is proportional to spotprices (gridload_spot). We, therefore, expect that if the grid and energy tariff components are calibrated appropriately, this tariff should, therefore, minimize the sum of grid and energy costs (see next section below).
5.1.2. Efficiency
Figure 6 shows the sum of grid, energy and residual cost which result under each tariff for the 2020 scenario. Across the board, the price impacts of all tariffs remain relatively modest, ranging from a reduction of −3.2% to an increase of +1.6%. The two main reasons for this are the small number of households that are equipped with flexible technology, and the assumption, that only 30% of grid costs depend on peak load.
As expected, the trend in network costs closely mirrors the outcomes of the effectiveness analysis, with DLC and grid-load tariffs reducing grid costs most strongly (by 6.46% and 2.05%, respectively).
Regarding the impact on energy cost, as expected, most tariffs hardly reduce the energy cost because of the high tariff periods for time variable tariffs (TOU, CPP_h, and CPP_d) cover hours with a high grid load, which may not be the hours with the highest spot prices and capacity tariffs (capacity) and direct load-control does not target a reduction in energy cost. Tariffs proportional to the spot price (spot), therefore, achieve the strongest reduction in energy cost (by 2.89%), followed by the combined tariff where the grid component is proportional to the total load, and the energy component is proportional to spot prices (gridload_spot).
However, the result regarding the sum of all cost components is different from expected. Even though the combined gridload_spot tariff is the only one that explicitly considers both cost components, the total cost reduction achieved by this tariff (1.42%) is lower than the total cost reduction achieved by direct load control (3.16%) or the grid-load tariff (1.6%). We assume that this is due to a sub-optimal design of the grid-load tariff signal, which puts too much weight on a reduction in grid-load during hours when the grid is not congested. This will be further discussed in
Section 6.
5.1.3. Profitability
Figure 7 displays the average electricity costs for households with different appliances under the baseline scenario with a constant price per kWh.
Figure 8 illustrates how electricity costs for households equipped with different devices and appliances change under different tariff scenarios compared to the baseline scenario with a constant price per kWh. With capacity pricing, electricity costs rise for households lacking flexible technology. The most significant increase occurs in households with PV systems. This is due to different approaches to allocating variable grid costs. In the baseline tariff, variable grid costs are evenly distributed across total energy consumption. Since households with PV systems exhibit lower grid consumption due to self-consumption, they bear only a minor share of variable grid costs under a fixed tariff. However, under the capacity tariff, variable grid costs are allocated solely to individual peak loads, resulting in higher electricity costs for PV-equipped households. The introduction of additional flexibilities can mitigate this cost increase to some extent, but the flexibility of EVs and BESS is not enough to completely offset the rise in costs, resulting in higher electricity expenses for households with these device combinations as well.
This phenomenon is also observed under TOU, CPP-h, and CPP-d. These tariffs spread variable network costs over a limited number of hours, mainly in the morning or evening when PV generation is lower. Conversely, households with high electricity consumption, which bear a significant portion of variable grid costs in the baseline scenario, can benefit from these tariffs by reducing their peak load or shifting consumption away from high-tariff periods. HPs are particularly advantageous as they can offer flexibility throughout the cold season. EVs, due to their limited stationary time, exhibit less flexibility, and therefore, have a smaller impact on load shifting.
Similarly, the spot tariff leads to increased annual electricity costs for prosumers and non-flexible households. For non-flexible households, this is primarily due to the low efficiency of the spot tariff, leading to an overall cost increase. In the case of prosumers, the strong negative correlation between spot prices and the PV generation profile results in lower savings from self-consumption during midday hours in the summer. Since this effect is more pronounced in the summer months, additional flexibility in the form of HPs has a modest cost-reducing effect. EVs, on the other hand, provide a stronger cost-reducing impact for prosumers under this tariff. In the gridload_spot tariff, the negative correlation between PV generation and price signal persists, causing prosumers without additional flexibilities to fare worse under this tariff compared to the baseline. Inflexible consumers, however, benefit from the tariff’s efficiency, resulting in only minor additional costs, typically less than 1 CHF per year.
Under the grid-load tariff, the additional costs for prosumers and households without flexibility are notably diminished. Only households with PV systems experience a slight uptick in electricity costs. This phenomenon can be attributed to both the effectiveness and efficiency of the grid-load tariff in the 2020 scenario, which lowers the costs for allocation. Furthermore, variable grid costs are still assigned to the total annual energy consumption, albeit with grid load-dependent weighting. Consequently, the cost increase for prosumers is less pronounced compared to time-variable or capacity tariffs.
Remarkably, the DLC tariff is the sole tariff resulting in decreased annual costs across all household types. This is due to the substantial reduction in total costs, which persist despite the fixed allocation to energy purchases.
5.1.4. Equity
Results in the previous section demonstrated that households equipped with multiple flexible appliances tend to profit more from dynamic tariffs than households with less flexibility. In order to verify, to what extent this effect will lead to a cost redistribution from richer to poorer households,
Figure 9 shows the average electricity price for households from different income brackets under each of the electricity tariffs.
Contrary to our expectations, the main impact of the tariffs is a parallel shift of the average cost across most income brackets. The reason for this is, that in 2020 heatpumps are the only flexible technology which is available to a larger number of households, and the share of households from different income brackets in
Table 1 is roughly the same in the case of “type 2” (with heatpump) and “type 1” (without flexibility). Surprisingly, the households with the lowest income in this case study exhibit the lowest electricity costs under all tariff scenarios. This is due to the fact, that there are quite a few households from the lowest income group which are equipped with PV panels, e.g., because they are tenants of a landlord that chose to install PV.
5.2. Scenario 2050
5.2.1. Effectivity
In the 2050 scenario, the peak load rises from 492 MW in the 2020 scenario to 919 MW in the 2050 scenario because of electrification. However, many of the new loads are flexible, so the share of households with flexible technology increases to 78% and 67% of the households are assumed to have PV. The impact of the different tariffs on peak load is illustrated in
Figure 10.
As a result of the higher share of flexible loads, the rebound peak which is created by time-varying tariffs (TOU, CPP_h, and CPP_d) increases sharply from between 5% and 15% in 2020 to more than 40% in 2050.
Capacity tariffs and DLC can effectively avoid rebound peaks, and reduce grid peak load by about 10% (in the case of capacity tariffs) and more than 40% (in the case of DLC). However, even this load reduction is inadequate to bring the total peak load down to the levels observed in the 2020 scenario, necessitating grid expansion to accommodate the increased demand.
By contrast to the 2020 scenario where the grid-load tariff contributed to a reduction in the peak load, it can no longer avoid rebound peaks in the 2050 scenario. Surprisingly, the rebound peak, which is caused by grid-load tariffs, even exceeds that which is caused by time-varying tariffs, causing the peak load to more than double compared to the baseline tariff. This phenomenon is a result of the shape of the price function associated with the grid-load tariff. Specifically, there is one single time step per day featuring a minimum price. Consequently, the entire flexible load around this time step is shifted to the moment with the lowest price. Given that these low-price periods usually occur during nighttime hours when a substantial number of EVs are available for charging (as depicted in
Figure 11), the charging load of multiple EVs is concentrated into a single time frame. This concentration of load results in significant rebound peaks. Suggestions for avoiding these rebound peaks will be discussed in
Section 6. In contrast to grid-load tariffs, the timing of the high tariff periods for the other time-varying tariffs (TOU, CPP_h, and CPP_d) occurs during morning or late afternoon hours. During these times, the proportion of available EVs is relatively limited (
Figure 11), which explains the lower rebound peaks.
5.2.2. Efficiency
Regarding grid costs, the same as for the 2020 scenario, the trend in network costs in
Figure 12 closely mirrors the outcomes of the effectiveness analysis. While time-varying tariffs (TOU, CPP_h, and CPP_d, and in 2050 also the grid-load tariff) increase grid costs due to rebound peaks, capacity tariffs and DLC can reduce the grid cost by 3.6% and 11.32%, respectively.
With regards to energy cost, as expected spot tariffs achieve the largest reduction in energy cost of about 9%, followed by the gridload_spot tariff, which reduces energy cost by about 8%.
Looking at the sum of all cost components, the impact of rebound peaks on grid costs clearly outweighs the beneficial impact of the grid load and spot tariffs on energy costs. Among the tariff designs that were investigated in this study, direct load control, therefore, achieves the largest cost reduction of about 12%, even though it does not significantly reduce energy costs. However, as we will describe in
Section 6, we assume that further improvements to the gridload_spot tariff design could lower the total cost even further.
5.2.3. Profitability
The substantial rise in total costs associated with time-variable tariffs has a significant impact on a considerable proportion of households. As shown in
Figure 13, time-varying tariffs increase annual electricity cost for most households. Only prosumers with PV & battery storage are partially shielded from escalating bills through potential reductions in their electricity consumption during peak periods, particularly with TOU and CPP tariffs. This is achieved by using their battery storage to offset demand during high-tariff periods, effectively mitigating the pronounced upswing in variable grid costs.
A noteworthy observation is that households equipped solely with an EV experience cost increases under the capacity tariff in the 2050 scenario, a contrast to the benefit they gained in the 2020 scenario due to decreasing prices in that tariff. While these households can curtail their peak load in the 2050 scenario, reducing it by an average of 29% from 13.4 kW to 9.5 kW, most households in the 2050 scenario possess multiple flexible appliances. These households exhibit even greater peak load reductions, averaging at 58%, from 13.3 kW to 5.5 kW. As a result, they bear only a minor portion of the variable grid costs under the capacity tariff, leaving the less flexible households to shoulder a larger portion of these costs. In the 2050 scenario, this includes households with an EV or a PV system along with an EV, leading to a less favorable outcome for them compared to the baseline tariff. In contrast, the DLC tariff significantly diminishes variable grid costs, contributing to a reduction in electricity costs for all types of households.
5.2.4. Equity
Although we assumed that the income distribution within household types remains unchanged between 2020 and 2050, the impact of the tariffs on average electricity cost in 2050 (
Figure 14) changes in two important ways compared to 2020.
First, the overall magnitude of the changes in electricity prices increases sharply. This is caused by the fact that the larger share of households with flexible devices in 2020 versus 2050 (see
Table 1) results in a much larger tariff impact on grid peak load (
Figure 10) and as a result, a larger impact on grid cost (
Figure 12).
Second, while the main impact of most tariffs is still a parallel shift, costs for poorer households increase significantly more than the cost for richer households in the case of capacity, TOU and CPP tariffs.
6. Discussion
The results from our simulations confirm the occurrence of rebound peaks in the case of time-varying tariffs in combination with automatic load control [
11,
12]. Direct load control and capacity-based tariffs can effectively avoid rebound peaks. However, due to the legal unbundling between grid and energy companies, direct load control is typically either used by grid operators to minimize grid costs or by energy suppliers, to minimize energy procurement costs.
Novel grid charges which are proportional to the grid load could overcome this problem. If customers are charged a gridload tariff (for their grid usage) and an energy tariff proportional to the spot price (for their energy consumption), they could ask independent aggregators to dispatch their loads in a way that minimizes the sum of grid and energy costs, which should minimize the sum of the total system cost.
While the performance of conventional direct load control (DLC) and capacity tariffs is similar in 2020 and 2050, the performance of the novel grid-load tariffs depends on the simulation year. Grid-load tariffs achieve the second biggest reduction in system peak load (
Figure 4) and system cost (
Figure 6) during 2020 when there are few flexible loads. This changes dramatically during 2050, when grid-load tariffs attract a much larger volume of flexible loads, resulting in rebound peaks of more than 100% (
Figure 10) and increasing system cost (
Figure 12). We believe that the failure of grid-load tariffs to minimize system cost, especially during years with a high share of flexible loads is due to the following two main reasons:
First, the tariff levels of the grid-load tariff were fixed in advance so that all flexible loads maximized consumption during the few time periods with the lowest tariff level. This could be avoided if tariff levels were fixed ex-post, based on the actual grid load which results after load-shifting and grid-load measurements were communicated close to real-time [
19]. This would mean that the incentive to shift towards a certain time period would be reduced as more loads start to shift towards that time period. Creating such a feedback loop between actual grid load and tariff levels could effectively mitigate rebound peaks.
Second, the grid load tariff which we have currently tested created incentives to reduce load even during such periods, when the grid was not congested. While this may be desirable from a grid perspective, it may reduce the incentive to minimize energy costs. To avoid this, grid tariffs should only send incentives for load-shifting, when the grid is constrained. During all other time periods, the grid tariff should not incentivize load-shifting, so that flexibility has an incentive to dispatch in a way that minimizes energy cost.
We have summarized our ideas for designing a grid tariff that complies with these criteria in the following research note [
20]. However, due to the complexity of modeling real-time tariffs, we have so far not been able to assess the impact of these proposals.
7. Limitations
When interpreting the results, it is important to note that certain simplifications and assumptions were made in this model.
First, we assume automatic load control of all flexible loads in response to electricity prices. This assumption is clearly not met today. However, as the costs for automation fall, we expect that more and more households will be equipped with automatic load control.
Second, the determination of grid costs is based on historical data and greatly simplifies the grid-cost impact that will occur in a real grid. In particular, we assume a linear dependency between grid peak load and grid costs, whereas in practice, the impact will follow a step-function.
Third, our model simulates only a single electricity tariff within each grid area. In a liberalized electricity market, households have the freedom to choose their tariff. Therefore, the extreme scenario of a single tariff will be unlikely to occur in a distribution grid.
Fourth, it was so far not possible to model the tariff designs suggested in [
20]. Our current model either calculates the optimal dispatch of each household independently of each other or as part of a central optimization problem (see
Appendix C). By contrast, the calculation of an ex-post grid tariff with near real-time load forecasts would require an iterative calculation of decentral optimizations by each household, which are linked to each other through their impact on the total grid load.
Fifth, in our current paper, we have simulated the impact of tariff designs for a single grid node. This could be generalized in subsequent papers by modeling tariff impacts on a system with several nodes and calculating nodal versions of the proposed tariff designs based on estimations of the system state [
21].
Last but not least we assume exogenous wholesale prices in our model, implying no feedback effect of behavioral changes in the grid area on wholesale prices. While this assumption might hold true when new tariff schemes are introduced in a limited number of distribution grids, it may not remain valid in the case of a large-scale rollout.
8. Conclusions
The increasing penetration of electric vehicles, heat pumps, and energy storage, along with the rollout of smart metering technology, is expected to significantly increase the potential for residential demand response. Leveraging this potential is a critical challenge in future electricity markets. Price-based demand response strategies have the potential to play a pivotal role by providing incentives for households to adjust their electricity consumption patterns in a cost-effective manner. However, since loads are controlled by households, or aggregators who provide the load control as a service rather than the grid operator, price incentives need to be carefully crafted to ensure that the decentralized load adjustments reduce the need for grid expansion.
This research aims to contribute to the discussion on electricity tariff design by investigating the impacts of various tariff structures on the decisions of households equipped with different combinations of photovoltaics, batteries, electric vehicles, and heat pumps. The study employs four evaluation metrics: (i) effectiveness, (ii) efficiency, (iii) profitability of technologies and (iv) equity.
The first finding of our research is the importance of including appropriate impact metrics. For example, we find that equity impacts on households tend to be smaller than the impacts on the profitability of different technologies, because a non-negligible share of poor households may live in houses with PV production or flexible loads. Impacts on households with and without flexible technologies may thus not be a good proxy for the distributional implications of different policies. Likewise, an exclusive evaluation of the impact of grid tariffs on grid load may be misleading, as grid tariffs that achieve a lower reduction in grid load may still be preferable as they perform better at reducing total system cost.
Regarding grid tariff design, our findings confirm that time-varying network tariffs such as time-of-use (TOU) tariffs or critical peak prices (CPP) can lead to rebound peaks that surpass the original load peak by a significant margin.
Dynamic load control (DLC) by grid operators can avoid rebound peaks and reduce grid load by up to 43%. Capacity tariffs can also avoid rebound peaks but reduce the grid load to a much smaller extent (up to 3.6%), as individual consumption peaks do not correlate well with total grid consumption.
Due to unbundling regulations, grid operators in Switzerland and the European Union may not use direct load control to minimize energy procurement costs. Direct load control by grid operators is, therefore, not a suitable option for reducing the sum of grid and energy costs in these countries, while it might be a viable option in other jurisdictions.
A novel grid tariff that depends on grid load could overcome both problems. If it is appropriately designed, it could incentivize customers to reduce grid load and avoid rebound peaks. At the same time, customers who are exposed to a grid load tariff (for their grid usage) and an energy tariff (for their energy consumption) should have an incentive to minimize total system cost.
To avoid rebound peaks, the grid-load tariff should depend on real-time grid load instead of ex-ante projections of grid-load. At the same time, the grid-load tariff should avoid load-shifting incentives when the grid is not constrained, so that flexibility can be used to minimize energy procurement costs.