Next Article in Journal
COVID-19 and Supply Chain Disruption Management: A Behavioural Economics Perspective and Future Research Direction
Next Article in Special Issue
Analysis of Green Innovation of the E-Tailer and Supplier with a Drop Shipping Option in E-Commerce
Previous Article in Journal
Empowering the Online Media System: The Innovative Route of Effective Digital Government Response in China
Previous Article in Special Issue
Deep Filter Context Network for Click-Through Rate Prediction
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Enhancing Traceability in Wine Supply Chains through Blockchain: A Stackelberg Game-Theoretical Analysis

1
School of Economics and Management, Beijing Jiaotong University, Beijing 100044, China
2
School of Management, Wuhan Polytechnic University, Wuhan 430048, China
3
School of Economics and Management, University of Chinese Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100190, China
4
Department of Logistics and Maritime Studies, The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Hung Hom, Hong Kong 999077, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2023, 18(4), 2142-2162; https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer18040108
Submission received: 16 October 2023 / Revised: 8 November 2023 / Accepted: 14 November 2023 / Published: 22 November 2023

Abstract

:
Blockchain technology has been adopted to improve traceability and authenticity in wine supply chains (WSCs). However, whether through outsourcing or self-implementation of a blockchain-based wine traceability system (BTS), there are significant costs involved, as well as concerns regarding consumer privacy. Motivated by observations of real-world practice, we explore the value of blockchain in enhancing traceability and authenticity in WSCs through a Stackelberg game-theoretical analysis. By comparing the equilibrium solutions of the scenarios with and without blockchain, we uncover the value of blockchain in tracing wine products. Our findings show that blockchain adoption can increase WSC prices under certain conditions. We derive the threshold for a third-party BTS service fee that determines blockchain adoption for tracing wine products and reveal the moderating effect of consumer traceability preferences and privacy concerns. Furthermore, the investigation of who should lead the implementation of BTS finds that the equal cost sharing between the manufacturer and the retailer results in no difference in BTS implementation leadership. Otherwise, the manufacturer always benefits from taking the lead in the implementation of BTS, and the retailer should undertake a leadership role in BTS implementation if they need to bear higher costs.

1. Introduction

Improving wine traceability is essential for combating counterfeit products in wine supply chains (WSC) and meeting the expectations of consumers who are increasingly concerned about the origin and quality of the wines. Foremost, combating counterfeit wine products is one of the long-standing issues in managing WSCs and has a significant negative impact on consumers and wine producers. Fraudulent wine constitutes approximately 20% of the entire wine market in the past five years [1]. From December 2021 to May 2022, the European Anti-Fraud Office seized nearly 14.8 million litres of illicit wine across Europe [2]. In addition, Recorded Future tracked more than 93 million bottles of counterfeit wine between January 2020 and June 2022 [3]. Counterfeiters often replicate the appearance and packaging of well-known wine brands, using low-quality ingredients or substandard production methods to create bottles that appear authentic. For instance, in 2022, a major Italian wine producer was accused of blending low-quality wine with premium varieties and selling it under prestigious labels [4]. In 2021, a posh wine retailer in New York was fined $100K for fake bourbon sales [5]. The vulnerability to counterfeiting has become one of the distinctive features of the WSC. First, the rarity and high value of some fine wines make them an attractive target for counterfeiters looking to make a quick profit. Second, the complex supply chain involved in the production and distribution of wines makes it difficult to identify all the actors involved in the fraud. Moreover, distinguishing itself from other luxury goods, wine is difficult to detect as fake even for experienced connoisseurs, as the taste and aroma of a particular vintage can vary depending on a variety of factors such as storage conditions and ageing. Meanwhile, the value of bottled wine products is greatly reduced after being opened and tested.
Meanwhile, consumers’ preference for the traceability and authenticity of wine products is also becoming increasingly important [6,7,8]. Several factors drive consumers’ preference for traceability, including concerns about product safety, environmental sustainability, ethical production practices, etc. Consumers want to know where the wine comes from, how it was produced, and whether it was produced in an environmentally friendly way. They also want to know whether the wine was produced using ethical labour practices and whether the workers involved in the production process were treated fairly.
Many efforts have been made to improve the traceability of the WSC. For example, the wine producer, Paumanok Vineyards (New York, USA), used genotyping and DNA marking of the wine and packaging to ensure product traceability. Comtes von Neipperg, a vineyard in France, applied a translucent polymer seal or stick-on label with a unique configuration of bubbles for wine authentication and anti-counterfeiting [9]. Unfortunately, those traceability efforts are unable to eliminate wine counterfeiting and cannot gain consumers’ full trust in traceable information about the wine products. Meanwhile, the emergence of blockchain technology has brought a tremendous improvement in traceability due to its unique ability to provide robust anti-counterfeiting and traceability measures [10,11,12]. The blockchain-based tracing system (BTS) provides an immutable ledger that allows for secure and transparent tracking of wines from farm to table. This ensures that all stakeholders in the wine industry, from manufacturers to consumers, can have confidence in the authenticity and quality of the product. With blockchain-based traceability, any issues or concerns can be easily identified and addressed, which leads many technology giants to invest in BTS and provide blockchain-as-a-service (BaaS) for the WSC, like Alibaba and IBM (detailed in Table 1). The global BaaS market size stood at USD 1.90 billion in 2019 and is projected to reach USD 24.94 billion by 2027 [13]. Additionally, few top leading wine manufacturers like Moutai (China), Diageo (UK) or retailers like Walmart (U.S.), JD (China) have opted to build their own BTS.
However, the adoption of blockchain in WSCs has faced several obstacles. One of the biggest hurdles is the cost of purchasing BaaS solutions or implementing a BTS by WSC members. The pricing of different third-party BTS providers is illustrated in Table 1. The price may not seem much at first glance, but it can add up quickly over time and across multiple nodes in WSCs. Plus, implementing BTS by WSC members themselves also requires investing in hardware, software, maintenance, and security. The exact cost of implementing a BTS varies depending on the complexity and scale of the system, with an estimate of around USD 40K to USD 300K [18]. Therefore, both options pose significant financial challenges for WSC members who want to adopt blockchain in the wine industry.
In addition, consumer privacy is another concern for blockchain technologies, which also applies to the WSC. A KPMG report shows 56% of customers distrust companies’ privacy policies [19]. Even though blockchain is pseudonymous [20], hackers can link pseudo-identities to real ones and infer 80% of transactions. Ironically, they can reveal all their past purchases whenever they want due to blockchain’s immutability. It can be a more serious issue in WSCs, as the target customers of high-valued fine wines are normally individuals with high social status and wealth [21] and are therefore sensitive to the leak of personal information. At the same time, as one popular choice of luxury gifts, some consumers want to conceal the wine’s former ownership and regifting history. Obviously, blockchain’s transparency and immutability increase their privacy concerns. Hence, ensuring data security while utilising the benefits of blockchain technology presents a significant challenge in the wine industry.
Motivated by the observations of real-world practices, this study seeks to address the following questions:
  • What are the optimal wholesale and retail prices and level of traceability effort for the WSC members with blockchain adoption for WSC traceability and authenticity?
  • How does the adoption of BTS affect the WSC performance? Is it possible that adopting blockchain does more harm than good?
  • How does the adoption of a third-party’s BTS or self-implementation affect WSC members’ operational decisions and performance?
To address the above research questions, we develop a consumer utility-based analytical model and conduct a Stackelberg game-theoretical analysis. To better understand the value of blockchain to the WSC, we compare the two scenarios with and without blockchain, and derive the condition for adopting blockchain. Our analysis uncovers the value of blockchain in tracing wine products within the WSC and includes extended modelling to discuss the preferable choice of using blockchain technology.
To the best of our knowledge, this paper is one of the pioneering analytical operations management (OM) studies that explore blockchain-based traceability in WSC with the consideration of different ways to adopt BTS (e.g., outsourcing or self-implementation). Compared to studies that discuss the value of blockchain-based traceability in the general supply chain [22,23], our research focusses on wine products and emphasises the interaction between the WSC’s unique characteristics (counterfeit vulnerability, privacy concerns, and traceability preference) and blockchain technology, complementing existing research on blockchain-based traceability. Compared to studies that examine the value of blockchain in combating counterfeits [24,25,26,27], we additionally consider the influence of non-blockchain-based traceability efforts on wine authenticity. This assumption, which is more closely aligned with wine industry practices, enables us to provide practitioners with novel insights into the potential benefits of blockchain-based authenticity. Compared to the limited research that examines various modes of blockchain adoption [27,28], our study enriches the topic by providing a comparative analysis between outsourcing BTS and self-implementing BTS by different WSC members. Our findings yield several significant implications that offer guidance to managers on the effective implementation of BTS.
The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. Section 2 presents the literature review. Section 3 describes the basic analytical models for the WSC without BTS adoption (Model N) and with third-party BTS adoption (Model B). In Section 4, the two basic models are compared, and the values of blockchain in WSC are examined. Section 5 presents an extended analysis of the various approaches to implementing blockchain in WSC, and Section 6 concludes the study.

2. Literature Review

2.1. The Adoption of Blockchain Technology in the WSC

With the prevalent adoption of blockchain technology in supply chains, the cases of blockchain application in the WSC are often cited as compelling evidence of how blockchain technology can be used to improve supply chain traceability, visibility, trust, etc. [29,30,31]. Meanwhile, some scholars have undertaken detailed case studies of implementing blockchain technology within the WSC. Danese et al. [32] conducted a multiple-case study of five Italian wine companies using blockchain and found that the key factor in designing blockchain systems is the desired level of counterfeiting protection that a brand owner wants to provide to customers through blockchain. Brookbanks and Parry [33] present a case study of two wine supply chains through semi-structured interviews to determine how trust and trustworthiness develop in buyer–supplier relationships and the impact of a blockchain-based technology’s proof of concept on supply chain trust.
Moreover, considering the uniqueness of the WSC, several researchers employ other methodologies to investigate the application of blockchain technology in the WSC. Brookbanks and Parry [34] examine the determinants of technology adoption in the grape wine supply chain by proposing a blockchain architecture. They find that disintermediation, traceability, price, trust, compliance, and coordination and control are the most significant factors in the given order for actors in the grape wine supply chain to adopt blockchain technology. Tokkozhina et al. [35] propose an architecture for a blockchain-based system to track WSC transactions from grape harvesting to wine purchase. This system demonstrates the potential of blockchain technology to reduce counterfeiting, assure wine origin, avoid health risks, and increase brand reputation. Adamashvili et al. [36] design an agent-based model and a GAMA program simulation to investigate whether a blockchain-based WSC could be more effective than a traditional one in terms of information sharing and of time and costs of tracking back products. Luzzani et al. [37] conduct an exploratory study on the use of blockchain technology in the WSC for improving sustainability. It shows that blockchain allows for the collection of relevant data and information, but wine companies have little familiarity with its applications.
A review of existing studies on blockchain technology reveals several key trade-offs in its application to the WSC, including enhanced traceability and authenticity, concerns over consumer privacy, and high costs. Our research addresses the issue of blockchain adoption in the WSC; we extend the current literature by utilising a game theory-based analytical model, and our model examines the effects of blockchain technology on challenging OM problems.

2.2. Supply Chain Traceability Management

Constructing a robust and reliable tracing system is vital for supply chains. Previous research has shown that consumers have a sufficient preference for product traceability [38,39,40]. In addition, earlier studies have also explored how traditional wine tracing technologies, such as wireless sensor networks (WSN) or radio frequency identification (RFID), can enhance WSC traceability [41,42]. These methods can help identify and control wine quality and satisfy consumer’s traceability preferences to some extent. However, they are not fully trustworthy tracing systems.
Nowadays, supply chain traceability management has entered a new era with the development of blockchain technology in recent years. For instance, Yiu [43] discusses blockchain technology’s potential to develop decentralised product anti-counterfeiting and traceability ecosystems in the supply chain. The paper identifies key areas of decentralisation, fundamental system requirements, and feasible mechanisms for developing secure and immutable scientific data provenance tracking and management platforms utilising blockchain technology. Hastig and Sodhi [44] conduct a thematic analysis of the implementation of blockchain for supply chain traceability. Their findings indicate that the critical success factors for successful implementation include companies’ capabilities, collaboration, technology maturity, supply chain practices, leadership, and governance of traceability efforts. Cui et al. [45] provide a theoretical investigation into the value and design of traceability-driven blockchains under different supply chain structures. They find that firms operating in various supply chains may encounter unique challenges when they adopt blockchain technology. It may be easier to gain traction in a serial supply chain, whereas it would be more critical for the buyer in a parallel supply chain to influence data governance and compensate suppliers for their efforts to improve data quality. Wu et al. [28] analytically explore the strategies for adopting a blockchain technology system in the fresh product supply chain (FPSC) by comparing the scenarios of non-blockchain technology with three different FPSC members respectively leading the construction of the blockchain system. They derive the optimal conditions for blockchain system deployment in FPSC and design a two-part tariff contract for FPSC coordination. Fan et al. [23] discuss the adoption of blockchain in supply chains and provide a trade-off condition regarding consumers’ traceability awareness, production costs, and the cost of blockchain adoption. They also find that revenue-sharing contracts can promote the use of blockchain.
Existing research indicates that supply chain traceability management is a persistent topic of interest, particularly with the advancement of tracing technology. While early studies have focused on the adoption of previous-generation tracing technology in the WSC, the adoption of blockchain has primarily been examined through qualitative methods. Our research considers the unique characteristics of the WSC and extends the current literature on traceability management.

2.3. Blockchain-Based Supply Chain Operations Management

Finally, our work is also related to the growing body of literature that tackles the OM problems in the blockchain-based supply chain. Currently, many types of supply chains have scholars conducting blockchain-based OM research, such as medicine supply chains, E-commerce supply chains, green product supply chains, and so on [46,47,48,49]. To be specific, Liu et al. [50] develop an analytical model to examine the value of blockchain technology in the imported fresh food supply chain during the COVID-19 pandemic. By considering the risk attitudes of supply chain members, they find that blockchain technology does not necessarily bring substantial benefits to the food supply chain.
However, it can help manufacturers and retailers increase their profits under certain conditions. Choi [24] examines various consumer utility-driven operational models and emphasises the importance of blockchain technology-supported platforms for diamond authentication and certification. The paper reveals that the shopping convenience and the cost of blockchain technology-based diamond authentication and certification are critical factors in determining whether to adopt blockchain or not.
Furthermore, other related studies also reveal some interesting insights in general supply chain content. Pun et al. [26] employ a model based on signalling game theory to investigate the potential use of blockchain technology by firms and governments in combating counterfeiting. Their analysis considers the impact of customers’ post-purchase regret and concerns about leaving a digital footprint on the adoption of blockchain technology. Additionally, the authors consider the effectiveness of different government strategies in promoting the use of blockchain technology. Shen et al. [27] examine the use of permissioned blockchain technology (PBT) to combat copycats in the supply chain. They find that PBT benefits brand-name companies (BNCs) by helping customers identify product authenticity and quality, increasing BNC profitability, consumer surplus, and social welfare, and reducing copycat earnings. However, BNCs may decrease product quality when using PBT if consumers can distinguish between genuine and imitation products.
Table 2 summarises the positioning of this study in the context of the most relevant literature. Our research contributes to this research area by identifying two key characteristics of blockchain-based traceability in the WSC: its ability to combat wine counterfeiting and its potential impact on consumer privacy. Additionally, we examine the optimal mode of BTS adoption, whether through outsourcing or self-implementation, which enriches the existing research.

3. The Basic Model

As a high-value-added product with a complex production process, the traceability of wine products is an important issue in the wine industry. The more detailed the traceability, like raw material origin, brewing year, storage method, etc., the more the consumers’ expectations in terms of quality, collection value, or eco-production preference can be guaranteed. In addition, as one of the most obvious exogenous benefits of wine traceability, the level of traceability is positively correlated with the ability of consumers to identify the authenticity of wine, which means the more effort manufacturers spend on wine traceability, the higher possibility that customers can distinguish the wine authenticity when the WSC suffers counterfeiting.
Meanwhile, blockchain technology has significantly improved wine traceability in the supply chain. Its decentralised and transparent ledger system guarantees that traceability information cannot be tampered with. This means that the BTS can not only transmit basic production and processing information, but also eliminate wine counterfeiting. The same is true for non-blockchain-based tracing systems; the higher the level of traceability efforts in the BTS, the better the traceability preferences of consumers can be satisfied.
In our study, we consider whether the manufacturer and the retailer decide to use blockchain to enhance traceability in the WSC. Each agent in the WSC makes its own pricing decision. To enhance readability, the definitions of different models and some important variables are described in Table 3.

3.1. Model N: Non-Blockchain-Based Tracing Systems

In Model N, we assume the wine traceability-sensitive consumer θ has the possibility α to buy fake wine. Following [26,27], we investigate the situation where all the supply chain members have a perception that wine counterfeiting might occur. In addition, to describe the manufacturer’s traceability efforts for wine without using blockchain, we denote t n as the non-blockchain-based traceability (NBT) effort. Meanwhile, considering the increased NBT efforts can enhance consumers’ ability to distinguish authentic wine. Thus, α t n indicates the probability that consumers successfully identify the authentic wine, and α 1 t n represents the probability of failing to identify the counterfeit wine. This assumption is in line with previous studies [47].
We consider a single consumer market in which consumers have a heterogeneous valuation v of the wine. We assume v follows a distribution f ( · ) , which is a uniform distribution with a lower bound of 0 and an upper bound of 1. When the consumer decides whether to buy the wine, they will consider factors including (i) the retail price p n ; (ii) the level of traceability, which we denote by θ t n ; and (iii) the level of consumers suffering from counterfeit α 1 t n , where α and 1 t n represent the likelihood of buying counterfeit wine and the failure rate of identifying the fake one, respectively. Noting that consumers choose to buy the wine when the consumers’ utility U n = v p n α 1 t n + θ t n > 0 . Then, the demand function is given as follows:
D n = 1 p n α 1 t n + θ t n
The structure of the WSC in Model N is shown in Figure 1, and the sequence of events is as follows. The manufacturer determines the wholesale price w n and NBT effort t n as the WSC leader. Then, the retailer determines the retail price p n as the follower. To focus on our main research problem and avoid trivial cases, we assume that the manufacturer’s production cost and the retailer’s selling cost are zero [26,50,52]. However, we consider the NBT cost K n ( t n ) incurred by the manufacturer in implementing non-blockchain-based measures, which is given by k n t n 2 / 2 , where k n > 0 and represents the NBT cost coefficient [53,54,55,56]. Intuitively, improving the traceability level indicates more information sharing among WSC members, like stricter wine distribution monitoring, more advanced security measures, etc. Those lead to a non-trivial cost when the desirable NBT level is higher. It is therefore reasonable to apply a quadratic cost structure, which reflects the fact that the marginal NBT cost increases for achieving a higher traceability level.
Thus, the profit functions of the manufacturer ( π m ) and the retailer ( π r ) are given as follows:
π m n w n , t n = w n D n K n ( t )
π r n p n = ( p n w n ) D n
Using backward induction, we derive the optimal decisions of the WSC without blockchain. For a given w n , checking the second-order condition of Equation (3), we find that 2 π r n p n 2 = 2 < 0 , which implies that Equation (3) is a concave function. Then, by solving the first-order condition of Equation (3), we derive the optimal retail price for given w n and t n . Putting p n * w n , t n into the demand function Equation (1), we derive the optimal demand for given w n   and   t n , i.e., D n * w n , t n . Then, putting it into Equation (2), we find that π m n is jointly concave in w n and t n when k n > ( θ + α ) 2 4 , so we derive the analytical closed-form expressions of the equilibrium wholesale price w n * = 2 k n A , the traceability effort t n * = ( α + θ ) A , and the retail price p n * = 3 k n A , where, A = ( 1 α ) 4 k n ( α + θ ) 2 . Note that it is reasonable to set k n > ( θ + α ) 2 4 , which indicates that exerting effort to improve the identifiability of genuine wine is expensive. Hence, we yield the optimal profit of both manufacturer and retailer as follows: π m n * = k n ( 1 α ) 2 A , π r n * = k n 2 A 2 .
Choi [24] finds that the increase in fake certification leads to a monotonic decrease in market price and supply chain profit. Different from their findings, we find that wine counterfeiting ( α ) increases WSC prices when k n < ( 2 α + θ ) ( α + θ ) / 4 , and the WSC.
Where E = 1 + θ α + θ 2 / 4 2 α + θ 1 , profits rise with α when k n < ( 1 + θ ) ( α + θ ) / 4 . This is counterintuitive and depends on the value of the NBT cost coefficient ( k n ) . When k n is small, it allows wine manufacturers to improve traceability more efficiently, helping consumers better identify genuine wines. The prevalence of counterfeit wine may lead consumers to be more willing to pay a higher price for the increase in NBT levels (i.e., due to distrust of counterfeit wine or the need to show their social status), resulting in increased profits for authentic wines. Moreover, we also find that wine counterfeiting induces traceability improvement when k n is lower than a certain threshold, or ( α ,   θ ) are low; WSC prices, profits, and NBT effort increase with traceability sensitivity θ but decrease with NBT cost coefficient k n monotonically. All the sensitivity analyses results of Model N are summarised in Table 4.

3.2. Model B: Adopting Third-Party BTS

We now consider the case that the WSC members purchase a third-party BTS from a technology company (i.e., IMB, Alibaba) to enhance wine traceability. The structure of the WSC in Model B is shown in Figure 2.
First, in Model B, technology giants provide third-party BTS as BaaS to WSC, offering a basic blockchain-based traceability (BBT) level t b , and charging a unit service fee c to each WSC member. t b can be considered a basic level of wine traceability effort in the context of blockchain adoption and is an exogenous variable. The case of endogenous traceability efforts will be discussed in the extended analysis. It should be noted that t n < t b 1 due to the real-time visibility and data access provided by the BTS to all WSC participants, facilitating enhanced collaboration and trust compared to non-blockchain-based tracing systems. Second, the BTS ensures that data are stored and verified by multiple nodes in a network, which makes it impossible to tamper with or manipulate, so the possibility of purchasing a counterfeit wine is set to zero [24]. Third, when consumers buy wine products endorsed by the BTS, there may be concern about their personal information being collected and misused [57], or exposing unwanted details of the wine’s previous exchanges when regifting it. Following [26,50], we denote the dis-utilities associated with the consumer privacy concern as g . We summarise the impact of blockchain on model set-ups in Table 5.
As discussed above, we have the consumers’ utility function U b = v p b g + θ t b . Following [28,48], and the same market assumptions in Model N, the demand for wine at a given price p b and BBT effort t b is expressed as the following:
D b = 1 p b g + θ t b
We set the constant parameter c as the unit service fee for using third-party BTS, which means the manufacturer and the retailer should respectively pay for using the third-party BTS service [50]. This is also consistent with industrial practice. For instance, the Microsoft Azure Blockchain Service charges USD 0.10 per transaction unit per hour for their standard version of BaaS services [58]. Following the same approach in Model N, we present the profit functions of the manufacturer and the retailer below.
π m b w b = w b c D b
π r b ( p b ) = ( p b w b c ) D b
Since the proofs of the optimal solutions for Model B are similar to Model N, we omit them and similarly for the extended model. Using backward induction, we derive the optimal decisions under Model B. First, the equilibrium wholesale price and retail price are w b * = 1 2 B ,   p b * = 1 4 ( 3 B + 2 c ) , where B = 1 g + θ t b ; the abbreviation also captures the non-economic effect of adopting third-party BTS. Substituting w b * and p b * into Equations (5) and (6), respectively, we derive the optimal profits at the optimal prices under Model B as follows: π r b * = 1 16 ( B 2 c ) 2 ,   π m b * = 1 8 ( B 2 c ) 2 . All the sensitivity analyses results of Model B are summarised in Table 6.
From the derived optimal decisions of the retailer and the manufacturer when blockchain technology is adopted, we find that higher consumer privacy concern yields lower prices and profits for the WSC. Liu et al. [50] derived similar results but in a different supply chain context. In addition, we extend the conclusions of Fan et al. [23] to show that a higher level of BBT and consumer traceability sensitivity can also result in higher prices and profits for the WSC. Moreover, we find that an increase in BTS service fees not only increases the retail price but also reduces the profits of the whole WSC. Although this conclusion seems intuitive, it is novel compared to existing blockchain-based OM studies, which find that the optimal wholesale price is independent of BTS service fees [23,24,27,50,52]. Meanwhile, it also means that the third-party BTS providers can influence the wine’s retail price. Therefore, compared to outsourcing wine traceability to a third-party BTS, is it wise and beneficial to self-implement BTS and endogenously determine traceability efforts? We will explore this in Section 5.

4. Value of Blockchain in the WSC

Now, we examine the value of adopting blockchain technologies in combating fake wine. We need to understand when blockchain is beneficial to supply chain members.

4.1. Effects of Using Blockchain on WSC Prices

By comparing the optimal solutions under Model N and Model B (i.e., w = w b * w n * , p = p b * p n * ), we derive the following proposition.
Proposition 1.
The prices in the WSC with blockchain are higher than those without blockchain if and only if any of the following conditions hold: (i) when 4 k n A < B w > 0 ; ( i i )   w h e n   12 k n A < 3 B + 2 c p > 0 .
Proposition 1 shows the effect of blockchain adoption on the pricing decision of the manufacturer and retailer, noting that parameter B is a critical factor, which captures the non-economic effect of adopting third-party BTS. Specifically, if consumers are less concerned about their personal information, or the third-party BTS provides a higher level of traceability effort, then the manufacturer and retailer can increase their prices by using blockchain. The results are reasonable because if most consumers are keen to find ways to buy wine with more traceability information, they could be wine traceability-sensitive rather than price-sensitive. Thus, a higher price is acceptable with blockchain adoption, particularly for luxury wine products. Moreover, if the third-party BTS can provide more reassuring consumer information protection, it will further encourage people to buy blockchain-certified wines. In addition, from Proposition 1, we can see that although the third-party BTS provider charges a unit service fee to each member of the WSC, all the costs in the equilibrium result act on the retail price. Hence, there has an increase in the retail price when c > 3 [ 4 k n A B ] 2 .

4.2. Effects of Using Blockchain on WSC Profits

Comparing the optimal expected profits under Model N and Model B (i.e., π m = π m b * π m n * , π r = π r b * π r n * ), we derive the following proposition.
Proposition 2.
Using blockchain to improve the traceability and authenticity of the WSC has a positive impact on the profits of the manufacturer and retailer, only if any of the following conditions hold: (i) when c < B 2 k n ( 1 α ) A , we have π m > 0 ; (ii) when c < B 4 k n A 2 , we have π r > 0 .
The most critical factor in determining whether supply chain firms should use blockchain is its cost. Proposition 2 gives the necessary conditions on costs to determine whether the manufacturer and the retailer can benefit from blockchain. When c is small enough, using blockchain becomes beneficial to both manufacturer and retailer. Meanwhile, we find that the manufacturer is more likely to benefit from the adoption of blockchain than the retailer, as the manufacturer can reach the conditions for profitable blockchain adoption earlier than the retailer when service fees charged by third-party BTS decline. Additionally, we notice that the non-economic impact of adopting BTS can also influence the decision on blockchain adoption. For example, lowering the upper bound of g can further increase the threshold of c that makes using blockchain more profitable (i.e., when   0 < g < 1 + θ t b 4 k A 2 2 c < 1   a n d   c < B 4 k n A 2 < 1 + θ t b 4 k A 2 , we still have π r b * > π r n * ). That means it is necessary to reduce consumer concerns about personal privacy or ensure that the third-party BTS provides a higher level of wine traceability.
Proposition 2 indicates that using blockchain may not be necessary for WSC. For WSC members who have not adopted blockchain, the NBT cost coefficient can also affect the value of π m and. π r . Based on Proposition 2, we derive the following corollary.
Corollary 1.
When k n < B 2 c α + θ 2 4 B 2 c 1 α , we have π m < 0 π r < 0 .
It is clear from Corollary 1 that there exists a threshold for k n that abandoning blockchain is more profitable. This highlights the fact that if the NBT level can be efficiently improved, WSC members should not blindly vote for using blockchain. Some studies [25,27,50,59,60,61] have used similar methods to demonstrate the value of blockchain by comparing the equilibrium results of whether the BTS is used or not. Enriching existing research, we show that WSC members who do not adopt blockchain can achieve comparable outcomes by efficiently improving their NBT levels. Additionally, some studies [22,46,60] also analyse the value of blockchain from a cost-benefit perspective. The comparison of the optimal results for models B and N is summarised in Table 7.
We differ from them by emphasising the cost coefficient of the NBT effort and advocating for judicious consideration of the value of blockchain in wine traceability.

5. Extension: Self-Implementation of the BTS

Now, we examine the scenario in which WSC members self-implement their own BTS. Although some well-known wine manufacturers and retailers like Diageo or JD have already implemented their own BTS, WSC members may have conflicting interests or incentives that hinder their willingness to participate in the self-implementation of BTS due to the high investment and uncertain benefits. In the following analysis, we will discuss the cases where manufacturers and retailers lead the implementation of BTS and explore the optimal strategy for using blockchain (i.e., outsourcing or self-implementation). In the WSC, we assume that whoever leads the implementation of the BTS will have the right to determine the self-implemented blockchain-based traceability (SBT) efforts. Other WSC agents may need to bear a certain share of the SBT cost, which is consistent with industry practice.

5.1. Model SM: Manufacturer Leading the Implementation of the BTS

First, we explore the situation of the manufacturer leading the BTS implementation. For example, the Spirits maker Diageo announced the launch of a blockchain-based track-and-trace system for its bottles to combat counterfeiting, boost the company’s sustainability practices, and ensure the wine traceability is self-controlled and more flexible [62]. In Model SM, the manufacturer takes the lead to implement the BTS across the entire WSC and determines the level of SBT effort t s m and the wholesale price w s m first. Then, the retailer decides on the retail price p s m . Consumer privacy concerns g are consistent with the settings in Model B. The structure of the WSC in Model SM is shown in Figure 3, and the decision structure of the WSC in Model SM is shown in Table 3. Following the same market assumptions in the basic model, we have the demand and profit function in Model SM.
D s m = 1 p s m g + θ t s m
π m s m w s m , t s m = w s m D s m ϕ K s m t s m
π r s m ( p s m ) = ( p s m w s m ) D s m ( 1 ϕ ) K s m t s m
Specifically, k s indicates the cost coefficient of wine traceability when the manufacturer or the retailer self-implements the BTS; ϕ   0 ϕ 1   refers to the proportion of the SBT cost paid by the manufacturer; K s m   represents the SBT cost of the WSC, where K s m = k s t b 2 + k s ( t s m t b ) 2 / 2 . Considering a higher traceability level means more data need to be recorded and verified on the blockchain, which increases the complexity and resource consumption of the system, it is reasonable to apply a quadratic cost structure. This has also been validated by previous studies [61,63]. However, this study further considers the cost structure of endogenous traceability efforts when adopting the BTS. For the manufacturer or the retailer who wants to self-implement the BTS, they should reference the existing third-party BTS in the market when designing their own BTS, and their requirement for the SBT level should be higher than that of BBT ( t s m > t b ). Otherwise, they will have no incentive to implement blockchain technology themselves. Hence, the SBT cost structure consists of the sum of the BBT effort level part k s t b 2 / 2   and the enhancement part k s ( t s m t b ) 2 / 2 . Song et al. [64] considered a similar cost structure for blockchain-based information disclosure, but with a binary constant cost.
Following the same approach above, the equilibrium decisions are given in Table 8.
Next, we conduct sensitivity analyses of the above extended models with respect to the key parameters to gain more insights. We report the results of the sensitivity analyses derived from checking the corresponding first-order derivatives of the optimal solutions. All the sensitivity analyses results of Model SM are summarised in Table 9.
For the retailer: (i) π r s m decreases with g when 0 < φ 2 3   and   k s > θ 2 θ 2 φ 2 φ 2  or 2 3 < φ < 1   and   k s > θ 2 4 φ . When the retailer needs to spend less than 1 / 3 of the SBT cost, the increasing consumer privacy concerns make the retailer’s profit decrease, which is similar to the case in Model B. While the difference is that when the retailer needs to spend more than 1 / 3 of the cost, it is the higher cost coefficient ( k s > θ 2 θ 2 φ 2 φ 2 ) that causes the negative utility β to affect the retailer’s profit. (ii) π r s m decreases with t b when φ < 2 3   and   θ 2 4 φ < k s < θ 2 θ 2 φ 2 φ 2 . When the retailer needs to absorb a higher SBT cost ( 1 φ > 1 3 ), retailer’s profit decreases with the level of BBT effort t b . This is reasonable, because with a relatively low cost coefficient ( k s < θ 2 θ 2 φ 2 φ 2 ), the rational retailer will call for increasing the SBT level t s to obtain profit growth. Recall that endogenous SBT effort t s   is referred to BBT effort t b . An increase in t b is equivalent to narrowing the improvement margin of t s , which in turn leads to a decrease in retailer profit. (iii) An increase in φ can result in a decrease in retail prices while simultaneously increasing retailer profit under specific conditions, that is, φ 2 3 or φ > 2 3 and k s > θ 2 8 ( 1 φ ) . Noting that the cost coefficient will increase when the manufacturer covers at least 2/3 of the cost. This is because if ks is low, it is difficult for the retailer to gain a profit advantage from further expansion of φ.
For the manufacturer, we find that (i) an increase in the manufacturer’s SBT cost share φ↑ results in a decrease in the wholesale price w s m , while simultaneously reducing the manufacturer’s profitability π m s m and input of SBT efforts t s m . (ii) π m s m decreases with t b when k s > B θ + b θ 2 4 b φ and increases with t b when θ 2 4 φ < k s < B θ + b θ 2 4 b φ . Similar to the analysis of retailer profit, the SBT cost coefficient k s m plays a key role in these effects. If the k s m is too high, the increasing level of BBT efforts will conversely lead to lower profitability for manufacturers. In this case, the manufacturer should give up self-implementing the BTS. (iii) In the SM model, it is the manufacturer determines the level of SBT effort t s m ; so, in the setting where endogenous t s m are considered, we find that t s m increase with the t b , but decrease with the g . Like our assumption, the endogenous SBT effort t s m is an enhancement in the level of BBT effort t b ; therefore, the level of BBT provided by the third-party BTS can be considered a benchmark in Model SM, whereby t s m is monotonically increasing with t b . However, the increasing privacy concerns g implies that consumers do not trust blockchain technology, and under such a condition the manufacturer will reduce the level of SBT effort t s m , which means reducing the investment in blockchain technology.

5.2. Model SR: Retailer Leading the Implementation of the BTS

Now, we explore the situation that the retailer leads the BTS implementation. JD, one of the largest online wine retailers in China, uses its self-implemented blockchain platform to provide the highest level of traceability for partner wine brands such as Lafite (France), Torres (Spain), and Penfolds (Australia), ensuring the authenticity of the wine sold on its platform [65]. All partner brand products sold on JD have exclusive blockchain traceability codes for consumers to track the product’s supply chain journey [66].
In Model SR, when we consider the retailer leading the implementation of the BTS, the demand and the profit functions are as follows:
D s r = 1 p s r g + θ t s r
π m s r w s r , t s r = w s r D s r ϕ K s r t s r
π r s r ( p s r ) = ( p s r w s r ) D s r ( 1 ϕ ) K s r t s r
where t s r refers to the SBT level set by the retailer, and the cost function of SBT can be rewritten as K s r t s r = k s t b 2 + k s ( t s r t b ) 2 / 2 . Like the derivations and analyses conducted for Model SM, we can derive the equilibrium decisions for Model SR. The equilibrium decisions under Model SR are similar to those for Model SM and are summarised in Table 10.
Then, by comparing the findings under Model B, Model SM, and Model SR, we have some insights into the way of using the BTS as follows.

5.3. Explore the Optimal Strategy for Implementing Blockchain

To figure out which way of using blockchain technology is more beneficial to WSC members, we compare the equilibrium decisions for each of the three models that have adopted the blockchain, and the comparison results are summarised in Table 11, Table 12, and Table 13, respectively. First, we compare Model SM to Model SR, and derive the following proposition.
Proposition 3.
For given θ , g , t b , a n d   k s , we have (i) D s m > D s r π m s m * > π m s r * when φ 1 2 ; (ii) w s m * > w s r * , p s m * > p s r * , t s m * > t s r * , and π r s m * < π r s r * when 0 < φ < 1 2 .
From Proposition 3, we find that the different cost-sharing arrangements will yield the following outcomes. When the manufacturer and the retailer share the SBT cost equally, there is no difference in who leads the implementation of the BTS. Otherwise, under any cost-sharing arrangement, the demand and manufacturer’s profit are strictly larger in Model SM. So, the manufacturer always benefits from leading the implementation of the BTS. When the manufacturer shares less than 50% of the cost, there are higher wholesale and retail prices, as well as a higher level of SBT in Model SM. However, the retailer profit is smaller in Model SM. When the manufacturer shares more than 50% of the cost, the comparison results of the retail price, wholesale price, SBT effort, and retailer profit will be reversed. It means that the wholesale and retail prices and SBT levels are higher when the BTS lead covers fewer costs. For the retailer, once they need to absorb higher costs, they should choose to take the lead in implementing the tracing system themselves.
By comparing Model SM to Model B, we derive the following proposition.
Proposition 4.
For given θ , g , t b , φ   a n d   k s , we have D s m * > D b * ; w s m * > w b * ; p s m * > p b * , when c < m i n [ 3 B θ 2 2 E , B 2 ] ; π r s m * > π r b * , when min 0 , B E 2 2 k s ( t b 2 E 2 ( φ 1 ) + B 2 ( E E φ + 2 k s φ ( 3 φ 2 ) ) ) 2 E < c < B 2 ; π m s m * > π m b * , when m i n [ 0 , B 2 B 2 k φ b 2 E k φ E ] < c < B 2 .
In Model SM, manufacturer-led implementation of the BTS can increase demand and wholesale price directly, while it is conditional to raising the retail price, as well as manufacturer and retailer profits. A decrease in service fee c leads to a decrease in the retail price p b   in Model B. Thus, if c is smaller than the certain thresholds, the retail price in Model SM is higher. Meanwhile, it is worth noting that p s m * is strictly larger than p b *   when   θ 2 4 φ < k s < θ 2 φ . That means if the cost coefficient k s can be controlled within a certain range, manufacturer-led BTS implementation can achieve a price advantage compared with Model B. For the manufacturer and the retailer, there is a threshold of c that determines whether it is profitable for the manufacturer to self-implement the BTS or to outsource, respectively.
Similar to the above analysis, we compared Model SR to Model B and obtained the following findings like Proposition 4. For given θ , g , t b , φ   and   k s , we have D s r * > D b * when c >   max   [ 0 , B θ 2 ( 3 φ 2 ) 2 F ] ; w s r * > w b * ; p s r * > p b * , when c <   min [ B θ 2 2 φ 2 F , B 2 ] ; π r s r * > π r b * , when min 0 , 3 B F + 2 2 k s ( 1 φ ) ( 9 b 2 F 2 + B 2 ( θ 2 + F ( 3 φ 4 ) + 2 k s ( 1 φ ) 2 ( 3 φ 1 ) ) ) 6 F < c < B 2 ; π m s r * > π m b * , when   min   [ 0 , B 2 B 2 k s 2 B 2 k s φ b 2 F k s φ + B 2 k s φ 2 F ] < c < B 2 . Different from the comparison results between Model SM and Model B, some special cases make the demand higher in Model B compared with Model SR. When the manufacturer has to cover more than two-thirds of the cost of SBT effort ( φ > 2 / 3 ), it is a better option for the whole supply chain to seek outsourced third-party BTS. In addition, the retailer-led implementation of the BTS can increase the retail price directly. The other findings are similar to those in Proposition 4.

6. Conclusions

6.1. Concluding Remarks

Motivated by the real-world practices of using blockchain to enhance traceability, this study explores the value of blockchain-based traceability in the WSC. Considering rampant WSC counterfeiting and consumers’ attitude towards wine traceability and information privacy, we develop consumer utility-based analytical models to study the cases without and with blockchain in the basic models. We derive the optimal solutions and uncover the value of blockchain in tracing wine products for the WSC through the comparison of the two scenarios. Furthermore, we extend our analyses to discuss the situation where WSC members endogenously determine the level of BTS traceability effort. By comparing the optimal solutions, we explore an optimal strategy for implementing the BTS and provide managerial insights on whether to use blockchain in the WSC and how to use it. The main findings are summarised as follows.
(i) Wine counterfeiting can increase prices and decrease profitability for WSC members, as well as reduce NBT effort when NBT costs are high. In addition, higher consumer sensitivity and a lower NBT cost coefficient can increase WSC profits. However, there exist thresholds for k n that make the WSC prices and profits increase with the wine counterfeiting. This differs from [24] but is consistent with industrial practice, such as the example of Paumanok and Comtes von Neipperg. This is mainly due to our consideration of NBT’s role in enhancing consumers’ ability to identify counterfeit products. This finding indicates that WSC may not need to adopt blockchain to eliminate counterfeiting. The increase in counterfeit wine can somehow increase consumers’ traceability sensitivity. If WSC can efficiently improve the NBT level, consumers will accept the price increase, and WSC’s profits will also increase.
(ii) When blockchain is adopted, we find that WSC prices and profits increase with higher traceability sensitivity and BBT effort but decrease with higher consumer privacy concerns. This finding extends the results of Liu et al. [50] to the WSC and adds to the work of Fan et al. [23] by considering the impact of the BBT effort. Additionally, we found that the optimal wholesale price is independent of BTS service fees.
(iii) The adoption of blockchain can increase the WSC prices under certain conditions. We have derived the threshold for third-party BTS service fees, which will determine whether to trace wine products through blockchain. Meanwhile, the moderating effect of consumer traceability preferences and privacy concerns should be considered when paying BTS service fees. Additionally, compared to studies investigating the value of blockchain from a cost-benefit perspective [22,46,60], we find that if the NBT effort can effectively work on improving WSC traceability, it may not be necessary for WSC to adopt blockchain. Eliminating counterfeit wines through BTS may not align with the interests of WSC members.
(iv) Different from Shen et al. [27], who considered endogenous quality decisions when using blockchain, we consider the traceability effort the endogenous decision variable, and our analysis focusses more on the cost sharing of SBT, leading to some new conclusions. We find that increasing the manufacturer’s SBT cost share lowers WSC prices and manufacturer profitability but can increase the retailer’s profit under certain conditions. Endogenous SBT effort increases with BBT effort but decreases with consumer privacy concerns. The impact of other key parameters on WSC prices and profits remains consistent with the basic model, with added threshold conditions.
(v) Self-implementing the BTS can increase the wholesale price directly, while it is conditional to raising the demand, retail price, and WSC profits, depending on the service fee of the third-party BTS. Equal SBT cost sharing between the manufacturer and the retailer results in no difference in BTS implementation leadership. Otherwise, the manufacturer benefits from leading. For the retailer, when the manufacturer shares less than half of the cost, the retail price is higher in Model SM, but the retailer profit is smaller. When the manufacturer shares more than half of the cost, these results are reversed.

6.2. Managerial Implications

Our research provides several managerial implications for the operations of the WSC with blockchain.
The operational solutions of the WSC in determining the adoption of blockchain. In non-blockchain-based tracing systems, the probability of identifying counterfeit wine is related to the level of wine traceability, so wine merchants need to weigh the trade-off between NBT costs and combating counterfeits. For the WSC members who do not adopt the BTS, targeting submarkets valuing wine traceability and reducing NBT costs are advantageous strategies, which can further avoid price dropping due to rampant counterfeiting. When the BTS is adopted, wine merchants need to notice the potential increase in retail price resulting from the rise in third-party BTS service fees. Moreover, alleviating privacy concerns and enhancing cybersecurity are crucial for blockchain adoption in the WSC.
The value of blockchain in the WSC. Manufacturers and retailers can increase prices with blockchain adoption, as traceability-sensitive consumers may prioritise traceability over price. Enhanced consumer information protection by BTS further incentivises purchases of blockchain-certified wine. In addition to the two mentioned value-adding measures that result in price growth, WSC members also need to be aware of the forced price increase caused by the service fees charged by a third-party BTS. When the service fees of the BTS are relatively low, using blockchain is always a more profitable choice. However, when the service fees of the BTS increase, if a third-party BTS cannot provide BBT levels that match their service prices, or if consumer privacy concerns exceed a certain level, using blockchain is not economically viable. In this case, using blockchain technology to satisfy consumer traceability preferences may not be financially rewarding for the WSC. This is because some consumers might be reluctant (e.g., because of concerns about privacy issues) to buy blockchain-certified wine products. Considering the benefits that blockchain brings to the WSC, the manufacturer is more likely to accept the transition to adopt the BTS due to the relatively small impact of service fees, which may harm the retailer’s interests.
The implications of the ways to adopt blockchain. Compared to purchasing a third-party BTS, WSC members need to pay extra attention to two key factors when self-implementing the BTS: the cost coefficient and the cost-sharing arrangement of SBT. Taking the manufacturer-led BTS implementation as an example, if the cost borne by the retailer exceeds one-third, only when the cost coefficient reaches the threshold will the negative utility of the blockchain affect the retailer’s profit. Moreover, if the SBT cost coefficient is too high, an increase in the BBT effort level may instead reduce the manufacturer’s profit. If the SBT cost coefficient can be controlled, self-implementing the BTS can achieve a more competitive advantage over outsourcing. Meanwhile, WSC members should promptly determine the threshold of third-party BTS service fees that can determine whether outsourcing the BTS or self-implementing the BTS is more profitable. In addition, when the BTS leader bears less SBT cost, both the prices and traceability level of the WSC will be higher. Plus, the retailer needs to pay extra attention once they need to bear higher costs. They should choose to lead the BTS implementation themselves.

6.3. Future Studies

We note some potential directions for future research. Firstly, the WSC is a complex system. Given the numerous stages involved in wine production and processing, it would be interesting to explore a multi-level supply chain model. Additionally, as crypto-currency transactions are becoming more common within the WSC, it would be valuable to investigate the impact of crypto-currency on the fairness of WSC transactions and WSC structure. Finally, it would be interesting to investigate how the risk-averse attitudes of WSC members may influence their investments in a BTS.

Author Contributions

Conceptualisation, Y.K. and X.S.; methodology, Y.K. and X.Y.; software, Y.K. and X.Y.; validation, X.S, X.Y., W.Z. and S.S.L.; formal analysis, Y.K. and W.Z.; investigation, Y.K. and S.S.L.; writing—original draft preparation, Y.K.; writing—review and editing, X.Y., W.Z. and S.S.L.; supervision, X.S.; funding acquisition, Y.K. and X.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 71831001) and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities Project (No.2020YJS053).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Data are contained within the article.

Acknowledgments

We would like to express our gratitude to the anonymous reviewers for their insightful comments on our paper, and we also appreciate the assistance from Jingchen Shi and Zibo Shi.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. The Wine Wankers. ‘20% of All Wine in the World Is Fake’—This Expert’s Guide Will Save You a Fortune. Available online: https://winewankers.com/2017/06/23/20-of-all-wine-in-the-world-is-fake-this-experts-guide-will-save-you-a-fortune/ (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  2. 8 Million Litres Alcoholic Drinks Seized across Europe. Available online: https://anti-fraud.ec.europa.eu/media-corner/news/148-million-litres-alcoholic-drinks-seized-across-europe-2022-11-17_en (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  3. Recorded Future. Counterfeit Wine, Spirits, and Cheese. Available online: https://www.recordedfuture.com/counterfeit-wine-spirits-cheese (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  4. Italian Police Arrest Winemakers for Allegedly Producing 130,000 Cases of Counterfeit Wine. Available online: https://www.winespectator.com/articles/italian-police-arrest-winemakers-for-allegedly-producing-counterfeit-wine (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  5. NYC Wine Store Fined $100K for Fake Bourbon Sales—But Hasn’t Fired Anybody over Scandal. Available online: https://nypost.com/2023/03/01/nyc-wine-store-fined-100k-for-fake-bourbon-sales-but-hasnt-fired-anybody/ (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  6. Behnke, K.; Janssen, M.F.W.H.A. Boundary Conditions for Traceability in Food Supply Chains Using Blockchain Technology. Int. J. Inform. Manag. 2020, 52, 101969. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Casino, F.; Kanakaris, V.; Dasaklis, T.K.; Moschuris, S.; Stachtiaris, S.; Pagoni, M.; Rachaniotis, N.P. Blockchain-Based Food Supply Chain Traceability: A Case Study in the Dairy Sector. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2021, 59, 5758–5770. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Dasaklis, T.K.; Voutsinas, T.G.; Tsoulfas, G.T.; Casino, F. A Systematic Literature Review of Blockchain-Enabled Supply Chain Traceability Implementations. Sustainability 2022, 14, 2439. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Wines & Vines—The Proof Is in the Packaging. Available online: https://winebusinessanalytics.com/sections/printout_article.cfm?article=feature&content=119744 (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  10. Charles, V.; Emrouznejad, A.; Gherman, T. A Critical Analysis of the Integration of Blockchain and Artificial Intelligence for Supply Chain. Ann. Oper. Res. 2023, 327, 7–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  11. Yadav, V.S.; Singh, A.R.; Raut, R.D.; Cheikhrouhou, N. Blockchain Drivers to Achieve Sustainable Food Security in the Indian Context. Ann. Oper. Res. 2021, 327, 211–249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Yavaprabhas, K.; Pournader, M.; Seuring, S. Blockchain as the “Trust-Building Machine” for Supply Chain Management. Ann. Oper. Res. 2022, 327, 49–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Blockchain-as-a-Service (BaaS) Market Size, Share. Global Report. 2030. Available online: https://www.fortunebusinessinsights.com/blockchain-as-a-service-baas-market-102721 (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  14. AliCloud Product Pricing. Available online: https://www.alibabacloud.com/zh/pricing (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  15. “Blockchain + Baijiu” Application Is Showing Signs of Promise. Available online: https://chuangxin.chinadaily.com.cn/a/202107/07/WS60e64fe6a3101e7ce9758a13.html (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  16. eProvenance Uncorks VinAssure™, an IBM Blockchain-Powered Platform to Strengthen Collaboration and Optimize the Wine Supply Chain. 10 December 2020. Available online: https://newsroom.ibm.com/2020-12-10-eProvenance-Uncorks-VinAssure-TM-an-IBM-Blockchain-Powered-Platform-to-Strengthen-Collaboration-and-Optimize-the-Wine-Supply-Chain (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  17. IBM Blockchain Platform: Hyperledger Fabric Support Edition. Available online: https://www.ibm.com/products/blockchain-platform-hyperledger-fabric (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  18. A Comprehensive Guide on Blockchain App Development Cost. Available online: https://appinventiv.com/guide/blockchain-app-development-cost (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  19. Corporate Data Responsibility: Bridging the Consumer Trust Gap. Available online: https://kpmg.com/us/en/articles/2023/bridging-the-trust-chasm.html (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  20. Bitcoin Transactions Aren’t as Anonymous as Everyone Hoped. Available online: https://www.technologyreview.com/2017/08/23/149531/bitcoin-transactions-arent-as-anonymous-as-everyone-hoped/ (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  21. Wine Market Size, Industry Share, Global Analysis, Future Demand. 2030. Available online: https://www.fortunebusinessinsights.com/wine-market-102836 (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  22. Biswas, D.; Jalali, H.; Ansaripoor, A.H.; De Giovanni, P. Traceability vs. Sustainability in Supply Chains: The Implications of Blockchain. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2023, 305, 128–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Fan, Z.-P.; Wu, X.-Y.; Cao, B.-B. Considering the Traceability Awareness of Consumers: Should the Supply Chain Adopt the Blockchain Technology? Ann. Oper. Res. 2022, 309, 837–860. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Choi, T.-M. Blockchain-Technology-Supported Platforms for Diamond Authentication and Certification in Luxury Supply Chains. Transport. Res. Part E Logist. Transport. Rev. 2019, 128, 17–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Li, Z.; Xu, X.; Bai, Q.; Guan, X.; Zeng, K. The Interplay between Blockchain Adoption and Channel Selection in Combating Counterfeits. Transport. Res. Part E Logist. Transport. Rev. 2021, 155, 102451. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Pun, H.; Swaminathan, J.M.; Hou, P. Blockchain Adoption for Combating Deceptive Counterfeits. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2021, 30, 864–882. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Shen, B.; Dong, C.; Minner, S. Combating Copycats in the Supply Chain with Permissioned Blockchain Technology. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2022, 31, 138–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Wu, X.-Y.; Fan, Z.-P.; Cao, B.-B. An Analysis of Strategies for Adopting Blockchain Technology in the Fresh Product Supply Chain. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2021, 61, 3717–3734. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Rogerson, M.; Parry, G.C. Blockchain: Case Studies in Food Supply Chain Visibility. Supply Chain Manag. 2020, 25, 601–614. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Sunny, J.; Undralla, N.; Pillai, V.M. Supply Chain Transparency through Blockchain-Based Traceability: An Overview with Demonstration. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2020, 150, 106895. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Tiscini, R.; Testarmata, S.; Ciaburri, M.; Ferrari, E. The Blockchain as a Sustainable Business Model Innovation. Manag. Decis. 2020, 58, 1621–1642. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Danese, P.; Mocellin, R.; Romano, P. Designing Blockchain Systems to Prevent Counterfeiting in Wine Supply Chains: A Multiple-Case Study. Int. J. Oper. Prod. Manag. 2021, 41, 1–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Brookbanks, M.; Parry, G. The Impact of a Blockchain Platform on Trust in Established Relationships: A Case Study of Wine Supply Chains. Supply Chain Manag. 2022, 27, 128–146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Saurabh, S.; Dey, K. Blockchain Technology Adoption, Architecture, and Sustainable Agri-Food Supply Chains. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 284, 124731. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Tokkozhina, U.; Ferreira, J.C.; Martins, A.L. Wine Traceability and Counterfeit Reduction: Blockchain-Based Application for a Wine Supply Chain. In Proceedings of the International Conference on Intelligent Transport Systems, Indianapolis, IN, USA, 19–22 September 2021; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2021; pp. 59–70. [Google Scholar]
  36. Adamashvili, N.; State, R.; Tricase, C.; Fiore, M. Blockchain-Based Wine Supply Chain for the Industry Advancement. Sustainability 2021, 13, 13070. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Luzzani, G.; Grandis, E.; Frey, M.; Capri, E. Blockchain Technology in Wine Chain for Collecting and Addressing Sustainable Performance: An Exploratory Study. Sustainability 2021, 13, 12898. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Qian, J.; Ruiz-Garcia, L.; Fan, B.; Robla Villalba, J.I.; McCarthy, U.; Zhang, B.; Yu, Q.; Wu, W. Food Traceability System from Governmental, Corporate, and Consumer Perspectives in the European Union and China: A Comparative Review. Trends Food Sci. Technol. 2020, 99, 402–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Lu, J.; Wu, L.; Wang, S.; Xu, L. Consumer Preference and Demand for Traceable Food Attributes. Br. Food. J. 2016, 118, 2140–2156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Ubilava, D.; Foster, K. Quality Certification vs. Product Traceability: Consumer Preferences for Informational Attributes of Pork in Georgia. Food Policy 2009, 34, 305–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Cimino, M.G.; Marcelloni, F. Enabling Traceability in the Wine Supply Chain. In Methodologies and Technologies for Networked Enterprises; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2012; pp. 397–412. [Google Scholar]
  42. Expósito, I.; Gay-Fernández, J.A.; Cuiñas, I. A Complete Traceability System for a Wine Supply Chain Using Radio-Frequency Identification and Wireless Sensor Networks [Wireless Corner]. IEEE Antennas Propag. Mag. 2013, 55, 255–267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Yiu, N.C.K. Toward Blockchain-Enabled Supply Chain Anti-Counterfeiting and Traceability. Future Internet 2021, 13, 86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Hastig, G.M.; Sodhi, M.S. Blockchain for Supply Chain Traceability: Business Requirements and Critical Success Factors. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2020, 29, 935–954. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Cui, Y.; Hu, M.; Liu, J. Value and Design of Traceability-Driven Blockchains. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2023, 25, 1099–1116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Choi, T.-M. Values of Blockchain for Risk-Averse High-Tech Manufacturers under Government’s Carbon Target Environmental Taxation Policies. Ann. Oper. Res. 2022, 1–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Luo, S.; Choi, T. E-commerce Supply Chains with Considerations of Cyber-security: Should Governments Play a Role? Prod. Oper. Manag. 2022, 31, 2107–2126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Niu, B.; Dong, J.; Liu, Y. Incentive Alignment for Blockchain Adoption in Medicine Supply Chains. Transport. Res. Part E Logist. Transport. Rev. 2021, 152, 102276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Xu, J.; Duan, Y. Pricing and Greenness Investment for Green Products with Government Subsidies: When to Apply Blockchain Technology? J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2022, 51, 101108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Liu, S.; Hua, G.; Kang, Y.; Edwin Cheng, T.C.; Xu, Y. What Value Does Blockchain Bring to the Imported Fresh Food Supply Chain? Transport. Res. Part E Logist. Transport. Rev. 2022, 165, 102859. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Li, Z.; Xu, X.; Bai, Q.; Chen, C. Optimal Joint Decision of Information Disclosure and Ordering in a Blockchain-Enabled Luxury Supply Chain. Ann. Oper. Res. 2022, 329, 1263–1314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Wu, J.; Wang, X. Platform-Leading Blockchain Adoption for Traceability under Upstream Competition. Ann. Oper. Res. 2023, 1–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Chen, J.; Liang, L.; Yao, D.-Q.; Sun, S. Price and Quality Decisions in Dual-Channel Supply Chains. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 259, 935–948. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. He, S.; Ma, Z. Service Quality and Price Competition in Crowdsourced Delivery Markets. Int. Trans. Oper. Res. 2022, in press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Zhao, Y.; Hou, R.; Lin, X.; Lin, Q. Two-Period Information-Sharing and Quality Decision in a Supply Chain under Static and Dynamic Wholesale Pricing Strategies. Int. Trans. Oper. Res. 2022, 29, 2494–2522. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Hu, H.; Li, Y.; Li, M. Decisions and Coordination of Green Supply Chain Considering Big Data Targeted Advertising. J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2022, 17, 53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. IMI Blockchain Data Privacy Concerns. Available online: https://identitymanagementinstitute.org/blockchain-data-privacy-concerns/ (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  58. Microsoft Azure. Application Service Pricing. Available online: https://azure.microsoft.com/zh-cn/pricing/details/app-service/windows/ (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  59. Choi, T.-M.; Ouyang, X. Initial Coin Offerings for Blockchain Based Product Provenance Authentication Platforms. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2021, 233, 107995. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Niu, B.; Mu, Z.; Cao, B.; Gao, J. Should Multinational Firms Implement Blockchain to Provide Quality Verification? Transport. Res. Part E Logist. Transport. Rev. 2021, 145, 102121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Wu, X.-Y.; Fan, Z.-P.; Li, G. Strategic Analysis for Adopting Blockchain Technology under Supply Chain Competition. Int. J. Logist. Res. App. 2022, 26, 1384–1407. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Diageo Eyes Blockchain Tech to Check Pilferage. Available online: https://timesofindia.indiatimes.com/business/india-business/diageo-eyes-blockchain-tech-to-check-pilferage/articleshow/92026777.cms (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  63. Liu, J.; Zhao, H.; Lyu, Y.; Yue, X. The Provision Strategy of Blockchain Service under the Supply Chain with Downstream Competition. Ann. Oper. Res. 2022, 327, 375–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Song, Y.; Liu, J.; Zhang, W.; Li, J. Blockchain’s Role in e-Commerce Sellers’ Decision-Making on Information Disclosure under Competition. Ann. Oper. Res. 2022, 329, 1009–1048. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  65. JD Cooperates with Six Internationally Renowned Wineries to Establish a Strategic Alliance of Red Wines. Available online: http://finance.ce.cn/gsxw/201805/10/t20180510_29088726.shtml (accessed on 15 October 2023).
  66. EcommerceStrategyChina.com. JD Launched the World’s First Blockchain-Based Commodities Traceability Mini Program. Available online: https://www.ecommercestrategychina.com/column/jd-launches-the-worlds-first-commodities-traceability-mini-program-using-blockchain-technology (accessed on 15 October 2023).
Figure 1. The structure of the WSC in Model N.
Figure 1. The structure of the WSC in Model N.
Jtaer 18 00108 g001
Figure 2. The structure of the WSC in Model B.
Figure 2. The structure of the WSC in Model B.
Jtaer 18 00108 g002
Figure 3. The structure of the WSC in Model SM.
Figure 3. The structure of the WSC in Model SM.
Jtaer 18 00108 g003
Table 1. Some examples of BaaS for the WSC.
Table 1. Some examples of BaaS for the WSC.
CompanyDescription
Alibaba (China) [14,15]
1.
Alibaba Cloud provides a BaaS platform called Ant Blockchain, which enables wine producers and distributors to track the provenance of wine and reduce the risk of fraud in the supply chain;
2.
Taking the Hyperledger Fabric version as an example, it can charge monthly and yearly subscriptions, or charges $0.000472 per GB per hour for storage space beyond 6 TB per node.
IBM (U.S.) [16,17]
3.
IBM’s blockchain-based platform is used by major players in the wine industry, such as wineries and retailers, to track the journey of wine from the vineyard to the store shelf.
4.
It has introduced a new hourly pricing model that is based on virtual processor core (VPC) allocation. The nodes are allocated on an hourly basis, at a flat rate of $0.29/VPC-hour 12.
Table 2. The relationship with the core cited blockchain-based OM studies.
Table 2. The relationship with the core cited blockchain-based OM studies.
Supply Chain CategoryStudyThe Uniqueness of BTS Adoption in the WSC
Traceability LevelProductConsumerSupply Chain
Anti-CounterfeitPrivacy ConcernAdoption Mode
Food[50]
[28]
Luxury[24]
[51]
General[45]
[23]
[26]
[27]
WineOur paper
Table 3. Abbreviation and definitions of variables.
Table 3. Abbreviation and definitions of variables.
Notation/AcronymMeaning
WSCWine supply chain
BTSBlockchain-based tracing systems
BaaSBlockchain-as-a-service
NBTNon-blockchain-based traceability
BBTBasic blockchain-based traceability
SBTSelf-implemented blockchain-based traceability
i Abbreviation of the   different   Model   i = N ,   B ,   S M ,   S R
U i Consumers’ utility of purchasing the wine
v Consumers’ valuation of the wine
D i The demand of the retailer
α The likelihood that the supply chain suffers wine counterfeiting
g Consumers’ concerns about personal traceability information
θ Consumers’ sensitivity to wine traceability
t i The traceability effort of the wine (NBT, BBT, and SBT)
k i The cost coefficient of traceability effort
K i t The traceability cost
p i The retail price of wine
w i The wholesale price of the manufacturer
c b The unit service fee c b from BTS
π m i The profit of the manufacturer
π r i The profit of the retailer
Table 4. The results of the sensitivity analyses in Model N.
Table 4. The results of the sensitivity analyses in Model N.
α θ k n
p n * :   k n > α + θ 2 α + θ / 4 : θ + α 2 / 4 < k n < α + θ 2 α + θ / 4
w n * :   k n > α + θ 2 α + θ / 4 : θ + α 2 / 4 < k n < α + θ 2 α + θ / 4
t n * : ( 0 < α 1 2 & & 1 2 α < θ < 1 & & k n > E ) | | ( 1 2 < α < 1 & & 0 < θ < 1 & & k n > E ) : ( 0 < α 1 2 & & 0 < θ 1 2 α ) | | ( 1 2 α < θ < 1 & & k n < E ) ) ) | | ( 1 2 < α < 1 & & 0 < θ < 1 & & k n < E )
π r n * :   k n > ( 2 α + θ ) ( α + θ ) / 4 : θ + α 2 / 4 < k n < ( 2 α + θ ) ( α + θ ) / 4
π m n * : k n > ( 1 + θ ) ( α + θ ) / 4 : θ + α 2 / 4 < k n < ( 1 + θ ) ( α + θ ) / 4
Table 5. Features of using blockchain for the WSC.
Table 5. Features of using blockchain for the WSC.
Features of WSCWithout BTSWith BTSFeatures of Blockchain Technology
Wine traceability level t n (NBT) t b (BBT)Real-time data acquisition and greater visibility
Wine authenticity concerns α 1 t n NoneAsymmetric cryptography and permanent data record
Privacy concernsNone g Public blockchain and distributed ledgers
Table 6. The results of the sensitivity analyses in Model B.
Table 6. The results of the sensitivity analyses in Model B.
c θ β t b
p b *
w b *
π r b *
π m b *
Table 7. The comparison of optimal decision between Model B and Model N.
Table 7. The comparison of optimal decision between Model B and Model N.
ParameterValue
D   = D b * D n * > 0 c < B 4 k n A 2
w = w b * w n * > 0 4 k n A < B   ( i . e . ,   g < 1 + θ t b 4 k n A   o r   t b > 4 k n A 1 + g θ )
p = p b * p n * > 0 12 k n A < 3 B + 2 c   ( i . e . , t b > 12 k n A + g 2 c 3 3 θ   o r   g < 1 + θ t b 12 k n A + 2 c 3   o r   c > 3 [ 4 k n A B ] 2 )
π r = π r b * π r n * > 0 c < B 4 k n A 2   o r   c < 4 ( 1 α ) + B [ α + θ 2 4 ] 2 [ α + θ 2 4 ] & & k n > ( B 2 c ) ( α + θ ) 2 4 ( ( B 2 c ) ( 1 α ) )
π m = π m b * π m n * > 0 c < 1 2 B k n 1 α A   o r   c < 1 2 α g + t θ & & k n > B 2 c 2 α + θ 2 4 B 2 c 2 1 α 2
A = ( 1 α ) / 4 k n ( α + θ ) 2 ; B = 1 g + θ t b .
Table 8. The equilibrium decisions in Model SM.
Table 8. The equilibrium decisions in Model SM.
ParameterEquilibrium Results in Model SM
D s m * k s φ B / E
w s m * 2 k s φ B / E
p s m * 3 k s φ B / E
t s m * θ θ g + 4 k s φ t b / E
π m s m * ( B 2 t b 2 E ) k s φ / 2 E
π r s m * k s B 2 [ E E φ + 2 k s φ 3 φ 2 ] / 2 E 2 k s t b 2 ( 1 φ ) / 2
B = 1 g + θ t b   E = 4 k s φ θ 2 .
Table 9. The results of the sensitivity analyses in Model SM.
Table 9. The results of the sensitivity analyses in Model SM.
θgtb k s φ
p s m *
w s m *
t s m *
π r s m * :   1 2 < φ < 2 3   & &   k s > θ 2 θ 2 φ 4 φ + 8 φ 2 :   ( 0 < φ 2 3 & & k s > θ 2 θ 2 φ 2 φ 2 ) | | ( 2 3 < φ < 1 & & k s > θ 2 4 φ ) : φ < 2 3 & & θ 2 4 φ < k s < θ 2 θ 2 φ 2 φ 2 : 1 2 < φ < 2 3 & & k s > θ 2 θ 2 φ 4 φ + 8 φ 2   o r   φ > 2 3 :   φ 2 3   o r   φ > 2 3 & & θ 2 8 ( 1 φ ) < k s
π m s m * : k s > B θ + t b θ 2 4 b φ : θ 2 4 φ < k s < B θ + t b θ 2 4 b φ
Table 10. The equilibrium decisions in Model SR.
Table 10. The equilibrium decisions in Model SR.
ParameterEquilibrium Results in Model SM
D s r * B k s ( 1 φ ) 2 / F
w s r * B ( 2 F + θ 2 2 k s ( 1 φ ) 2 ) / 3 F
p s r * B ( 2 F + θ 2 + k s ( 1 φ ) 2 ) / 3 F
t s r * t b + θ ( 1 φ ) B / F
π m s r * k s ( B 2 ( 1 φ ) 2 t b 2 φ F ) / 2 F
π r s r * k s ( 1 φ ) ( 9 t b 2 F 2 + B 2 ( θ 2 + F ( 4 + 3 φ ) + 2 k ( 1 + φ ) 2 ( 1 + 3 φ ) ) ) / 18 F 2
B = 1 g + θ t b F = 4 k s 1 φ 2 + θ 2 3 φ 2 .
Table 11. Comparison of optimal decision between Model SM and Model SR.
Table 11. Comparison of optimal decision between Model SM and Model SR.
ParameterDifferences
D s * φ = 1 2 : D s m = D s r ; φ 1 2 :   D s m > D s r
w s * 0 < φ < 1 2 : w s m * > w s r * ; φ = 1 2 : w s m * = w s r * ; 1 2 < φ < 1 : w s m * < w s r *
p s * 0 < φ < 1 2 : p s m * > p s r * ; φ = 1 2 : p s m * = p s r * ; 1 2 < φ < 1 :   p s m * < p s r *
t s * 0 < φ < 1 2 : t s m * > t s r * ; φ = 1 2 : t s m * = t s r * ; 1 2 < φ < 1 : t s m * < t s r *
π r s * 0 < φ < 1 2 : π r s m * < π r s r * ; φ = 1 2 : π r s m * = π r s r * ; 1 2 < φ < 1 : π r s m * > π r s r *
π m s * φ = 1 2 : π m s m * = π m s r * ; φ 1 2 : π m s m * > π m s r *
Table 12. Comparison of optimal decision between Model SM and Model B.
Table 12. Comparison of optimal decision between Model SM and Model B.
ParameterDifferences
D s m * D s m * > D b *
w s m * w s m * > w b *
p s m * c <   min 3 B θ 2 2 E , B 2 : p s m * > p b * ; 3 B θ 2 2 E < c < B 2 a n d k s > θ 2 φ :   p s m * < p b *
π r s m * min 0 , B E 2 2 k s ( t b 2 E 2 ( φ 1 ) + B 2 ( E E φ + 2 k s φ ( 3 φ 2 ) ) ) 2 E < c < B 2 :   π r s m *   >   π r b * ; 0 < c < B E 2 2 k s ( t b 2 E 2 ( φ 1 ) + B 2 ( E E φ + 2 k s φ ( 3 φ 2 ) ) ) 2 E : π r s m * < π r b *
π m s m * min [ 0 , B 2 B 2 k φ b 2 E k φ E ] < c < B 2 : π m s m * > π m b * ;   0 < c < B 2 B 2 k φ b 2 E k φ E , :   π m s m * < π m b *
B = 1 g + θ t b E = 4 k s φ θ 2 .
Table 13. Comparison of optimal decision between Model SR and Model B.
Table 13. Comparison of optimal decision between Model SR and Model B.
ParameterDifferences
D s r * c > m i n 0 , B θ 2 2 + 3 φ 2 F : D s r * > D b * ;
c < B θ 2 ( 2 + 3 φ ) 2 F   and   φ > 2 / 3 :   D s r * < D b *
w s r * w s r * > w b *
p s r * c < m i n [ B θ 2 2 φ 2 F , B 2 ] : p s r * > p b * ;
B θ 2 2 φ 2 F < c < B 2   a n d   k s > θ 2 ( 1 φ ) :   p s r * < p b *
π r s r * min 0 , 3 B F + 2 2 k ( 1 φ ) ( 9 b 2 F 2 + B 2 ( θ 2 + F ( 3 φ 4 ) + 2 k ( 1 φ ) 2 ( 3 φ 1 ) ) ) 6 F < c < B 2 :   π r s r * > π r b * ;
0 < c < 3 B F + 2 2 k ( 1 φ ) ( 9 b 2 F 2 + B 2 ( θ 2 + F ( 3 φ 4 ) + 2 k ( 1 φ ) 2 ( 3 φ 1 ) ) ) 6 F :   π r s r * < π r b *
π m s r * m i n 0 , B 2 B 2 k 2 B 2 k φ b 2 F k φ + B 2 k φ 2 F < c < B 2   :   π m s r * > π m b * ;
0 < c < B 2 B 2 k 2 B 2 k φ b 2 F k φ + B 2 k φ 2 F :   π m s r * < π m b *
B = 1 g + θ t b ;     F = 4 k s 1 φ 2 + θ 2 3 φ 2 .
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kang, Y.; Shi, X.; Yue, X.; Zhang, W.; Liu, S.S. Enhancing Traceability in Wine Supply Chains through Blockchain: A Stackelberg Game-Theoretical Analysis. J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2023, 18, 2142-2162. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer18040108

AMA Style

Kang Y, Shi X, Yue X, Zhang W, Liu SS. Enhancing Traceability in Wine Supply Chains through Blockchain: A Stackelberg Game-Theoretical Analysis. Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research. 2023; 18(4):2142-2162. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer18040108

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kang, Yuxuan, Xianliang Shi, Xiongping Yue, Weijian Zhang, and Samuel Shuai Liu. 2023. "Enhancing Traceability in Wine Supply Chains through Blockchain: A Stackelberg Game-Theoretical Analysis" Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research 18, no. 4: 2142-2162. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer18040108

APA Style

Kang, Y., Shi, X., Yue, X., Zhang, W., & Liu, S. S. (2023). Enhancing Traceability in Wine Supply Chains through Blockchain: A Stackelberg Game-Theoretical Analysis. Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research, 18(4), 2142-2162. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer18040108

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop