Addressing the Sharing Economy—Some (Potential) Inconsistencies of Its Emancipatory Defense
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Informativeness and Veracity
2.1. An Attempt at Definition
2.2. Operationalizing the Object of Study
- Collaborative or consumer participation [18,19], as defined by traditional sharing, bartering, lending, trading, renting, gifting, and swapping, has been redefined through the advent of technology and peer communities. It is contended that collaborative consumption yields significant economic savings by granting access to goods without changing their ownership, while also saving time or space. Consequently, it would represent an efficient mode of consumption, as it valorizes underutilized assets or services. It encompasses platforms such as Airbnb, Uber, eBay, Zipcar, Wallapop, and DogVacay. Additionally, less commercial-oriented instances include BitTorrent and The Pirate Bay, citizen initiatives to exchange services or accommodation altruistically such as time-banks and Couchsurfing, the use of local currencies led by social movements or local business platforms, and practices like bartering, social lending, clothing swaps, co-housing, and peer-to-peer rental.
- Open or common knowledge [16,20,21,22], i.e., the knowledge that “is free to use, reuse, and redistribute without legal, social, or technological restriction” [23]. Knowledge has always been produced collaboratively. The novelty is that now the “processes of production, power, exploitation, hegemony, and struggles take on the form of transnational networks that are mediated by networked information and communication technologies and knowledge processes” [24] (p. 180). The concept of “digital” or “cognitive capitalism” [25,26] is used to theorize the extent to which knowledge has become the new arena of political, economic, and ideological contention. Here too, a wide range of practices coexist: from altruistic and gratuitous acts, such as giving a talk for a civil association or contributing to create a Wikipedia page, to for-profit initiatives such as SharingAcademy and Trip4Real, or even protecting an academic manuscript with a Creative Commons license.
- Collaborative, P2P production or co-production [16,27,28] is regarded both as an outcome of open knowledge and as its prerequisite. As extensively advocated [29,30], it entails a new industrial revolution that paves the way to a “transition from an economy of exchange and production to one of pollination and contribution” [31] (p. 143). Within this emerging “social factory” the new modes of production are so “dispersed throughout the unlimited social terrain that they outgrow the physical and temporal limits of the old Fordist factory” [32] (p. 53). Illustrative examples encompass urban community gardens, somewhat informal yet scarcely commodified shared workspaces, on-demand work platforms such as Upwork, Wework, and 99Design, or even YouTube, Flickr, Facebook, and X, formerly known as Twitter.
- Collaborative finance enables people to carry out economic transactions without a third-party intermediary [33]. It is purported to “replace credit cards and banks with lower-interest person-to-person loans” [6] (p. 21). They also include quite disparate examples. From non-strictly commercial initiatives like peer-to-peer microloans or microcredits, the contingency funds of some trade unions, and savings cooperatives such as Coop57 or FairCoop, to crowdfunding platforms like Lanzanos, Goteo, or Verkami, as well as international charity tools such as GiveDirectly. For-profit examples include equity crowdfunding platforms such as Kickstarter or IndieGogo matching entrepreneurial projects with venture capital, peer-to-peer lending platforms like LendingClub or Prosper, and even digital currency and blockchain tools like Verse or BitSquare.
3. Beyond Conceptualizing: Political Conceptions on the Sharing Economy
3.1. As Inclusive Capitalism
3.2. As an Advancement of the Neoliberal Agenda
3.3. As an Emancipatory or Post-Capitalist Economy
4. Some Shortcomings of the Emancipatory View
4.1. Collaborative Communities and the Equality Principle
Only civilization brought individualization and differentiation. Primitive thought consists mainly of the common feelings of the members of small groups. Modern collectivism is a relapse into that wild state, an attempt to rebuild those strong bonds that exist in limited groups.[7] (p. 127)
- Equivalence occurs in communities where the guiding distributive principle is epitomized by the Saint-Simonian maxim to each according to his/her need, from each according to his/her ability. These communities comply with the principle of exclusion of mathematical partitions: that one is a member implies that another is not, akin to dynamics observed in familial or affective relationships, or within groups of hackers like Anonymous.
- Hierarchical relationships are typically associated with centralized institutions founded on authority, wherein members are organized according to a lexicographic stratification of the type to each according to their rank. Examples include armies, monotheistic religions, or the bulk of teams comprising events like the football World Cup.
- Equality relationships are typified abelian groups such as carpools, babysitting cooperatives, or the very concept of citizenship.5 Its distributive pattern, one man one vote, diverges from metrics and hierarchical rankings. The idea of basic income—granting cash to all unconditionally, would be an example, as well as the rotational system of public office in Athenian democracy.
- Proportionality, or “geometric equality”, as Aristotle [66] (1132a) would put it, is associated with the practice of market pricing, underpinned by the principle of to each according to their contribution. Examples include capitalist market transactions like wages and salaries, bank interest rates, contributory benefits, or consequentialist analyses.
4.2. Motivational Monism
However selfish human beings may be supposed to be, there are evidently some principles in their nature which make them interested in the fate of others and make their happiness necessary to them, even if they derive from it nothing more than the simple pleasure of contemplating it.[74] (p. 9)
4.3. A-Institutional Markets and the Psychologization of Economic Life
Either the state, or a corporation, or a cartel, or a holding company, or a cooperative association, or a trade union, or an employers’ association, or a trade association, or a joint trade agreement of two associations, or a stock exchange, or a board of trade, may lay down and enforce the rules which determine for individuals this bundle of correlative and reciprocal economic relationships.[87] (p. 649)
5. Conclusions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
1 | “A theory –positive or normative–, is all the more informative the more possible worlds are incompatible with it” [7] (p. 117). |
2 | The conception of “truth as correspondence” stated by John Searle can be understood as “the idea that our true statements are made true by the way things are in a real world that exists independently of the statements” [8] (p. xii; 199–226). |
3 | According to Alan Fiske, “people construct complex and varied social forms using combinations of these models implemented according to diverse cultural rules” [38] (p. 689). In fact, however, no institution embodies a single behavioral pattern: families, for example, do not operate exclusively in an egalitarian way, nor does the state function solely based on hierarchically subjecting its citizens. |
4 | See note 3 above. |
5 | The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy defines “abelian groups” as groups whose operation is commutative. In algebra, it is conventionally referred to as addition rather than multiplication operations, which it is the reason why they are also sometimes called “additive groups”. |
6 | For an accurate critic of the term “community” associated to the Airbnb hosts and guests and their socio-economic consenquences on real neighbor communities and local economies, see: Allyson E. Gold [68]. I am in debt with one of this journal’s reviewers for the reference. |
7 | Neoclassical economics could be defined in several ways, as each of them emerged as a result of various historical, methodological, and econometric critic. One of the most succict ways to understand it is by using an operative strategy that underlines—or decomposes—the most basic theoretical axioms that almost all variants of neoclassical economy must stick to: i.e., (i) methodological individualism (socio-economic explanation must be sought at the level of the individual agent); (ii) methodological instrumentalism (all behavior is preference-driven); and (iii) methodological equilibration (axiomatic imposition of equilibrium in theoretical and economic reasoning). For a further development of these axioms, see: Christian Arnsperger and Yanis Varoufakis [75]. Additionally, for a historical account of the term “neoclassical economy”, see: Tony Aspromourgos [76]. |
8 | Empirical evidence shows that “warm connotations of reciprocity are only part of the human story. Anthropological scholarship includes many examples of manipulative forms of reciprocity [...] in certain cases, it is actually the withholding of reciprocity that strengthens societal bonds” [79] (p. 1103). |
9 | To further expand Commons’ critical perspective of neoclassical economics and extend it to the a-institutional character of the emancipatory view of the SE, see: Antoon Spithoven [82] and Rodrigo Constantino Jeronimo et al. [33]. I am grateful to one of the anonymous reviewers for suggesting these valuable references to me. |
10 | As the same Karl Polanyi observed, “the emergence of the market to a ruling force of the economy can be traced by noting the extent to which land and food were mobilized through exchange, and labor was turned into a commodity free to be purchased in the market” [89] (p. 255). |
References
- Botsman, R.; Rogers, R. What’s Mine Is Yours: The Rise of Collaborative Consumption; Harper Collins: New York, NY, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Belk, R. You are what you can access: Sharing and collaborative consumption online. J. Bus. Res. 2014, 67, 1595–1600. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Botsman, R. The Sharing Economy Lacks a Shared Definition. In: FastCompany. 21 November 2013. Available online: https://www.fastcompany.com/3022028/the-sharing-economy-lacks-a-shared-definition (accessed on 10 January 2024).
- Arcidiacono, D.; Gandini, A.; Pais, I. Sharing what? The ‘sharing economy’ in the sociological debate. Sociol. Rev. Monogr. 2018, 66, 275–288. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schor, J. Consumo colaborativo: Una introducción. Econ. Front. 2014, 12, 7–10. [Google Scholar]
- Slee, T. What’s Yours is Mine. Against Sharing Economy; OR Books: New York, NY, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Domènech, A. Ocho desiderata metodológicos de las teorías sociales normativas. Isegoría. Rev. Filos. Moral Política 1998, 18, 115–141. [Google Scholar]
- Searle, J. The Construction of Social Reality; The Free Press: New York, NY, USA, 1995. [Google Scholar]
- Acquier, A.; Daudigeos, T.; Pinkse, J. Promises and paradoxes of the sharing economy: An organizing framework. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 2017, 125, 1–10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Frenken, K.; Schor, J. Putting the sharing economy into perspective. Environ. Innov. Soc. Transit. 2017, 23, 3–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sundararajan, A. The Sharing Economy. The End of Employment and the Rise of Crowd-Based Capitalism; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Benkler, Y. Sharing nicely: On shareable goods and the emergence of sharing as a modality of economic production. Yale Law J. 2004, 114, 273–358. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Murillo, D.; Buckland, H.; Val, E. When the sharing economy becomes neoliberalism on steroids: Unravelling the controversies. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 2017, 125, 66–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aristotle. Metaphysics; Dover Publications: New York, NY, USA, 2007. [Google Scholar]
- Bauwens, M. The Sharing Economy as a Locust Economy. In: P2P Foundation. 16 August 2014. Available online: https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/the-sharing-economy-as-a-locust-economy/2014/08/16 (accessed on 10 January 2024).
- Benkler, Y. The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom; Yale University Press: New Haven, CT, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
- Schor, J. Debating the Share Economy. In: Great Transition Initiative. October 2014. Available online: https://www.greattransition.org/publication/debating-the-sharing-economy (accessed on 10 January 2024).
- Bardhi, F.; Eckhardt, G.M. Access-based consumption: The case of car sharing. J. Consum. Res. 2018, 39, 881–898. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fitzsimmons, J.A. Consumer Participation and Productivity in Service Operations. Interfaces 1985, 15, 60–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boyle, J. The Second Enclosure Movement and the Construction of the Public Domain. Law Contemp. Probl. 2003, 66, 33–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Caffentzis, G. Autonomous Universities and the Making of the Knowledge Commons. In: The Commoner. 18 November 2008. Available online: www.thecommoner.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/06/caffentzis_autonomous-universities.pdf (accessed on 10 January 2024).
- Jemielniak, D. Common Knowledge? An Ethnography of Wikipedia; Stanford University Press: Stanford, CA, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
- Open Knowledge Foundation (OKF). What Is Open? In: Open Knowledge Foundation Blog. Available online: https://okfn.org/en/library/what-is-open/ (accessed on 10 January 2024).
- Fuchs, C. Labor in Informational Capitalism and on the Internet. Inf. Soc. 2010, 26, 179–196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boutang, Y.M. Cognitive Capitalism; Polity Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Schiller, D. Digital Capitalism: Networking the Global Market System; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1999. [Google Scholar]
- Humphreys, A.; Grayson, K. The Intersecting Roles of Consumer and Producer: A Critical Perspective on Co-production, Co-creation and Prosumption. Sociol. Compass 2008, 2, 963–980. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lanier, C.D.; Jensen Schau, H. Culture and co-creation: Exploring consumers’ inspirations and aspirations for writing and posting on-line fan fiction. In Consumer Culture Theory: Research in Consumer Behavior; Belk, B., Sherry, J.F., Eds.; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2007; pp. 321–342. [Google Scholar]
- Berardi, F. La Fábrica de la Infelicidad. Nuevas Formas de Trabajo y Movimiento Global; Traficantes de Sueños: Madrid, Spain, 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Hardt, M. The Common in Communism. Rethink. Marx. 2010, 22, 346–356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boutang, Y.M. L’abeille et L’économiste; Carnets Nord: Paris, France, 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Hardt, M.; Negri, A. Empire; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Constantino Jeronimo, R.; Anthony Scorsone, E.; Ribeiro Guedes, S.N. Ride-Hailing Platforms in Brazil: Regulatory Challenges in Times of Crisis. J. Econ. Issues 2024, 58, 503–510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Powell, A. Democratizing production through open source knowledge: From open software to open hardware. Media Cult. Soc. 2012, 34, 691–708. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Langley, P.; Leyshon, A. Platform capitalism: The intermediation and capitalisation of digital economic circulation. Financ. Soc. 2017, 3, 11–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kostakis, V.; Bauwens, M. Network Society and Future Scenarios for a Collaborative Economy; Palgrave Macmillan: New York, NY, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
- Celata, F.; Stabrowski, F. Crowds, communities, (post)capitalism and the sharing economy. City 2022, 26, 119–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fiske, A. The Four Elementary Forms of Sociality: Framework for a Unified Theory of Social Relations. Psychol. Rev. 1992, 99, 689–723. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Richardson, L. Performing the sharing economy. Geoforum 2015, 67, 121–129. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hesmondhalgh, D. Capitalism and the media: Moral economy, well-being and capabilities. Media Cult. Soc. 2017, 39, 202–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Drayton, W. Everyone a Changemaker. Social Entrepreneurship’s Ultimate Goal. Innovations 2006, 1, 80–96. [Google Scholar]
- Moreno-Chacón, P.; Selvam, R.M.; Marimon, F. On the Convergence of Collaborative and Social Economy: A Quality Model for the Combined Effects. Sustainability 2021, 13, 1907. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schor, J. Getting Sharing Right. Contexts 2015, 14, 14–15. [Google Scholar]
- Allen, D.; Chris, B. The Sharing Economy. How Over-Regulation Could Destroy an Economic Revolution; Institute of Public Affairs: Melbourne, Australia, 2014. [Google Scholar]
- Cañigueral, A. Los retos de la economía colaborativa. Econ. Front. 2014, 12, 22–24. [Google Scholar]
- Morozov, E. The Sharing Economy Undermines Workers’ Rights. In: Financial Times. 14 November 2013. Available online: https://www.ft.com/content/92c3021c-34c2-11e3-8148-00144feab7de (accessed on 10 January 2024).
- Hobbis, G.; Hobbis, S. Beyond platform capitalism: Critical perspectives on Facebook markets from Melanesia. Media Cult. Soc. 2022, 44, 121–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shuman, M. Going Local: Creating Self-Reliant Communities in a Global Age; Routledge: New York, NY, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Qiu, J.L. Goodbye iSlave: A Manifesto for Digital Abolition; University of Illinois Press: Urbana, IL, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Terranova, T. Free Labor: Producing Culture for the Digital Economy. Soc. Text 2000, 63, 35–58. [Google Scholar]
- Vasudevan, R. Share and share unlike: Reciprocity, corporate power, and the open source ethos. New Media Soc. 2023, 25, 2981–3001. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Martin, C.J.; Upham, R.; Klapper, R. Democratising platform governance in the sharing economy: An analytical framework and initial empirical insights. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 166, 1395–1406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dyer-Witheford, N. Cyber-Proletariat. Global Labour in the Digital Vortex; Pluto: London, UK, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Scholz, T. Uberworked and Underpaid: How Workers are Disrupting the Digital Economy; Polity Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Moreno, J.A. Semillas de economía alternativa: ¿construyendo otro mundo? Mediterráneo Económico 2014, 26, 291–307. [Google Scholar]
- Albert, M. Parecon: Life After Capitalism; Verso: London, UK, 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Mason, P. Postcapitalism: A Guide to Our Future; Farrar, Strauss & Giroux: New York, NY, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Widlok, T. Sharing as an alternative economy activity. In Handbook of the Sharing Economy; Belk, R., Eckhardt, G.M., Bardhi, F., Eds.; Edward Elgar Pub: Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA, USA, 2019; pp. 27–38. [Google Scholar]
- Alegre, J. Economía Colaborativa: Un Salto Cuántico. In: Economistas Frente a la Crisis. 4 June 2015. Available online: https://www.economistasfrentealacrisis.com/economia-colaborativa-un-salto-cuantico/ (accessed on 10 January 2024).
- Komarraju, S.A.; Arora, P.; Raman, U. Agency and servitude in platform labour: A feminist analysis of blended cultures. Media Cult. Soc. 2021, 44, 672–689. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hagedorn, K. Environmental Co-Operation and Institutional Change: Theories and Policies for European Agriculture; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2002. [Google Scholar]
- Martin, C.J. The sharing economy: A pathway to sustainability or a nightmarish form of neoliberal capitalism? Ecol. Econ. 2016, 121, 149–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gibson-Graham, J.K. A Postcapitalist Politics; University of Minnesota Press: Minneapolis, MN, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
- Sützl, W. The anti-economy of sharing. Else Art J. 2014, 1, 122–140. [Google Scholar]
- Lobel, O. The Law of the Platform. Minn. Law Rev. 2016, 101, 87–166. [Google Scholar]
- Aristotle. Nicomachean Ethics; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Lakoff, G.; Johnson, M. Metaphors We Live By; Chicago University Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 1980. [Google Scholar]
- Gold, A. Community consequences of AirBnB. Wash. Law Rev. 2019, 94, 1577–1637. [Google Scholar]
- Entman, R.M. Framing: Toward Clarification of a Fractured Paradigm. J. Commun. 1993, 43, 51–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bowles, S.; Gintis, H. Social Capital, Moral Sentiments, and Community Governance. In Moral Sentiments and Material Interests. The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life; Gintis, H., Bowles, S., Boyd, R., Fehr, E., Eds.; MIT University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2005; pp. 379–398. [Google Scholar]
- Martiskainen, M. The role of community leadership in the development of grassroots innovations. Environ. Innov. Soc. Transit. 2017, 22, 78–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zamagni, S. Por una Economía del Bien Común; Hernando, I., Translator; Ciudad Nueva: Madrid, Spain, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Zamagni, S. Bienes comunes y economía civil. Rev. Cult. Económica 2014, 87, 8–25. [Google Scholar]
- Smith, A. Theory of Moral Sentiments; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1976. [Google Scholar]
- Arnsperger, C.; Varoufakis, Y. What Is Neoclassical Economics? Post-Autistic Econ. Rev. 2006, 38, 2–12. [Google Scholar]
- Aspromourgos, T. On the Origins of the Term Neoclassical. Camb. J. Econ. 1986, 10, 265–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zaman, A.; Karacuka, M. The Empirical Evidence Against Neoclassical Utility Theory: A Review of the Literature. Int. J. Plur. Econ. Educ. 2012, 3, 366–414. [Google Scholar]
- Helbing, D. A New Kind of Economy is Born: Social Decision-Makers Beat the Homo Economicus. In: Real-World Economics Review Blog. 13 September 2013. Available online: www.rwer.wordpress.com/2013/09/13/a-new-kind-of-economy-is-born-social-decision-makers-beat-the-homo-economicus (accessed on 10 January 2024).
- Lange, P.G. Sharing in the digital era: Histories and consequences. Media Cult. Soc. 2018, 40, 1101–1106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Elster, J. Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1989. [Google Scholar]
- Johnson, S. Future Perfect: The Case for Progress in a Networked Age; Riverhead Books: New York, NY, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Spithoven, A. Gig Workers and Policies of Minimal Social Dislocation. J. Econ. Issues 2021, 55, 516–523. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bertomeu, M.J.; Domènech, A. El republicanismo y la crisis del rawlsismo metodológico (Nota sobre método y sustancia normativa en el debate republicano). Isegoría. Revista Filosofía Moral Política 2005, 33, 51–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Arrow, K.; Debre, G. Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy. Econometrica 1954, 22, 256–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cowhey, P.F.; Aronson, J.D. Digital DNA: Disruption and the Challenges for Global Governance; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Srnicek, N. Platform Capitalism; Polity: Cambridge, NY, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Commons, J. Institutional Economic. Am. Econ. Rev. 1931, 21, 648–657. [Google Scholar]
- Olsen, N. The Sovereign Consumer; Palgrave: Cham, Switzerland, 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Polanyi, K. The Economy as Instituted Process. In Trade and Market in the Early Empires, Economies in History and Theory; Polanyi, K., Arensberg, C.M., Pearson, H.M., Eds.; The Free Press & The Falcon’s Wing Press: Illinois, IL, USA, 1957; pp. 243–270. [Google Scholar]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2024 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Laín, B. Addressing the Sharing Economy—Some (Potential) Inconsistencies of Its Emancipatory Defense. Philosophies 2024, 9, 180. https://doi.org/10.3390/philosophies9060180
Laín B. Addressing the Sharing Economy—Some (Potential) Inconsistencies of Its Emancipatory Defense. Philosophies. 2024; 9(6):180. https://doi.org/10.3390/philosophies9060180
Chicago/Turabian StyleLaín, Bru. 2024. "Addressing the Sharing Economy—Some (Potential) Inconsistencies of Its Emancipatory Defense" Philosophies 9, no. 6: 180. https://doi.org/10.3390/philosophies9060180
APA StyleLaín, B. (2024). Addressing the Sharing Economy—Some (Potential) Inconsistencies of Its Emancipatory Defense. Philosophies, 9(6), 180. https://doi.org/10.3390/philosophies9060180