1. Introduction
Local authorities have sought to cope with the increasingly complex public procurement context by working together [
1,
2]. Collaborative procurement between local authorities has proven to be a solution for the difficulties they experience. In the public sector, a general trend towards the development and establishment of central purchasing bodies in an attempt to provide joint purchasing provision has been observed. The expected benefits of collaboration, such as joint purchasing, etc., include the fact that local authorities can benefit from the economies of scale, such as cost reduction, etc., [
3]. Furthermore, collaborative procurement reduces transaction costs because the number of transactions is reduced, and this collaboration provides local authorities with greater access to procurement expertise, which they could not reach themselves, thus fulfilling a condition for increased effectiveness [
4]. The advantages of collaboration seem to outweigh the disadvantages, for example, a reduced efficiency and higher agency costs [
2]; when compared to higher agency costs, structural cost savings often outweigh the need to increase coordination amongst members [
5]. Giving up a portion of autonomy through the establishment of a CPB seems like a small price to pay for the availability of the expertise, which is currently needed to bring the complex public procurement process to a successful outcome [
6]. Furthermore, concerning the success stories of procurement collaboration, academics have also critiqued the current trend. For example, [
7,
8] raise the issues around whether collaborative public procurement serve certain procurement objectives but not others?
Therefore, the aim of this paper is to explore what key factors exist that enable the alignment of the CPBs socio-economic goals within this collaborative public procurement (CPP) setting, and to understand the main issues and relationships that exist within a currently established CBP arrangement. The case study involves a Dutch municipality–CPB arrangement. The work starts by covering some of the key literature around current CBP and CPP relationships, identifying the key issues and underlying factors that are central to the correct functioning of such a relationship. From here, the authors employ a quantitative approach towards identifying and ranking through statistical significance, the key factors relevant to the example municipality-CBP relationship. The results of this work conclude by highlighting the underlying factors and government mechanisms relevant to the case study employed, but also which are common for other similar CPP settings, thus providing important new knowledge in the area of collaborative public procurement systems.
2. Literature Review
Agency theory is applied to relationships between the one party who delegates tasks (the principal) to another party (the agent) who then performs those tasks [
9]. Within the principal–agent relationship, agency theory seeks to find the optimum contract arrangements between parties, and helps to explain the observable actions of the principal and agent [
10]. The two main assumptions of agency theory are the existence of goal conflict and information asymmetry between the principal and agent [
9]. Within this research, local authorities (principals) strive to reach their procurement goals via a collaborative approach delegated to the CPB (agent). By applying a principal–agency perspective, deeper insight into the underlying causes of the effects of collaborative public procurement by CPBs on non-financial procurement performance indicators can be gained [
11].
One of the causes of agency problems is goal conflict between the agent and principal. According to agency theory, the chance that a CPB will pursue its own goals does increase if the agent is not monitored [
12]. However, high monitoring costs are seen as one of the barriers to overcoming the agency problem of goal conflict [
13]. Besides goal conflict between the principal and agent, information asymmetry is one of the main pillars under agency [
11,
13]. Within the context of collaborative public procurement (CPP), the size of the collaboration, the number of members, and the geographical scope make it more difficult to reduce information asymmetry within CPP arrangements [
14,
15,
16]. Agency theory is based upon the assumption that people’s actions are rational and motivated by self-interest [
8,
10]. This assumption lays at the base of the agency problems (goals conflict and information asymmetry) as described above. Self-interested, opportunistic behaviour becomes an agency problem when the interests of the principal and agent are not aligned [
13]. Where municipalities delegate the procurement task for certain commodities to a CPB, the CPB might have other interests than the principals’ [
17].
The theory suggests that the performance of socio-economic goals is negatively influenced due to goal conflict and information asymmetry between the principals (local authorities) and agent (CPB). According to the literature, the solutions to agency problems result in a higher level of goal congruence and a better information position for principals. Derived from the literature review and existing theory, the framework for this research, is utilised to structure the paradigm of this study. The main proposition is that, according to what the literature predicts, the solutions for agency problems contribute positively to information symmetry and goal congruence. The agency theory assumptions of goal conflict and information asymmetry [
11] are considered in their positive forms, which are, respectively, goal congruence and information symmetry [
18].
Table 1 outlines the key issues raised and, hence, the variables in this literature review, which enables the authors to develop their research framework shown in
Figure 1.
Therefore, the aim of this quantitative research study is to explore what opportunities (governance mechanisms) for agency problems within a Dutch municipality–CPB relationship are significant in aligning socio-economic goals within a collaborative public procurement (CPP) setting. Hereby, the theoretical fundament under CPP, which mostly emphasises value delivery through the economics of scale, is expended by empirical evidence to better understand how CPP can better align performance on socio-economic goals. Constructed on the results of this study, agency theory is enriched with empirically tested constructs in order to measure the conditions that determine the level of goal congruence and information symmetry within a collaborative public procurement setting in the Netherlands. The research framework is applied to a specific form of CPP, the municipal central purchasing body (CPB) in the Netherlands. As a result, it should be possible to infer what governance mechanisms are valuable to invest in aligning CPB performance with socio-economic objectives within this specific context. In line with the research framework, and given the specific context of this study, the following research questions are proposed:
What underlying factors of governance mechanisms that affect information symmetry are significant within the principals–agent relationship of a municipal CPB in the Netherlands?
What underlying factors of governance mechanisms that affect goal congruence are significant within the principals–agent relationship of a municipal CPB in the Netherlands?
What are the defining features of the underlying factors of governance mechanisms within the specific context of a municipal CPB in the Netherlands?
5. Discussion
The discussion is structured according to the governance mechanisms for agency problems as presented in the research framework (see
Figure 1). By subsequently addressing the government mechanism categories and their defining features, the third research question has been answered. Subsequently, the first two research questions are also answered through this approach. The factor analysis provided two underlying factors that represent the government mechanisms of the preliminary screening of the procurement collaboration (in this case, the CPB). Firstly, the track record of the CPB is found to be a decisive factor for municipal organisations to look at before committing to a joint tender. Secondly, the composition of the collaboration is a decisive factor for municipal organisations in deciding whether to commit to a (new) joint tender executed by a CPB. Screening the track record of the CPB as a decisive factor supports the agency theory assumption of adverse selection [
9]. Furthermore, it supports the premise of preliminary screening as a possible effective solution for the agency problem of information asymmetry [
11,
33]. Ref. [
34] states that large collaborative procurement organisations (such as CPBs) should have very competent resources to overcome information asymmetry between CPB and their members. In line with earlier research, the findings in this study show the extent of the importance on screening these resources, based on the available knowledge and the prior performance of the CPB. In contrast with previous research [
20,
21], screening the agent on how their activities are funded to reach socio-economic goals is not a decisive element in agent selection for the population in this study. This could be caused by the availability of the information and/or the costs associated with the screening efforts to obtain the information [
21,
22,
23]. Another explanation as to why this item is not found to be decisive might be the character of the relationship between the municipal organisations (principals) and the CPB (agent). Both parties are part of the government structure, which initially leads to high levels of trust and less emphasis on screening funding constructs [
2].
Municipal organisations want to know what other organisations participate in, the collaboration, and how strong their influence is. This underpins the findings of [
35], who found member commitment to be one of the main drivers for collaborative public procurement. The tension between autonomy and the collective is found to be a strong barrier for collaborative procurement [
36]; this could further explain why municipal organisations emphasise the composition of the collaboration and assessment of their level of influences as a decisive screening factor. Furthermore, assessing the composition of the collaboration underpins the findings of [
37], who found that the formation of a community among members strengthens the commitment to the collaboration. Municipal organisations find it important that other municipalities with which they can identify themselves also participate in the collaboration. The phenomenon probably increases the needed trust [
34,
37] that the CPB will act in the best interest of the members of the organisation.
In contrast with the existing literature [
18,
23,
35], the findings of this study do not support the conclusion that getting to know the CPB organisation is a decisive screening factor for municipal organisations. Furthermore, this study does not support the conclusion that members emphasise the way of working of the CPB as an important factor for the collaborative to succeed [
35], nor does it support the findings in prior studies [
18,
23,
35], where it was found that the composition of the purchasing team was an important factor for organisations to commit to collaborative procurement projects. This contradiction to prior results might be influenced by the earlier mentioned confidence that is derived from the screening of the other CPB members. The logic behind this trust factor would be as follows: ‘if participating in the collaborative is good for an organisation similar to me then it must be good for me too’. Detailed information on the team composition and organisational structure of the CPB seems to be of minor importance.
The factor analysis resulted in one underlying factor that represents the governance mechanism of monitoring the CPB. This factor is intuitively labelled as Direct monitoring/control. In contrast to screening solutions, the post-contract solutions for agency problems [
33] are applied, while the CPB executes the joint tenders on behalf of the municipal organisations. The governance mechanism ‘direct monitoring or control’ is a post-contract solution and therefore relates to the execution of CPB activities.
The findings in this study partially support the findings of earlier research. What stands out in the EFA results is that only direct control measures load on this factor. The items that described indirect monitoring measures did not load on the factors derived from this study. The findings are consistent with the findings of the research conducted by [
20], who found that direct monitoring measures were effective in reducing information asymmetry. However, their study was conducted in a project management context without inter-organisation collaboration elements. Research by [
2,
38] resulted in the (agency) costs for direct control measures being a major barrier to principals adopting these measures. Surprisingly, the fact that respondents in this study emphasised direct control measures seems to contradict this. An explanation for this novelty within the trade-off between monitoring measures and agency costs might be the relatively young age of the CPB in this study. As found by [
34], the relationship between members of collaboration becomes closer as the collaboration matures. In this relatively new principal–agent relationship, it might be the case that member organisations need to build up more experience and conviction with the execution of joint tenders to rely on (just) ex ante reports issued by the CPB. The overall conclusion could be that a proactive and direct monitoring system to address information asymmetry between principals and the agent seems to fit a public procurement collaboration in its early life cycle phase. The factor analysis provided two underlying factors that represent guidance as a government mechanism for agency problems. Firstly, the representation of CPB member organisations within the government structure of the CPB is found to be a factor of importance for municipal organisations to align the socio-economic goals with the goals pursued by the CPB. Secondly, direct involvement in working out requirements that address socio-economic goals is ought to result in better goal alignment for the population in this study.
The factor ‘representation’ withholds measures that see to ways of providing information within the governance structure of the CPB. This finding supports the solutions for information asymmetry provided by [
9], who suggests that principals could invest in information systems, such as additional management stages (in this case, the steering and advisory committee). The results of research conducted before the millennium focused on a better information position of the principal, based on the assumption of agent’s self-interest. The findings in this study provide evidence for the positive approach introduced by [
24,
25]. The underlying factor, which consists mainly of items that aim to provide information to the agent, confirms the assumption of honest incompetence [
23,
24] and guidance provided by the principal as a solution for information asymmetry [
18,
35].
In contrast with prior research from one item, a priori linked to incentives (INC007) loads on this factor as well. A possible reason for this result is found in the indirect or soft character of the incentives described in this item as follows: the public recognition of the CPB, promises of future commitment, etc., [
20]. These characteristics are closely related to the characteristics of the guidance items within this study. In contrast, the (other) classic measures linked to incentive items are either direct outcome-based or direct behaviour-based incentives for the agent [
9]. The analysis in this study shows that guiding the agent in the alignment of socio-economic goals ought to contribute to the reduced honest incompetence of the CPB, therefore reducing the level of information asymmetry.
Direct involvement as an explanation factor for agency problems seems to be in contrast with the basic assumption of agency theory. Agency theory assumes a principal–agent relationship where tasks are delegated from principal to agent [
9]. The results of this study show that, especially in items where the principal contributes to the execution of the joint tender, responsibilities load on the underlying factor of ’direct involvement’. Furthermore, the analysis shows that the item that described an indirect approach to reducing goal conflict was deleted, according to the EFA strategy applied. Similar to the explanation of screening category factors, this result could underpin the life cycle development of procurement collaborations [
34]. Guiding the CPB via direct involvement might best suit the life cycle phase of this relatively new CPB. The ‘direct involvement’ factor offers a solution for goal conflict, as it consists of measures that are aimed at working out socio-economic goals on behalf of the CPB. Thereby, municipal organisations align their objectives with the objectives pursued within the joint tender most directly.
Conferring to what agency theory indicates, two underlying factors represent incentives as a solution for the agency problem of goal conflict. One factor addresses outcome-based incentives, and the other factor addresses behaviour-based incentives. Structuring incentives form one of the classic solutions for agency problems [
9]. The population in this study emphasises outcome-based incentives to align their socio-economic goals with the goals pursued by the CPB. This supports the results derived from [
39,
40], whose aims of collaborative procurement organisations are clarified when the beneficiaries are known, and where otherwise, may increase difficulties in understanding between organisation members. In other words, as the results of this study suggest, if the outcome-based incentives for the CPB (as beneficiary) are structured well, the level of goal conflict should decrease as a result.
This study also provided a factor that consists mainly of behaviour-based items. Hereby, the actions of the CPB are influenced by offering resources specifically allocated to activities aimed at reaching the socio-economic goals of the principals that provide those resources. This confirms the results of prior research as it is assumed that behaviour-based contracts are especially efficient when the monitoring ability is high [
41]. Within the context of this study, there is no direct competition between the CPB and the member organisations, as the CPB is founded by the member municipalities themselves. The monitoring ability, therefore, is assumed to be high, while the activities result in public tender publications.
The ‘Principal’s engagement’ is the solution category with the highest number of deleted items. Therefore, the conclusion could be that this study does not support the findings of the prior literature. For instance, the item PRIN007 (working out parts of the joint tender) comes forward within the guidance factor ‘direct involvement’. Another example can be found in PRIN001 and PRIN002 (representation within the governance structure of the CPB), which come forward within the guidance factor ‘representation’. In contrast with the existing theory [
22], the number of deleted items shows that there is no clear evidence for the principal’s engagement as a strong self-contained government mechanism for the agency problems found in this study. Nevertheless, two underlying factors were derived from the factor analysis, which represents the a priori expected construct of principal engagement. Firstly, the population within this study finds goal certainty a factor of importance for municipal organisations to align socio-economic goals with the goals pursued by the CPB. Secondly, dividing tenders into clusters is found to be a measure to overcome the agency problem of goal conflict.
Aiming for goal certainty before municipal organisations (principals) commit to the execution of a joint tender on their behalf supports the assumption of goal conflict and agent’s seeking self-interest [
9]. The underlying factor of goal certainty addresses concrete measures that affect goal congruence between municipal organisations and the CPB. Similarly, the factor addresses the development of the procurement organisation to maturity, thereby supporting the findings of [
34,
39], who found the determination of common objectives by members of the CPB to be one of the elements that determine the life cycle phases of procurement collaborations.
Dividing joint tenders into clusters by the size of municipalities and or geographical region supports the findings of [
23,
40], who found that goal congruence increases when the physical distance between the principal and agent decreases. Furthermore, the literature not only suggests that the physical distance influences goal congruence within the principal–agent relationship, but other differences between organisations do also. Dividing tenders into clusters, therefore, is a remedy for goal conflict caused by the organisational distance among CPB members and between members and the CPB [
19]. Finally, dividing joint tenders into smaller clusters is aligned with the findings of [
6], who found that large collaborations are difficult to manage and small collaborations fail to obtain the right amount of expertise. By starting off as a large collaborative and then dividing into clusters, a win–win situation could arise.
Three explorative research questions were stated to structure the research. Through addressing the defining features of the underlying factors, the previous sections embrace the answer to the third research question, What are the defining features of the underlying factors of governance mechanisms, within the specific context of a municipal CPB in The Netherlands? Therefore, to answer the research questions, namely what are the underlying factors of governance that affect (1) information symmetry and (2) goal congruence within the principal–agent relationship of a municipal CPB in the Netherlands?
Table 6 and
Table 7 identify the factors that have been derived from the EFA. Four out of nine factors consist of solutions that affect information symmetry.
The other five factors, derived from the EFA, consist of solutions that affect goal congruence and are presented in
Table 7.
Overall, the results of this study support the results of previous studies concerning governance mechanisms for agency problems and the way they have been categorised in prior research. The two basic mechanisms, monitoring and incentives [
8], emerge clearly from the analysis.
The literature provided two other solutions to overcome agency problems, which were, respectively, screening [
21,
33] and principal’s engagement [
22]. By providing four underlying factors, this study supports the findings of the research that resulted in these solution categories for agency problems. Within the context of CPP through a CPB, it seems to provide more clarity if screening, hidden information, is recognised as a separate solution category rather than classifying it as a subcategory under monitoring [
33]. As discussed, the principal’s engagement category does not seem to be a strong self-contained category of solutions. Looking at the preventive characteristics of the factors derived from the EFA, one could argue that these factors appeal to the assumptions of guidance and therefore should be reordered into this solution category [
24,
25]. With regard to the guidance category provided by [
25], the results of this study are in line with the assumption of honest incompetence and the corresponding solutions [
24]. This research also supports the findings in the prior literature [
18,
24], arguing that guidance measures can positively affect goal congruence as well as information symmetry. Finally, this study underpins the general structure of the research framework and provides a more precise measurement scale for the agency problem solutions as follows: screening, monitoring, guidance, incentives, and principal’s engagement. In general, the results of this analysis support the results of previous studies concerning governance mechanisms for agency problems and the way they have been categorised in prior research. The two basic mechanisms, monitoring and incentives [
9], emerge clearly from the analysis.
6. Conclusions
The present research aimed to explore what solutions (governance mechanisms) for agency problems within a Dutch municipality–CPB relationship are decisive in aligning socio-economic goals within a collaborative public procurement (CPP) setting. The study adopted an agency theory perspective and, from this perspective, constructed three previously identified research questions. Established from the exploratory factor analysis of primary data, results have been collected via a web-based questionnaire from Dutch municipal organisations; insight was gained into the underlying factors of solutions for agency problems. The analysis resulted in nine factors which supported the general premise of agency theory and the known categorisation of governance mechanisms. To summarise,
Table 8 identifies the key factors following solutions for agency problems which were found to be decisive for aligning socio-economic goals within a Dutch municipality CPB relationship.
This study shows that the CPP governance items are also applicable within the context of socio-economic objectives for CPP. However, in contrast with previous research [
20,
21], screening the agent in terms of how their activities aiming to reach socio-economic goals are funded is not a decisive element in agent selection for the population in this study. Likewise, in contrast to prior research [
19,
20,
21], one item a priori linked to incentives (INC007) loads on this factor as well. A possible reason for this result is found in the indirect or soft character of the incentives described in the following item: public recognition of the CPB, promises of future commitment, etc., [
20]. These characteristics are closely related to the characteristics of the guidance items within this study. In contrast, the (other) classic measures linked to incentive items are either direct outcome-based or direct behaviour-based incentives for the agent [
9]. Overall, the results of this study support the results of previous studies concerning governance mechanisms for agency problems and the way they have been categorised in prior research.
The literature provided two other solutions to overcome agency problems, which were, respectively, screening [
21,
33] and principal’s engagement [
22]. By providing four underlying factors, this study supports the findings of the research that resulted in these solution categories for agency problems. Within the context of CPP through a CPB, it seems to provide more clarity if screening, hidden information, is recognised as a separate solution category rather than classifying it as a subcategory under monitoring [
33]. Besides supporting the existing theory, this study provides additional knowledge in the field of agency theory and collaborative public procurement (CPP). Firstly, the authors of this study designed, developed and tested an original comprehensive measurement scale to conduct research, based on agency theory, within the context of CPP governance, and specifically in the area of central purchasing bodies (CPBs) in the Netherlands. A quite remarkable result of this study is the number of factors that consist of direct control measures. Although shifting tasks to the agent is one of the main conditions of a principal–agent relationship, municipal organisations seem to indicate that they do not want to commit to CPP when it is executed out of sight or out of their direct control. In addition, in contrast with the existing literature, a manageable size of the procurement collaboration seems to be an important defining feature for Dutch municipal organisations to voluntarily join a central purchasing body (CPB). Furthermore, most probably related to the level of experience among or trust in CPB activities, direct monitoring systems, despite their higher agency costs, are preferred by local government agents as a decisive solution for the alignment of socio-economic goals.
Agency theory [
42] is enriched through the operationalisation of the underlying factors for solutions to agency problems within this setting, making it possible for future researchers to measure the level of goal congruence and information symmetry based on empirically tested items. Besides the further operationalisation of the classical governance mechanisms (monitoring and incentives), this study especially provides a deeper understanding of relevant items related to non-classical governance mechanisms (screening, guidance, and principal’s engagement). Furthermore, in the field of collaborative public procurement, this study contributes to knowledge via providing additional insight into the decisive elements of organisational design, especially for the most extensive form of procurement collaboration (the central purchasing body) in the Netherlands. By focusing on the alignment of socio-economic goals for public procurement, the results of this study will contribute to what is known about the benefits and barriers of collaborative public procurement. The underlying factors to prevent agency problems extracted from this study might contribute to future research in the field of the development of CPP organisations during their life cycle.
The results of this study are applicable in practise on the administrative and management level. Municipal organisations that initiate and/or govern a central purchasing body can take the results of this study into account in order to guide the further development of the CPB organisation. Combined with the knowledge of prior research in the field of CPP life cycle development, the results of this study are useful in streamlining the expected change in the pursuit of goals by members of a CPB. One can prevent a high level of dropouts via the preventive implementation of the governance mechanisms derived from this study. On a managerial level, this study provides useful insights for decision-makers in municipal organisations. They can better asses the way a CPB carries out the joint tenders at hand and determine if the joint approach delivers the best results in terms of their objectives.
Limitations and Future Research
The main strength of this study is the focus on a general type of collaborative public procurement and how the distinct set of socio-economic goals for procurement could be aligned within this form of collaboration. The aim of this specific research area provides useful results to govern specifically that type of organisation and that type of procurement goal. Taking into account the research method and target population, this study has been conducted in the business environment of the public sector in the Netherlands.
However, the authors acknowledge that this study has only employed a quantitative research approach. Through incorporating qualitative research approaches alongside the quantitative analyses, the authors understand that it would have assisted in the identification of key themes and patterns, which would provide richer descriptions of the issues around CPP that the quantitative methods employed were not fully able to achieve. Furthermore, through the adopted quantitative approach, this study applies an explorative perspective to generalise, which limits the ability to infer the extent to which the proposed governance mechanisms have an impact on the level of goal congruence and information symmetry. Likewise, this study only adopts the principal perspective of the principal–agent relationship, which influences the alignment of socio-economic goals. For instance, the level of trust between principals and the agent is seen as a possible explanation for the results derived from this study. However, the analyses in this study were not controlled via a measurement of the level of trust. The same goes for the explanation of the results related to the early life cycle phase of the CPB studied. Future studies might compare the results of the principal–agent relationships of CPBs in different life cycle phases to support or reject this explanation. Finally, this study has been conducted throughout the whole target population without addressing a specific case or commodity. This limited the ability to control variables that could influence the response provided. Certain conditions of joint tenders by a CPB could have been experienced by one or several respondents and not by the others. This limitation could be overcome through researching a distinct case (a specific joint tender by a specific CPB).
Future research is necessary to overcome the limitations presented in the previous paragraphs. First, research into different forms of CPP would further enrich the knowledge on governing CPP organisations. This could answer the following question: Does the organisational form of CPP influence the effectiveness of governance mechanisms for agency problems? Related to this type of research question, future research could focus on the comparison of results between different structures of CPP organisations in different life cycle stages. Secondly, via answering the question To what extent do governance mechanisms influence agent’s behaviour?, future research could take up both the principal and agent side of the relationship to further deepen the understanding of the relational constructs, and could also include comparative studies of different forms of CPP, investigations of agents’ behaviour in governance relationships, and case studies to quantify the impact of proposed governance mechanisms on goal alignment in collaborative procurement. It would also be useful to explore the influence of the life cycle of procurement organisations on the effectiveness of governance mechanisms. Furthermore, work could also progress into the category of principal’s engagement. Finally, this study could be followed by a case study that quantifies the effect of the proposed governance mechanisms on the level of goal congruence and information symmetry within a CPP setting. The following research question is proposed for future research: To what extent do the different governance mechanisms in a principal-agent relationship and CPP setting influence the degree of goal congruence and information symmetry?