An Optimal Three-Way Stable and Monotonic Spectrum of Bounds on Quantiles: A Spectrum of Coherent Measures of Financial Risk and Economic Inequality
Abstract
:1. Introduction
A very serious shortcoming of VaR, in addition, is that it provides no handle on the extent of the losses that might be suffered beyond the threshold amount indicated by this measure. It is incapable of distinguishing between situations where losses that are worse may be deemed only a little bit worse, and those where they could well be overwhelming. Indeed, it merely provides a lowest bound for losses in the tail of the loss distribution and has a bias toward optimism instead of the conservatism that ought to prevail in risk management.
- (I)
- The common risk measures and are in the spectrum: and ; thus, interpolates between and for and extrapolates from and on towards higher degrees of risk sensitivity for . Details on this can be found in Section 5.1.
- (II)
- The risk measure is coherent for each and each , but it is not coherent for any and any . Thus, is the smallest value of the sensitivity index for which the risk measure is coherent. One may also say that for the risk measure inherits the coherence of , and for it inherits the lack of coherence of . For details, see Section 5.3.
- (III)
- is three-way stable and monotonic: in , in , and in X. Moreover, as stated in Theorem 3.4 and Proposition 3.5, is nondecreasing in X with respect to the stochastic dominance of any order ; but, this monotonicity property breaks down for the stochastic dominance of any order . Thus, the sensitivity index α is in a one-to-one correspondence with the highest order of the stochastic dominance respected by .
- *
- In Section 2, the three-way stability and monotonicity, as well as other useful properties, of the spectrum of upper bounds on tail probabilities are established.
- *
- In Section 3, the corresponding properties of the spectrum of risk measures are presented, as well as other useful properties.
- *
- The matters of effective computation of and , as well as optimization of with respect to X, are considered in Section 4.
- *
- An extensive discussion of results is presented in Section 5, particularly in relation with existing literature.
- *
- Concluding remarks are collected in Section 6.
- *
- The necessary proofs are given in Appendix A.
2. An Optimal Three-Way Stable and Three-Way Monotonic Spectrum of Upper Bounds on Tail Probabilities
- (i)
- is nonincreasing in .
- (ii)
- If and , then for all .
- (iii)
- If and for all real , then for all .
- (iv)
- If and , then as and as , so that for all .
- (v)
- If and for some real , then as and as , so that for all .
- (i)
- For all , one has
- (ii)
- For all , one has .
- (iii)
- The function is continuous and convex if ; we use the conventions and for all real ; concerning the continuity of functions with values in the set , we use the natural topology on this set. Also, the function is continuous and convex, with the convention .
- (iv)
- If , then the function is continuous.
- (v)
- The function is left-continuous.
- (vi)
- is nondecreasing in , and for all .
- (vii)
- If , then ; even for , it is of course possible that , in which case for all real x.
- (viii)
- , and if and only if .
- (ix)
- .
- (x)
- for all .
- (xi)
- If , then is strictly decreasing in .
- (i)
- (ii)
- Model-independence:
- depends on the r.v. X only through the distribution of X.
- Monotonicity in X:
- is nondecreasing with respect to the stochastic dominance of order : for any r.v. Y such that , one has . Therefore, is nondecreasing with respect to the stochastic dominance of any order ; in particular, for any r.v. Y such that , one has .
- Monotonicity in α:
- is nondecreasing in .
- Monotonicity in x:
- is nonincreasing in .
- Values:
- takes only values in the interval .
- α-concavity in x:
- is convex in x if , and is concave in x if .
- Stability in x:
- is continuous in x at any point – except the point when .
- Stability in α:
- Suppose that a sequence is as in Proposition 2.3. Then .
- Stability in X:
- Suppose that and a sequence is as in Proposition 2.4. Then .
- Translation invariance:
- for all real c.
- Consistency:
- for all real c; that is, if the r.v. X is the constant c, then all the tail probability bounds precisely equal the true tail probability .
- Positive homogeneity:
- for all real .
3. An Optimal Three-Way Stable and Three-Way Monotonic Spectrum of Upper Bounds on Quantiles
- (i)
- .
- (ii)
- If then .
- (iii)
- .
- (iv)
- .
- (v)
- If , then the function
- (vi)
- If , then for any , one has .
- (vii)
- If , then .
- Model-independence:
- depends on the r.v. X only through the distribution of X.
- Monotonicity in X:
- is nondecreasing with respect to the stochastic dominance of order : for any r.v. Y such that , one has . Therefore, is nondecreasing with respect to the stochastic dominance of any order ; in particular, for any r.v. Y such that , one has .
- Monotonicity in α:
- is nondecreasing in .
- Monotonicity in p:
- is nonincreasing in , and is strictly decreasing in if .
- Finiteness:
- takes only (finite) real values.
- Concavity in or in :
- is concave in if , and is concave in .
- Stability in p:
- is continuous in if .
- Stability in X:
- Suppose that and a sequence is as in Proposition 2.4. Then .
- Stability in α:
- Suppose that and a sequence is as in Proposition 2.3. Then .
- Translation invariance:
- for all real c.
- Consistency:
- for all real c; that is, if the r.v. X is the constant c, then all of the quantile bounds equal c.
- Positive sensitivity:
- Suppose here that . If at that , then for all ; if, moreover, , then .
- Positive homogeneity:
- for all real .
- Subadditivity:
- is subadditive in X if ; that is, for any other r.v. Y (defined on the same probability space as X) one has:
- Convexity:
- is convex in X if ; that is, for any other r.v. Y (defined on the same probability space as X) and any one has
4. Computation of the Tail Probability and Quantile Bounds
4.1. Computation of
4.2. Computation of
- (i)
- (ii)
- (i)
- If , then is convex in the pair .
- (ii)
- If , then is strictly convex in .
- (iii)
- is strictly convex in , unless for some .
4.3. Optimization of the Risk Measures with Respect to X
4.4. Additional Remarks on the Computation and Optimization
5. Implications for Risk Assessment in Finance and Inequality Modeling in Economics
5.1. The Spectrum Contains and .
5.2. The Spectrum Parameter α as a Risk Sensitivity Index
- (i)
- one of the portfolios is clearly riskier than the other;
- (ii)
- this distinction is sensed (to varying degrees, depending on α) by all the risk measures with ;
- (iii)
- yet, the values of are the same for both portfolios.
5.3. Coherent and Non-Coherent Measures of Risk
5.4. Other Terminology Used in the Literature for Some of the Listed Properties of
5.5. Gini-Type Mean Differences and Related Risk Measures
5.6. A Lorentz-Type Parametric Family of Risk Measures
5.7. Spectral Risk Measures
5.8. Risk Measures Reinterpreted as Measures of Economic Inequality
5.9. “Explicit” Expressions of
6. Conclusions
- and are three-way monotonic and three-way stable – in α, p, and X.
- The monotonicity in X is graded continuously in α, resulting in varying, controllable degrees of sensitivity of and to financial risk/economic inequality.
- is the tail-function of a certain probability distribution.
- is a -percentile of that probability distribution.
- For small enough values of p, the quantile bounds are close enough to the corresponding true quantiles , provided that the right tail of the distribution of X is light enough and regular enough, depending on α.
- In the case when the loss X is modeled as a normal r.v., the use of the risk measures reduces, to an extent, to using the Markowitz mean-variance risk-assessment paradigm – but with a varying weight of the standard deviation, depending on the risk sensitivity parameter α.
- and are solutions to mutually dual optimizations problems, which can be comparatively easily incorporated into more specialized optimization problems, with additional restrictions on the r.v. X.
- and are effectively computable.
- Even when the corresponding minimizer is not identified quite perfectly, one still obtains an upper bound on the risk/inequality measures or .
- The quantile bounds with constitute a spectrum of coherent measures of financial risk and economic inequality.
- The r.v.’s X of which the measures and are taken are allowed to take values of both signs. In particular, if, in a context of economic inequality, X is interpreted as the net amount of assets belonging to a randomly chosen economic unit, then a negative value of X corresponds to a unit with more liabilities than paid-for assets. Similarly, if X denotes the loss on a financial investment, then a negative value of X will obtain when there actually is a net gain.