1. Introduction
Disasters impose a huge amount of uncertainty on the stock market. They are usually identified by the intensity and probability of occurrence, which are practically unknown to investors and can create severe changes in stock prices (see
Giglio et al. (
2021);
Hanspal et al. (
2021);
Gormsen and Koijen (
2020)). Even the gradual unfolding of disaster realization can lead to a huge amount of heterogeneity in the harsh time of a crisis. This heterogeneity tightly depends on the type of disaster and the corresponding firm’s characteristics that make investors learn and update their beliefs.
Apart from uncertainty usually caused by any crisis, the COVID-19 pandemic induced a sort of heterogeneity directly related to specific firms’ characteristics. Some firms relative to others are less risky and more “resilient” to COVID-19-like pandemics, in the sense that these firms have more flexible workforces in the presence of social distancing rules and lockdown restrictions. Such flexibility empowers them to deal with corresponding managerial issues. In order to maximize shareholder wealth, firms need to diagnose and take different types of risk seriously in their decisions. In the post-pandemic era, “resilience” risk, which is directly related to the working environment, can be introduced as known risks and should be assessed and managed to optimize shareholder wealth. For risk management to affect value as
Stulz (
2024) explains, there should be a significant effect of risk on future expected cash flows.
Daadmehr (
2024) provides different pieces of evidence of heterogeneous expected cash flows and its impact on implied discount rates in the time of COVID-19. The COVID-19 literature provides different interpretations of how such risks can potentially affect expected returns (
Pagano et al. 2023). Having evidence of the significant impact of COVID-19 on overall economic contraction (
Daadmehr 2022) enables this paper to propose a novel specific asset pricing model considering a clear “definition” for COVID-19 disaster states to explain more precisely existing heterogeneity.
On the other hand, investors learn from not only the possibility of disaster that itself depends on COVID-19 intensity but also the duration of disaster. Yet, there is no study to show how such workplace-related risk can be transmitted from cash flows to expected returns, including the impact of COVID-19 disaster probability and investors’ updating probabilities as two different kinds of probabilities (opposed to
Pagano et al. (
2023)). As a piece of evidence,
Figure 1 exhibits the lower growth of earning expectations for low-resilience firms. This figure suggests that workplace resilience can mitigate the consequences of the association between COVID-19 intensity and social distancing rules, which accelerates investors’ learning in favor of more workplace-flexible firms and updating trading strategies as well.
This paper tries to figure out what happened to expectations during the COVID-19 disaster when workplace flexibility was triggered by COVID-19 intensity. Improving the pricing methodology in
Daadmehr (
2024) to see the impact of the time-varying intensity of the disaster, this paper proposes a new setup and shows how the resilience and intensity of the COVID-19 pandemic interact with each other to establish the corresponding heterogeneity in expected returns. It explains the transit channel and proves the existence of heterogeneity in asset prices, expected returns, and its differentials, specifically due to not only workplace resilience but also COVID-19 intensity and the probability of disaster. Results emphasize the necessity and importance of disentangling investors’ updatingprobabilities and disaster probabilities and suggest that low-resilience firmshave higher expected returns than high-resilience ones, in line with
Pagano et al. (
2023) and
Daadmehr (
2024). Moreover, the model sheds light on investors’ learning originating from the intensity of COVID-19 and reveals to what extent expected returnsdepend on this novel insight which exhibits the lower bound for investors’ updating probabilities, based on the firm’s resilience as well as disaster probability and COVID-19 intensity. Results suggest fewer expected returns for more resilient assets and higher expected return differentials in cases of higher COVID-19 intensity, through investors’ learning.
In brief, this paper, as a novel work, provides theoretical proof and rationalizes empirical evidence in the literature. First, it defines “disaster periods” based on the intrinsic feature of this crisis and COVID-19 as an exogenous pathological disease. Second, it takes into account the fact that investors learn from the probability of disaster and update this probability to a new probability called investors’ updating probability (IUP), which depends on the duration of a crisis. Specifically, it shows analytically that an increase in COVID-19 intensity increases the expected returns of low-resilience assets more than those of high-resilience ones.
To this aim, after a quick review of the literature in
Section 2, this paper explains the setup and provides results and solutions in
Section 3 and
Section 4, respectively; then, it concludes.
2. Motivation and Contribution to the Literature
From one side, this paper joins the literature in corporate resilience. This strand of the literature has grown fast, especially since COVID-19’s emergence. A wide range of studies deviate from the general definition of resilience as the capacity of firms to have a short recovery period in cases of any disturbance during and after a crisis. The definition of resilience in the period of COVID-19 is mostly accompanied by investigating the role of the working environment to create tolerance toward social distancing rules and lockdown restrictions in response to the exogenous COVID-19 pandemic. Apart from the early literature from 2020 that explains to what extent jobs can be carried out from home and the impact of this together with flexibility in on-site teamwork communication on firms’ production costs (see
Koren and Pető (
2020);
Dingel and Neiman (
2020);
Hensvik et al. (
2020)), some papers start to quantify corporate resilience based on firms’ financial status and interaction withworkplace flexibility which are main resilience-related characteristics (
Daadmehr 2024). Although such studies provide key tools for risk management, there is still a long path to realize how different firms’ characteristics generate risk and expected return differentiation.
To do this, one may be interested in proposing an asset pricing setup in which the role of interaction between workplace resilience and cash flow sheds light on differentiation in expected returns. This paper contributes to studies in risk management from an asset pricing perspective, specifically when the economy is hit by rare events like the COVID-19 pandemic.
In the asset pricing literature, “rare disaster” appears as a response to the equity premium puzzle (see
Campbell (
2017) and
Rietz (
1988)) where preferences make expected returns greater than what consumption (distribution) implies. The early studies on rare disasters (
Weitzman (
2005);
Rietz (
1988);
Barro (
2006)) suggest that not only uncertainty but also a small possibility of disaster may lead to non-lognormality in consumption growth and its distribution tends to have a heavier tail (
Weitzman 2005).
Martin (
2013) starts with power utility and arbitrary iid consumption growth and explains the role of the cumulant generating function for consumption risk. The proposed equity premium based on the generating function reveals an increasing trend in terms of relative risk aversion, meaning that a decreasing amount of RRA is needed to fit any given equity premium (
Martin 2013).
There are two main strands in the literature in asset pricing with rare events. In the first strand, papers start to establish the importance of the state of the economy and take into account disaster probability in the sense of the probability of adverse events (see
Barro (
2006) and
Daadmehr (
2022)).
Barro (
2006) calibrated the probability of disaster based on historical data, including different kinds of rare events since WW1. A new asset pricing model for the COVID-19 period, including the macro-time effect of disasters on firms’ productivity as well as the price of an equity claim to the output of firms, is provided by
Daadmehr (
2022). The second strand starts to consider the sequence of disasters as a realization of the Poisson processes. Among all,
Wachter and Zhu (
2024) consider the aggregate consumption process containing the Poisson term for capturing the impact of disasters. They define disaster states based on two high and low amounts of intensity in the Poisson process and provide the theoretical evolution of asset pricing implications. Moreover, defining the impact of gradual unfolding disaster as an aggregate of the Poisson processes has its own merits.
Ghaderi et al. (
2022) calibrate agents’ updating belief and show that it follows the true state of the economy.
As a first step, it is vital to examine the feasibility of considering the COVID-19 pandemic as a “disaster”.
Daadmehr (
2022) statistically tests and reports the significant impact of this exogenous shock on macroeconomic contraction. Her results allow the proposal of a new asset pricing model embedding a specific definition for disaster states. Since the COVID-19 shock is a pandemic disease crisis with a severe impact on the workforce, this paper, as a novel work, provides a new definition of disaster states based on COVID-19 intensity using a critical threshold of new COVID-19 cases or deaths. On top of this, the setup enables the disentanglement of investors’ updating probability and the probability of COVID-19 disaster. This suggests a sort of lower bound for investors’ updating probability. As opposed to
Pagano et al. (
2023), this additional novelty potentially provides evidence of the impact of the updating beliefs of investors with long-run memory. The theoretical results prove the existence of learning even in the case of no disaster. To clarify, this paper takes into account different sources of variation: resilience, the intensity of disaster, and the corresponding probability of disaster.
Gabaix (
2012) introduces a time-varying rare disaster framework. He presents an asset-specific dividend process magnified by a positive rate of survival in disaster time. His definition of time-varying “resilience” is increasing the asset-specific surviving rate. In his proposed framework, resilience is a linearity-generating process that sees shock uncorrelated with disaster occurrence (
Gabaix 2012). Following
Pagano et al. (
2023), this paper adds a piece of novelty to the strand of the literature on “resilience” in asset pricing by considering appropriate so-called workplace resilience (
Daadmehr 2024), which accords with the intrinsic features of the pandemic crisis and the consequent social distancing mitigation policies. As opposed to
Daadmehr (
2022) who uncovers the impact of this sort of workplace resilience on expected future cash flows and dividend streams, the model in this paper with additional novelties is in line with
Pagano et al. (
2023) and emphasizes the importance of this type of resilience to explain the variation in expected returns and the differentials between high- and low-resilience assets.
On the other hand, this paper introduces another possible source of time-variation, as a new piece of insight, consistent with the nature of the COVID-19 health crisis, called “intensity of disaster”. The results theoretically show how expected returns and their differentials vary with the intensity of COVID-19. Contrary to
Pagano et al. (
2023) who consider a three-period consumption-portfolio choice model and the intensity of disaster a parameter, this paper assumes that investors have longer memory and learn from the realization of the COVID-19 pandemic and solve a three-period consumption-portfolio choice model at each point in time. This study shows the response of expected returns and their differentials in the case of an upward change in the intensity rate of the COVID-19 disaster at any point in time. Consistent with
Pagano et al. (
2023) and
Daadmehr (
2024), the model proves the sensitivity of resilience heterogeneity in expected returns to the intensity of COVID-19 and shows that all these sensitivities are more severe for low-resilience assets. Moreover, expected return differentials see higher revisions when investors perceive a higher COVID-19 intensity, as well as a higher possibility of disaster.
Furthermore,
Gourio (
2012),
Gabaix (
2012), and
Wachter and Zhu (
2024) declare the time-varying probability of disaster that generates covariation in equity premium. As opposed to
Wachter and Zhu (
2024) who use the jump Poisson process to capture disaster and apply Markov switching simulation to investigate the effect of learning with rare disasters,
Ghaderi et al. (
2022) consider gradually unfolding disasters. They explain that investors are not aware of the true state of the economy and introduce a Bayesian learning framework showing that updating investors’ beliefs captures the effect of the slow unfolding of disasters in a way so that prices truly react to consumption decline and show that updating agents’ belief accords with the true state of the economy. This study joins this literature by defining the “disaster state” directly based on the intensity of COVID-19 with the Poisson distribution.
Generally speaking, this paper contributes to the literature through three novelties: First, it differentiates from
Gabaix (
2012) and
Ghaderi et al. (
2022), among all, by introducing a different definition of a disaster state based on the nature of the COVID-19 pandemic as an exogenous health crisis. Second, it deviates from
Pagano et al. (
2023) by disentangling the probability of disaster and investors’ updating probabilities. Third, it provides the theoretical proof of the empirical study by
Daadmehr (
2024) by adding these novelties to an empirical asset pricing model. All these new insights lead to a novel result of the model, which is not mentioned by the existing literature:
“An increase in COVID-19 intensity increases the expected returns of low-resilience assets much more than those of high-resilience ones”.
This key finding emphasizes the need to adopt appropriate strategies for managerial issues, especially in firms with low resilience in their working environment. It not only helps investors to diagnose riskier assets (in terms of workplace resilience) but also enables managers to be aware of the impact of workplace conditions on expected returns as well as the firm’s performance in the future. This highlights the necessity and importance of this study and especially that the experience of COVID-19 and its impact on financial markets reveal that neither managers nor investors had learned from the lessons of previous pandemic crises. The following sections contain a detailed interpretation of the model, the solution, and more importantly the trace of first and second novelties in the third one.
4. Theoretical Results
The proposed setup and model lead to several propositions that shed light on price fluctuations in the pandemic era.
Proposition 1. In any period, t, high-resilience assets see higher prices and the asset price differential increases if The first-order condition with respect to
, replacing the equilibrium values of consumption in disaster/no-disaster states in the marginal utility function, directly proves that high-resilience assets see higher prices, since
Moreover, the first-order condition with respect to
, replacing the equilibrium values of consumption in the marginal utility function, directly proves the increasing price differential for high- and low-resilience assets if
In other words, if the price change in the period
satisfies this condition, the price differential will be updated upward in the following period. This condition shows the existence of an upper bound depending on the resilience differential
7 (
). This upper bound is time-varying and the impact of the resilience differential on the upper bound is magnified by the relative resilience to COVID-19 intensity, B (
Section 3.2), and risk aversion. It is straightforward to show that the upper bound always increases as the relative resilience to shock intensity (B) rises (
) in the case of constant COVID-19 intensity realization. This means that when the economy is relatively more resilient compared to the intensity of shock, there is much more space for price fluctuations in the period
8 to satisfy this condition, and as a result, this implies more space for an increasing price differential in the following period,
t.
On the other hand, the derivative of the upper bound with respect to risk aversion () depends on . is negative if and it is positive if . This implies that more risk-averse investors expect higher price differentials in the following period when the resilience of the economy to the intensity of shock is relatively small ().
Apart from the impact of the resilience differential of assets () and risk aversion (), COVID-19 intensity in three periods (, , and t) affects the threshold for the following price differential (), directly through its value in the period t and indirectly through the value of investors’ updating probability in previous periods ( and ).
Figure 6 suggests that
9 decreases as investors realize higher
, in line with the fact that tail events are rare events with a lower probability of occurrence.
Figure 7 shows that any increase in
decreases
and, as a result, implies a higher instantaneous investors’ updating probability (
) since
(
Section 3.1). By rewriting the condition as
it can be easily proved that the upper bound is decreasing in terms of instantaneous COVID-19-intensity (
), regardless of upward or downward IUP from
to
. This means that the price differential increases under the tighter condition. In other words, an increase in COVID-19 intensity gives new information to investors, updates IUP upward, and tightens the price differential condition in a sense that the price differential increases if this differential was much smaller in the previous period.
Furthermore, investors’ updating of disaster probability in two recent periods (
and
) plays a key role in price differentials. One interesting feature is the implicit role of the number of disaster periods in the realized sequence in investors’ updating probability in these periods and the consequent upper bound of price differentials above. Consistently, as the number of disaster states increases in the pandemic era
10, the maximum investors’ updating probability surges to one (
Figure 2 and
Figure 3). The key point here is that under the proposed conditions in
Section 3.1 and in the disaster situation
, investors may update their beliefs upward,
, or downward,
, depending on resilience of the asset. This affects price movements in the current period and the corresponding upper bound and, as a result, the price differential trend in the following period. This evidence establishes the importance of disentangling investors’ updating probability and disaster probability.
This proposition shows how long-memory investors play a role in future price fluctuations and implies that even in the case of a no-disaster period, there is a process of learning in investors’ behavior, emphasizing the novelty and necessity of the proposed setup.
Proposition 2. High-resilience assets see fewer expected returns, as opposed to low-resilience ones, if This condition proposes a lower bound for investors’ updating probability (IUP) that is defined in a different way from disaster probabilities and remarks how this lower bound is related indirectly to COVID-19-intensity through disaster probability (
) and directly to risk aversion,
. This lower bound can potentially be an answer to the flip points in the evolution of the expected returns of high- and low-resilience assets (
Pagano et al. 2023).
Solving the maximization problem and first-order conditions with respect to
and
and replacing the equilibrium values of consumption in the marginal utility function yield the following expression for high- and low-resilience asset prices:
Then, using the short-hand
, the expected return for high- and low-resilience assets in any period of
t is
In any period
t, it can clearly be seen that by differentiating the expected returns with respect to asset resilience,
,
This statement is negative if
Equivalently,
This inequality implies a lower bound for the odds ratio of investors’ updating probability, . Specifically, it shows that more risk-averse investors, who change their perception about disaster probability more often than others, impose fewer expected returns for high-resilience assets. It is straightforward to show that in the case of any increase in risk aversion in (), the lower bound increases and suggests tighter conditions in a sense that the relative investors’ updating probability () can potentially become much greater than the relative disaster probability ().
Moreover, the lower bound is positive in disaster periods when the relative resilience to the intensity of shock is at a very low level (
). This implies a wider condition for the perceived odds ratio of disaster by investors (
), meaning that it is more possible to see that investors impose a higher probability for a disaster event than disaster probability itself. Obviously, this condition proves that in any case of B, there are fewer expected returns for high-resilience assets in a sense that these assets are less risky, in line with
Daadmehr (
2024).
Proposition 3. Regardless of having a disaster or no-disaster event in the period t, any increase in disaster intensity in the following period implies greater expected returns.
Using Equation (
2), the expected returns of either high-resilience or low-resilience assets,
, is an increasing function of intensity:
:
This proposition reveals the instantaneous effect of COVID-19 intensity on expected returns. Investors expect more returns as soon as they observe a higher number of new deaths or new cases. The next proposition proves that such expectations increase severely for low-resilience assets.
Proposition 4. An increase in COVID-19 intensity increases the expected returns of low-resilience assets more than those of high-resilience ones.
According to Proposition 2, the following is the corresponding derivative of expected returns with respect to
and
:
The proposition is satisfied if is less than zero (Proposition 2). Consequently, is negative. This proposition provides a theoretical proof to show that the expected returns of low-resilience assets are instantaneously more sensitive to COVID-19 intensity, meaning that investors are more elastic to the return expectations in response to COVID-19 intensity for low-resilience assets. Investors asymmetrically expect many more returns for low-resilience assets when the economy is at risk of a higher number of new deaths or new number of cases.
It is noteworthy to mention that a similar statement is investigated for expected cash flows in a “different framework” by
Daadmehr (
2022).
Proposition 5. In any period t, as investors’ updating probability regarding disaster increases, the expected return increases.
Using Equation (
2), the expected return with respect to
is the following:
which is always positive.
Proposition 6. Regardless of being in a disaster or no disaster in the period t, any increase in disaster intensity, , leads to a greater expected return differential.
Using Equation (
2), the expected return differential is the following:
Using Equation (
3), the variation in the expected return differential with respect to
is obtained as the following:
which is positive for
where
and
This proposition explains that depending on disaster probability and under some conditions for investors’ updating probability, a higher number of new cases or new deaths as an indicator of COVID-19 intensity implies an increase in the expected return differential between high- and low-resilience assets.
Proposition 7. An increase in investors’ updating probability regarding disaster results in greater revisions in the expected return differential.
According to Equation (
3), the variation in the expected return differential with respect to
is
which is positive since
. This proposition theoretically explains how the expected return differential is responsive to investors’ updating probability that itself depends not only on disaster probability by definition but also on COVID-19 intensity as a possible realization of the number of new cases or number of new deaths through the Poisson distribution (previous propositions).
Proposition 8. In any period t, the expected return increases as COVID-19 intensity increases.
Based on Equation (
2), Proposition 5, and the condition of
implying
in no-disaster periods and
in disaster periods (
Section 3.1), the variation in the expected return with respect to COVID-19 intensity,
, is the following:
and it is always positive.
Proposition 9. The expected return sensitivity to COVID-19 intensity in the period t increases as the average intensity rate of COVID-19 sees greater values.
This proposition emphasizes the implicit role of the perceived average rate of COVID-19 pathological disease (average intensity of exogenous shock) on expected return revisions. It proves that when the overall rate of COVID-19 cases (or deaths) increases, the expected return is realistically more responsive to variation in the intensity of disaster.
Proposition 10. Higher COVID-19 intensity implies an increase in the expected return differential.
The variation in the expected return differential with respect to COVID-19 intensity,
, is the following:
According to Proposition 7 and
Section 3.1, it is always positive. The proposition provides an implicit link between the type of disaster (pathological COVID-19 disease) and the characteristics of assets (workplace resilience). This theoretically tracks how the differential of the expected returns of assets categorized based on workplace resilience can be affected by more cases or new deaths as a proxy for COVID-19 intensity.
Proposition 11. The expected return differential sensitivity to COVID-19 intensity in the period t increases as the average intensity rate of COVID-19 hits a higher value.
Following Proposition 10,
which is always positive if the average intensity of shock (
) is less than
. As is explained in Proposition 10, this proposition similarly reveals the implicit role of the rate of COVID-19 pathological disease on the expected return differential. It proves that when the overall intensity rate of COVID-19 (
) increases, the expected return differential between high- and low-resilience assets is realistically more responsive to the variation in the current intensity of disaster.
These theoretical results highlight how pandemic intensity creates information and plays a role in investors’ updating beliefs with different probabilities depending on the probability of disaster and its prolongation. These results specifically emphasize the necessity of disentangling investors’ updating probability and disaster probability and the impact on expected returns.
Although including data-driven evidence (e.g., historical stock returns during the pandemic) would strengthen the credibility of the results, empirical analysis without enough data is not reliable. This paper did not use historical stock returns to avoid the contamination of the impact of previous crises (2011 European crisis, 2008 financial crises, 2005 SARS-CoV, and others like WW1 and WW2) since different types of disasters have different consequences on the economy or affect the economy with different mechanisms (
Jordà et al. 2022). This limits the period of time, which is a very short period for (calibrating) such a detailed asset pricing model.
On the other hand, there were nine years (2013–2022) unaffected by the impact of any other crises, and more importantly, neither investors nor managers had learned from the impact of the previous pandemics (a severe market crash as explicit evidence). This redirected this paper to rationalize the evidence in other empirical studies by proposing the theoretical framework. This paper decided to work on how the pandemic affects expectations (expected returns).
In the period of a pandemic, especially with different mitigation policies like social distancing and lockdowns, the exogenous impact of COVID-19 on human interaction and the consequent impact on the workforce place this model in a completely different category of asset pricing models. This paper emphasizes the importance of proposing a trackable analytical characterization for heterogeneous expected returns. These propositions provide a theoretical specification for resilient heterogeneous expected returns and enable theoretically tracking how workplace resilience affects these expectations, which are vital for firms to adopt appropriate corporate policies.
Firms can optimize their performance and expected returns as a proxy by controlling corporate financials. For instance, corporate policies on cash holdings can influence expected returns. Firms with higher cash holdings tend to have higher expected equity returns, particularly if they have riskier cash flows like low-workplace-resilience firms (as
Daadmehr (
2022) empirically proves). In other words, firms can manage to alleviate the impact of social distancing rules and lockdowns on human interaction by having a higher level of cash holdings.