1. Introduction
Banks, insurance companies, and other financial institutions frequently maintain and manage large credit portfolios. The main risk associated with such portfolios is that debtors may default on their obligations. Portfolio credit risk is concerned with large but rare loss events induced by defaults. Factor models are commonly used to represent the asset returns of a company, and defaults are said to occur when these assets fall below a certain threshold. From a statistical perspective, correlation between defaults of distinct companies is introduced by allowing the assets to share systemic factors, also referred to as latent factors or random effects. Specifically, if
denotes the value of the
i-th firm (as determined by its assets), then this dependence can be modeled, in the simplest case, by setting
where
,
are independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) random variables and independent of
Z. A useful feature of (
1) is that, conditioned on the latent variable
Z, the assets
are independent. When
Z and
are Normally distributed, (
1) reduces to the widely used single-factor Gaussian model, referred to as the Gaussian copula model in the literature. More generally, assuming that there are
k, possibly dependent, factors influencing the asset variable
, an additive factor model takes the form
The i-th firm is then said to default if , where d represents the threshold; in other words, setting , and letting , where is the loss incurred when the i-th loan defaults, then denotes the total loss due to defaults, and our primary focus in this paper is to provide sharp tail approximations of under different asymptotic regimes, where either , or d is replaced by as
To motivate (
2) from a financial perspective, it is helpful to briefly review the classical framework originally introduced by
Merton (
1974). To this end, beginning with a single loan to a firm with assets
at time
t, it is natural to model
according to the stochastic differential equation
for some mean drift
m and volatility
, where
is a standard Brownian motion. Now, if the firm is to repay a loan of size
K at the future time
T, then default occurs if
. Upon integrating and applying Ito’s formula, we see that, viewed from the current time
t, this default will happen if
where the threshold
d denotes the “distance to default”. Now consider a portfolio of loans to a collection of firms. Let the values of the
n firms be given by
; then the model in (
3) can be extended to
where
is
l-dimensional Brownian motion, and
and
are positive constants for all
. Using the reasoning leading to (
4), it follows that the default occurs when
; and this is equivalent to
which, after conducting simple algebra, yields that
for
. Thus, choosing one component of the Brownian motion to be firm-specific for each loan, and the remaining factors to be common among all loans (so that
, we are led to the factor model
where
and
are positive constants for all
, and
and
are i.i.d. standard Normal random variables, which is (
2), but with
in place of
and an independent Normal assumption on the factors. The variables
represent the
common factors, while the random variables
represent the
idiosyncratic factors (or individual factors).
The Gaussian assumption has often been criticized and other distributional assumptions have been suggested. For instance,
Schönbucher (
2000),
Gordy (
2003),
Hull and White (
2004), and
Burtschell et al. (
2009) propose extensions of factor models with non-normal distributions, including Archimedean and t-copula models. The reference
Bush et al. (
2011) analyzes a dynamic extension of Vasicek’s homogeneous single factor model in which the systematic risk factors follow a Brownian motion. Some large deviation estimates for sums of random variables have been provided in
Maier and Wüthrich (
2009), where the dependencies are modeled according to a copula (rather than through a threshold factor model).
The aim of this work is to develop
sharp asymptotics for the tails of the total loss distribution. Such tail asymptotics were first introduced under independent Gaussian assumptions in
Glasserman et al. (
2007). However, in contrast, we will adopt a general framework where both the common and idiosyncratic factors are allowed to assume very general distributions (and not necessarily the same distributions). Our work seems to provide the first theoretical results that are nonlogarithmic and do not invoke convenient tail assumptions (as are specified in the Normal or regularly varying distributions, and their multivariate extensions via the Gaussian and
t-copulas).
To describe our results, let
be given as in (
2), and, as before, let
where
and
is an i.i.d. sequence, independent of
. As the random variable
represents the loss incurred when the
loan defaults, we have that
, where
is the size of the
loan and
represents the recovery rate. Assume that the sequence
is i.i.d. and independent of
, and assume without loss of generality that
Furthermore, set
Then conditional on
, the central tendency of
is given by
where
by (
2). Then by the conditional Chebyshev inequality,
implying that
converges in probability to
conditioned on
. Hence,
In particular, if
in (
2) and
, then it follows from (
11) that
which is a formula originally established in
Vasicek (
1991).
As observed in
Glasserman et al. (
2007), this last equation shows that a meaningful asymptotic result can only be obtained by studying the problem in a limiting sense, e.g., by letting
, or by replacing the threshold
d with
and letting
Notice that as
, the right-hand side of (
12) converges to zero, and using the formula for the tails of a Normal distribution (as given, e.g., in
Chow and Teicher (
1997)), this term decays asymptotically as
In particular, taking
and letting
, this last expression is asymptotic to
and hence
suggesting that
will exhibit a similar limit behavior to that of
; namely,
Asymptotics of this type were established on a logarithmic scale in
Glasserman et al. (
2007) for Gaussian
k-factor models with finitely many types.
Letting
be a sequence converging to one and satisfying certain regularity conditions, our first main result examines the decay of
as
for the factor model in (
2). Setting
and letting
denote its distribution function, then we establish that
where
is given as in (
10) and is thus
determined by the distribution of the idiosyncratic factors . On the other hand, the tail decay is determined by
, i.e.,
by the common factors, thus exhibiting an interesting interplay between the roles of the common factors and the individual factors associated with the given loans. [Here and in the following,
as
means that
] We establish this result under very general assumptions on the common factors
and the idiosyncratic sequence
, where, in principle, we do not even assume that any of these random variables have a common distribution. However, as in
Glasserman et al. (
2007) and the heuristic estimate (
15), the rate at which
tends to one must satisfy certain weak constraints (requiring that
does not grow “too quickly”), where these constraints are dependent both on the distributions of
and on
. Specifically, we describe a range of possible values for
(in contrast to a single sequence, as in
Glasserman et al. (
2007)), and also provide a uniform estimate for (
16) within this range. We emphasize here that our result is the first to study sharp asymptotics for a general class of distributions and, in particular, in the context of the Gaussian model. In the process, we also introduce a new approach based on a simple conditioning argument combined with Hoeffding’s concentration inequality. We also relate our estimate to Value-at-Risk estimation, and describe an extension to multiple types, where the default level
d and parameters
and
b are allowed to belong to different classes, and hence are allowed to vary amongst the different loans.
The asymptotic regime described in (
16) can be viewed as the
large loss regime, where defaults occur simultaneously because, as
, it becomes increasingly likely that the given loans default, and default occurs under the conditional law of large numbers whenever
exceeds the theshold
. In
Glasserman et al. (
2007), a
small default regime, is also considered, where the default theshold
d is replaced with a sequence
, where
, and default occurs when
, where
is again given as in (
2). Note that as
, we have that
, so as
n increases, the quality of the credit increases. Thus, this regime considers high-quality credits, with small default probabilities, and thus the event
will decay to zero, even when
is fixed. For the small-default regime, we once again adopt a rather general framework, where the common factors and idiosyncratic factors may assume general distributions, as in (
16). Under some natural conditions on the decay of
, we show that if the distribution of
is symmetric, then
where
denotes the distribution function of
. [A corresponding result also holds under general assumptions on
.] Since
x is fixed, we note that the quantity on the right-hand side is determined by the rate of decay of
for some constant
C, i.e., the rate of decay behaves roughly like
; and similarly, the tail behavior of
will also determine how large the sequence
may be chosen. Thus, we see that the decay rate in (
17) and the choice of
are both essentially determined by
and hence the common factors, while the idiosyncratic factors plays no role in determining the rate of decay in this estimate.
We conclude by observing that estimates such as (
16) and (
17) also provide some insight into the role of
dependence amongst the common factors
, which, in the existing literature, are generally assumed to be independent. From a practical perspective, these factors will generally be dependent, with their dependence described through the distribution of the random variable
. For example, in the Normal case, this dependence is characterized through a covariance matrix, while for general elliptical distributions, such as the
t-distribution, this dependence is characterized through the corresponding dispersion matrix. As an example, we calculate the rate function in the Normal case, and illustrate how this dependence influences the rate of decay in our estimates.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows.
Section 2 is concerned with the main results in the large loss and small default regimes, while
Section 3 describes extensions to multiple types, and to a nonstandard formulation of the problem, where the number of factors is allowed to tend to infinity as the number of loans tends to infinity.