Next Article in Journal
Integrating Semilinear Wave Problems with Time-Dependent Boundary Values Using Arbitrarily High-Order Splitting Methods
Previous Article in Journal
New Oscillation Theorems for Second-Order Differential Equations with Canonical and Non-Canonical Operator via Riccati Transformation
Previous Article in Special Issue
Analyzing Medical Data by Using Statistical Learning Models
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Impact of Regulatory Reforms on Demand Weighted Average Prices

by
Sherzod N. Tashpulatov
1,2
1
Department of Economics, Management and Humanities, Faculty of Electrical Engineering, Czech Technical University in Prague, Technická 2, 166 27 Prague 6, Czech Republic
2
School of Business, University of New York in Prague, Londýnská 41, 120 00 Prague 2, Czech Republic
Mathematics 2021, 9(10), 1112; https://doi.org/10.3390/math9101112
Submission received: 7 April 2021 / Revised: 4 May 2021 / Accepted: 6 May 2021 / Published: 14 May 2021

Abstract

:
Average prices are popularly used in the literature on price modeling. Calculating daily or weekly prices as an average over hourly or half-hourly trading periods assumes the same weight ignoring demand or traded volumes during those periods. Analyzing demand weighted average prices is important if producers may affect prices by decreasing them during low-demand periods and increasing them during high-demand periods within a day. The prediction of this price manipulation might have motivated the regulatory authority to introduce price caps not only on annual average prices but also on annual demand weighted average prices in the England and Wales wholesale electricity market. The dynamics of demand weighted average prices of electricity has been analyzed little in the literature. We show that skew generalized error distribution (SGED) is the appropriate assumption for model residuals. The estimated volatility model is used for evaluating the impact of regulatory reforms on demand weighted average prices during the complete history of the England and Wales wholesale electricity market.

1. Introduction

Defining daily or weekly prices as an arithmetic average of hourly or half-hourly prices assumes the same weight for each period. However, demand or traded volume is not the same during all periods. That is why, in this research, we consider demand weighted average electricity prices during the complete history of the England and Wales wholesale market, which have not been analyzed before. This is especially interesting given that the regulatory authority in Great Britain introduced price caps on annual average and annual demand weighted average prices of electricity. The motivation of introducing two different price caps could have been related to the prediction by the regulatory authority that producers may increase prices when demand is high and reduce prices when demand is low. Later after price-cap regulation, in order to improve competition on the market another kind of reform, divestment series, was introduced. The design of the England and Wales electricity market has been adopted in several countries. Market reforms pursued by the regulatory authority in Great Britain present the international gold standard for energy market liberalization [1].
The dynamics of the wholesale price in the England and Wales electricity market has not been extensively analyzed in the literature. We refer to the analyses of volatility of weekly average prices in [2], monthly Lerner indices in [3], volatility of daily average prices in [4] or volatility of prices from the peak demand period over days in [5].
In Figure 1, we present the empirical distribution of demand weighted average prices (for short, we refer to as price). Pearson’s χ 2 goodness of fit test concludes that prices and log prices (for short, we refer to as lprice) are not normally distributed. Indeed, the empirical distributions presented in Figure 1 are skewed to the right and have a peak higher than in the fitted normal distribution. The empirical distribution of lprice has also heavy tails reflecting rare observations scattered farther from the mean.
For these reasons we do not consider normal distribution as done, for example, in [6,7,8,9]. Our decision is consistent with [10], which highlights that there is ample evidence that data do not follow normal distribution. Replacing the assumption of normal distribution by a heavy-tailed distribution might improve forecast results [11].
Heavy tails are usually modeled by Student’s t distribution introduced in [12] or generalized error distribution (GED) introduced in [13]. According to [14], replacing normal or Student’s t distributions by GED is considered as more encouraging. GED is heavy tailed and has a higher peak compared to normal distribution. This distribution includes normal distribution as a special case. Moreover, GED does not have an issue of possible infinite unconditional moments as does Student’s t distribution. Some research (e.g., [15,16,17,18]) though consider normal or Student’s t distribution when applying the volatility model of [14] that was originally based on GED.
In order to model the feature of heavy tails, instead of normal distribution [19] assumes Student’s t distribution for model residuals. This approach however does not take into account asymmetry and the observation that GED may be more heavy tailed than Student’s t distribution.
Normal and Student’s t distributions have been recently used in volatility modeling in, for example, [20,21] even if the analyzed time series data are asymmetric. Earlier, [22] highlighted the importance of correctly modeling volatility of electricity prices in evaluating the deregulation experience, in forecasting, and in pricing electricity futures and other energy derivatives.
Other distributions applied in the literature are skew Student’s t distribution, skew generalized error distribution (SGED), and generalized hyperbolic distribution (GHD). In terms of accurately estimating the value at risk, [23] finds that a volatility model assuming skew Student’s t distribution outperforms volatility models based on normal and Student’s t distributions. In terms of forecast performance, however, [24] finds that skew Student’s t distribution does not outperform normal distribution. Forecasts of returns based on the SGED assumption are found to be more accurate than those when assuming normal and Student’s t distributions [25]. SGED is similarly used for modeling European call option prices in [26], the dynamics of electricity prices of the peak demand period over days in [5], and daily returns of carbon price time series in [27]. GHD and its special cases have been applied in various areas. For example, [28] applies GHD for modeling grain size distributions of wind blown sands, [29] applies for returns of daily prices of shares.
The paper is structured as follows. First we describe the volatility model. Then we verify in detail the two distributional assumptions (an i.i.d. and an assumed theoretical distribution) for model residuals of the estimated volatility model. Next the sign bias test is applied in order to verify the correctness of the estimated volatility model. Based on the correctly estimated volatility model we discuss the impact of reforms on price level and volatility. In the last section we draw our conclusions.

2. Methodology

2.1. Volatility Modeling

For modeling volatility of l p r i c e t , representing the log of demand weighted average price of electricity during day t, we extend the original autoregressive and autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (AR–ARCH) volatility model introduced in [30] in the following way:
Mean equation: l p r i c e t = a 0 + i = 1 P a i l p r i c e t i + w t · b + ε t
Volatility equation: h t = α 0 + i = 1 p α i ε t i 2 + w t · δ
Two distributional assumptions: ν t = ε t h t i . i . d . SGED ( μ = 0 , σ = 1 , β , χ )
The dependent variable l p r i c e t in the mean equation may depend on its past values through the AR process and exogenous variables. The AR process based on statistically significant lags of l p r i c e t allows taking into account partial adjustment effects and seasonality features. Exogenous variables included in vector w t are periodic functions and regime dummy variables corresponding to regulatory reforms. In modeling weekly seasonality, using periodic functions may be preferred to using daily dummy variables for obtaining a parsimonious model and for using dummy variables to denote regulatory regime periods. We do not consider fuel prices because they are available as quarterly average prices. Volatility h t , modeled using the ARCH process in the second equation, can also depend on exogenous variables.
For the mean and volatility equations, we apply the maximum likelihood method, which requires assuming a distribution for model residuals. We assume that standardized residuals ν t defined in the third equation are independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) and follow SGED. The density of SGED is defined based on [31] proposing a general procedure for introducing skewness into a symmetric distribution in order to account for the presence of asymmetry. We also verify two alternative distributional assumptions of skew Student’s t introduced in [32] and GHD introduced in [28]. Details and statistical features of these distributions are described in the next section.

2.2. Statistical Features of SGED, Skew Student’s t Distributions, and GHD

SGED includes many other distributions as its special or limiting cases. These are GED, (skew) Laplace, (skew) normal, and uniform distributions.
SGED ( μ , σ , β , χ ) is characterized by four parameters: mean μ , standard deviation σ , shape parameter β , and skewness parameter χ . The shape parameter β reflects the peak and tails of a distribution. The skewness parameter χ reflects asymmetry of a distribution. For example, when χ = 1 , then the distribution is symmetric and we obtain GED ( μ , σ , β ) as a special case of SGED. Further, when β = 2 , then we obtain N ( μ , σ ) .
Student’s t distribution is another popularly used distribution for volatility modeling. Depending on the variance, there are two kinds of Student’s t distribution: with non-unit variance (described in Figure 2a) and with unit variance (described in Figure 2b).
Only in the non-unit variance case has Student’s t distribution noticeable heavy tails. Even if Student’s t distribution with non-unit variance has the desired feature of heavy tails, we cannot apply it because of two reasons. Firstly, its peak is lower than in normal distribution, which is opposite to what we observed in Figure 1. Secondly, the distributional assumption is needed for standardized residuals where we must have a unit variance as described in Equation (3). As described in Figure 2b, Student’s t distribution with unit variance does not have noticeable heavy tails. Figure 3 presents a comparison of tails of Student’s t distribution of unit variance and GED. We observe that GED (a special case of SGED) can be more heavy tailed.
We consider skew Student’s t with unit variance as a possible alternative distribution to SGED. Skew Student’s t distribution depends on four parameters: mean μ , standard deviation σ , the number of degrees of freedom ν , and skewness parameter χ . The number of degrees of freedom affects the peak and tails of the distribution as illustrated for its symmetric version (i.e., when χ = 1 ) in Figure 2b. Skew Student’s t distribution nests Student’s t, (skew) Cauchy, (skew) Gaussian or normal as its special or limiting cases.
We also consider GHD, which nests the following distributions as its special or limiting cases: hyperbolic, (variance, inverse) Gamma, (inverse, generalized inverse, normal inverse, skew) Gaussian, (skew) Student’s t, (skew) Cauchy, (skew) Laplace, and exponential.

3. Estimation Results

During the liberalization process, the regulatory authority introduced several reforms in the England and Wales electricity market. The regulatory reforms are described, for example, in [33,34]. In Figure 4, we summarize the timeline of those reforms.
Table 1 contains summary statistics of demand weighted average price over days. The summary statistics show that during price-cap regulation, the average price level is lower but variance is higher. However, after the second series of divestments the price level and variance decreased. These findings are new and therefore motivate to analyze in more detail the price dynamics in relation to the regulatory reforms. The concepts of variance and volatility are not the same. The former corresponds to a sample variance and the latter corresponds to the definition of h t provided in the volatility equation.
In volatility modeling, we consider the log of demand weighted average price during day t (denoted as l p r i c e t ) because as presented in Figure 1b its empirical distribution is closer to normal distribution, which is a special case of SGED. A logarithmic transformation may also mitigate the effect of outliers observed in Figure 1a.
Prior to estimating the volatility model, we find that l p r i c e t is stationary, which allows applying the time and frequency domain analyses in order to determine the lag structure and periodic functions with required frequencies. These are needed for modeling the partial adjustment effects and seasonality pattern (i.e., daily, weekly, annual seasonalities) of electricity prices.
Based on the methodology described in the previous section, we present estimation results of the volatility model in Table 2.
In volatility modeling we assumed that standardized residuals ν t = ε t h t are i.i.d. and follow SGED ( μ = 0 , σ = 1 , β , χ ) . Using the Q-test proposed in [39] and BDS-test further developed in [40], we find that the standardized residuals and standardized residuals squared of the estimated volatility model are not serially correlated and are i.i.d. The results are presented in Table A1 and Table A2, respectively.
We estimated the volatility model under three distributional assumptions: SGED ( μ = 0 , σ = 1 , β , χ ) , skew Student’s t ( μ = 0 , σ = 1 , ν , χ ) , and GHD ( μ = 0 , σ = 1 , α ¯ , γ , λ ) . In Figure 5a–c we present the empirical distributions of standardized residuals superimposed by the fitted SGED, skew Student’s t, and GHD, respectively. Visually, all theoretical distributions provide a good match for the empirical distributions. This is also confirmed statistically by the goodness of fit test.
The distributional parameters of SGED estimated through the volatility model presented in Table 2 and estimated through fitting of standardized residuals ν ^ t presented in Figure 5a are about the same. Both approaches are based on the maximum likelihood estimation.
For the first estimated volatility model based on SGED we perform additional tests for the shape parameter β and skewness parameter χ . When β = 2 and χ = 1 , then SGED narrows down to normal distribution. We reject H 0 : β = 2 , which suggests that the empirical distribution of standardized residuals has a higher peak and heavy tails compared to normal distribution (because β ^ 1.28 < 2 ). Further rejecting H 0 : χ = 1 suggests that the empirical distribution is also asymmetric (more precisely skewed to the right because χ ^ 1.05 > 1 ).
Similarly, for the second estimated volatility model based on skew Student’s t distribution we test asymmetry of the empirical distribution of standardized residuals. As presented in Table A4, we obtain χ ^ 1.038 with its standard error of approximately 0.0247 . Using these results we do not reject H 0 : χ = 1 , which implies that the empirical distribution of standardized residuals is symmetric.
The asymmetry of standardized residuals under all distributional assumptions can also be tested based on the skewness coefficient following [41]. The test results of skewness coefficient presented in Table 3 suggest that the empirical distributions of standardized residuals ν ^ t are asymmetric in all volatility models. In the first volatility model we assumed standardized residuals ν t following SGED, in the second—skew Student’s t distribution, and in the third—GHD. The conclusion of asymmetry of the empirical distribution of standardized residuals from the second volatility model is however in contradiction with the earlier test of skewness parameter from skew Student’s t distribution, which suggested that the empirical distribution of standardized residuals is symmetric.
Another contradiction is related to the significance of the ARCH terms. We obtain two statistically insignificant ARCH terms when assuming skew Student’s t distribution and GHD (Table A4 and Table A5). Excluding the statistically insignificant ARCH terms led to violation of the i.i.d. assumption.
The appropriateness of the distributional assumption (SGED, skew Student’s t distribution, or GHD) for standardized residuals can be verified using the Kullback–Leibler distance, which is a general methodology for comparing the distance between the empirical and theoretical distributions [42]. For most values of k presented in Table 4, the Kullback–Leibler distance is smaller when comparing the empirical distribution of standardized residuals from the first volatility model to SGED.
Therefore, taking into account the contradiction of asymmetry test results when assuming skew Student’s t, statistically insignificant ARCH terms and a greater Kullback–Leibler distance when assuming skew Student’s t or GHD, we suggest that in our research SGED provides a better distributional fit for model residuals than do skew Student’s t distribution or GHD.
Even if both distributional assumptions for standardized residuals are satisfied (an i.i.d. and SGED), the estimated volatility model may still be incorrect because of possible remaining asymmetries in the effect of positive and negative shocks on volatility. That is why, in order to evaluate the correctness of the volatility model we perform the sign bias test, where the null hypothesis states that the volatility model is correctly specified. Based on the test results in Table A3, we do not reject the null hypothesis. This suggests that the volatility model is correctly specified.
The estimated volatility model explains about 80% of variation in the price data and partially confirms the preliminary results from Table 1. In the next section, after discussing our methodological contributions, we discuss in detail the impact of regulatory reforms on price level and volatility.

4. Discussion

Among others, there are two distributions popularly applied in modeling the dynamics of energy price data: normal and Student’s t. Sometimes the reason for preferring Student’s t distribution to normal distribution was to model the presence of heavy tails reflecting a higher probability of occurrence of extreme values than under normal distribution [19]. In Figure 3 we showed that under the same peak, GED (a special case of SGED) can be more heavy tailed. Another possible alternative distribution considered in this paper is GHD, which also nests many distributions as its special or limiting cases.
If the distributional assumption is not satisfied, then a quasi maximum likelihood estimation introduced in [43] could be used. This methodology addresses the model misspecification problem related to the wrong theoretical distributional assumption and allows statistical inferences to be drawn robustly. For example, ref. [44] models the dynamics of electricity prices from various countries assuming a normal distribution, even if prices are asymmetric and have platykurtic and leptokurtic distributions. For statistical inference the research applies robust standard errors following [43]. However, due to the wrong assumption of normal distribution, we believe that the results in [44] based on the maximum likelihood estimation may be biased.
Only few papers discuss the empirical distribution of model residuals in order to check if the distributional assumptions (an i.i.d. and an assumed theoretical distribution) were satisfied or not. After verifying the two distributional assumptions, it was necessary to check if the estimated volatility model is correct using the sign bias test. Given that the distributional assumptions and estimated volatility model are correct, it is possible to proceed to the interpretation of our results, that is, the impact of regulatory reforms on price level and volatility.
In Table 5 we provide an excerpt from Table 2, which contains coefficient estimates in front of regime dummy variables. These coefficient estimates from the mean and volatility equations indicate changes in the price level and volatility, respectively, compared to Regime 1, i.e., the reference period during 1 April 1990 to 31 March 1993.
For the qualitative analysis we recalculate intercept terms of the mean and volatility equations in percentages, where the intercept term for the reference period, i.e., Regime 1, is set equal to 100%. The calculations are summarized in Figure 6.
The estimate of coefficient in front of Regime 2 (after coal contracts expired on 31 March 1993 and before price-cap regulation started on 1 April 1994) in the volatility equation is almost zero. This suggests that price volatility was about the same during Regime 1 (i.e., 1 April 1990 to 31 March 1993) and Regime 2 (i.e., 1 April 1993 to 31 March 1994). Our result does not necessarily contradict to the finding in [2], which documents increased price volatility after the expiry of coal contracts because the research considered arithmetic average price over weeks.
We find that compared to the reference period, during price-cap regulation, that is, Regime 3 (i.e., 1 April 1994 to 31 March 1996) the price level is lower (i.e., 0.0566 + ( 0.0166 ) = 0.04 or 71% for Regime 3 is lower than 0.0566 or 100% for Regime 1), which however takes place at the cost of increased price volatility (i.e., 0.0012 + 0.0060 = 0.0072 or 616% for Regime 3 is higher than 0.0012 or 100% for Regime 1). Generally, higher price volatility may be stemming from different bidding strategies discussed in [4,45]. After the first series of divestments (i.e., Regime 4) price level and volatility are higher than during price-cap regulation (i.e., Regime 3).
From the estimated volatility model, it is not possible to state that the second series of divestments (i.e., Regime 5) was more successful than price-cap regulation (i.e., Regime 3). This is because compared to price-cap regulation, after the second series of divestments price level is higher (i.e., 0.0566 + ( 0.0131 ) = 0.0435 or 77% for Regime 5 is greater than 0.0566 + ( 0.0166 ) = 0.04 or 71% for Regime 3) and price volatility is lower ( 0.0012 + 0.0047 = 0.0059 or 502% for Regime 5 is less than 0.0012 + 0.0060 = 0.0072 or 1039% for Regime 3). But had we used only the results of summary statistics of demand weighted average prices of electricity presented in Table 1, we would have stated that the second series of divestments was more successful than price-cap regulation because average level and variance of prices were lower after the second series of divestments was introduced.
We find that the second series of divestments was more successful than the first series at decreasing the price level (i.e., 0.0566 + ( 0.0131 ) = 0.0435 or 77% for Regime 5 is lower than 0.0566 + ( 0.0033 ) = 0.0533 or 94% for Regime 4) and price volatility (i.e., 0.0012 + 0.0047 = 0.0059 or 502% for Regime 5 is lower than 0.0012 + 0.0079 = 0.0091 or 781% for Regime 4). The changes observed after the second series of divestments are statistically significant.

5. Conclusions

Modeling volatility of energy prices is of interest to investors, producers, and market regulators. Various models have been applied in analyzing price volatility, most of which however have assumed normal or Student’s t distributions. The empirical distribution of data or model residuals usually does not follow normal or Student’s t distributions due to asymmetry, excess kurtosis, a higher peak than in normal distribution or heavy tails. That is why we conclude that in such cases, the assumption of normal or Student’s t distributions should be replaced by SGED. Alternatively, in some cases skew Student’s t distribution with unit variance or GHD could be also considered.
Because testing asymmetry under the assumption of skew Student’s t distribution led to contradictory conclusions, some ARCH terms were found statistically insignificant and the value of the Kullback–Leibler distance was mostly greater when assuming skew Student’s t distribution or GHD, we conclude that SGED is more appropriate for modeling the volatility of our price data. According to [46], correct modelling of price volatility is important for building accurate pricing models, for forecasting future price volatility, and for enriching our understanding of the broader financial markets, the energy industry, and the overall economy.
SGED could be used in more complex volatility models, too. In some cases complicating a volatility model may become unnecessary if one assumes a flexible distribution capturing such features as asymmetry, heavy tails, or a higher peak than in normal distribution. Correctly estimated volatility models can reliably be used for policy analysis or forecast.
Our volatility model includes a vector of explanatory variables. This vector can be generalized to include market shares of firms, renewable energy sources, fuel prices, or other variables, when analyzing current energy markets. In most cases, this adaptation however would depend on the availability and completeness of data.
Interestingly, we find that conclusions based on summary statistics and estimated volatility model are not qualitatively the same. Based on summary statistics one would conclude that the second series of divestments was more successful than price-cap regulation because both price level and variance are lower. However, based on the estimated volatility model, we find that compared to price-cap regulation, the price level is higher after the second series of divestments, although the difference between coefficient estimates is not large (0.0435 versus 0.04). We also find that the second series of divestments was more successful than the first series at reducing the price level and volatility. Therefore, we conclude that divestment series might be preferred because they may allow reducing the influence of big companies, improving competition, and avoiding monitoring costs arising under price-cap regulation.
Demand weighted average prices have not been analyzed much in the literature probably due to limitations of data on demand. We believe that distinguishing between arithmetic and weighted averages is important because the former assumes the same weight regardless of demand or traded volumes in various trading periods over days. Our results and conclusions could be of interest to regulators and investors in markets, which were formed based on the original model of the England and Wales electricity market.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Acknowledgments

I am very grateful to the Department for Business, Innovation and Skills (formerly, the Department of Trade and Industry), National Grid plc, and Office of Gas and Electricity Markets for providing access to the data and publication materials.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Abbreviations

ARAutoregressive
ARCHAutoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity
BDS-testBrock–Dechert–Scheinkman test of i.i.d. further developed in [40]
Coef of VarCoefficient of Variation (in %)
GEDGeneralized Error Distribution
GHDGeneralized Hyperbolic Distribution
i.i.d.independent and identically distributed
ObsNumber of Observations
Regime 11 April 1990–31 March 1993 (Coal contracts), Reference period
Regime 21 April 1993–31 March 1994
Regime 31 April 1994–31 March 1996 (Price-cap regulation)
Pre-Regime 41 April 1996–30 June 1996
Regime 41 July 1996–19 July 1999 (Divestment 1 introduced on 1 July 1996)
Regime 520 July 1999–26 March 2001 (Divestment 2 introduced on 20 July 1999)
SGEDSkew Generalized Error Distribution
St DevStandard Deviation
Notation
μ Mean parameter in SGED and (skew) Student’s distribution
σ Standard deviation parameter in SGED and (skew) Student’s distribution
β Shape parameter in SGED
ν The number of degrees of freedom in (skew) Student’s t distribution
χ Skewness parameter in SGED and skew Student’s distribution
l p r i c e t Natural logarithm of the demand weighted average price during day t
ε t Residuals from the mean equation (not standardized)
h t Volatility (based on notation in [30])
ν t Standardized residuals
p-valueProbability value of a test statistic
(if p-value is less than 0.10, then the null hypothesis is rejected)
Q-testTest of serial correlation introduced in [39]
χ 2 -testGoodness of fit test
G 1 Sample skewness coefficient (notation used in [41])

Appendix A. Tables

Table A1. Q-test for standardized residuals when assuming SGED.
Table A1. Q-test for standardized residuals when assuming SGED.
Lag Q-Testp-Value Q-Testp-Value
1 0.050.82 0.220.64
10 11.800.30 7.600.67
20 25.990.17 20.490.43
30 35.360.23 29.610.49
100 97.430.55 94.370.64
200 188.600.71 182.250.81
300 275.470.84 283.210.75
H 0 : ν t has no serial correlation H 0 : ν t 2 has no serial correlation
Note: No serial correlation in ν t is interpreted as νt being homoscedastic.
Table A2. BDS-test for standardized residuals when assuming SGED.
Table A2. BDS-test for standardized residuals when assuming SGED.
DimensionBDS-Testp-Value BDS-Testp-Value
2−0.00040.77 −0.00220.33
30.00240.26 0.00180.61
40.00300.22 0.00320.45
50.00340.19 0.00340.44
60.00340.17 0.00320.46
H 0 : ν t is i.i.d. H 0 : ν t 2 is i.i.d.
Table A3. t-test values of the sign bias test for standardized residuals when assuming SGED.
Table A3. t-test values of the sign bias test for standardized residuals when assuming SGED.
t-Testp-Value
Sign Bias0.320.75
Negative Sign Bias0.390.69
Positive Sign Bias0.880.38
Joint Effect2.440.49
Table A4. Estimation results when assuming skew Student’s t distribution.
Table A4. Estimation results when assuming skew Student’s t distribution.
Mean Equation Volatility Equation
lprice t = a 0 + i = 1 P a i lprice t i + w t · b + ε t h t = α 0 + i = 1 p α i ε t i 2 + w t · δ
VariableCoef Std Err VariableCoef Std Err
a 0 0.0467 0.0329 α 0 0.0012***0.0001
l p r i c e t 1 0.5794***0.0001 ε t 1 2 0.2209***0.0300
l p r i c e t 2 0.0741***0.0059 ε t 3 2 0.0132 0.0118
l p r i c e t 3 0.0596***0.0065 ε t 4 2 0.0474***0.0169
l p r i c e t 4 0.0459***0.0066 ε t 5 2 0.0719***0.0220
l p r i c e t 6 0.0650***0.0061 ε t 6 2 0.0223 0.0164
l p r i c e t 7 0.2380***0.0011 ε t 7 2 0.1769***0.0300
l p r i c e t 8 −0.0829***0.0058 cos ( 6 π t / 7 ) 0.0008***0.0001
l p r i c e t 9 −0.1115***0.0047 sin ( 2 π t / 7 ) 0.0006***0.0001
l p r i c e t 14 0.0695***0.0061 sin ( 6 π t / 7 ) −0.0008***0.0002
l p r i c e t 21 0.1151***0.0045 Regime 20.0000 0.0002
l p r i c e t 22 −0.0872***0.0056 Regime 30.0059***0.0009
l p r i c e t 25 −0.0395***0.0064 Pre-Regime 40.0120***0.0044
l p r i c e t 28 0.0849***0.0056 Regime 40.0081***0.0010
l p r i c e t 29 −0.0619***0.0065 Regime 50.0051***0.0007
l p r i c e t 35 0.0624***0.0067
l p r i c e t 36 −0.0753***0.0059 Skew Student’s t parameters
l p r i c e t 42 0.0385***0.0069 ν ^ 5.2192***0.4413
l p r i c e t 49 0.0590***0.0068 χ ^ 1.0376***0.0247
l p r i c e t 50 −0.0844***0.0055
l p r i c e t 56 0.0528***0.0068
l p r i c e t 61 −0.0431***0.0059
l p r i c e t 63 0.0341***0.0071
l p r i c e t 71 −0.0386***0.0062
l p r i c e t 108 −0.0210***0.0062
l p r i c e t 147 0.0206***0.0061
l p r i c e t 225 −0.0170***0.0057
l p r i c e t 364 0.0500***0.0055
cos ( 2 π t / 7 ) −0.0039**0.0018
sin ( 6 π t / 7 ) −0.0065***0.0014
Regime 20.0006 0.0030
Regime 3−0.0141***0.0043
Pre-Regime 4−0.0087 0.0149
Regime 4−0.0021 0.0037
Regime 5−0.0127***0.0041
Notes: The p-values of ε t 3 2 and ε t 6 2 are approximately 0.26 and 0.18, respectively. We keep these terms in order to satisfy the i.i.d. assumption. ** and *** stand for the 5% and 1% significance levels, respectively.
Table A5. Estimation results when assuming GHD.
Table A5. Estimation results when assuming GHD.
Mean Equation Volatility Equation
lprice t = a 0 + i = 1 P a i lprice t i + w t · b + ε t h t = α 0 + i = 1 p α i ε t i 2 + w t · δ
VariableCoef Std Err VariableCoef Std Err
a 0 0.0452 0.0381 α 0 0.0012***0.0001
l p r i c e t 1 0.5798***0.0004 ε t 1 2 0.2200***0.0302
l p r i c e t 2 0.0741***0.0106 ε t 3 2 0.0134 0.0119
l p r i c e t 3 0.0598***0.0123 ε t 4 2 0.0476***0.0169
l p r i c e t 4 0.0457***0.0116 ε t 5 2 0.0718***0.0221
l p r i c e t 6 0.0648***0.0101 ε t 6 2 0.0223 0.0164
l p r i c e t 7 0.2389***0.0016 ε t 7 2 0.1779***0.0304
l p r i c e t 8 −0.0838***0.0096 cos ( 6 π t / 7 ) 0.0008***0.0001
l p r i c e t 9 −0.1119***0.0060 sin ( 2 π t / 7 ) 0.0007***0.0001
l p r i c e t 14 0.0702***0.0102 sin ( 6 π t / 7 ) −0.0008***0.0002
l p r i c e t 21 0.1138***0.0058 Regime 2 0.00000.0002
l p r i c e t 22 −0.0864***0.0089 Regime 30.0059***0.0009
l p r i c e t 25 −0.0393***0.0098 Pre-Regime 40.0120***0.0044
l p r i c e t 28 0.0847***0.0094 Regime 40.0081***0.0010
l p r i c e t 29 −0.0616***0.0111 Regime 50.0051***0.0007
l p r i c e t 35 0.0625***0.0125
l p r i c e t 36 −0.0757***0.0103 GHD parameters
l p r i c e t 42 0.0390***0.0106 shape0.0252 0.0231
l p r i c e t 49 0.0591***0.0124 skewness0.9527***0.0151
l p r i c e t 50 −0.0847***0.0090 λ ^ −2.6159***0.2224
l p r i c e t 56 0.0530***0.0112
l p r i c e t 61 −0.0427***0.0081
l p r i c e t 63 0.0337***0.0108
l p r i c e t 71 −0.0389***0.0087
l p r i c e t 108 −0.0206***0.0068
l p r i c e t 147 0.0207***0.0065
l p r i c e t 225 −0.0171***0.0059
l p r i c e t 364 0.0498***0.0069
cos ( 2 π t / 7 ) −0.0040**0.0020
sin ( 6 π t / 7 ) −0.0065***0.0015
Regime 20.0004 0.0033
Regime 3−0.0143***0.0044
Pre-Regime 4−0.0083 0.0149
Regime 4−0.0023 0.0038
Regime 5−0.0128***0.0042
Notes: The p-values of ε t 3 2 and ε t 6 2 are approximately 0.26 and 0.18, respectively. We keep these terms in order to satisfy the i.i.d. assumption. ** and *** stand for the 5% and 1% significance levels, respectively.

References

  1. Joskow, P.L. Foreword: US vs. EU Electricity Reforms Achievement. In Electricity Reform in Europe; Glachant, J.M., Lévêque, F., Eds.; Edward Elgar Publishing Limited: Cheltenham, UK, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  2. Robinson, T.; Baniak, A. The volatility of prices in the English and Welsh electricity pool. Appl. Econ. 2002, 34, 1487–1495. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Evans, J.E.; Green, R.J. Why Did British Electricity Prices Fall After 1998? MIT Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2003; Volume 03-007 WP, pp. 1–14. [Google Scholar]
  4. Tashpulatov, S.N. Estimating the volatility of electricity prices: The case of the England and Wales wholesale electricity market. Energy Policy 2013, 60, 81–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Tashpulatov, S.N. The impact of behavioral and structural remedies on electricity prices: The case of the England and Wales electricity market. Energies 2018, 11, 3420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Ji, Q.; Guo, J.F. Oil price volatility and oil-related events: An Internet concern study perspective. Appl. Energy 2015, 137, 256–264. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Ergen, I.; Rizvanoghlu, I. Asymmetric impacts of fundamentals on the natural gas futures volatility: An augmented GARCH approach. Energy Econ. 2016, 56, 64–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Klein, T.; Walther, T. Oil price volatility forecast with mixture memory GARCH. Energy Econ. 2016, 58, 46–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Nonejad, N. Crude oil price volatility and equity return predictability: A comparative out-of-sample study. Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 2020, 71, 1–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Shalini, V.; Prasanna, K. Impact of the financial crisis on Indian commodity markets: Structural breaks and volatility dynamics. Energy Econ. 2016, 53, 40–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Shen, Z.; Ritte, M. Forecasting volatility of wind power production. Appl. Energy 2016, 176, 295–308. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. “Student”; Gosset, W.S. The probable error of a mean. Biometrika 1908, 6, 1–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Subbotin, M.T.H. On the law of frequency of error. Mat. Sb. 1923, 31, 296–301. [Google Scholar]
  14. Nelson, D.B. Conditional heteroskedasticity in asset returns: A new approach. Econometrica 1991, 59, 347–370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Charles, A.; Darné, O. Forecasting crude-oil market volatility: Further evidence with jumps. Energy Econ. 2017, 67, 508–519. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Ciarreta, A.; Zarraga, A. Modeling realized volatility on the Spanish intra-day electricity market. Energy Econ. 2016, 58, 152–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Zhang, Y.J.; Yao, T.; Ripple, R. Volatility forecasting of crude oil market: Can the regime switching GARCH model beat the single-regime GARCH models? Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2019, 59, 302–317. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Lin, Y.; Xiao, Y.; Li, F. Forecasting crude oil price volatility via a HM-EGARCH model. Energy Econ. 2020, 87, 1–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Koopman, S.J.; Ooms, M.; Carnero, M.A. Periodic seasonal Reg-ARFIMA-GARCH models for daily electricity spot prices. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 2007, 102, 16–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Ziel, F.; Weron, R. Day-ahead electricity price forecasting with high-dimensional structures: Univariate vs. multivariate modeling frameworks. Energy Econ. 2018, 70, 396–420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Herrera, A.M.; Hu, L.; Pastor, D. Food price volatility and macroeconomic factors: Evidence from GARCH and GARCH-X estimates. Int. J. Forecast. 2018, 34, 622–635. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Hadsell, L.; Marathe, A.; Shawky, H.A. Estimating the volatility of wholesale electricity spot prices in the US. Energy J. 2004, 25, 23–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Mabrouk, S.; Saadi, S. Parametric value-at-risk analysis: Evidence from stock indices. Q. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2012, 52, 305–321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Frömmel, M.; Han, X.; Kratochvil, S. Modeling the daily electricity price volatility with realized measures. Energy Econ. 2014, 44, 492–502. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Lee, Y.H.; Pai, T.Y. REIT volatility prediction for skew-GED distribution of the GARCH model. Expert Syst. Appl. 2010, 37, 4737–4741. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Theodossiou, P. Skewed generalized error distribution of financial assets and option pricing. Multinatl. Financ. J. 2015, 19, 223–266. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Fu, Y.; Zheng, Z. Volatility modeling and the asymmetric effect for China’s carbon trading pilot market. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Its Appl. 2020, 542, 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Barndorff-Nielsen, O.E. Exponentially decreasing distributions for the logarithm of particle size. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. A Math. Phys. Eng. Sci. 1977, 353, 401–419. [Google Scholar]
  29. Eberlein, E.; Keller, U. Hyperbolic distributions in finance. Bernoulli 1995, 1, 281–299. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Engle, R.F. Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of the variance of United Kingdom inflation. Econometrica 1982, 50, 987–1007. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Fernández, C.; Steel, M. On Bayesian modeling of fat tails and skewness. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 1998, 93, 359–371. [Google Scholar]
  32. Hansen, B.E. Autoregressive conditional density estimation. Int. Econ. Rev. 1994, 35, 705–730. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Lízal, L.M.; Tashpulatov, S.N. Do producers apply a capacity cutting strategy to increase prices? The case of the England and Wales electricity market. Energy Econ. 2014, 43, 114–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Tashpulatov, S.N. Analysis of electricity industry liberalization in Great Britain: How did the bidding behavior of electricity producers change? Util. Policy 2015, 36, 24–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Department of Trade and Industry. Digest of United Kingdom Energy Statistics; Department of Trade and Industry: London, UK, 1997–2002.
  36. National Grid Company. Seven Year Statement; National Grid Company: Coventry, UK, 1994–2001. [Google Scholar]
  37. Newbery, D.M. The UK experience: Privatization with market power. In A European Market for Electricity? Bergman, L., Brunekreeft, G., Doyle, C., von der Fehr, N.H.M., Newbery, D.M., Pollitt, M., Régibeau, P., Eds.; Monitoring European Deregulation; Center for Economic Policy Research: London, UK, 1999; Volume 2. [Google Scholar]
  38. Wolfram, C.D. Measuring duopoly power in the British electricity spot market. Am. Econ. Rev. 1999, 89, 805–826. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Ljung, G.M.; Box, G.E.P. On a measure of lack of fit in time series models. Biometrika 1978, 65, 297–303. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Brock, W.A.; Dechert, W.D.; Scheinkman, J.A.; LeBaron, B. A test for independence based on the correlation dimension. Econom. Rev. 1996, 15, 197–235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Joanes, D.N.; Gill, C.A. Comparing measures of sample skewness and kurtosis. J. R. Stat. Soc. Ser. D 1998, 47, 183–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Kullback, S.; Leibler, R.A. On information and sufficiency. Ann. Math. Stat. 1951, 22, 79–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. White, H. Maximum likelihood estimation of misspecified models. Econometrica 1982, 50, 1–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Erdogdu, E. Asymmetric volatility in European day-ahead power markets: A comparative microeconomic analysis. Energy Econ. 2016, 56, 398–409. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  45. Wolfram, C.D. Strategic bidding in a multiunit auction: An empirical analysis of bids to supply electricity in England and Wales. RAND J. Econ. 1998, 29, 703–725. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Ewing, B.; Malik, F. Modelling asymmetric volatility in oil prices under structural breaks. Energy Econ. 2017, 63, 227–233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Distribution of demand weighted average price and log of demand weighted average price over trading days (1 April 1990–26 March 2001). Author’s calculations.
Figure 1. Distribution of demand weighted average price and log of demand weighted average price over trading days (1 April 1990–26 March 2001). Author’s calculations.
Mathematics 09 01112 g001
Figure 2. Student’s t distribution with non-unit variances (a) and unit variances (b). Author’s illustration. Notes: As the number of degrees of freedom ν increases, both kinds of Student’s t distribution approach normal distribution. This holds true for the case of their skewed distributions, too.
Figure 2. Student’s t distribution with non-unit variances (a) and unit variances (b). Author’s illustration. Notes: As the number of degrees of freedom ν increases, both kinds of Student’s t distribution approach normal distribution. This holds true for the case of their skewed distributions, too.
Mathematics 09 01112 g002
Figure 3. Student’s t distribution with σ = 1 and generalized error distribution (GED) with β < 2 . Author’s illustration. Notes: Heavy tails and a peak higher than in normal distribution can be described by Student’s t distribution with σ = 1 and by generalized error distribution (GED) when the shape parameter β is less than 2. However, for the same peak, we observe that GED can be more heavy tailed than Student’s t distribution.
Figure 3. Student’s t distribution with σ = 1 and generalized error distribution (GED) with β < 2 . Author’s illustration. Notes: Heavy tails and a peak higher than in normal distribution can be described by Student’s t distribution with σ = 1 and by generalized error distribution (GED) when the shape parameter β is less than 2. However, for the same peak, we observe that GED can be more heavy tailed than Student’s t distribution.
Mathematics 09 01112 g003
Figure 4. Regulatory reforms in the electricity supply industry in Great Britain during 1990–2001. Author’s illustration. Sources: [2,35,36,37,38].
Figure 4. Regulatory reforms in the electricity supply industry in Great Britain during 1990–2001. Author’s illustration. Sources: [2,35,36,37,38].
Mathematics 09 01112 g004
Figure 5. Empirical and fitted theoretical distributions of standardized residuals ν ^ t . Note: We apply the maximum likelihood method for standardized residuals ν ^ t from volatility models assuming SGED, skew Student’s t, and GHD in order to obtain parameter estimates of theoretical distributions.
Figure 5. Empirical and fitted theoretical distributions of standardized residuals ν ^ t . Note: We apply the maximum likelihood method for standardized residuals ν ^ t from volatility models assuming SGED, skew Student’s t, and GHD in order to obtain parameter estimates of theoretical distributions.
Mathematics 09 01112 g005
Figure 6. Price level and volatility during regulatory regime periods. Notes: Regime 1 is the reference period, 100%. Blue and red columns represent percent values of the intercept from the mean and volatility equations, respectively (based on Table 5).
Figure 6. Price level and volatility during regulatory regime periods. Notes: Regime 1 is the reference period, 100%. Blue and red columns represent percent values of the intercept from the mean and volatility equations, respectively (based on Table 5).
Mathematics 09 01112 g006
Table 1. Summary statistics of demand weighted average electricity price over days during 1 April 1990–26 March 2001.
Table 1. Summary statistics of demand weighted average electricity price over days during 1 April 1990–26 March 2001.
PriceRegime 1Regime 2Regime 3Pre-Regime 4Regime 4Regime 5
Apr. 90–Mar. 93Apr. 93–Mar. 94Apr. 94–Mar. 96Apr. 96–Jul. 96Jul. 96–Jul. 99Jul. 99–Mar. 01
Price-Cap Reg Divestment 1Divestment 2
Mean20.2124.5920.8920.6423.4219.97
Min11.8011.027.2012.6510.8711.72
Max32.2131.1268.6934.9450.4534.26
St Dev2.913.677.364.727.943.80
Coef of Var14.4214.9435.2122.8633.9219.04
Obs1096365731911114616
Table 2. Estimation results when assuming SGED.
Table 2. Estimation results when assuming SGED.
Mean Equation Volatility Equation
lprice t = a 0 + i = 1 P a i lprice t i + w t · b + ε t h t = α 0 + i = 1 p α i ε t i 2 + w t · δ
VariableCoef Std ErrVariableCoef Std Err
a 0 0.0566***0.0037 α 0 0.0012***0.0001
l p r i c e t 1 0.5763***0.0006 ε t 1 2 0.2041***0.0286
l p r i c e t 2 0.0799***0.0020 ε t 3 2 0.0176 0.0114
l p r i c e t 3 0.0579***0.0013 ε t 4 2 0.0402**0.0158
l p r i c e t 4 0.0448***0.0014 ε t 5 2 0.0814***0.0217
l p r i c e t 6 0.0658***0.0015 ε t 6 2 0.0284*0.0157
l p r i c e t 7 0.2302***0.0011 ε t 7 2 0.1670***0.0284
l p r i c e t 8 −0.0735***0.0019 cos ( 6 π t / 7 ) 0.0006***0.0001
l p r i c e t 9 −0.1125***0.0017 sin ( 2 π t / 7 ) 0.0006***0.0001
l p r i c e t 14 0.0617***0.0015 sin ( 6 π t / 7 ) −0.0008***0.0001
l p r i c e t 21 0.1213***0.0016 Regime 20.0001 0.0002
l p r i c e t 22 −0.0930***0.0026 Regime 30.0060***0.0009
l p r i c e t 25 −0.0415***0.0018 Pre-Regime 40.0109***0.0042
l p r i c e t 28 0.0861***0.0024 Regime 40.0079***0.0009
l p r i c e t 29 −0.0602***0.0014 Regime 50.0047***0.0007
l p r i c e t 35 0.0667***0.0017
l p r i c e t 36 −0.0750***0.0019 SGED parameters
l p r i c e t 42 0.0335***0.0041 β ^ 1.2802***0.0384
l p r i c e t 49 0.0574***0.0012 χ ^ 1.0458***0.0179
l p r i c e t 50 −0.0812***0.0020
l p r i c e t 56 0.0560***0.0012
l p r i c e t 61 −0.0444***0.0014
l p r i c e t 63 0.0365***0.0032
l p r i c e t 71 −0.0433***0.0015
l p r i c e t 108 −0.0209***0.0014
l p r i c e t 147 0.0228***0.0014
l p r i c e t 225 −0.0167***0.0013
l p r i c e t 364 0.0489***0.0013
cos ( 2 π t / 7 ) −0.0041***0.0015
sin ( 6 π t / 7 ) −0.0060***0.0004
Regime 20.0010 0.0018
Regime 3−0.0166***0.0042
Pre-Regime 4−0.0038 0.0165
Regime 4−0.0033 0.0032
Regime 5−0.0131***0.0041
Notes: Even if the p-value ≈ 0.12 of ε t 3 2 is slightly above 10% in the estimated model, we keep this term in order to satisfy the i.i.d. assumption. *, **, and *** stand for the 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels, respectively.
Table 3. Testing symmetry of empirical distribution of standardized residuals ν ^ t using the skewness coefficient.
Table 3. Testing symmetry of empirical distribution of standardized residuals ν ^ t using the skewness coefficient.
Sample Skewness ( G 1 )Std Err of G 1 Test ValueDecision for H 0 : Skewness = 0
ν ^ t based on SGED0.16820.04054.15Reject
ν ^ t based on Skew t0.20410.04055.03Reject
ν ^ t based on GHD0.20590.04055.08Reject
Table 4. Kullback–Leibler distance for the empirical distributions of standardized residuals when comparing to SGED, skew Student’s t distribution, and GHD.
Table 4. Kullback–Leibler distance for the empirical distributions of standardized residuals when comparing to SGED, skew Student’s t distribution, and GHD.
Assumed Distributions
kSGEDSkew Student’s tGHD
10.02440.04380.0293
20.03590.02420.0365
30.00900.01730.0542
40.00600.01820.0367
50.00980.04210.0164
60.00120.03690.0182
70.00010.03080.0196
80.00350.02550.0114
90.00130.01380.0158
100.00540.01860.0153
110.01140.01950.0167
120.00680.02770.0147
130.00240.02180.0113
140.00060.01580.0099
150.00500.01850.0046
160.00840.01370.0044
170.00770.01350.0001
180.00550.00920.0007
190.00310.01180.0028
200.00130.00870.0036
Notes: The Kullback–Leibler distance allows to determine how close an empirical distribution is to a theoretical probability distribution [42]. k is the number of values in the nearest neighbor search algorithm. The default number of values is usually set to 10.
Table 5. Analysis of the impact of regulatory reforms.
Table 5. Analysis of the impact of regulatory reforms.
Price Level Price Volatility
VariableCoef Std Err VariableCoef Std Err
a 0 0.0566***0.0037 α 0 0.0012***0.0001
Regime 20.0010 0.0018 Regime 20.0001 0.0002
Regime 3−0.0166***0.0042 Regime 30.0060***0.0009
Pre-Regime 4−0.0038 0.0165 Pre-Regime 40.0109***0.0042
Regime 4−0.0033 0.0032 Regime 40.0079***0.0009
Regime 5−0.0131***0.0041 Regime 50.0047***0.0007
Note: *** stand for the 1% significance level.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Tashpulatov, S.N. The Impact of Regulatory Reforms on Demand Weighted Average Prices. Mathematics 2021, 9, 1112. https://doi.org/10.3390/math9101112

AMA Style

Tashpulatov SN. The Impact of Regulatory Reforms on Demand Weighted Average Prices. Mathematics. 2021; 9(10):1112. https://doi.org/10.3390/math9101112

Chicago/Turabian Style

Tashpulatov, Sherzod N. 2021. "The Impact of Regulatory Reforms on Demand Weighted Average Prices" Mathematics 9, no. 10: 1112. https://doi.org/10.3390/math9101112

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop