Next Article in Journal
(2, 4)-Colorability of Planar Graphs Excluding Cycles with 3, 4, and 6 Vertices
Previous Article in Journal
ReceiptQA: A Question-Answering Dataset for Receipt Understanding
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Optimizing Sustainable Supply Chains: An Analysis of Quantity-Discount Pricing Strategies Under Carbon Cap-and-Trade Regulations

1
Department of Distribution Management, Takming University of Science and Technology, Taipei 114, Taiwan
2
Department of Marketing and Logistics Management, Chihlee University of Technology, Banqiao 220305, Taiwan
3
Department of Industrial Management, National Taiwan University of Science and Technology, Taipei 106, Taiwan
4
Artificial Intelligence for Operations Management Research Center, National Taiwan University of Science and Technology, Taipei 108, Taiwan
5
Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Chung Yuan Christian University, Zhongli District, Taoyuan City 32022, Taiwan
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Mathematics 2025, 13(11), 1761; https://doi.org/10.3390/math13111761
Submission received: 12 April 2025 / Revised: 16 May 2025 / Accepted: 16 May 2025 / Published: 26 May 2025
(This article belongs to the Section D2: Operations Research and Fuzzy Decision Making)

Abstract

:
This study investigates two pricing strategies within a vendor-buyer supply chain system under cap-and-trade regulation, emphasizing demand sensitivity to market price and green technology investment. The findings reveal that quantity discounts significantly enhance profitability across the supply chain by encouraging buyers to place larger orders, thereby benefiting vendors, buyers, and end consumers. A novel profit-sharing parameter is introduced to foster sustainable and mutually beneficial relationships between supply chain participants. A search algorithm is developed to determine the optimal solutions by using the profit-sharing mechanisms. The analysis yields three key insights: first, a critical cap threshold is identified, enabling supply chain participants to make informed strategic decisions based on the value of the cap; second, another critical cap threshold is derived to assist governments in setting feasible emission limits that incentivize vendors to invest in green technology—caps below this threshold may discourage such investments; third, a reasonable return on investment (ROI) benchmark is established to guide vendors in adopting effective green technology strategies. Numerical examples and sensitivity analyses are conducted to illustrate the theoretical framework and validate the findings.

1. Introduction

The rising importance of environmental issues, governmental regulations through imposing tariffs, and social responsibility has led to increased research attention on sustainable supply chain management. Sustainability in supply chain management has emerged as a critical focus for businesses worldwide, driven by increasing environmental concerns and societal expectations. A sustainable supply chain integrates environmental, social, and governance (ESG) principles into operational practices to minimize ecological harm while promoting social equity and economic viability. Its overarching goal is to reduce the negative environmental impact of supply chains while enhancing social welfare and maintaining profitability.
The importance of this study lies in addressing one of the most pressing global challenges: carbon emissions. Carbon emissions are nearly irreversible and have far-reaching consequences for climate change, biodiversity loss, and public health. Governments worldwide are implementing policies such as subsidies, penalties, and cap-and-trade regulations to curb emissions. However, achieving meaningful reductions requires coordinated efforts across supply chains involving vendors, buyers, and consumers. This study contributes to this effort by exploring how pricing strategies can align economic incentives with environmental goals through green technology investments and carbon emission reductions.
The complexity of carbon reduction initiatives stems from several factors: government intervention through carbon pricing mechanisms; coordination among supply chain participants; investments in green technologies; consumer awareness of ESG concerns; and willingness to pay higher prices for environmentally sustainable products. These challenges necessitate innovative approaches that balance profitability with sustainability.
The high-tech industry serves as a compelling example of these dynamics. For instance, producing an iPhone X generates approximately 80 kg of carbon emissions. In Sweden, where carbon taxes are among the highest globally, Apple could face taxation exceeding USD 10 per unit—a cost that could amount to approximately USD 2 billion annually if applied globally. To address these challenges, Apple has implemented significant sustainability measures. As outlined in its 2020 Environmental Progress Report, Apple achieved 100% carbon neutrality across its operations by 2019 through initiatives such as renewable energy adoption and collaboration with over 100 supply chain partners to transition to sustainable practices. Furthermore, Apple has committed to ensuring that every device sold will have a net-zero climate impact by 2030. This case study highlights the broader implications for global industries: prioritizing environmental sustainability can yield substantial benefits for companies while addressing critical societal concerns.

Literature Review

In the era of environmental concerns and trade protection through imposing tariffs, Daryanto et al. [1] explored low carbon supply chain coordination for imperfect quality deteriorating items. Hua et al. [2] focused on deriving an economic lot size by incorporating carbon footprints into inventory management, aiming to minimize total costs under constant demand conditions. Dwicahyani et al. [3] introduced a supply chain inventory system that includes a warehouse and a distributor, addressing environmental and remanufacturing capacity constraints. Their analysis indicated that while the system may increase waste and carbon emissions, it can reduce energy consumption. They also noted that increasing the collection of returned products could lower the total joint cost. Ghosh et al. [4] examined the optimization of production batch sizes under conditions of stochastic market demand, carbon emission caps, and partial stock outs, taking into account significant emission sources like production, storage, and transportation. Tiwari et al. [5] developed a pricing and inventory model that accounts for housing, transportation, imperfect quality, and related carbon emission costs. Yang and Chen [6] explored the use of green quality costs and sales revenue sharing as mechanisms to achieve Pareto optimality in supply chain operations. Bai et al. [7] suggested that governmental subsidies for carbon emission reduction could incentivize manufacturers to invest in green technology facilities.
Turki et al. [8] investigated the differences between new and remanufactured products, considering factors such as random machine failures, carbon constraints, and random demand. Their study analyzed the effects of carbon emission caps, carbon trading prices, and the proportion of recycled materials on carbon emissions. Chelly et al. [9] contributed to the field of operations management (OM) by focusing on low-carbon supply chain management (LCSCM) within the broader context of green supply chain management (GSCM). Their review highlighted supply chain management research specifically aimed at reducing carbon emissions and managing associated constraints. Yu et al. [10] established a closed-loop inventory model involving a manufacturer and a retailer, with both return and demand rates being sensitive to price. Their study aimed to optimize sales prices, return prices, batch sizes for new and returned components, and production quantities delivered to retailers. Taleizadeh et al. [11] considered carbon reduction, return policies, and quality improvement as key factors, examining technology investment, trading, and capping strategies to reduce carbon emissions in forward logistics. They also studied hybrid remanufacturing of imperfect quality products under technology licensing in reverse logistics, assessing the impact of remanufacturing on carbon emission reduction, quality enhancement, and overall supply chain efficiency.
Integrating environmental protection into traditional supply chain design through the collection and reuse of used products is a primary goal of closed-loop systems, which encompass both forward and reverse supply chains. A study by Nahr et al. [12] developed a bi-objective, multi-period, multi-product closed supply chain network, incorporating environmental considerations, discount strategies, and system uncertainties. Entezaminia et al. [13] focused on developing cost-effective and environmentally friendly control policies for companies implementing green investments, analyzing the impact of cost and system parameters on these strategies. Taleizadeh et al. [14] also explored a vendor-managed inventory system, where suppliers make replenishment decisions at the buyer’s location to enhance supply chain coordination, considering partial stock outs and limited storage capacity. Ramandi and Bafruei [15] examined the reduction of greenhouse gas emissions in a two-tier supply chain with one supplier and one retailer under government policies, focusing on emissions from transportation. Roy and Sana [16] investigated strategies for simultaneously reducing lead time and setup costs in a two-stage supply chain model under trade credit financing, considering the impact of variable production rates and batch sizes on delivery times. Rout et al. [17] developed a sustainable supply chain inventory management (SSCIM) model using an integrated approach with a single supplier and multiple buyers, addressing item spoilage and imperfect production. Jiang and Jiang [18] analyzed cooperative and competitive dynamics between original equipment manufacturers (OEMs) and contract manufacturers (CMs) concerning green investments. Hoque [19] proposed a single-manufacturer multi-retailer integration model, incorporating carbon neutrality mechanisms and imperfect remanufacturing processes. Heydari et al. [20] analyzed supply chain coordination between a manufacturer and a buyer under demand conditions sensitive to price and green quality, applying a hybrid strategy combining green cost and revenue sharing to achieve channel coordination. Recently, Sarkar and Bhuniya [21] developed a model focusing on flexible manufacturing–remanufacturing with green investments under variable demand. Their work emphasizes the integration of service facilities to enhance customer satisfaction and sustainability. Sarkar and Guchhait [22] examined the impact of information asymmetry on green supply chains, incorporating cap-and-trade policies, service levels, and vendor-managed inventory strategies. They utilized RFID technology to mitigate asymmetry and improve coordination. Guchhait et al. [23] proposed an extended MRP framework within hybrid energy-enabled smart production systems. Their model integrates renewable energy sources and reverse logistics, demonstrating cost savings and enhanced sustainability. Guchhait and Sarkar [24] analyzed the economic implications of outsourcing logistics to 4PL providers in flexible production systems, particularly for deteriorating products. Their findings suggest significant cost reductions and improved efficiency. Table 1 shows the differences between this study and existing studies. Our study can fill the research gap for sustainable supply chains inside thoroughly regarding negotiation mechanism.
Environmental issues must be addressed and implemented over the long term because the implementation of environmental protection is crucial to whether a company can operate sustainably and whether society can survive healthily forever. Pricing strategy is related to the competitiveness of enterprises in the market. The above two problem characteristics are very important for today’s business operations.
This study considered the setup, holding, green facility cost, and penalty cost when the demand is sensitive to price and green technology level. The goals are the improvements in manufacturing processes, energy efficiency, product design optimization, recycling initiatives, and pollution reduction. By examining pricing strategies within a sustainable supply chain framework under cap-and-trade regulation, this study provides valuable insights into how businesses can align their operations with environmental objectives while maintaining economic competitiveness.

2. Modelling

This study developed a quantity-discount pricing strategy model with a market price and technology level of carbon emission reduction sensitive demand. Take the famous retailer, Walmart, as an example. We compared the effects of the three cases when facing a leader of the supply chain. Figure 1 shows how the two parties behave in a two-echelon supply chain in our study.
The scenario matrix of our study is shown in Figure 2. Case 1 is an equal strength case in point when the supplier is also very powerful, and they will make their own buying and selling decisions. Case 2 is an example of an unequal relationship between vendor and buyer, when Walmart’s suppliers have a high dependence on Walmart. Suppliers will choose to integrate into Walmart’s system to seek opportunities for stable development of their own businesses. So, the vendor will cooperate with the buyer to make decisions. In the example of Case 3, in addition to being highly dependent on Walmart, the supplier may have competitors in the Walmart system. Therefore, in addition to complying with the integration, the supplier also provides discounts, combined with Walmart’s profit-sharing mechanism, to create a win-win opportunity for both buyers and sellers. To ensure mutually beneficial strategy, in Case 3, a negotiation factor is incorporated to enable profit sharing between both parties.
The mathematical model developed in this paper is based on the following assumptions:
(a)
There is one vendor and one buyer.
(b)
The vendor’s (or manufacturer’s) replenishment rate is finite.
(c)
The demand rate is sensitive to market price and technology level of carbon emission reduction.
(d)
All unit quantity discounts are considered.
(e)
The vendor is fully responsible for carbon emission reduction.
(f)
The players have complete knowledge of each other’s information.
Three cases are discussed: the first case considers a buyer’s market, where the buyer prioritizes maximizing their profit. The second case considers the integration to maximize vendor-buyer profit. The third case considers integration and quantity discount.
The decision variables are as follows:
S: The technology level of carbon emission reduction
Pm: Market price
Tb: The replenishment period for the buyer
N: Number of replenishments per cycle for the retailer
Pb: Buyer’s unit purchase cost from the vendor in Case 3 (constant in Cases 1 and 2)
The buyer’s other related parameters are:
d: Market demand rate
d0: Potential market demand rate
d1: Technology level sensitive coefficient of carbon emission reduction on market demand
d2: Price-sensitive coefficient on market demand
Cb: Setup cost per replenishment
Fb: Holding cost per dollar per unit time
The vendor’s related parameters are:
Cv: Setup cost per production cycle
Cvb: Fixed cost to process each replenishment to the buyer
Fv: Holding cost per dollar per unit time
Pv: Unit purchase cost
g : Production rate
C: Cap (or called quota) of carbon emission regulated by the government
Cp: Unit price per carbon emission that can be bought (or sold) from an organization when the manufacturer’s carbon emission exceeds (or is less than) the cap C
1 2 η S 2 : Facility cost of green technology, where η is the influence coefficient
a b S : Carbon emission for each one produced product, where a > b S . a: base carbon emission per unit product when the carbon emission reduction technology level is zero, a > 0; and b: influence coefficient of emission reduction technology on reducing emissions, b > 0.
Other related parameters:
Φ : Negotiation factor between vendor and buyer for sharing extra profit
TPb: Buyer’s total profit, considering net sales revenue, setup cost, and holding cost
TPv: Vendor’s total profit, considering net sales revenue, setup cost, and holding cost
TP: Total profit, considering net sales revenue, setup cost, and holding cost, where T P = T P b + T P v
T C v g : Green cost, including facility cost and the penalty cost (or subsidy) with government cap-and-trade regulation, T C v g 0   o r   T C v g 0
T P v # : T P v # = T P v T C v g
TP#: Total profit considering net sales revenue, setup cost, holding cost, and green cost, where T P # = T P v # + T P b .
When the demand is sensitive to market price and technology level of carbon emission reduction, it is assumed as follows:
d = d 0 + d 1 S d 2 P m
The buyer’s total profit is expressed as:
T P b ( P m , S , T b ) = P m P b d C b T b 1 2 P b d T b F b
On the right side of Equation (2), the first item represents net sales revenue, the second item represents setup cost, and the last item represents holding cost. The vendor’s (or manufacturer’s) total profit can be expressed as:
  T P v P m , S , T b , N = P b P v d C v + N C v b N T b 1 2 d T b N 1 1 d g + d g P v F v
On the right side of Equation (3), the first item represents net sales revenue, the second item represents the setup cost, and the third item represents the holding cost. The expression 1 2 d T b [ N 1 1 d g + d g ] represents the average inventory level for the vendor when the replenishment rate is constant. The sum of Equations (2) and (3) can be expressed as:
T P P m , S , T b , N = T P b P m , S , T b + T P v P m , S , T b , N
Generally, the pressure of carbon emission reduction is placed on the manufacturer (or vendor) instead of the retailer (or buyer). The vendor’s green cost and total profit are expressed as:
T C v g ( S , P m ) = 1 2 η S 2 + C p [ a b S d C ]
where a > 0 , b > 0 , a > b S
T P v # P m , S , T b , N = T P v P m , S , T b , N T C v g ( S , P m )
On the right-hand side of Equation (5), the first item represents the cost of facility investment in carbon emission reduction, and the second item represents the loss (or earn) when the actual carbon emission exceeds (or falls short of) the cap of carbon emission. The sum of Equations (2) and (6) are written as:
T P # P m , S , T b , N = T P b P m , S , T b + T P v # P m , S , T b , N
In Equation (7), there are four decision variables. Within the whole system of the vendor and buyer, including the green cost of carbon emission reduction, the problem is:
M a x i m i z e   T P # P m , S , T b , N  
Subject to S 0 , P m 0 , T b 0 , N 0 .
Let S * be the optimal solution of (8). After substituting S = S * and demand d in Equation (1) into Equations (2) and (3), T P b and T P v are expressed as:
T P b P m , T b = P m P b d 0 + d 1 S * d 2 P m C b T b 1 2 P b ( d 0 + d 1 S * d 2 P m ) T b F b
T P v # P m , T b , N = P b P v d 0 + d 1 S * d 2 P m C v + N C v b N T b     1 2 d T b N 1 1 d 0 + d 1 S * d 2 P m g + d 0 + d 1 S * d 2 P m g P v F v T C v g ( S * , P m )
Case 1: Considering a buyer’s market without a quantity discount
In this case, the vendor offers a fixed price to the buyer and the buyer decides the values of Pm and Tb in Equation (9). Since the value of S (i.e., green technology level) in Equation (9) is related to the green cost of carbon emission reduction, it is reasonable for the vendor to set the value of S to be equal to S * .
Case 2: Considering vendor-buyer integration without quantity discount
In this case, the vendor and buyer make the decision in Equation (8) simultaneously.
Case 3: Considering integration and quantity discount
The vendor offered a discount-price P b to the buyer. In this case, there are five decision variables: P m , S T b , N and P b in Equation (8). Let the optimum values of T P b and T P v   ( o r   T P v # ) in Case 1 be expressed as T P b 1 and T P v 1   ( o r   T P v 1 # ) , respectively.
Two pricing strategies for sharing the extra profit are discussed as follows:
Strategy I: Sharing the extra profit from net sales revenue, setup cost, and holding cost. The characteristic of Strategy I is when the discount price remains stable.
Strategy II: Sharing the extra profit from net sales revenue, setup cost, holding cost, and green cost. The green cost may be positive or negative depending on whether 1 2 η S 2 > C p [ a b S d C ] or 1 2 η S 2 < C p a b S d C , respectively. The characteristic of Strategy II is that the discount price adjusts according to the government’s carbon emission cap.
The extra total profit for the buyer (or the vendor) in Case 3 is defined as the difference in total profit between Case 3 and Case 1. It is written as:
T P b = T P b T P b 1
and
T P v = T P v T P v 1 ( o r   T P v # = T P v # T P v 1 # )
A key parameter in negotiating the profit share between the vendor and the buyer, Φ , is defined as:
( T P v ) = Φ ( T P b )   o r   T P v # = Φ ( T P b )
If Φ = 1 , it means the vendor’s extra total profit is equal to the buyer’s extra total profit. If Φ = 100 (or Φ = 10 ) , the vendor’s profit is more than 100 times (or 10 times) compared to the buyer’s extra total profit. A constrained problem in Case 3 can be rewritten as:
M a x i m i z e   T P # P m , S , T b , P b , N    
Subject to   ( T P v ) = Φ ( T P b )
o r T P v # = Φ ( T P b )

3. Solution Procedure

Case 1:
The buyer’s total profit is optimized first, followed by the vendor’s total profit.
Step 1: By taking the first derivative of T P b P m , T b with respect to P m , T b setting to zero simultaneously, the value of P m , T b is determined.
T P b P m , T b P m = 0
T P b P m , T b T b = 0
Step 2: The optimal solution of N ζ , denoted as N ζ * , must satisfy the following conditions:
T P v # ( N ζ * 1 ) T P v # ( N ζ * ) T P v # ( N ζ * + 1 )
Case 2:
The total profit in Equation (8) is optimized. For a fixed value of N (denoted N ζ ), the following conditions must be satisfied simultaneously.
Step 1: By taking the first derivative of T P # P m , S , T b , N with respect to P m , S , T b ,   N   setting to zero simultaneously, the value of P m , S , T b ,   N is determined.
T P # ( P m , S , T b , N ζ ) P m = 0
T P # ( P m , S , T b , N ζ ) S = 0
T P # ( P m , S , T b , N ζ ) T b = 0
Step 2: The optimal solution of N ζ must satisfy the following conditions:
T P # ( N ζ 1 ) T P # ( N ζ ) T P # ( N ζ + 1 )
Case 3:
The first step is to derive P b from Equation (13), where P b is expressed as P b ( P m , S , T b , N ) . For a fixed value of N (denoted as N ζ ), the optimal solution in Equation (14) must simultaneously satisfy the following conditions:
Step 1: By taking the first derivative of T P # ( P m , S , T b , P b , N ) with respect to P m , S , T b , P b , N setting to zero simultaneously, the value of P m , S , T b , P b , N is determined.
T P # ( P m , S , T b , P b ( P m , T b , N ζ ) , N ζ ) P m = 0
T P # ( P m , S , T b , P b ( P m , T b , N ζ ) , N ζ ) S = 0
T P # ( P m , S , T b , P b P m , T b , N ζ , N ζ ) T b = 0
Step 2: The optimal solution of N ζ must satisfy the following conditions:
T P # ( N ζ 1 ) T P # ( N ζ ) T P # ( N ζ + 1 )

4. Numerical Example and Sensitivity Analysis

4.1. Numerical Example for Three Cases

In this study, the following example data illustrate the proposed approach. They are offered by Yiming Co. Ltd., Taiwan, (Taiwan, China) which belongs to A&I Group. The factory produces consumer goods and utensils through plastic injection molding and metal extrusion molding and sells to large-scale hypermarkets.
The buyer-related parameters are C b = 100; F b = 0.3; P b = 35 for Cases 1 and 2. The vendor-related parameters are: C v = 6000; C v b = 100; F v = 0.2; P v = 20; g = 30000. The parameters related to green technology are C = 300,000, C p = 0.5. η = 1.5. a = 425. b = 1.1. The demand parameters: d 0 = 3000; d 1 = 0.1; d 2 = 35. The negotiation factor:   Φ = 100, 10, 1, 0.1, and 0.01. By applying the above solution procedure, the results for Cases 1, 2, and 3 are presented in Table 2.
Under the conditions considering the net sales revenue, setup, and holding costs, the following observations can be made, as shown in Table 2 for Cases 1 and 2. The buyer’s order size increases from 130.42 units to 253.65 units. However, no discount is provided to compensate for the larger order, which appears unreasonable. With integration, it leads to an additional total profit increase of 4.53% (i.e., 29905 ÷ 28608 − 1). Comparing Case 3 under Strategy I with Case 1 reveals the following: (i) integration combined with a quantity discount yields a higher total profit increase of 4.68% (i.e., 29946 ÷ 28608 − 1). (ii) The vendor offers a unit price discount from $35 to $33.633 (3.91% discount rate) to the buyer, while the buyer reduces the market price to consumers from $61.282 to $57.457 (6.24%). These actions stimulate sales (1026.9 ÷ 893.0 1 = 14.99%) and benefit all players in the supply chain. This represents a real win-win and sustainable strategy.
When green cost, net sales revenue, setup cost, and holding cost are considered, a comparison between Case 3 using Strategy II and Case 1 shows that: (i) the buyer’s order quantity increases from 130.42 to 255.70 and the vendor offers a unit price discount from $35 to $33.880 (3.20% discount). (ii) Integration and quantity discount together lead to an additional total profit increase of 3.63% (i.e., 23049 ÷ 22241 − 1). (iii) The vendor provides a 3.20% discount to the buyer, who then reduces the market price to consumers from $61.282 to $57.440 (6.27%). These activities increase sales from 893.0 units to 1027.5 (a 15.06% rise) and benefit all members of the supply chain.
Generally, Case 1 benefits the buyer more, while Case 2 favors the vendor. Case 3 benefits the vendor, buyer, and consumer simultaneously. When a reasonable profit-sharing mechanism is adopted within the supply chain system, the profits of the buyer, the vendor, and the entire system in Case 3 exceed those in Case 1.

4.2. Sensitivity Analysis and Discussion

A sensitivity analysis is carried out when key parameters are changed by ± 5 % , ± 10 % . If the seller (vendor) benefits more from the extra total profit, a higher discount can be offered, encouraging the buyer to place a larger order quantity. This, in turn, results in an increased total profit for both the seller and the buyer; Table 3 shows the results.
From Table 4, under the condition ( T P v ) = ( T P b ) , the discount price remains constant (i.e., $33.633). However, under the condition T P v # = ( T P b ) , the transaction price varies significantly, ranging from $38.922 to $28.847; this is due to the cost/profit-sharing mechanism. As shown in Figure 3, a critical point occurs when C = 211,033, which marks the intersection of Strategies I and II. When C < 211,033, the buyer prefers Strategy I, while the vendor prefers Strategy II. Conversely, when C > 211,033, the preferences are reversed. The relationship between T P v ,   T C v g ,   T P v # , and cap C is illustrated in Figure 4. A critical point is found at cap C = 223,786, where TCvg = 0. This indicates that the vendor’s subsidy from carbon emission reduction is equal to that of the investment cost for green facilities. If the government emission quota is below the critical value, the vendor incurs a cost loss and may be reluctant to invest in green technologies. However, considering that government resources are limited, a reasonable suggestion is to set up the cap value at least equal to or above the critical point.
Therefore, the critical point of C (the cap of carbon emission) can be a metric for selecting Strategy I and Strategy II. Moreover, C is also a key factor affecting ROI. If the value of C is too low, the ROI will be negative and the company will suffer losses. The return on investment of the green technology facility for Case 3 and Strategies I and II is presented in Table 5 and Figure 5. The facility investment is given by 1 / 2 · η S 2 and the return is calculated as the difference between T P # and T P in Table 4. Figure 5 shows that the ROI is positive only when the cap is 231,000. As the cap value decreases from 220,500 to 189,000, the ROI becomes negative, ranging from −1.50% to −16.20%. From Table 6, as the value of Cv increases, the value of N tends to increase to prolong the production cycle time, thereby reducing the setup cost per unit of time. From Table 7, as the holding cost per dollar per unit time increases, the replenishment time interval tends to decrease to counteract the effect of the higher holding cost. From Table 8, when the value of Cp increases, it results in a greater increase in the vendor’s profit and a smaller increase in the buyer’s profit. It can be observed that a higher value of Cp allows for carbon emission reduction. From Table 9, a greater value of b may decrease the facility’s technological level of emission reduction (i.e., S), thereby reducing the vendor’s green cost (i.e., TCvi) and increasing the vendor’s profit. As shown in Table 10, the value of S increases with the value of η , which then reduces the vendor’s total profit (i.e., T P v # ). As shown in Table 11, the increase in a value will make it necessary to increase the facility’s technology level for carbon emission reduction. As shown in Table 12, when the value of d1 increases, the technology level decreases, the market price rises, and both the buyer’s sales amount and total profit increase. Table 13 shows that as the price-sensitive coefficient increases, the market price decreases, thereby promoting sales volume.

5. Conclusions

This study explores two quantity-discount pricing strategies under cap-and-trade regulations, where demand is influenced by market price and green technology. A key finding is that it is feasible to increase profits for the vendor, buyer, and consumer simultaneously using quantity discounts. Offering greater price discounts, which involves sacrificing some of the vendor’s profit to enhance the buyer’s profit, leads to higher total profits.
A critical value of C = 211,033 is identified as a strategic threshold. If the government’s cap is below this value, the buyer will opt for Strategy I, while the vendor will choose Strategy II. Conversely, if the cap exceeds this value, each player will select the opposite strategy. This critical value guides strategic decisions and highlights the importance of incorporating negotiation factors to distribute extra profits based on each player’s contribution. For government policy, this critical value suggests that setting caps below or above this threshold can significantly influence market strategies and outcomes. Another critical value, C = 223,786, is crucial for setting reasonable carbon emission quotas. If the quota is below this value, vendors may be reluctant to invest in green technology. This finding underscores the need for governments to set quotas that encourage sustainable investments.
From the vendor’s perspective, the return on investment in green technology is positive only under specific conditions, such as when C = 231,000. This indicates that vendors may be interested in investing in green technology if the return is positive. The study contributes to understanding strategic decision-making under cap-and-trade regulations, emphasizing the importance of critical values and sensitivity coefficients in guiding investments and pricing strategies. It highlights how changes in setup costs, holding costs, and sensitivity coefficients can impact production cycles and inventory management. From the sensitivity analysis, it is shown that:
  • If the buyer (retailer) is willing to share more profits, the seller (supplier) can offer higher price discounts to encourage the buyer to place larger orders; this will increase the profits of both parties.
  • The critical point of C (the cap of carbon emission) can be a metric for selecting Strategy I and Strategy II. In addition, C is also a key factor affecting ROI. If the value of C is too low, the ROI will be negative, and the company will suffer losses.
  • In addition, when the subsidy for carbon emission reduction obtained by the supplier is lower than the critical value, the supplier will suffer cost losses and may be unwilling to invest in green technology. Therefore, the government should set a carbon emission cap above the critical point.
  • Extending the production cycle can reduce the setup cost per unit time.
  • Reducing the time interval between replenishments can reduce holding costs.
  • A higher Cp value (Unit price per carbon emission) can promote lower carbon emission.
For future research, exploring how different regulatory frameworks and technological advancements can further influence these strategies would be beneficial. Additionally, examining the impact of consumer preferences and benefits could provide valuable insights into how businesses can align their strategies with growing eco-consumer demands.

Author Contributions

Methodology, H.-M.W.; Investigation, J.C.-P.Y.; Writing—original draft, X.-B.L.; Writing—review & editing, K.-J.W. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

National Science and Technology Council, Taiwan, R.O.C., under research grant NSTC 113-2410-H-147-001.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in this study are included in the article. Further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the Editor-in-Chief and the anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments and suggestions. The funding from the National Science and Technology Council, Taiwan, R.O.C., under research grant NSTC 113-2410-H-147-001 is greatly appreciated.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Daryanto, Y.; Wee, H.M.; Widyadana, G. Low carbon supply chain coordination for imperfect quality deteriorating items. Mathematics 2019, 7, 234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Hua, G.; Cheng, T.C.E.; Wang, S. Managing carbon footprints in inventory management. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2011, 132, 178–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Dwicahyani, A.R.; Jauhari, W.A.; Rosyidi, C.N.; Laksono, P.W. Inventory decisions in a two-echelon system with remanufacturing, carbon emission, and energy effects. Cogent Eng. 2017, 4, 1379628. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Ghosh, A.; Jha, J.K.; Sarmah, S.P. Optimal lot-sizing under strict carbon cap policy considering stochastic demand. Appl. Math. Model. 2017, 44, 688–704. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Tiwari, S.; Daryanto, Y.; Wee, H.M. Sustainable inventory management with deteriorating and imperfect quality items considering carbon emission. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 192, 281–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Yang, H.; Chen, W. Retailer-driven carbon emission abatement with consumer environmental awareness and carbon tax: Revenue-sharing versus cost-sharing. Omega 2018, 78, 179–191. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Bai, Q.; Xu, J.; Zhang, Y. Emission reduction decision and coordination of a make-to-order supply chain with two products under cap-and-trade regulation. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2018, 119, 131–145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Turki, S.; Sauvey, C.; Rezg, N. Modelling and optimization of a manufacturing/ remanufacturing system with storage facility under carbon cap and trade policy. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 193, 441–458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Chelly, A.; Nouira, I.; Frein, Y.; Hadj-Alouane, A.B. On the consideration of carbon emissions in modelling-based supply chain literature: The state of the art, relevant features and research gaps. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2019, 57, 4977–5004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Yu, J.C.P.; Yang, P.C.; Lai, X.C. Integrated manufacturer-retailer closed-loop inventory system with price-sensitive return and demand rates. J. Ind. Prod. Eng. 2019, 36, 134–145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Taleizadeh, A.A.; Alizadeh-Basban, N.; Taghi Akhavan Niaki, S. A closed-loop supply chain considering carbon reduction, quality improvement effort, and return policy under two remanufacturing scenarios. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 232, 1230–1250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Nahr, J.G.; Pasandideh, S.H.R.; Niaki, S.T.A. A robust optimization approach for multi-objective, multi-product, multi-period, closed-loop green supply chain network designs under uncertainty and discount. J. Ind. Prod. Eng. 2020, 37, 1–22. [Google Scholar]
  13. Entezaminia, A.; Gharbi, A.; Ouhimmou, M. Environmental hedging point policies for collaborative unreliable manufacturing systems with variant emitting level technologies. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 250, 119539. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Taleizadeh, A.A.; Shokr, I.; Joali, F. Optimizing vendor-managed inventory systems with limited storage capacity and partial backordering under stochastic demand. Rairo-Oper. Res. 2020, 54, 179–209. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Ramandi, M.D.; Bafruei, M.K. Effects of government’s policy on supply chain coordination with a periodic review inventory system to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2020, 148, 106756. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Roy, M.D.; Sana, S.S. Production rate and lot-size dependent lead time reduction strategies in a supply chain model with stochastic demand, controllable setup cost and trade-credit financing. Rairo-Oper. Res. 2021, 55, 1469–1485. [Google Scholar]
  17. Rout, C.; Paul, A.; Kumar, R.S.; Chakraborty, D.; Goswami, A. Integrated optimization of inventory, replenishment and vehicle routing for a sustainable supply chain under carbon emission regulations. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 316, 128256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Jiang, S.; Ye, F.; Lin, Q. Managing green innovation investment in a co-competitive supply chain under capital constraint. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 291, 125254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Hoque, M. An optimal solution policy to an integrated manufacturer-retailers problem with normal distribution of lead times of delivering equal and unequal sized batches. Opsearch 2021, 58, 483–512. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Heydari, J.; Govindan, K.; Basiri, Z. Balancing price and green quality in presence of consumer environmental awareness: A green supply chain coordination approach. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2021, 59, 1957–1975. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Yu, J.; Lin, Y.; Wang, K. Coordination-based inventory management of two-echelon supply chain with profit sharing”. Int. J. Syst. Sci. 2013, 44, 1587–1601. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Sarkar, B.; Bhuniya, S. A sustainable flexible manufacturing–remanufacturing model with improved service and green investment under variable demand. Expert Syst. Appl. 2022, 202, 117154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Sarkar, B.; Guchhait, R. Ramification of information asymmetry on a green supply chain management with the cap-trade, service, and vendor-managed inventory strategies. Electron. Commer. Res. Appl. 2023, 60, 101274. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Guchhait, R.; Sarkar, M.; Sarkar, B.; Yang, L.; AlArjani, A.; Mandal, B. Extended material requirement planning (MRP) within a hybrid energy-enabled smart production system. J. Ind. Inf. Integr. 2024, 42, 100717. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Guchhait, R.; Sarkar, B. Economic evaluation of an outsourced fourth-party logistics (4PL) under a flexible production system. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2025, 279, 109440. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. The flows of a two-echelon supply chain [21].
Figure 1. The flows of a two-echelon supply chain [21].
Mathematics 13 01761 g001
Figure 2. The different scenarios are characterized by the relationship between the vendor and the buyer.
Figure 2. The different scenarios are characterized by the relationship between the vendor and the buyer.
Mathematics 13 01761 g002
Figure 3. Cap C vs. discount price Pb.
Figure 3. Cap C vs. discount price Pb.
Mathematics 13 01761 g003
Figure 4. The relationship between T P v ,   T C v g ,   T P v # , and cap C.
Figure 4. The relationship between T P v ,   T C v g ,   T P v # , and cap C.
Mathematics 13 01761 g004
Figure 5. Return on investment vs. cap C (105).
Figure 5. Return on investment vs. cap C (105).
Mathematics 13 01761 g005
Table 1. Comparison between the proposed work and previous studies.
Table 1. Comparison between the proposed work and previous studies.
Authors (Year)Sustainable Supply ChainsCarbon ReductionPricing StrategyProfit/Cost Negotiation Mechanism
Daryanto et al. (2019) [1]YesYesNoNo
Hua et al. (2011) [2]NoYesNoNo
Dwicahyani et al. (2017) [3]YesNoNoNo
Ghosh et al. (2017) [4]NoYesNoNo
Tiwari et al. (2018) [5]NoYesYes
Yang and Chen (2018) [6]YesNoNoYes
Bai et al. (2018) [7]NoYesNoYes
Turki et al. (2018) [8]NoYesNoNo
Chelly et al. (2019) [9]YesYesNoNo
Yu et al. (2019) [10]YesNoYesNo
Taleizadeh et al. (2019) [11]YesYesNoNo
Nahr et al. (2020) [12]YesNoYesNo
Entezaminia et al. (2020) [13]YesNoNoNo
Taleizadeh et al. (2020) [14]YesNoNoNo
Ramandi and Bafruei (2020) [15]NoYesNoNo
Roy and Sana (2021) [16]NoNoNoYes
Rout et al. (2021) [17]YesNoNoNo
Jiang et al. (2021) [18]YesNoNoNo
Hoque, M. (2021) [19]YesYesNoNo
Heydari et al. (2021) [20]YesNoYesYes
Sarkar and Bhuniya (2022) [22]YesNoYesYes
Sarkar and Guchhait (2023) [23]YesNoYesYes
Guchhait et al. (2024) [24]YesNoYesYes
Guchhait and Sarkar (2025) [25]YesNoYesYes
Proposed model YesYesYesYes
Table 2. The optimum solution in various cases.
Table 2. The optimum solution in various cases.
Case iCase 1Case 2Case 3
S t r a t e g y   I
( T P v ) = ( T P b )
S t r a t e g y   I I
T P v # = ( T P b )
N13777
S379.24379.24378.43378.62
Pb353533.63333.880
Pm61.28257.39957.45757.440
Tb0.146040.246510.249210.24886
d893.01028.91026.91027.5
dTb130.42253.65255.89255.70
TPb22,10221,31022,77122,506
TPv6506859571757434
TP28,60829,90529,94629,940
TCvg6366689968886891
T P v # 139.681696.0287.64543.44
T P # 22,24123,00623,05923,049
Remark: ( T P v = 7175 6506 ) = ( T P b = 22,771 22,102 ) = 669 ; T P v # = 543.44 139.68 = T P b = 22,506 22,102 = 404 .
Table 3. The sensitivity analysis with various values of Φ in Case 3.
Table 3. The sensitivity analysis with various values of Φ in Case 3.
Φ 1001010.10.01
N77777
S378.60378.58378.43378.27378.24
Pb34.24834.14833.63333.10432.998
Pm57.44157.44457.45757.47157.474
Tb0.248470.248590.249210.249850.24997
d1027.41027.31026.91026.31026.2
dTb255.28255.38255.89256.43256.53
TPb22,11522,22222,77123,33523,448
TPv78117707717566296519
TP29,92629,92929,94629,96429,968
TCvg6890.56890.06887.66884.96884.4
T P v # 920.16816.95287.64−255.64−364.93
T P # 23,03523,03923,05923,07923,083
Remark: The black column represents central values.
Table 4. The sensitivity analysis with various values of C ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 3.
Table 4. The sensitivity analysis with various values of C ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 3.
Item Strategy   I :   T P v = T P b Strategy   II :   T P v # = T P b
C189,000199,500210,000220,500231,000189,000199,500210,000220,500231,000
Pb 33.63333.63333.63333.63333.63338.92236.40033.88031.36228.847
N777777
S378.43378.42378.52378.62378.73378.83
Pm57.45757.45557.44857.44057.43257.424
Tb0.249210.243600.246190.248860.251620.25447
d1026.81026.91027.21027.51027.71028.0
dTb255.89250.15252.88255.70258.60261.60
TPb22,77117,16119,83322,50625,17927,853
TPv71751258610010743448592285
TP29,94629,74729,84329,94030,03830,138
TCvg17,38812,13868881638 3612 ε 17,38812,13968911642−3606
T P v # −10,212−4962288553810,788−4802−212954332175891
T P # 125,5917,80923,05928,30933,55912,35917,70423,04928,39633,744
Remark: ε : A negative value indicates that the vendor can sell the additional carbon emission savings and the revenue generated exceeds the cost of investing in carbon emission reduction facilities.
Table 5. Return on investment of green technology with various values of the cap.
Table 5. Return on investment of green technology with various values of the cap.
Cap :   C   ( 10 5 )   ( ± 5 % , ± 10 % )1.891.9952.12.2052.31
Strategy IInvestment: 1 2 η S 2 107,407
Return: T P # T P −17,387−12,137−6887−16373613
ROI−16.2%−11.3%−6.4%−1.5%3.4%
Strategy IIInvestment: 1 2 η S 2 107,401107,458107,515107,577107,634
Return: T P # T P −17,388−12,139−6891−16423606
ROI−16.2%−11.3%−6.4%−1.5%3.4%
Table 6. The sensitivity analysis with various values of Cv ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 2.
Table 6. The sensitivity analysis with various values of Cv ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 2.
Cv54005700600063006600
N77778
S378.82379.03379.24379.44379.62
Pm57.43157.41557.39957.38457.371
Tb0.236430.241530.246510.251390.22984
d1027.81028.41028.91029.51030.0
dTb243.01248.38253.65258.81236.73
TPb2135621333213102128821364
TPv88998745859584488209
TP30,25430,07829,90529,73629,572
TCvg68936896689969016904
T P v # 20061849169615461305
T P # 23,36123,18223,00622,83422,668
Table 7. The sensitivity analysis with various values of Fb ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 2.
Table 7. The sensitivity analysis with various values of Fb ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 2.
Fb0.270.2850.30.3150.33
N77788
S379.08379.16379.24379.30379.38
Pm57.41257.40557.39957.39557.389
Tb0.250480.248470.246510.219840.21832
d1028.51028.71028.91029.11029.3
dTb257.62255.61253.65226.24224.72
TPb21,43421,37221,31021,34521,290
TPv86038599859584968493
TP30,03729,97129,90529,84129,783
TCvg68966898689969006900
T P v # 17071702169615961592
T P # 23,14123,07323,00622,94122,882
Table 8. The sensitivity analysis with various values of Cp ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 2.
Table 8. The sensitivity analysis with various values of Cp ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 2.
Cp0.450.4750.50.5250.55
N77777
Pm52.67255.26757.39959.19460.734
S397.01386.78379.24373.58369.27
Tb0.229010.238130.246510.254320.26165
d1196.21104.31028.9965.6911.2
dTb273.93262.97253.65245.56238.42
TPb19,26420,58121,31021,67921,816
TPv10,5859487859578527222
TP29,84930,06829,90529,53129,038
TCvg17,40912,20968991550−3806
T P v # −6824−27221696630211,028
T P # 12,44017,85923,00627,98132,844
Table 9. The sensitivity analysis with various values of b ( ± 1 % ,   ± 2 % ) in Case 2.
Table 9. The sensitivity analysis with various values of b ( ± 1 % ,   ± 2 % ) in Case 2.
b1.0781.0891.11.1111.122
N77777
Pm55.76056.59957.39958.16558.897
S392.91385.94379.24372.80366.61
Tb0.239900.243210.246510.249800.25307
d1087.71057.61028.91001.5975.3
dTb260.94257.23253.65250.18246.81
TPb20,79421,08221,31021,48621,615
TPv92898933859582737966
TP30,08330,01529,90529,75929,580
TCvg11,5689204689946532465
T P v # −2280−271169636205500
T P # 18,51420,81123,00625,10627,115
Table 10. The sensitivity analysis with various values of η ( ± 1 % ,   ± 2 % ) in Case 2.
Table 10. The sensitivity analysis with various values of η ( ± 1 % ,   ± 2 % ) in Case 2.
η 1.471.4851.51.5151.53
N77777
Pm58.19157.79757.39956.99956.596
S376.46377.84379.24380.65382.07
Tb0.249860.248180.246510.244870.24324
d1001.01014.91028.91043.11057.4
dTb250.11251.88253.65255.42257.20
TPb21,50021,41121,31021,19821,073
TPv82668430859587618930
TP29,76629,84129,90529,95930,003
TCvg46185759689980359170
T P v # 364826701696726−240
T P # 25,14824,08123,00621,92420,833
Table 11. The sensitivity analysis with various values of a ( ± 1 % ,   ± 2 % ) in Case 2.
Table 11. The sensitivity analysis with various values of a ( ± 1 % ,   ± 2 % ) in Case 2.
a416.5420.75425429.25433.5
N77777
Pm58.18557.79257.39957.00656.613
S368.71373.98379.24384.51389.78
Tb0.249940.248210.246510.244850.24323
d1000.41014.71028.91043.21057.5
dTb250.03251.84253.65255.44257.22
TPb21,48121,40221,31021,20821,095
TPv82598427859587638932
TP29,74129,82829,90529,97130,026
TCvg242246506899916611,454
T P v # 583737761696−403−2522
T P # 27,31925,17823,00620,80518,573
Table 12. The sensitivity analysis of various value of d1 ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 2.
Table 12. The sensitivity analysis of various value of d1 ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 2.
d10.090.0950.10.1050.11
N77777
Pm57.25057.32557.39957.47457.548
S379.58379.41379.24379.07378.90
Tb0.246340.246430.246510.246600.24668
d1030.41029.71028.91028.21027.5
dTb253.83253.74253.65253.56353.46
TPb21,18821,24921,31021,37121,432
TPv86128603859585868797
TP29,80029,85329,90529,95724,569
TCvg69056902689968956892
T P v # 17071701169616911686
T P # 22,89522,95123,00623,06223,118
Table 13. The sensitivity analysis with various value of d2 ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 2.
Table 13. The sensitivity analysis with various value of d2 ( ± 5 % ,   ± 10 % ) in Case 2.
d231.533.253536.7538.5
N77777
Pm64.47060.72557.39954.42651.750
S371.10375.47379.24382.52385.40
Tb0.249210.247750.246510.245440.24452
d1006.31018.51028.91038.11046.2
dTb250.78252.32253.65254.80255.80
TPb27,93824,47121,31018,42115,772
TPv83288471859587028797
TP36,26632,94229,90527,12324,569
TCvg67346835689969366954
T P v # 15941636169617671843
T P # 29,53226,10723,00620,18817,615
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Lin, X.-B.; Yu, J.C.-P.; Wang, K.-J.; Wee, H.-M. Optimizing Sustainable Supply Chains: An Analysis of Quantity-Discount Pricing Strategies Under Carbon Cap-and-Trade Regulations. Mathematics 2025, 13, 1761. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13111761

AMA Style

Lin X-B, Yu JC-P, Wang K-J, Wee H-M. Optimizing Sustainable Supply Chains: An Analysis of Quantity-Discount Pricing Strategies Under Carbon Cap-and-Trade Regulations. Mathematics. 2025; 13(11):1761. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13111761

Chicago/Turabian Style

Lin, Xi-Bin, Jonas Chao-Pen Yu, Kung-Jeng Wang, and Hui-Ming Wee. 2025. "Optimizing Sustainable Supply Chains: An Analysis of Quantity-Discount Pricing Strategies Under Carbon Cap-and-Trade Regulations" Mathematics 13, no. 11: 1761. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13111761

APA Style

Lin, X.-B., Yu, J. C.-P., Wang, K.-J., & Wee, H.-M. (2025). Optimizing Sustainable Supply Chains: An Analysis of Quantity-Discount Pricing Strategies Under Carbon Cap-and-Trade Regulations. Mathematics, 13(11), 1761. https://doi.org/10.3390/math13111761

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop