Female Wage Employment and Fertility in Kenya
Abstract
1. Introduction
- Whether a woman has ever given a live birth, irrespective of the baby’s gender.
- Total number of children ever born alive.
- Number of males.
- Number of females.
2. Overview of Related Literature
3. Modelling Women’s Work and Fertility
3.1. Feminism Model
3.2. Economic Model
3.2.1. Background
3.2.2. Child Quantity, Child Quality, and Full Income
3.2.3. Formal Model
3.2.4. Predictions and Limitations of the Model
3.2.5. The Emerging Research Hypothesis
3.3. Hybrid Model
4. Empirical Models and Estimation Methods
5. A Snapshot of Sample Data
- About 17.4% of women had wage employment.
- Close to 65% of women had given birth by the time of the survey.
- The household size was 5.5.
- The total number of children born (per woman) was 3.5.
- The number of male children born alive was 1.79 per woman.
- The number of female children born alive was 1.75.
- About 65% of households had experienced severe drought or floods.
- The average age of women in the labor force (age 15–64) was 32.2 years, but for those in the estimation sample it was below 30.
- Approximately, 63% of the households lived in rural areas.
- Nearly 85% of women had attended school.
- The food-budget share was 60% of household total expenditure, suggesting that the majority of the households were food poor.
- About 1.4 children lived away from home.
- Around 47% of women were in monogamous marriages.
6. Key Findings
6.1. OLS Estimates
6.2. Heckit/CF Estimates
6.3. Poisson/Negative-Binomial Results (Preferred Estimates)
Variables | Male Live Births (1) | Female Live Births (2) | Total Live Births (3) | First Birth? (Yes = 1) Reduced-Form Probit: AME (4) |
---|---|---|---|---|
Wage Employment (=1) | Coef = −0.085 AME = −0.157 t = (4.44) ** | −0.039 −0.071 (1.82) * | −0.062 −0.228 (4.44) ** | 0.026 (3.70) ** |
Estimation Method | Generalized Negative Binomial | Poisson | Negative Binomial | MLE |
Over-Dispersion Test; Ho: Equidispersion | Ln pr (Male Births) −0.066 (8.97) ** | Ln pr (Female Births) 0.0099 (1.22) | Ln pr (Total Births) −0.040 (10.72) ** | … |
All Covariates Included in the Baseline, OLS Model Included here? | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 8135 | 8135 | 8135 | 12,715 |
7. Observations on Parameter Estimates
- The decline in the number of male live births associated with female wage employment is 2.0–2.5 times larger than that for female babies in all models, including the OLS estimates.
- Female wage employment is associated with a 0.197 and a 0.228 reduction in the total number of babies born alive in the Heckit and Poisson models, respectively, with the Poisson estimate being 15.7% higher.
- Additionally, female wage employment is associated with a 2.6% increase in the probability of the first birth.
- The number of subsequent live births associated with female wage employment status naturally depends on the first birth; thus, the two should be modeled together, as performed in this paper.
- If fertility at the intensive margin is zero, it is also zero at the extensive margin, i.e., in a given survey period, women who report a zero for the first birth also report a zero for a higher-order birth. It is worth clarifying that women who report a zero for the first birth are taken into account in the estimation of the association between fertility and female wage employment at both margins using the Heckit (Heckman, 1979) and the Poisson (Favero et al., 2020) procedures.
- In the Heckit formulation of the fertility model, women reporting a zero for the first birth are included in the selection equation (estimated with a sample for all women) but are excluded from the structural equation (estimated using only the motherhood sample). In the Poisson model, only women with non-zero counts for the number of children born alive are included in the motherhood sample, by design of the Heclit, even though the Poisson counts zeros (Favero et al., 2020). However, as in the usual Heckman setup, a variable that captures the unobservable covariates in the selection equation, i.e., the inverse of the Mills ratio, is included as an explanatory in the fertility models to ensure that the estimates are generalizable outside of the motherhood sample (see Appendix A). Thus, data from both sample margins are taken into account during estimations.
- Changes in fertility at both margins determine the population-level fertility associated with an exogenous variation in the female labor force participation.
- A 1% exogenous increase in the probability of female wage employment in the Poisson model is associated with a 0.05 reduction in fertility, i.e., (−0.228)*(0.026) = −0.051; see the first row of Table 3 and columns 3 and 4.
- The evidence generated in this paper can be used to design female wage employment policies that encourage population-level fertility decisions in socially desired ways while also: (i) enhancing women’s reproductive health; (ii) empowering women economically and socially; (iii) improving child health in utero; (iv) addressing disparities in sex ratios; (v) improving work environments for expectant mothers; (vi) making childcare broadly available; and (vi) improving women’s overall human capital.
- The Heckit two-step estimates are consistent across specifications when the correlation between the structural equation error term and the error term of the selection equation is not close to + −1 (see Nawata, 1994, Tables 1–6). The rho values for our Heckit two-step models are generally less than 0.45. Multi-collinearity is absent from the data because the VIF value is below two. Additional robustness tests show that the two-step Heckit coefficient estimates are close to the estimates obtainable with the MLE estimator using publicly available data in STATA software, version 14).
- The OLS estimate (−0.261) of the association between fertility and female wage employment (Table 2) is 32.5% larger than the CF’s estimate. The OLS upward bias in the structural models is 23–56% of the Heckit/Poisson estimates. However, even though when expressed in ratio form, these coefficients are about the same across gender (2.0–2.5), the OLS ratios are misleading because they fail to reveal that the underlying absolute OLS coefficient estimates exaggerate the reduction in fertility associated with an increase in female wage employment.
- It is worth noting that the models generating the preferred parameter estimates presented in Table 2 and Table 3 are short-form versions of complex Heckit/Control function models (see Appendix E). The coefficient estimates for the long-form models are the same as for the short-form models, designed to shorten lengthy results tables, printed out by estimation algorithms currently in use (see e.g., appendix results printouts from STATA versions 14 or 17). The results for the long-form models (STATA results printouts) are included in the Appendix tables to highlight the enormous economy of presentation made possible by the short-form models presented in the main text. The exact correspondence of parameter estimates in the two forms is worth noting, especially since they are derived differently. Lastly, in some results tables in the main text, and in the Appendixes, the term effects and correlations are used synonymously, but the estimated coefficients should be interpreted as associations, not as causal effects.
8. Contextualization and Synthesis
9. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Non-Linear Sample Selection Models
Variables | Male Births (1) | Female Births (2) | Total Births (3) | First Birth? (Yes = 1) Reduced-Form Probit Estimates (Average Marginal Effects), (4) |
---|---|---|---|---|
Wage Employment (=1) | −0.141 (3.87) | −0.057 † (1.47) * | −0.197 3.92 | 0.026 † (3.70) ** |
Generalized Residual (GR), obtained from Employment Probit (controls for endogeneity) | 0.414 (3.96) | 0.377 (3.41) | 0.791 (5.46) | … |
Shocks (=1) | 0.192 (6.11) | 0.196 (5.88) | 0.388 (8.89) | 0.019 (3.69) |
Religion (1 = Christians) | −0.061 (1.79) | −0.052 (1.42) | −0.113 (2.38) | 0.0005 (0.09) |
Married | 0.351 (7.50) | 0.269 (5.43) | 0.621 (9.55) | 0.173 (34.6) |
Education (=1) | −0.704 (11.14) | −0.0715 (10.71) | −1.420 (16.03) | −0.034 (2.67) |
Rural | 0.038 (0.99) | −0.715 (10.75) | 0.173 (3.26) | 0.012 (1.88) |
Age | 0.276 (11.7) | 0.135 (3.33) | 0.553 (16.82) | 0.059 (37.1) |
Age Squared × (10−2) | −0.268 (8.54) | −0.266 (8.01) | −0.534 (12.3) | −0.075 (28.1) |
Food-Budget Share | 0.953 (9.95) | 0.821 8.10 | 1.77 (13.4) | 0.128 (8.94) |
IMR for the First Birth Probit (Controls for sample Selection) | 0.401 (4.54) | 0.368 3.94 | 0.769 (6.29) | … |
Log (Household Total Landholding, Acres) | - | - | - | −0.016 * (3.90) |
Household Rent, Dummy | - | - | - | −0.008 * (0.81) |
Constant | −5.23 (9.42) | −5.18 (8.81) | −10.4 (13.5) | - |
R2/Pseudo R2 | 0.240 | 0.229 | 0.404 | 0.66 |
N | 8135 | 8135 | 8135 | 12,715 ξ |
Wage Employment (=1) | −0.197 | |
(3.87) ** | ||
Generalized Residual | 0.791 | |
(5.42) ** | ||
Shocks (=1) | 0.388 | |
(8.82) ** | ||
Religion (1 = Christians) | −0.113 | |
(2.36) * | ||
Married = 1 | 0.621 | |
(9.54) ** | ||
Education = 1 | −1.420 | |
(16.10) ** | ||
Rural | 0.173 | |
(3.23) ** | ||
Age | 0.553 | |
(16.75) ** | ||
Age Squared | −0.005 | |
(12.21) ** | ||
Food-Budget Share | 1.775 | |
(13.27) ** | ||
Constant | −10.410 | |
(13.45) ** | ||
Selection Equation: | Ever Given Birth? (Probit Estimates) | |
Wage Employment | 0.208 | |
(3.69) ** | ||
Log (Household Total Landholding) | −0.126 | |
(3.89) ** | ||
Rent (2 = Urban) | −0.066 | |
(0.81) | ||
Shocks | 0.155 | |
(3.69) ** | ||
Religion (1 = Christian) | 0.004 | |
(0.09) | ||
Married (=1) | 1.417 | |
(31.97) ** | ||
Education (=1) | −0.280 | |
(2.90) ** | ||
Rural (=1) | 0.098 | |
(1.87) | ||
Age | 0.486 | |
(32.77) ** | ||
Age Squared | −0.006 | |
(25.99) ** | ||
Food-Budget Share | 1.042 | |
(8.89) ** | ||
Constant | −8.612 | |
(33.08) ** | ||
Mills | Lambda (same as in Table A1) | 0.769 |
(6.41) ** | ||
N | 12,715 (Censored = 4580) (Uncensored = 8135) |
Wage Employment (=1) | −0.141 | |
(3.85) ** | ||
Generalized Residual | 0.414 | |
(3.95) ** | ||
Shocks | 0.192 | |
(6.08) ** | ||
Religion (1 = Christian) | −0.061 | |
(1.78) | ||
Married | 0.351 | |
(7.50) ** | ||
Education | −0.704 | |
(11.14) ** | ||
Rural | 0.038 | |
(0.99) | ||
Age | 0.276 | |
(11.64) ** | ||
Age Squared | −0.003 | |
(8.52) ** | ||
Food-Budget Share | 0.953 | |
(9.92) ** | ||
Constant | −5.232 | |
(9.40) ** | ||
Selection Equation: | Ever Given Birth? (Probit Estimates) | |
0.208 | ||
Wage Employment | ||
(3.69) ** | ||
Log (Household Total Landholding) | −0.126 | |
(3.89) ** | ||
Rent (Urban) | −0.066 | |
(0.81) | ||
Shocks | 0.155 | |
(3.69) ** | ||
Religion | 0.004 | |
(0.09) | ||
Married | 1.417 | |
(31.97) ** | ||
Education | −0.280 | |
(2.90) ** | ||
Rural | 0.098 | |
(1.87) * | ||
Age | 0.486 | |
(32.77) ** | ||
Age Squared | −0.006 | |
(25.99) ** | ||
Food-Budget Share | 1.042 | |
(8.89) ** | ||
Constant | −8.612 | |
(33.08) ** | ||
Mills | Lambda (same as in Table A1 column 1) | 0.401 |
(4.59) ** | ||
N | 12,715 (Censored = 4580) (Uncensored = 8135) |
Wage Employment (=1) | −0.057 | |
(1.47) | ||
Generalized Residual | 0.377 | |
(3.40) ** | ||
Shocks | 0.196 | |
(5.86) ** | ||
Religion | −0.052 | |
(1.42) | ||
Married | 0.269 | |
(5.43) ** | ||
Education | −0.715 | |
(10.71) ** | ||
Rural | 0.135 | |
(3.32) ** | ||
Age | 0.276 | |
(11.01) ** | ||
(8.00) ** | ||
Food-Budget Share | 0.821 | |
(8.08) ** | ||
Constant | −5.177 | |
(8.79) ** | ||
Selection Equation: | Ever Given Birth? (Probit Estimates) | |
0.208 | ||
Wage Employment (=1) | ||
(3.69) ** | ||
Log (Household Total Landholding) | −0.126 | |
(3.89) ** | ||
Rent (Urban =1) | −0.066 | |
(0.81) | ||
Shocks (=1) | 0.155 | |
(3.69) ** | ||
Religion (1 = Christian) | 0.004 | |
(0.09) | ||
Married (=1) | 1.417 | |
(31.97) ** | ||
Education (=1) | −0.280 | |
(2.90) ** | ||
Rural (=1) | 0.098 | |
(1.87) * | ||
Age, Years | 0.486 | |
(32.77) ** | ||
Age Squared | −0.006 | |
(25.99) ** | ||
Food-Budget Share | 1.042 | |
(8.89) ** | ||
Constant | −8.612 | |
(33.08) ** | ||
Mills | Lambda (same as in Table A1 column 2) | 0.368 |
(3.97) ** | ||
N | 12,715 (Censured = 4580) (Uncensored = 8135) |
Appendix B. The Olsen Model, Augmented with a Generalized Residual (GR), Derived from Reduced-Form LPM
Variables | Male Births (1) | Female Births (2) | Total Births (3) | First Birth? (Yes = 1) Reduced−Form Probit (Marginal Effects) (4) | Wage Employment? (Yes = 1) Reduced−Form (LPM Estimates), (5) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Wage Employment (=1) | −0.14089 (3.92) ** | −0.0558 (1.43) * | −0.1967 (3.88) ** | 0.026 (3.70) ** | 0.0335 (4.72) ** |
Generalized Residual for Wage Employment (controls endogeneity) | −1.16 (3.61) | −1.16 (3.41) | −2.32 (5.14) | … | … |
Shocks (=1) | 0.185 (5.99) | 0.188 (5.79) | 0.373 (8.83) | 0.019 (3.69) | 0.018 (3.49) |
Religion (1 = Christians) | −0.058 (1.75) | −0.048 (1.35) | −0.107 (2.32) | 0.0005 (0.09) | −0.0012 (0.34) |
Married (=1) | −0.326 (6.22) | −0.239 (4.23) | 0.565 (7.48) | 0.173 (34.6) | 0.259 (36.3) |
Education (=1) | −0.695 (9.07) | −0.696 (8.68) | −1.39 (13.88) | −0.034 (2.67) | −0.066 (6.12) |
Rural (=1) | 0.057 (1.59) | 0.148 (3.91) | 0.206 (4.13) | 0.012 (1.88) | 0.011 (1.63) |
Age | 0.250 (12.3) | 0.254 (12.0) | 0.504 (18.4) | 0.059 (37.1) | 0.150 (52.9) |
Age Squared × (10−2) | −0.236 (8.40) | −0.240 (8.12) | −0.476 (12.4) | −0.075 (28.1) | −0.143 (43.0) |
Food-Budget Share | 0.928 (9.50) | 0.793 (7.80) | 1.72 (12.7) | 0.128 (8.94) | 0.209 (12.9) |
IMR for the First Birth, Derived From Heckit Probit (addresses selectity bias) | 0.405 (4.54) | 0.368 (4.95) | 0.773 (8.24) | … | … |
Log (Household Total Landholding) | − | − | − | −0.016 (3.90) ** | −0.021 (−4.69) |
Household Rent, Dummy | − | − | − | −0.008 (−0.81) | −0.002 (−0.20) |
Constant | −5.02 (9.49) | −5.09 (9.36) | −10.1 (14.1) | − | −1.54 |
R2/Pseudo R2 | 0.241 | 0.230 | 0.404 | 0.66 | 0.68 |
N | 8135 | 8135 | 8135 | 12,715 | 12,715 ξ |
Appendix C. Tests of Instruments Validity
- All Births:
- Sanderson–Windmeijer multivariate F test of excluded instruments; first stage regression
- F(2, 8124) = 55.38, p = 0.000.
- Correlation of instruments with error term is rejected, thus suggesting they are exogenous.
- Weak-instrument-robust inference
- Tests of joint significance of endogenous regressor, β1, in the main equation; second stage regression: Ho: β1 = 0 and orthogonality conditions are valid.
- Anderson–Rubin Wald test F(2, 8124) = 27.10 p = 0.000
- Anderson–Rubin Wald test Chi-sq(2) = 54.27 p = 0.000
- Stock–Wright LM S statistic Chi-sq(2) = 53.91 p = 0.000
- The hypothesis that instruments do not affect fertility via wage employment is rejected.
- Over-identification test of all instruments, second stage regression.
- Sargan statistic: 7.334, Chi-sq (1), p = 0.0068. (Over-identification is not rejected).
- Instrumented: wage employment (wage employment dummy, i.e., mother works for a wage).
- Included instruments: shocks, religion, married, education, rural age, agesq,
- Food-budget share.
- Excluded instruments: logland, rent-urban.
- Male Births:
- Sanderson–Windmeijer multivariate F test of excluded instruments; first stage regression
- F(2, 8124) = 55.38, p = 0.000
- Weak-instrument-robust inference
- Tests of joint significance of endogenous regressor, β1, in the main equation; second stage regression:
- Ho: β1 = 0 and orthogonality conditions are valid
- Anderson–Rubin Wald test F(2, 8124) = 16.76 p = 0.000
- Anderson–Rubin Wald test Chi-sq(2) = 33.37 p = 0.000
- Stock–Wright LM S statistic Chi-sq(2) = 33.43 p = 0.000
- Over-identification test of all instruments, second stage regression.
- Sargan statistic: 9.04, Chi-sq (1), p = 0.0027(Over-identification is not rejected).
- Instrumented: wage employment (wage employment dummy, i.e., mother works for a wage).Included instruments: shocks, religion, married, education, rural, age, agesq,
- food-budget share.
- Excluded instruments: logland, rent-urban.
- Female Births
- Sanderson–Windmeijer multivariate F test of excluded instruments; first stage regression
- F(2, 8124) = 55.38, p = 0.000
- Weak-instrument-robust inference
- Tests of joint significance of endogenous regressor, β1, in the main equation; second stage reg:
- Ho: β1 = 0 and orthogonality conditions are valid
- Anderson–Rubin Wald test F(2, 8124) = 9.41 p = 0.000
- Anderson–Rubin Wald test Chi-sq(2) = 19.85 p = 0.000
- Stock–Wright LM S statistic Chi-sq(2) = 18.81 p = 0.000
- Over-identification test of all instruments, second stage regression.
- Sargan statistic: 0.956, Chi-sq (1), p = 0.328. (Over-identification is rejected).
- Instrumented: wage employment (wage employment dummy, i.e., mother works for a wage). Included instruments: shocks, religion, married, education, rural, age, agesq,
- food-budget share.
- Excluded instruments: logland, rent-urban.
Appendix D. Tests for the Difference Between Regression Coefficients for Male and Female Births
Variables | Coefficient Estimates |
---|---|
Wage Employment (=1) | −0.0838 (1.52) |
Generalized Residual for Wage Employment, Wage Employment Dummy | 0.0373 (0.23) |
Shocks (=1) | −0.004 (0.08) |
Religion (1 = Christians) | −0.010 (0.849) |
Married (=1) | 0.082 (1.11) |
Education (=1) | 0.0109 (0.1000) |
Rural (=1) | −0.0970 (−1.69) |
Age | −0.0002 (−0.0100) |
Age Squared × (10−2) | −0.0019 (−0.04) |
Food-Budget Share | 0.1449 (0.363) |
IMR for the First Birth, Derived from Heckit Probit | 0.0330 (0.3000) |
Constant | −0.0547 (−0.07) |
R2 F(11, 8123), p = 0.395 | 0.001 1.05 |
N | 8135 |
Appendix E. Sample Statistics and Data Sources
Appendix E.1. Analytic Dataset
Variables | Observations | Mean | Sd Dev | Min | Max |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Wage Employment (=1) | 12,715 | 0.143 | 0.350 | 0 | 1 |
Female Births | 8135 | 1.83 | 1.53 | 0 | 11 |
Male births | 8135 | 1.86 | 1.45 | 0 | 10 |
All Births | 8135 | 3.69 | 2.27 | 0 | 16 |
Ever Given Birth? (=1) | 12,715 | 0.639 | 0.480 | 0 | 1 |
Any Severe Shocks (Drought/Floods)?, Yes | 12,715 | 0.724 | 0.447 | 0 | 1 |
Religion (1 = Christian) | 12,715 | 0.219 | 0.4133 | 0 | 1 |
Married? (=1) | 12,715 | 0.467 | 0.499 | 0 | 1 |
Education (=1) | 12,715 | 0.950 | 0.217 | 0 | 1 |
Age, Years | 12,715 | 28.54 | 10.2 | 15 | 59 |
Age Squared | 12,715 | 918.83 | 632.47 | 225 | 3481 |
Rural | 12,715 | 0.771 | 0.420 | 0 | 1 |
Food-Budget Share | 12,715 | 0.604 | 0.162 | 0 | 0.99 |
Inverse Mills Ratio (First Birth Probit) | 12,715 | 0.766 | 0.922 | 0.0004 | 3.49 |
Generalized Residual (Employment, Probit) | 12,715 | 1.684 | 0.4003 | 0.818 | 3.889 |
Generalized Residual (Employment, LPM) | 12,715 | 0.171 | 0.077 | −0.371 | 0.400 |
Appendix E.2. Other Data Sources
- The Female Labor Force Participation Rates are available from the International Labor Organization (ILO).
- Total Fertility Rates (TFR) are from 2020 Kenya Demographic and Health
- Surveys, Kenya Bureau of Statistics reports of 1989, 1993, 1998, 2003, 2008–2009,
- 2014, and 2022. The 2022 KNBS report has a summary of this information.
- Kenya Integrated Household Budget Survey (KIHBS), 2015–2016, was augmented with the Kenya Continuous Household Survey (KCHS), starting in 2021; however, the KCHS data was not used because it is limited to a small sub-sample of the original households interviewed in 2015.
- Administrative data on FLFP (%) and fertility (children)
Year | FLFP | Fertility |
2022 | 72.527 | 3.4 |
2021 | 72.597 | |
2020 | 71.706 | |
2019 | 72.39 | |
2018 | 72.189 | |
2017 | 71.994 | |
2016 | 71.812 | |
2015 | 71.784 | |
2014 | 71.75 | 3.9 |
2009 | 4.6 | |
2003 | 4.9 | |
1998 | 4.7 | |
1993 | 5.4 | |
1989 | 6.7 |
Appendix F. Hybrid Fertility Model
References
- Aassve, A., Engelhardt, H., Francavilla, F., Kedir, A. M., Kim, J., Mealli, F., Mencarini, L., Pudney, S., & Prskawetz, A. (2006). Poverty and fertility dynamics: A comparative analysis. Population Review, 45(2), 1–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Adair, L., Bisgrove, E., Gultiano, S., & Guilkey, D. (2002). Effect of childbearing on Filipino women’s work hours and earnings. Journal of Population Economics, 15(4), 625–645. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- African Economic Research Consortium (AERC). (2024). Annual report, 2023–2024. Middle East Bank Towers. Available online: https://publication.aercafricalibrary.org/items/8eeb4117-7fcb-468a-b368-03b291604900 (accessed on 29 September 2025).
- Ajayi, K. F., & Koussoubé, E. (Eds.). (2024). Pathways to prosperity for adolescent girls in Africa. World Bank. [Google Scholar]
- Alatas, V., Banerjee, A., Hanna, R., Olken, B., & Tobias, J. (2012). Targeting the poor: Evidence from a field experiment in Indonesia. American Economic Review, 102(4), 1206–1240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Angrist, J., & Evans, W. (1998). Children and their parents’ labor supply: Evidence from exogenous variation in family size. American Economic Review, 88(3), 450–477. [Google Scholar]
- Barasa, L., & Kiiru, J. (2023). The Digital economy and youth employment in Africa. In G. Onyango (Ed.), Public policy and technological transformations in Africa: Nurturing policy entrepreneurship, policy tools and citizen participation (pp. 161–182). Palgrave Macmillan. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barrett, S., Dasgupta, A., Dasgupta, P., Adger, W. N., Anderies, J., Bergh, J. v. D., Bledsoe, C., Bongaarts, J., Carpenter, S., Chapin, F. S., Crépin, A., Daily, G., Ehrlich, P., Folke, C., Kautsky, N., Lambin, E. F., Levin, S. A., Mäler, K., Naylor, R., … Wilen, J. (2020). Social dimensions of fertility behavior and consumption patterns in the Anthropocene. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 117(12), 6300–6307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Becker, G. S. (1960). An economic analysis of fertility. In G. B. Roberts (Ed.), Demographic and economic change in developed countries (pp. 209–240). Columbia University Press. Available online: http://www.nber.org/books/univ60-2 (accessed on 29 September 2025).
- Becker, G. S. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal, 75(299), 493–517. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Becker, G. S. (1981). A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Becker, G. S., & Lewis, H. G. (1973). On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. Journal of Political Economy, 81(2), S279–S288. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beguy, D. (2009). The impact of female employment on fertility in Dakar (Senegal) and Lomé (Togo). Demographic Research, 20, 97–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Blau, F. D., & Kahn, L. M. (2000). Gender differences in pay. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4), 75–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bloom, D. E., Canning, D., Fink, G., & Finlay, J. E. (2009). Fertility, female labor force participation, and the demographic dividend. Journal of Economic Growth, 14(2), 79–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bloom, N. (2024). Working from home is powering productivity. Finance & Development Magazine, September, International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Boushey, H. (2016). Finding time: The economics of work-life conflict. Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Brewster, K. L., & Rindfuss, R. R. (2000). Fertility and women’s employment in industrialized nations. Annual Review of Sociology, 26(1), 271–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Brown, C., Ravallion, M., & van de Walle, D. (2018). A poor means test? Econometric targeting in Africa. Journal of Development Economics, 134, 109–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cáceres-Delpiano, J. (2012). Can we still learn something from the relationship between fertility and mother’s employment? Evidence from developing countries. Demography, 49(1), 151–174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chuard, C. (2020). Womb at work: The missing impact of maternal employment on newborn health. Journal of Health Economics, 73, 102342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chun, H., & Oh, J. (2002). An instrumental variable estimate of the effect of fertility on the labour force participation of married women. Applied Economics Letters, 9(10), 631–634. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Correll, S. J., Benard, S., & Paik, I. (2007). Getting a job: Is there a motherhood penalty? American Journal of Sociology, 112(5), 1297–1339. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Crenshaw, K. (1989). Demarginalizing the intersection of race and sex: A black feminist critique of antidiscrimination doctrine, feminist theory and antiracist politics. University of Chicago Legal Forum, 1989(1), 8. [Google Scholar]
- Davis, A. (1981). The approaching obsolescence of housework: A working-class perspective. In A. Davis (Ed.), Women, race and class (Chapter 13). The Women’s Press Ltd. [Google Scholar]
- DiPietro, J., & Voegtline, K. (2017). The gestational foundation of sex differences in development and vulnerability. Neuroscience, 342, 4–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Di Renzo, G. C., Rosati, A., Sarti, R. D., Cruciani, L., & Cutuli, A. M. (2007). Does fetal sex affect pregnancy outcome? Gender Medicine, 4(1), 19–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Donald, A., Goldstein, M., Koroknay-Palicz, T., & Sage, M. (2024). The fertility impacts of development programs (Policy Research Working Paper 10848). World Bank.
- Favero, L. P. L., Belfiore, P., dos Santos, M. A., & Souza, R. F. (2020). Overdisp: A stata (and Mata) package for direct detection of overdispersion in Poisson and negative binomial regression models. Statistics, Optimization & Information Computing, 8(3), 773–789. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Follett, L., & Henderson, H. (2023). A hybrid approach to targeting social assistance. Journal of Development Economics, 160, 103002. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Francavilla, F., & Giannelli, G. C. (2011). Does family planning help the employment of women? The case of India. Journal of Asian Economics, 22(5), 412–426. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fukuda, M., Fukuda, K., Shimizu, T., & Moller, H. (1998). Decline in sex ratio at birth after Kobe earthquake. Human Reproduction, 13(8), 2321–2322. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Giannelli, G. C. (1996). Women’s transitions in the labour market: A competing risks analysis on German panel data. Journal of Population Economics, 9(3), 287–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goldin, C. (2021). Career and family: Women’s century-long journey toward equity. Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gourieroux, C., Monfort, A., Renault, E., & Trognon, A. (1987). Generalised residuals. Journal of Econometrics, 34(1–2), 5–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hajdu, T. (2024). In utero shocks and health at birth: The distorting effect of fetal losses. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 87(3), 586–612. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hajdu, T., & Hajdu, G. (2023). Climate change and the mortality of the unborn. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 118, 102771. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hald, A. S., & Ozcan, B. (2021). The effects of unemployment on fertility. Advances in Life Course Research, 49, 100401. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hamoudi, A., & Nobles, J. (2014). Do daughters really cause divorce? stress, pregnancy, and family composition. Demography, 51(4), 1423–1449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Harrington, E., & Kahn, M. E. (2025). Has the rise of work-from-home reduced the motherhood penalty in the labor market? (NBER Working Paper No. w34147). University of Virginia. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=5395433 (accessed on 29 September 2025).
- He, X., & Zhu, R. (2016). Fertility and female labour force participation: Causal evidence from urban China. The Manchester School, 84(5), 664–674. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Heath, R. (2017). Fertility at work: Children and women’s labor market outcomes in urban Ghana. Journal of Development Economics, 126, 190–214. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Heath, R., & Mobarak, A. M. (2015). Manufacturing growth and the lives of Bangladeshi women. Journal of Development Economics, 115, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Heckman, J. J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kenya National Bureau of Statistics. (2023). Kenya demographic and health survey 2022. Ministry of Planning and National Development. Available online: https://statistics.knbs.or.ke/nada/index.php/catalog/13 (accessed on 29 September 2025).
- Kiiru, J. (2021). Taming predatory lending for a resilient financial system and economic growth. University of Nairobi, Mimeo. [Google Scholar]
- Kornstad, T., & Rønsen, M. (2018). Women’s wages and fertility revisited evidence from Norway. European Journal of Population, 34(4), 491–518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kraemer, S. (2000). The fragile male. BMJ, 321, 1609. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Livingston, G. (2013). The odds that you will give birth to a boy or girl depend on where in the world you live. Pew Research Center. [Google Scholar]
- Manca, T. (2025). ‘Vaccines protect both you and your newborn’: A discourse analysis of risk and uncertainty in information about vaccination in pregnancy. Social Science & Medicine, 364, 117526. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McCarthy, M. M. (2019). Stress during pregnancy: Fetal males pay the price. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 116(48), 23877–23879. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Morgan, A. K., Anima, P. A., Wadei, B., & Katey, D. (2025). Addressing stigma and discrimination towards school re-entry of teenage mothers in Ghana. International Journal of Adolescence and Youth, 30(1), 2441322. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mutuma, S., Barasa, S. F., Mwatha, R. G., Mwongeli-Musau, S., Musyoka-Kamere, I., Omondi, F., Otiato, J. W., Kimaru, W., & Mohammed, O. (n.d.). Women in management and leadership in the national government public service, Kenya. Kenyatta University. Available online: https://weehub.ku.ac.ke/women-in-management-and-l (accessed on 29 September 2025).
- Myong, S., Park, J., & Yi, J. (2020). Social norms and fertility. Journal of the European Economic Association, 19(5), 2429–2466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Navara, K. J. (2010). Programming of offspring sex ratios by maternal stress in humans: Assessment of physiological mechanisms using a comparative approach. Journal of Comparative Physiology B, 180(6), 785–796. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Nawata, K. (1994). Estimation of sample selection bias models by the maximum likelihood estimator and Heckman’s two-step estimator. Economics Letters, 45(1), 33–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Novelli, M., Cazzola, A., Angeli, A., & Pasquini, L. (2021). Fertility intentions in times of rising economic uncertainty: Evidence from Italy from a gender perspective. Social Indicators Research, 154(1), 257–284. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Olsen, R. J. (1980). A least squares correction for selectivity bias. Econometrica, 48(7), 1815. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Orzack, S. H. (2016). Old and new ideas about the human sex ratio. Significance, 13(1), 24–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Orzack, S. H., Stubblefield, J. W., Akmaev, V. R., Colls, P., Munné, S., Scholl, T., Steinsaltz, D., & Zuckerman, J. E. (2015). The human sex ratio from conception to birth. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 112(16), E2102–E2111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Petchesky, R. P. (1995). The body as property: A feminist re-vision. In F. D. Ginsburg, & R. Rapp (Eds.), Conceiving the new world order: The global politics of reproduction. University of California Press. [Google Scholar]
- Rammohan, A., & Whelan, S. (2005). Child care and female employment decisions. Australian Journal of Labor Economics, 8(2), 203–225. [Google Scholar]
- Schacht, R., Tharp, D., & Smith, K. R. (2019). Sex ratios at birth vary with environmental harshness but not maternal condition. Science Reports, 9(1), 9066. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schulman, J. D., & Karabinus, D. S. (2005). Scientific aspects of preconception gender selection. Reproductive BioMedicine Online, 10(Suppl. S1), 111–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schultz, T. P. (1973). A preliminary survey of economic analyses of fertility. American Economic Review, 63(2), 71–78. [Google Scholar]
- Schultz, T. P. (2002). Why governments should invest more to educate girls. World Development, 30(2), 207–225. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schultz, T. P. (2005). Fertility and income. In A. Banerjee, R. Benabou, & D. Mookherjee (Eds.), Understanding poverty (Chapter 9). Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Stuart, G.-B., Spears, D., & Visaria, L. (2021). Low fertility with low female labor force participation in South India, extended abstract. In PAA 2022 annual meeting. PAA. Available online: https://ipc2021.popconf.org/abstracts/210596 (accessed on 29 September 2025).
- Tiwari, C., Goli, S., & Rammohan, A. (2022). Reproductive burden and its impact on female labor market outcomes in India: Evidence from longitudinal analyses. Population Research and Policy Review, 41(6), 2493–2529. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- UNFPA. (2012). Sex Imbalances at birth: Current trends, consequences and policy implications. United Nations, UNFPA Asia and the Pacific Region Office. [Google Scholar]
- Walker, M. W., Shanka, N., Miguel, E., & Egger, D. (2025). Can cash transfers save lives? Evidence from a large-scale experiment in Kenya (NBER Working Paper No. 34152). National Bureau of Economic Research. Available online: https://www.nber.org/papers/w34152 (accessed on 29 September 2025).
- Wolfolds, S. E., & Siegel, J. (2019). Misaccounting for endogeneity: The peril of relying on the Heckman two-step method without a valid instrument. Strategic Management Journal, 40(3), 432–462. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wooldridge, J. M. (2015). Control function methods in applied econometrics. The Journal of Human Resources, 50(2), 420–445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yi, H., Yang, M., Tang, H., & Lin, M. (2022). Risk factors of pregnancy failure in infertile patients undergoing assisted reproductive technology. International Journal of General Medicine, 15, 8807–8817. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Younger, S. (2006). Labor market activities and fertility. Cornell University. [Google Scholar]
- Yu, X., & Liang, J. (2022). Social norms and fertility intentions: Evidence from China. Frontiers in Psychology, 13, 947134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zayed, N. M., Rashid, M., Darwish, S., Alam, F. E., Nitsenko, V., & Islam, K. M. A. (2022). The power of compensation system (CS) on employee satisfaction (ES): The mediating role of employee motivation (EM). Economies, 10(11), 290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zipfel, C. (2022). The demand side of Africa’s demographic transition: Desired fertility, wealth, and jobs. Stockholm School of Economics, and STICERD—Economic Organisation and Public Policy Discussion Papers Series 71, Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines, LSE, UK. Available online: https://sticerd.lse.ac.uk/dps/eopp/eopp71.pdf (accessed on 29 September 2025).
Variables | Number of Males Born Alive | Number of Females Born Alive | Total Number of Children Born Alive | Ever Given Birth? (Yes = 1) |
---|---|---|---|---|
Wage Employment (=1) | −0.174 (4.88) ** | −0.087 (2.25) ** | −0.261 (5.18) ** | 0.037 (5.01) ** |
Shocks | ||||
(1 = Severe Droughts/Floods) | 0.185 (5.98) ** | 0.189 (5.82) ** | 0.373 (8.80) ** | 0.017 (3.21) ** |
Religion | ||||
(1 = Christians) | −0.068 (1.81) * | −0.051 (1.41) * | −0.111 (2.40) | −0.003 (0.57) |
Married (1 = Yes) | ||||
0.252 (8.02) ** | 0.178 (5.31) ** | 0.430 (9.5) ** | 0.260 (36.4) ** | |
Educated (1 = Yes) | ||||
−0.776 (11.3) ** | −0.780 (10.9) ** | −1.56 (16.3) ** | −0.064 (1.90) * | |
Rural (=1) | ||||
0.102 (3.02) ** | 0.193 (5.53) ** | 0.294 (6.43) ** | 0.010 (1.69) * | |
Age, Years | ||||
0.152 (11.82) ** | 0.163 (12.0) ** | 0.314 (17.6) ** | 0.118 (63.0) ** | |
Age Squared × 10−2 | ||||
−0.111 (5.71) ** | −0.123 (5.93) ** | −0.234 (8.56) ** | 0.151 (53.3) ** | |
Food-Budget Share | ||||
0.740 (9.36) ** | 0.762 (9.52) ** | 1.61 (12.4) ** | 0.222 (13.9) ** | |
Constant | ||||
−2.07 (9.56) ** | −2.29 (10.1) ** | −4.36 (14.3) ** | −1.57 (54.7) ** | |
R-Squared | 0.237 | 0.227 | 0.398 | 0.683 |
N | 8135 | 8135 | 12,715 | 8135 |
Heckit/CF Estimates (t-Statistics in Parentheses) | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Dependent Variables (Intensive Margin, Structural Models | Ever Given Birth? (Yes), Extensive Margin, Reduced-Form Models | ||||
Total Babies Born Alive (CF/Heckit) | Babies Born Alive, Males (CF/Heckit) | Babies Born Alive, Females (CF/Heckit) | LPM Reduced Form-Estimates a | Probit Marginal Effects: Reduced- Form Estimates a | |
Female Wage Employment (=1) t-tests | −0.197 (3.87) ** | −0.141 (3.85) ** | −0.057 (1.47) * | 0.034 (4.72) ** | 0.026 (3.70) ** |
χ2/F tests | χ2(2) = 28.61 * (p < 0.05) | χ2(2) = 28.4 ** (p < 0.000) | χ2(2) = 15.77 (p < 0.000) | F (1) = 20.5 (p < 0.000) | χ2(2) = 11.87 (p < 0.000) |
Estimates of births for a cohort of 1000 women, given prob. of first-birth = 0.026. | (−0.197 × 0.026) = −5.122 | (−0.140 × 0.026) = −3.640 | (−0.057 × 0.026) = −1.482 | ||
N = 8135 | N = 8135 | N = 8135 | N = 12,715 ξ |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2025 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Mwabu, G.; Ban, R.; Mueni Kiiru, J.; Mwatha, R.G.; Schultz, T.P. Female Wage Employment and Fertility in Kenya. Economies 2025, 13, 298. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13100298
Mwabu G, Ban R, Mueni Kiiru J, Mwatha RG, Schultz TP. Female Wage Employment and Fertility in Kenya. Economies. 2025; 13(10):298. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13100298
Chicago/Turabian StyleMwabu, Germano, Radu Ban, Joy Mueni Kiiru, Regina Gathoni Mwatha, and T. Paul Schultz. 2025. "Female Wage Employment and Fertility in Kenya" Economies 13, no. 10: 298. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13100298
APA StyleMwabu, G., Ban, R., Mueni Kiiru, J., Mwatha, R. G., & Schultz, T. P. (2025). Female Wage Employment and Fertility in Kenya. Economies, 13(10), 298. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13100298