Next Article in Journal
Analysis of Success Factors, Benefits, and Challenges of Issuing Green Bonds in Lithuania
Next Article in Special Issue
An Empirical Study of Trade in Goods between China and Brazil: Analysis of Competitiveness and Complementarity
Previous Article in Journal
Time-Varying Elasticity of Cyclically Adjusted Primary Balance and Effect of Fiscal Consolidation on Domestic Government Debt in South Africa
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Nexus between Crime Rates, Poverty, and Income Inequality: A Case Study of Indonesia
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Latin America and the Caribbean’s Productivity: The Role of Pro-Market Policies, Institutions, Infrastructure, and Natural Resource Endowments

by
Néstor Le Clech
1,* and
Juan Carlos Guevara-Pérez
2
1
Department of Economics and Business, National University of Quilmes, Roque Sáenz Peña 352, Bernal B1876, Buenos Aires, Argentina
2
Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Zaragoza, 50005 Zaragoza, Spain
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2023, 11(5), 142; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11050142
Submission received: 16 March 2023 / Revised: 3 May 2023 / Accepted: 6 May 2023 / Published: 10 May 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Nexus between Politics and Economics in the Emerging Countries - II)

Abstract

:
This paper examines the role played by pro-market policies, institutions, natural resources, and infrastructure on the total factor productivity (TFP) of twenty Latin American and Caribbean countries over the period 2000–2018. In estimating the TFP, we use the Färe-Primont index based on DEA. We have verified cointegration and estimated the long-run parameters by the grouped-mean FMOLS estimator. For measuring the impact of institutions, natural resources, and infrastructure, we have used the Productive Capacity Indexes of UNCTAD. We found a positive effect of all these variables on the TFP. Natural resources and energy play the most important role. Followed by information and communication technology and institutions quality. Transport infrastructure has played a minor role. The pro-market policies have been measured by the Fraser Institute indexes. We verified the positive impact of pro-market policies in the area of international trade and financial openness through six different variables. Finally, we considered three areas to measure the impact of domestic regulations and policies; credit, labor and business. We could verify a positive impact of credit and business pro-market policies, but we did not get statistically significant results from the labor regulations index.

1. Introduction

In a recent article, Goldfajn, Martínez and Valdés asserted: “…The main risk in Latin America at present is that economic populism will gain ground and policymakers will discard the Washington Consensus policies altogether. That would be a mistake” (Goldfajn et al. 2021, p. 130). A sharp conclusion, for which we provide new evidence.
During the 1990s, there was broad agreement in favor of liberal reforms in Latin America and the Caribbean. However, these ideas began to unravel, and at the beginning of the XXI century, several Latin America and Caribbean (LAC) countries changed their direction towards statist and socialist development models. Rodrik (2018) attributes these shifts toward (left-wing) populism to the economic effects of globalization. Moreover, for the last two decades, there has been an increase in LAC countries that have been under some sort of autocratic leadership; these leaders consist of executives with overtly authoritarian tendencies (Velasco Guachalla et al. 2021).
These changes were not uniform. In some countries, there has been some respect for individual freedom and some degree of economic discipline. On the contrary, other governments have devolved into authoritarian systems and unstable economic systems. As Levitsky and Roberts (2011) have pointed out, in those countries where there exist consolidated democratic regimes and party systems, some moderate liberal policy has prevailed to some degree. Contrarily, in other countries where there has been a crisis of democratic regimes and party systems, governments turned towards heterodoxy policy or directly to deepest statism.
Thus, despite initial agreement regarding the potential of these liberal reforms, as soon as these began—in the beginning and mid-1990s—several economic crises affected the region1. This has stirred some controversy and criticisms about their benefits (De Gregorio and Lee 2004; Goldfajn et al. 2021). Although the results were inconclusive, there was some research done that attempted to analyze the outcome of those reforms on economic growth (Easterly et al. 1997; Lora and Barrera 1998; Fajnzylber and Lederman 1999; Escaith and Morley 2000; Fernández-Arias and Montiel 2001; Correa 2002; Bandeira and García 2002; Chong and Zanforlin 2004; De Gregorio and Lee 2004; Santiago et al. 2020; Azam 2022, amongst others).
Besides the earlier studies referenced above, little attention has been paid to this topic during the last two decades, except for two recent works by Santiago et al. (2020) and Azam (2022). Moreover, as Égert (2016) has pointed out; there is little empirical evidence of the impact of structural policies and institutions on aggregate productivity. Even more, to the best of our knowledge, no study has estimated the impact of these policies on the region’s productivity through econometrics techniques during the period of analysis proposed.
Therefore, a riveting question remains still valid in the region; are pro-market policies good economic institutions? To put it differently, can liberal policies be the key to LAC’s development? Some studies, such as Doucouliagos and Ulubasoglu (2004), found strong evidence of a positive effect of economic freedom on total factor productivity (TFP). However, is this the case in the LAC region? These questions are not trivial, and they are part of the current debate throughout the LA region.
In addition, there is some disagreement about the channels through which the institution’s influence on economic growth is manifested and the magnitude of its impact (Bluhm and Szirmai 2012). For example, some studies analyzed the influence of institutions on output (or output per capita) (Rodrik et al. 2004; Siddiqui and Ahmed 2013). Other authors examine the relationship between institutions, foreign direct investment, and domestic investment (Fukumi and Nishijima 2010; Farla et al. 2016) or between institutions and international competitiveness (Buitrago and Barbosa Camargo 2021), or that of Arora and De (2020), who integrate institutional economics with stakeholder theory, to examine the environmental sustainability practices in Latin America.
Although there are even an increasing number of works that have paid attention to the relationship between institutions and productivity (Hall and Jones 1999; Keita 2017; Kim and Loayza 2019), this relationship has not been widely analyzed. However, this last approach appears to be the most promising research channel for explaining the differences among countries since most of the cross-country variation in growth rates is explained by TFP (Easterly and Levine 2001). Furthermore, the pioneering work by Lora and Barrera (1997), which investigated the channels through which the impact of the reforms was produced in the LAC region, concluded that the main element had been the effect of these measures on total factor productivity. Hence, this is the approach that the present study will adopt, i.e., measuring the impact of pro-market policies and other key determinants on TFP2.
Several works have estimated and evaluated the TFP performance of the region. In general, those works have concluded that the main problem which explains the failure in the development of the region is the drawback in achieving a sustainable catching-up process, i.e., the lack of economic convergence. Even more remarkably, their analysis suggests that the TFP stagnation is due to institutional problems, which slows down the adoption of better and more efficient technologies (Cole et al. 2004; Daude and Fernández-Arias 2010; Fernández-Arias 2017; Fernández-Arias and Fernández-Arias 2021). Nonetheless, none of these works measured the impact of these determinants through econometric techniques.
Thus, this paper aims to contribute to the actual debate by analyzing the effect of different policy areas and other main determinants on the TFP, trying to identify whether pro-market policies have had a positive impact on TFP in the LAC region. Thereby, we will analyze five main policy areas; freedom to trade internationally, freedom of capital movements, credit market regulations, labor market regulations, and business regulations.
We measure the pro-market policy effects by nine indicators from the Fraser Institute indexes. We also include in our model the use of the Productive Capacity Indexes by UNCTAD considering five indicators; natural resource endowments, energy and information and communication technology availability, transport infrastructure and institutional quality.3
To carry out this analysis, we propose two innovations; the first one is to estimate the TFP through Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) techniques and the Färe-Primont index (FPI), which is an additive, multiplicative and primal index (O’Donnell 2018). This means that it allows for multi-lateral and multi-temporal comparisons and that it is an economically ideal index. As far as we are aware, this is the first study using this approach in calculating the TFP for the LAC countries.
The second innovation is to measure the effect of the policy orientation (pro-market policies) and other key determinants estimating the effects on the TFP through cointegration techniques. Finally, it is worth noting that the period of the analysis is long enough to capture the effect of these determinants. Given the data restrictions and the aim of this paper, we will conduct our analyses for twenty LAC countries from the period 2000–2018.4
This article is organized as follows: after the introduction, Section 2 provides a theoretical framework. The model, variables and data are described in Section 3, and the methodology and results are shown in Section 4. Section 5 presents the discussion. Finally, Section 6 presents the concluding remarks and policy recommendations.

2. Theoretical Framework

As TFP is the main concern of this study, we will first consider some relevant determinants of the TFP in order to establish our basic model. In this regard, the approach that this paper will follow is based on Isaksson (2007); Kim et al. (2016); Kim and Loayza (2019), who have made an extensive review of the literature about the key determinants of TFP. They have identified, in general, six main components of productivity: (a) education, (b) innovation and technology, (c) resource endowment, (d) infrastructure, (e) market efficiency, and (f) institutions and policies.
Education has been proposed as a key determinant of productivity gains since it gives knowledge and develops skills, raising the capacities of the labor factor. Both innovation and human capital are important to disseminate and promote the incorporation of existing technologies and the development of new ones. However, we are not going to include any education variable in the model because it will be included in the productivity calculation as a production factor (see next section). Nor will we consider innovation due to the difficulties in measuring it and the lack of quality data.5
Natural resource endowments include; natural resources (renewables and non-renewables) and energy availability. Physical infrastructure considers; transport, information and communication technologies. These areas support and facilitate general economic activity (Kim and Loayza 2019). However, based on the “natural resource curse” hypothesis (NRCH), natural resource and energy endowments can be a cause of slowing down economic growth.
Nonetheless, both are important growth drivers for the LAC economies (Kristjanpoller et al. 2016; Le and Bao 2019; Zeeshan et al. 2020). The main evidence on the LAC region seems to contradict the NRCH since several works found no evidence that supports this hypothesis (Haber and Menaldo 2012; Blanco and Grier 2012; Toscani 2017; Papyrakis and Pellegrini 2019; Azam 2022).6
Infrastructure is another key area for economic development since it has some spillover effects that positively affect productivity (Hulten and Schwab 2000). In particular, the evidence for transport infrastructure indicates a positive effect on productivity and economic growth (Kim and Loayza 2019). It reduces fixed costs of production and promotes investments in new plants, which in turn boosts productivity (Bougheas et al. 2000; Agénor 2013). It can even raise the productivity of agriculture and promote new opportunities for non-farm businesses at the regional level (UNCTAD 2006).7
ICT affects productivity through a variety of channels (Lugones et al. 2007). It can produce a reduction in transaction costs or improve education and labor skills. For instance, Jayakar and Park (2013) have shown that those countries with wide broadband availability have experienced higher economic growth and enjoyed lower unemployment rates. Its impact at the firm level can be critical since ICT upgrades firms by improving data processing and communications, which facilitate decision-making, reduce transaction costs, and make the organization more efficient (Forman and van Zeebroeck 2012; Cardona et al. 2013; Grazzi and Jung 2016).
In general, it is expected a positive effect from ICT on productivity e.g., Cardona et al. (2013) have pointed out that the empirical evidence overwhelmingly proved this positive relationship. This conclusion has been confirmed for LAC economies by Grazzi and Jung (2016).
Market efficiency, in this context, requires a short definition. Kim et al. (2016, p. 3) define it as: “…the effectiveness and timeliness with which capital and labor are allocated through the constant renewal of businesses across sectors”. Regarding this, Hall and Jones (1999) have pointed out that social infrastructure and the misallocation effect play the most important role in the TFP of an economy. Here is where policy orientation plays a key role since the most important misallocation effect is due to social infrastructure inefficiencies.
Some earlier works, such as those of Easterly et al. (1997); Fajnzylber and Lederman (1999); Fernández-Arias and Montiel (2001); Bandeira and García (2002); Chong and Zanforlin (2004); De Gregorio and Lee (2004), concluded that policy reforms—or the institutional quality—resulted in a positive impact on LA’s growth. Despite everything, some researchers still have a skeptical opinion about those same results (Lora and Barrera 1998; Escaith and Morley 2000; Correa 2002). Nonetheless, it is worth mentioning that the period those works have analyzed is probably not wide enough to catch the full effects of these reforms.
A more recent study by Santiago et al. (2020) has covered a larger period than previous studies (1995–2015), including twenty-four LAC economies. It measured the effects of globalization and economic freedom on economic growth through an autoregressive distributed lag econometric model. Their results indicate that the social and economic dimensions of globalization have had a positive impact on economic growth, whilst the political dimension of it has not had any significant effect. The study has also found evidence of a negative impact of economic freedom on economic growth measured by the aggregated index of freedom of Heritage.
On the other hand, Azam (2022) studied fourteen LA countries over the period 2002–2018 using three indicators of World Governance Indicators from the World Bank; Corruption, Political Stability, and Government Effectiveness. The estimations were run by two techniques: panel autoregressive distributed lag and pooled mean group. From this work, it can be concluded that good governance is critical for boosting economic growth.
In general, institutions and policies affect economic potential. That is the reason for having ‘good’ institutions (North 1990; Hall and Jones 1999; Acemoglu et al. 2005). Moreover, institutional differences explain most of the differences in gross domestic product per capita among countries (Bluhm and Szirmai 2012).8
All the same, nowadays, there is an important consensus that the quality of institutions is crucial for economic growth, and the evidence is substantial. For instance, Bluhm and Szirmai (2012), who have made an extensive review of these issues, stated: that institutional differences explain most of the differences in gross domestic product per capita (GDPPC) among countries. Thus, seen differences in economic institutions are the root cause of differences in economic development (Acemoglu et al. 2005). As Rodrik et al. (2004, p. 135) have asserted: “the quality of institutions trumps everything else”.
Here it is important to differentiate between institutions as a general concept, economic institutions, and policies. These are concepts that are closely related, and the distinction between them can be murky (Rodrik et al. 2004). Good institutions can be thought of as a social framework that is the result of a long-term process that involves historical, cultural, and religious issues, amongst others.
Economic institutions include matters such as the legal system, government integrity, and basic civil rights, amongst others. This is a similar distinction to that proposed by Acemoglu and Robinson (2012) between economic institutions and political institutions. For these authors, economic institutions include property rights and law, freedom to contract and exchange, etc. Similarly, Easterly (2005) makes a distinction between institutions and policies. Economic policies can be thought of as a flow variable that affects contemporaneous economic efficiency.
Economic policies affect economic efficiency mainly through the misallocation effect. Regarding this, Hall and Jones (1999) posited that social infrastructure and the misallocation effect play the most important role in the productivity of one economy. Furthermore, Jones (2016) has claimed that misallocation provides one of the most important explanations for understanding the huge distortions observed in poor economies and their TFP differences. In that way, efficiency is strongly affected by economic policies, and it can be seen as a ‘flow variable’ identified by the contemporaneous policies that a government implements. In other words, these are part of the rules governing the economic system (Lloyd and Lee 2018).
The effect of economic institutions and economic policies on the private sector is critical since those policies that encourage investment positively impact TFP (Isaksson 2007). Furthermore, entrepreneurship potential is crucially affected by both economic institutions and policies. Both can contribute to boosting private investment, raising employment, and motivating innovations. Furthermore, if the policies generate incentives for entrepreneurship, the number of firms will increase, enhancing competition and improving the efficiency and productivity of the economy (Gnangnon 2020).
Outward-oriented policies have a substantial impact on productivity. Alcalá and Ciccone (2004) have posited that the benefits of international trade are manifested through gains in TFP. There is three channel through which exports growth affect productivity; (a) specialization, which raises productivity and product quality, (b) economies of scale, due to the size of the market; and (c) technological change, which is caused by the competition that exporters face at international markets (Burinskiene 2012).
Regarding imports, the positive impact of importing on productivity is stated by the learning-by-importing hypothesis. The hypothesis states that firms can take advantage of global specialization by using forefront technology inputs. Here international technology diffusion is the key vehicle for technology transfer (Wagner 2012). In addition, firms may improve productivity by using a higher quality of foreign inputs and by specializing in activities where they have strengths. Furthermore, technology embodied in inputs and capital goods brings about a catching-up process that produces improvements in TFP (Coe et al. 2009; Haider et al. 2021).
Financial and capital freedom is also important since it can provide funding to support economic activity and improve technological capabilities. It also enhances efficiency and is an important driver of technology transfer. Moreover, FDI is a key determinant of natural resource production and energy consumption, as well as an important promotor of financial development and economic growth in the LAC region (Zeeshan et al. 2020).
However, whilst trade liberalization may promote technology and knowledge diffusion, this transmission might be inhibited by a lack of absorptive capacity (Isaksson 2007). This can be due to domestic regulations or insufficient labor and entrepreneurship capacities. The negative effect of domestic regulations is an old problem in the LAC region, e.g., Cole et al. (2004) posited that Latin America’s TFP gap was mainly accounted for by inefficient production, where international and domestic competitive barriers were the main reason.
Strong domestic regulations and red tape can reduce the entrance of new firms, as well as affect the optimal resource allocation, having a pervasive impact on the innovation process, which in turn, decreases productivity at the aggregate level (Nicoletti and Scarpetta 2003; Bouis et al. 2011; Andrews and Criscuolo 2013; Haltiwanger et al. 2014; Andrews and Cingano 2014).
This effect is more evident in small and medium-sized firms, which are negatively affected by market regulations and labor legislation (Isaksson 2007). Similarly, Égert (2016) found that anticompetitive regulations negatively impact TFP, while greater openness results in higher TFP. This study concludes that better institutions combined with lower barriers to trade and a friendly environment for investment amplify the positive impact of RandD spending on TFP.
Domestic financial development is crucial in financing capital accumulation. It allows investment opportunities to be easily seized. Hence, resources are allocated optimally, promoting specialization and productivity gains (Alfaro et al. 2009). However, if the financial sector is not efficient and/or highly controlled, these advantages do not materialize, such as in LAC economies, where it is frequent that firms have to rely on retained earnings for investment, delaying or losing investment opportunities.
As Isaksson has pointed out, “Financial repression, often exemplified by negative or artificially low real interest rates, thwarts incentives to save. They also distort the efficient allocation of savings into investment. Again, the negative effect on TFP growth is clear. It is important to learn more about the association between financial development and productivity growth” (Isaksson 2007, p. 36).
There is also evidence that shows that the distortions are driven by regulations in the labor and product market (Égert 2016), e.g., harsh employment legislation raises labor costs which affect the optimal reallocation process; therefore, if the restrictions dampen job reallocation, the productivity will decline (Haltiwanger et al. 2014; Andrews and Cingano 2014). However, the empirical evidence on the impact of labor regulations on job relocation is inconclusive (Haltiwanger et al. 2014).
Based on this theoretical framework, our main hypothesis is that pro-market policies and better-quality of institutions raise the TFP of the LAC region.

3. Model, Variables and Data

Based on our theoretical framework, we can formulate the main equation to be estimated as follow:
TFP = f (NatK; Energy, Transport; ICT; Institutions; Policy)
where TFP is the total factor productivity estimated by the methodology explained in the next subsection. NatK is an index that measures the availability of extractive and agricultural resources. Energy measures the availability, sustainability and efficiency of power sources. Transport measures the availability of roads and railways and air connectivity. ICT measures information and communication technology availability. Finally, Institutions is an aggregated index that measures our ‘Economic Institution’ variable. It includes areas such as political stability, corruption, rule of law, voice and accountability, and government efficiency. These variables (except TFP) are part of the Productive Capacity Indexes developed by UNCTAD (2021). These indexes have a scale of 0–100 and constitute the basic model from which we will analyze the impact of each of the different economic policy variables proposed.9
Finally, the variable ‘Policy’ will be measured by nine distinct indexes (see Table 1) that can be considered in two main areas; international opening and domestic regulations. Within international opening, we have six variables. The first two variables measure policies that directly affect international trade (MTR and Tariff), and the second two variables measure policies that affect the international capital flows (CC and FOCC). The last two variables in this area are general indexes that measure the whole outward-oriented policy effect (CMCP and FTI). Finally, we included three indexes that measure the effect of inward-oriented policies. These indexes measure the effect of government policies and regulations in areas such as the credit market (Credit), labor market (Labor) and business activities (Business).10
These variables are indexes elaborated by the Fraser Institute. The scale of Fraser indexes is 0–10, and UNCTAD’s indexes are scaled from 0–100; hence, in order to make the different parameters estimated relatively comparable, we have multiplied Fraser indexes by 10. The higher the score obtained by the index, the greater economic freedom.11
We propose a log–log model that will allow us to estimate elasticities. Therefore, all the variables are in logarithms.12
All estimations will include the variables in the first three main areas; Natural Resources (NatK and Energy), Infrastructure (Transport and ICT) and Economic Institutions (Institutions), and one variable of Policy each time. Thus, we have nine models, one for each policy variable (MTR; Tariff; CCIE; FOCC; CMCP; FTI; Credit; Labor; and Business).
Model 1: TFP = f(NatK; Energy; Transport; ICT; Institutions; MTR)
Model 2: TFP = f(NatK; Energy; Transport; ICT; Institutions; Tariff)
Model 3: TFP = f(NatK; Energy; Transport; ICT; Institutions; CC)
Model 4: TFP = f(NatK; Energy; Transport; ICT; Institutions; FOCC)
Model 5: TFP = f(NatK; Energy; Transport; ICT; Institutions; CMCP)
Model 6: TFP = f(NatK; Energy; Transport; ICT; Institutions; FTI)
Model 7: TFP = f(NatK; Energy; Transport; ICT; Institutions; Credit)
Model 8: TFP = f(NatK; Energy; Transport; ICT; Institutions; Labor)
Model 9: TFP = f(NatK; Energy; Transport; ICT; Institutions; Business)

TFP Calculation

Several works have measured and analyzed the performance of the TFP for the LA region. The most recent and relevant works are those of Daude and Fernández-Arias (2010); Ferreira et al. (2013); Araujo et al. (2014); Rodríguez-Apolinar and Fernández-Arias (2016); Fernández-Arias (2017); Fernández-Arias and Fernández-Arias (2021); Koengkan et al. (2022). All of them calculate the TFP using a growth-accounting approach, except Araujo et al. (2014), who estimate TFP using a parametric technique (stochastic-frontier model) and Koengkan et al. (2022), who estimate the TFP by both approaches; stochastic production frontier and data envelopment analysis.
These frontier approaches have several advantages for estimating TFP indexes over other techniques, especially the DEA non-parametric techniques, since it is more flexible than the parametric techniques. It performs better than other parametric techniques when technology is heterogeneous, and the assumption of constant returns to scale is relaxed (Van Biesebroeck 2007; Van Beveren 2012), two characteristics that are particularly important in our sample data.
For these reasons, we employ the DEA technique and Färe-Primont index (FPI) for estimating the TFP for the LAC region. This methodology is based on the advances developed by (O’Donnell 2008, 2010, 2011b, 2012, 2014, 2018).
FPI is constructed using output and input distance functions and has some important advantages over other similar indexes, being one of the most important that it allows for multi-lateral and multi-temporal comparisons. Furthermore, this index is what the literature names primal indexes, i.e., it is additive and multiplicative. For that reason, FPI is considered an exhaustive and ideal index since it satisfies all the relevant axioms and proofs in the index numbers theory (O’Donnell 2011a, 2011b).
Some of its advantages are: that it does not need to impose a specific functional form and, in contrast to the parametric frontier techniques, it does not need any assumption about the distribution of the inefficiency component. Moreover, it is not necessary to assume that all economic units are efficient and that the economic units follow a profit-maximization or cost-minimization behavior. In addition, no information about prices is required.13
TFP is defined as the relationship between outputs and inputs, represented as:
TFP it = Q it X it
where Q i t = D 0 ( x 0 , q i t , t 0 , )   D 1 ( x h s , q 0 , t 0 , ) and X i t = D 0 ( x 0 , q h s , t 0 , )   D 1 ( x i t , q 0 , t 0 , ) are the aggregate function of output and inputs, respectively.14
To estimate the TFP, we use one Output (Real GDP at constant 2017 national prices (in mil. 2017US$)) and three inputs; Capital (Capital stock at constant 2017 national prices (in mil. 2017US$)), Labor (Number of persons engaged, in millions), and Human Capital (Human capital index)15. All data and variables are from Penn World Table version 10.0 (Feenstra et al. 2015)16. We included the twenty LA countries, and we added the USA as a benchmark for the frontier17. The results are reported in the Appendix A, Table A1.18

4. Methodology and Results

The first step will be to examine the properties of the series by checking if the variables are non-stationary. We will implement a second-generation test developed by Pesaran (2007), which is the cross-sectional Im-Pesarn-Shin (CIPS) test. This test has several advantages since it takes into account the potential cross-sectional dependence (CSD) problem and allows for heterogeneity in the autoregressive coefficient of the regression, as well as among the units. Besides, it is also valid for panels where the number of cross-section units and the periods are similar (N ≈ T), and it shows good size properties even for small sample sizes.
Since we have only 19 periods in our data, we will report the truncated CIPS as it was recommended by Pesaran (2007). For all the tests, we chose the Modified Akaike criteria for the length lag selection, with a maximum of four lags. We have run all tests in levels; with a constant and constant plus trend. For the test in the first differences, we only report the results with a constant. The results reported in Table 2 confirm that all series contain unit roots, becoming stationary at the first difference. Therefore, they are I(1).
Now we will evaluate some characteristics of our models since it will guide us in selecting the proper cointegration test and the suitable methodology for estimating the long-run parameters of each model.
The first step will be checking for CSD. In this case, we propose the CD test developed by Pesaran (2015). This test is robust even in the presence of structural breaks and I(1) variables, as well as for panels with short T and large N (Pesaran 2021). Under the null hypothesis of cross-sectional independence (or weak CSD), the CD statistic follows a normal distribution. We conducted the test on the residuals after estimating each regression by Fixed Effect-OLS.
It Is also critical to verify homogeneity in the parameters. Therefore, we will run the tests proposed by Bersvendsen and Ditzen (2021), which are based on Pesaran and Yamagata (2008). In addition, we consider the extension that allows estimating HAC robust standard errors (Blomquist and Westerlund 2013, 2016). We have chosen the Quadratic-Sphere kernel, and the bandwidth was set at 2, which is a usual value for this time dimension. This test compares the distance between slopes obtained by cross-sectional unit regressions and pooled FE regression, weighting the difference by the unit-specific standard errors. It calculates the Delta and Delta Adjusted statistic to test the null hypothesis that posits that the parameters are homogeneous across cross-sectional units.19
In Table 3, we show the results for both tests. As we can see, the nine models strongly fail to reject the null hypothesis for CSD and slope homogeneity. This implies that it can be assumed that CSD is not present in our estimations and that all slope coefficients are homogeneous across cross-sectional units.
So far, we have verified slope homogeneity, absence of CSD and that all the variables are I(1). Given these conditions, the number of explanatory variables, and the time dimension of our panel, we proposed the test developed by (Pedroni 1999, 2004) to verify cointegration where the null hypothesis is no cointegration. Its rejection implies that the error term is stationary and all panels are cointegrated. This test offers seven statistics; three are part of the group-mean statistics, which average the results of each country. The other four are panel statistics that pool the statistics along the within-dimension. All statistics are adjusted and are distributed as N(0, 1).
On the other hand, for estimating the long-run parameters of each model, we propose the non-parametric Fully Modified Ordinary Least Square (FMOLS) developed by (Pedroni 1996, 2000, 2001), in particular, the grouped-mean FMOLS, which shows a good performance in small panels or when the relation T/N is small. It estimates the parameters country-by-country, averaging them across countries in a second step, getting this way the mean long-run slope coefficients. The estimations are always consistent, and they are also efficient when slopes can be assumed homogeneous (an assumption that has already been validated).
In addition, this estimator, and the associated t-statistic, are very precise even when there is substantial cross-sectional heterogeneity. Furthermore, this non-parametric estimator does not need to assume a specific parametric form for estimating the nuisance parameters. Hence, it is generally more robust than other parametric estimators like Dynamic Ordinary Least Square (DOLS) (Pedroni 2000).
On the contrary, Kao and Chiang (2000), among others, have claimed that DOLS outperforms FMOLS. However, it is worth mentioning that most of the empirical evidence is based on models with only one or two regressors and a relatively large relation between time and cross-section units (T/N). Additionally, the DOLS estimator is conditioned on the data length and the number of variables in the model. For instance, in panels with many regressors and small T, a large number of lags and leads make the regression unfeasible, e.g., in our estimations.
Finally, Pedroni (2001) has also pointed out that the parameters estimated through the grouped-mean FMOLS method have a more useful interpretation than the pooled version since they can be interpreted as the mean value for the cointegrating vectors. This interpretation does not apply to the pooled estimator. This is another reason for choosing the grouped-mean FMOLS estimator.
The Pedroni’s cointegration tests were run, including panel-specific time trends and specifying the lag structure for augmented Dickey–Fuller regressions by Akaike info criteria imposing a maximum of 4 lags. The method to estimate the long-run variance was the Bartlett kernel, and the lags to adjust for serial correlation were selected according to the Newey and West (1994) method. In Table 4, we show all the results of the cointegration tests. There, we can verify that all the test statistics strongly reject the null hypothesis, which means that the series in the nine models are cointegrated.
Confirming cointegration implies that the I(1) series are in long-run equilibrium; this proves the existence of a long-run relationship between the variables in the model. Moreover, as Pedroni (2019, p. 257) has pointed out: “…the presence of cointegration brings with it a form of robustness to many of the classic empirical problems that lead to the so-called violation of the exogeneity condition for the regressors. Obvious examples include omitted variables, measurement error, simultaneity, reverse causality or anything that leads the data generating process…”.
For estimating the long-run parameters, we use the grouped-mean FMOLS estimator. In all estimations, we include fixed effects and an individual linear trend as an additional deterministic regressor. We set (non-pre whitened) Bartlett kernel and Andrews’ automatic bandwidth selection method to compute the long-run covariances. It was also considered the finite sample adjustment for standard errors and covariance in all estimations.
In the results shown in Table 5, Table 6 and Table 7, we present the coefficients estimated and their respective p-values (the first two columns of each estimation). In addition, since collinearity could be an issue with these sorts of explanatory variables, we added a third column with the uncentered Variance Inflation Factors (VIF) for measuring the level of collinearity between the regressors in each estimation. As a rule of thumb, if the VIF is less than 4, then collinearity is not a concern, but a value greater than 10 indicates a high level of collinearity. Finally, at the bottom of each table, we present the results of the CSD test of Pesaran (2015), reporting the CD-Statistics and their p-values.
The results are robust and consistent in all nine models. Except for Labor, in Model 8, and Transport in some models, all the parameters are statistically significant at usual significance levels of 0.01 and 0.05. Besides, the coefficients show the expected positive sign. It is also worthwhile noting that the VIF statistics for all the variables in all models are very low; therefore, collinearity is not an issue. Finally, Pesaran’s test fails to reject the null hypothesis in almost all estimations except model 4. Thus, we can confirm that there is no evidence of CSD in eight of our nine models.

5. Discussion

As we have mentioned before, the effect of natural capital and energy endowments is not so clear. Some hypotheses, e.g., the ‘resource curse’ hypothesis, assert that the effect could even be negative. However, our results indicate a significant positive impact on TFP. The result is in line with other works, such as Zeeshan et al. (2020), who have found a positive relationship between natural resources and economic growth in the LAC region. Furthermore, in all our estimates, these variables are the ones that have the greatest impact on the dynamics of TFP. Natural resource endowments are the most important determinant of TFP, with elasticities within the range of 1–2. This means that natural resource abundance is a key factor in pushing the LAC TFP toward the technology frontier. This effect can be explained by the technological boom registered in agriculture during the last two decades (Le Clech and Fillat-Castejón 2020) and its importance in the world agricultural supply (Le Clech and Fillat-Castejón 2017).
Energy availability is the second main determinant of productivity in the LAC region, with elasticities ranging from 0.6 to 1. Findings that agree with Kühl Teles and Cesar Mussolini (2012), who estimated an elasticity of approximately 0.41. Additionally, Le and Bao (2019) and Santiago et al. (2020) found that energy use has a positive impact on LAC economic growth. In general, natural resources and energy endowments are important growth drivers for the LAC economies (Kristjanpoller et al. 2016; Zeeshan et al. 2020).
The impact of transport infrastructure on TFP is extremely low, with elasticities that do not surpass a value of 0.07, getting non-significant estimations in some models. These findings are in line with those of Calderón et al. (2015), who found an elasticity of infrastructure in a range between 0.07 and 0.10. These low elasticities (when significant) find an explanation in that the region has low transport infrastructure density relative to its income level. In addition, its performance has been characterized as mediocre and uncompetitive (Fay et al. 2017). This combination of inefficiency and underdevelopment could explain the small or insignificant role played by this variable. In other words, LAC countries should reduce their shortcomings in infrastructure (Alaimo et al. 2008).
Regarding ICT infrastructure, its effect can be considered relatively lower than expected, with values that range from 0.24 to 0.29. However, these results are consistent with those verified by Hofman et al. (2016), who conclude that the role of ICT has been minimal in the LAC region. In sum, these results suggest that the availability of ICT has had relatively little impact on productivity in LAC economies. It can be explained by the low performance of the speed of diffusion and adoption of new technologies due to the economic structure in those countries, which were not able to get the expected spillover effects (Cardona et al. 2013; Gnangnon 2021). Despite this relatively low effect, same as Grazzi and Jung (2016), we can confirm a significant and positive effect between ICT and productivity.
We have also verified a significant and positive impact of the variable Institutions. This means that better quality of institutions leads to improvements in the TFP of the LAC region. The estimations are consistent between all models, with an estimated elasticity of around 0.2. This result agrees with the findings of Azam (2022), who concluded that good governance is critical for boosting economic growth in the LAC region and, in general, with several other earlier studies that concluded that the institutional quality resulted in a positive impact on LAC’s economic growth (Easterly et al. 1997; Fajnzylber and Lederman 1999; Fernández-Arias and Montiel 2001; Bandeira and García 2002; Chong and Zanforlin 2004; De Gregorio and Lee 2004).
Regarding the pro-market policies, we have found that eight of the nine indexes proposed are statistically significant, and all the parameters indicate a positive impact on TFP. The only exception was Labor which was not statistically significant. This general result confirms that pro-market policies boost productivity in the region.
The two indexes that measure policies on international trade, (MTR and Tariff), have shown a positive effect (see Table 5), results that are similar to those previous studies that measured the impact on economic growth (Bandeira and García 2002; De Gregorio and Lee 2004). Especially the variable MTR, which is an index based on the unweighted mean of tariff rates applied to imports, demonstrates the relevance of trade policies in determining TFP in the LAC region. The elasticity estimated was 0.45, the highest value among the policy variables. Therefore, it is evident that the misallocation effect produced by protectionist policies can be critical for the development of the region. In this regard, we share the same conclusion as Isaksson (2007, p. 62); “…trade openness (as a policy) is important and that, in terms of outcome, imports are crucial for TFP”.
The estimated coefficients for our two measures of financial outward-oriented policies, namely, CC and FOCC (capital control and financial openness and capital control), were 0.074 and 0.178, respectively, both statistically significant at a 1% level (see Table 5 and Table 6). These results are similar to those reported by Bandeira and García (2002), who estimated the impact of financial and capital openness on economic growth in the LAC region for a previous period of analysis. In general, these sorts of outward-oriented policies have a direct impact on the attraction of FDI, especially important for the natural resources and energy sectors in the LAC region. This result is consistent with that of Alfaro et al. (2009), who showed evidence that financial opening raises TFP via knowledge spillovers and technology transfers, as well as enhancing resource allocation.
Considering these results and the positive and statistically significant coefficient estimated for the two general indexes, CMCP and FTI (controls of the movement of capital and people and freedom to trade internationally), reported in Table 6, we can conclude that opening policies are associated with higher TFP growth. These results contradict those obtained by Santiago et al. (2020), who found that the general index of economic freedom of Heritage shows a negative impact on economic growth. Nonetheless, at the same time, they found that the general KOF Globalization Index (Gygli et al. 2019) positively impacts economic growth and that the KOF index of economic globalization has a positive effect on growth in the long run but not in the short run.20
Finally, we have examined the impact of three inward-oriented policies in three key areas of the economy, namely, the credit market, labor market and business. The results reported in Table 7 confirm a positive and statistically significant coefficient in the credit market and business. However, we did not find any significant association between labor market flexibilization and TFP growth. This means, as was expected that fewer and/or better regulations lead to improvements in the TFP of the LAC countries.
We found strong evidence that financial freedom positively affects TFP. In other words, financial repression is bad for resource allocation since it thwarts capital accumulation. A similar effect was found by Bandeira and García (2002) and Bittencourt (2012) on economic growth for a previous period of analysis, e.g., Bittencourt (2012) emphasized the importance that a more open and competitive financial sector had in the LAC region for fostering entrepreneurship, which in turn stimulates economic growth.
Regarding the business environment, we found that the regulatory framework has a relevant impact on TFP. This finding is supported by a thorough investigation by Grazzi and Pietrobelli (2016), who examined firm performance in the LAC region. The study concluded that the benefits of improvements in governance, institutions, and other investment climate attributes had a positive impact on firm performance and wage levels, which in turn led to increases in productivity.
The result gathered by the labor market index can be explained by the structural transformation of the labor market in recent decades in the region, where the evidence has shown that the workforce has moved from high-productivity sectors to low-productivity activities, in many cases from agriculture and manufacturing towards low productivity services industry (Ferreira and da Silva 2015; Diao et al. 2019). Therefore, even though labor flexibility may have improved employment dynamics in the region, the structural effects of the region’s economies led resources toward low-productivity activities.

6. Concluding Remarks and Policy Recommendations

We have examined the role of some of the key determinants of the TFP for the LAC region over the period 2000–2018 and estimated the effect of five key productive capacity indicators embodied in the PCI of the UNCTAD, namely; natural resource, energy availability, transport and ICT infrastructure, and institutions. We have also analyzed the individual impact of nine different pro-market policy indicators on the TFP of the region. We were able to verify cointegration in the nine models. Finally, we estimated the long-run parameters through the grouped-mean FMOLS estimator, which allows us to interpret the estimated coefficients as the mean value for the cointegrating vectors, i.e., the average effect on the TFP in the region.
Regarding our results, it is very important to highlight that almost all the variables used to measure pro-market policies have pointed in the same direction; this assures the robustness of our estimations. In sum, the results confirm that pro-market policies have a positive impact on TFP. We have obtained for all the relevant estimations a positive and statistically significant parameter, which sends a clear message, the more economic freedom, the more productivity.
Considering the results of the productive capacity indexes, we can confirm a positive effect of the natural resource endowments and energy availability on the TFP. These two variables play the most important role in relating to the parameter estimated. It follows ICT infrastructure. On the other hand, transport infrastructure has had a negligible impact.
It is also clear that better institutions and pro-market policies with solid foundations are essential for improving the productivity of the region; these variables attain a positive and significant parameter in our estimations. Domestic economic freedom improves productivity and, through it, economic growth and wealth as well. Alongside this, a legal framework that encourages private initiative, with fewer and more efficient regulations, may be the key to boosting productivity growth. Once again, these results indicate that the less the government influences the economy, the greater the TFP gains for the economy. For those reasons, being part of economic globalization can be crucial for this region.
In addition to the misallocation effect that policies on Credit and Business sector can produce, it is also important to foreground the effects of regulations. In several LAC economies, firms must cut through the red tape, and it is an important determinant that affects TFP through its impact on market efficiency. Therefore, to achieve more productivity gains, it is important to promote efficiency in the domestic market by improving the quality of the regulations for both tradable and non-tradable economic activities. In addition, financial sector reform merits high priority on the policy agenda.
In this paper, we have collected evidence of the positive effect of pro-market policies on TFP in the region. The policy measures that can be recommended are well known. Most of them were offered two decades ago by many relevant economists. Just to mention one, we can illustrate the eight recommendations given by Sachs and Vial in 2001 in a document named “Latin American Competitiveness Report”. These were: (1) Promote credible market-friendly reforms, (2) Improve institutions, (3) Invest in human capital, (4) Search systematically for efficiency gains, (5) Use your natural resources wisely, (6) Seek trade enhancement and enlargement of markets, (7) Development of local research and innovation capabilities and (8) Promote diversification of exports (Sachs and Vial 2001).
Many of these recommendations and their effects are well documented in the literature. However, all these reforms require a long-term plan that takes into account as precisely as possible the economic adjustments and structural changes that will be required. This is a difficult challenge to overcome from the perspective of populism. Likewise, this type of reform cannot be carried out in parts, hence the ninth and most important recommendation; “To be successful, countries must move in all dimensions at once” (Sachs and Vial 2001, p. 27).
To conclude, it is indisputable that for those policies affecting the external and domestic sectors, more economic freedom allowed means additional gains in productivity. To put it differently, having more economic freedom boosts productivity. In that sense, we can call “pro-market” policies “good economic institutions”.

Author Contributions

Both authors have contributed to the conceptualization and analysis; methodology, resources and data, N.L.C.; writing—review and editing, J.C.G.-P.; supervision, N.L.C. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the Spanish Government, Project PID2020-113905GB-I00, and Project S56_20R, funded by the Aragon Regional Government.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The datasets used during the current study are available from the corresponding author upon reasonable request.

Acknowledgments

To Tania Dolzenko for proofreading and Jésica Romero for her assistance in data collection.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Total Factor Productivity 2000–2018. Färe-Primont index.
Table A1. Total Factor Productivity 2000–2018. Färe-Primont index.
YearArgentinaBoliviaBrazilChileColombiaCosta RicaDominican Rep.EcuadorEl SalvadorGuatemala
20000.67490.13370.67170.38750.54920.14040.21440.20890.14000.2567
20010.63990.13440.66630.39180.55500.14340.21520.21440.14090.2608
20020.57180.13610.67260.39190.56360.14620.22430.21960.14260.2685
20030.61940.13840.67130.39780.57860.15040.22140.22210.14430.2732
20040.66590.14300.69730.41540.60020.15490.22190.23670.14560.2800
20050.71160.14810.70780.42780.61670.15880.23890.24540.14930.2871
20060.75370.15380.72220.44120.64230.16990.25790.25210.15350.2948
20070.80040.15920.74820.44850.66550.18290.27210.25350.15760.3054
20080.81060.16720.76440.44750.67030.19030.27280.26440.15800.3082
20090.75230.17090.74550.42860.66140.18780.26880.26150.15200.3048
20100.81050.17600.77560.44010.67350.19640.28330.26560.15290.3086
20110.83460.18240.77820.45140.69960.20190.28400.28120.15380.3166
20120.80760.18910.76820.45840.70710.20860.28370.29090.15430.3211
20130.80910.19890.76540.46060.72210.21070.28990.29830.15450.3281
20140.77490.20650.74850.45520.73160.21550.30290.30280.15420.3374
20150.78180.21320.71050.45310.73090.22060.31480.29760.15520.3461
20160.75440.21900.68120.44960.72640.22710.32550.28980.15640.3505
20170.76050.22460.68490.44500.71750.23320.33080.29200.15720.3560
20180.73060.23040.68710.45210.71800.23660.34280.29110.15820.3619
YearHaitiHondurasJamaicaMexicoNicaraguaPanamaParaguayPeruUruguayVenezuela
20000.07370.09840.06220.68880.07490.12270.12630.33990.11700.0428
20010.07210.09980.06290.67180.07640.12250.12650.33650.11230.0435
20020.07110.10240.06330.65970.07630.12430.14290.34900.10370.0390
20030.07050.10590.06550.65800.07750.12850.14620.35730.10450.0355
20040.06720.11090.06630.67090.08090.13690.14910.36800.10960.0414
20050.06770.11610.06680.67230.08360.14530.14930.38310.11750.0449
20060.06840.12190.06860.68620.08600.15600.15510.40680.12130.0482
20070.06990.12720.06950.68470.08920.17230.16180.43360.12800.0512
20080.06980.13020.06900.67470.09110.18600.17010.46120.13590.0527
20090.07100.12570.06600.62760.08710.18530.16790.45630.14050.0499
20100.06640.12900.06510.64710.08990.19260.18420.48050.15010.0484
20110.06920.13130.06600.65630.09450.21030.18840.49210.15570.0497
20120.07040.13400.06540.66480.09930.22540.18420.50130.15880.0517
20130.07240.13500.06560.66080.10290.23410.19600.50970.16370.0516
20140.07350.13640.06590.66620.10650.23860.20170.50340.16650.0490
20150.07340.13870.06630.67400.11010.24460.20400.50450.16500.0454
20160.07350.14130.06710.68010.11350.24910.20940.51110.16580.0374
20170.07340.14500.06750.68260.11720.25500.21640.51110.16850.0314
20180.07360.14720.06860.68580.11140.25660.22020.51780.16970.0251
Source: Own estimation.

Notes

1
Some authors, such as Krueger (2002) and Kuczynski and Williamson (2003), have asserted that the crisis that emerged at the end of the 1990s and early 2000s was caused due to the failure to implement the reforms fully. Later, discussions changed, moving the focus toward institutional deficiencies (Coatsworth 2005).
2
For an extensive review of different works and approaches, we recommend: Aron (2000); Ugur (2010); Bluhm and Szirmai (2012); Kim and Loayza (2019), amongst others.
3
These productive capacity indexes have been used in a recent work by Gnangnon (2021), who analyzed the impact of these variables on economic growth using a panel of 117 developing countries from 2000 to 2018.
4
The countries included are Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Haiti, Honduras, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay and Venezuela.
5
About measures such as ‘investment in RandD’ Isaksson (2007, p. 7) has pointed out, “…statistical results may be affected by incomplete measures of knowledge and its proxies, which could lead to problems, such as weak correlations, and even to questioning what has actually been estimated”.
6
The literature on this topic is extremely extensive. Therefore, we recommend some relevant reviews that can be found at; Deacon (2011); Van der Ploeg (2011); Frankel (2012); Badeeb et al. (2017); Papyrakis (2019), amongst others.
7
In Calderon and Servén (2014), there is a more detailed discussion on the linkage between infrastructure and productivity.
8
Lloyd and Lee (2018) is an extensive review of the recent literature on institutions and economic growth.
9
UNCTAD defines productive capacity in a broad sense as: “…the productive resources, entrepreneurial capabilities and production linkages which together determine the capacity of a country to produce goods and services and enable it to grow and develop” (UNCTAD 2006, p. 62).
10
We did not consider the index Financial Openness alone because of its lack of variability. For that reason, we combined this with the capital control index.
11
A complete definition of these indexes can be found at: https://www.fraserinstitute.org/sites/default/files/uploaded/2022/economic-freedom-of-the-world-2022-appendix.pdf (accessed on 21 September 2022).
12
The variables CC and FOCC have few values equal to cero. In those cases, we calculated the logarithms as log(X + 0.1).
13
Jerzmanowski (2007) also discusses the advantage of DEA in estimating TFP.
14
For further details about the Färe-Primont index, we recommend reading O’Donnell (2014, 2018).
15
As Mankiw et al. (1992); Miller and Upadhyay (2000); Égert (2016), we also believe that it is important to include Human Capital as an input in the production function. Moreover, Ferreira et al. (2013) have concluded that the inclusion of human capital in the production function makes a crucial difference in TFP calculations for Latin America.
16
The database is available for download at www.ggdc.net/pwt (accessed on 7 October 2022).
17
In order to estimate the production function, we consider the output approach, and we have conducted our estimations allowing for variable returns to scale and technical regress. We have used the program DPIN 3.0 for the calculations. For further details, see O’Donnell (2011a).
18
When comparing our TFP’s results with two estimations of Penn World Table (PWT10), cwtfp (Welfare-relevant TFP levels at current PPPs) and r (Welfare-relevant TFP at constant national prices), the panel correlations were 0.95 and 0.92, respectively.
19
We only report the ‘Delta Adjusted’ statistics for this test, although we got the same results with the ‘Delta’ statistics. Results upon request.
20
It is important to highlight that the problem with using general indexes like the general index of economic freedom of Heritage is that we do not know what specific area we measure since it includes many different fields of policy. Another issue that must be taken into account when using Heritage indexes is that they must be lagged since the data assigned for each year accounts for the facts that happened in the previous period, e.g., the data of 2022 accounts for measures collected between the middle of 2020 and the end of 2021. The authors have not made it clear whether they have taken this into account.

References

  1. Acemoglu, Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty. London: Profile Books, pp. 45–47. [Google Scholar]
  2. Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2005. Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. Handbook of Economic Growth 1: 385–472. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Agénor, Pierre-Richard. 2013. Public Capital, Growth and Welfare. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Alaimo, Verónica, Pablo Fajnzylber, José Luis Guasch, J. Humberto López, and Ana María Oviedo. 2008. The Investment Climate in Latin America. In Does the Investment Climate Matter?: Microeconomic Foundations of Growth in Latin America. Edited by Pablo Fajnzylber, José Luis Guasch and Humberto López. Washington, DC: Palgrave MacMillan and The World Bank, Chapter 2. pp. 49–111. [Google Scholar]
  5. Alcalá, Francisco, and Antonio Ciccone. 2004. Trade and productivity. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 119: 613–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Alfaro, Laura, Sebnem Kalemli-Ozcan, and Selin Sayek. 2009. FDI, productivity and financial development. The World Economy 32: 111–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Andrews, Dan, and Chiara Criscuolo. 2013. Knowledge-based capital, innovation and resource allocation. In OECD Economics Department Working Papers. No. 1046. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Andrews, Dan, and Federico Cingano. 2014. Public policy and resource allocation: Evidence from firms in OECD countries. Economic Policy 29: 253–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Araujo, Jair, Débora G. Feitosa, and Almir B. Silva. 2014. Latin America: Total factor productivity and its components. CEPAL Review 114: 51–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Aron, Janine. 2000. Growth and Institutions: A Review of the Evidence. The World Bank Research Observer 15: 99–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Arora, Punit, and Prabal De. 2020. Environmental sustainability practices and exports: The interplay of strategy and institutions in Latin America. Journal of World Business 55: 101094. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Azam, Muhammad. 2022. Governance and Economic Growth: Evidence from 14 Latin America and Caribbean Countries. Journal of the Knowledge Economy 13: 1470–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Badeeb, Ramez A., Hooi Hooi Lean, and Jeremy Clark. 2017. The evolution of the natural resource curse thesis: A critical literature survey. Resources Policy 51: 123–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Bandeira, Andrea, and Fernando García. 2002. Reformas y crecimiento en América Latina. CEPAL Review 77: 83–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Bersvendsen, Tore, and Jan Ditzen. 2021. Testing for slope heterogeneity in Stata. The Stata Journal 21: 1–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Bittencourt, Manoel. 2012. Financial development and economic growth in Latin America: Is Schumpeter right? Journal of Policy Modeling 34: 341–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Blanco, Luisa, and Robin Grier. 2012. Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America. Resources Policy 37: 281–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Blomquist, Johan, and Joakim Westerlund. 2013. Testing slope homogeneity in large panels with serial correlation. Economics Letters 121: 374–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Blomquist, Johan, and Joakim Westerlund. 2016. Panel bootstrap tests of slope homogeneity. Empirical Economics 50: 1359–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Bluhm, Richard, and Adam Szirmai. 2012. Institutions and Long-Run Growth Performance: An Analytic Literature review of the Institutional Determinants of Economic Growth. MERIT Working Papers 2012-033. Maastricht: United Nations University-Maastricht Economic and Social Research Institute on Innovation and Technology (MERIT). [Google Scholar]
  21. Bougheas, Spiros, Panicos O. Demetriades, and Theofanis P. Mamuneas. 2000. Infrastructure, specialization, and economic growth. Canadian Journal of Economics 33: 506–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Bouis, Romain, Romain Duval, and Fabrice Murtin. 2011. The policy and institutional drivers of economic growth across OECD and non-OECD economies: New evidence from growth regressions. In OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 843. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Burinskiene, Aurelija. 2012. The Theoretical Link between Trade and Productivity. DAAAM International Scientific Book. Vienna: DAAAM International, Chapter 25. pp. 287–304. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Buitrago, Ricardo E., and María Inés Barbosa Camargo. 2021. Institutions, institutional quality, and international competitiveness: Review and examination of future research directions. Journal of Business Research 128: 423–435. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Calderon, César, and Luis Servén. 2014. Infrastructure, Growth, and Inequality: An Overview. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 7034. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2497234. (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  26. Calderón, César, Enrique Moral-Benito, and Luis Servén. 2015. Is infrastructure capital productive? A dynamic heterogeneous approach. Journal of Applied Econometrics 30: 177–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Cardona, Melisande, Tobias Kretschmer, and Thomas Strobel. 2013. ICT and productivity: Conclusions from the empirical literature. Information Economics and Policy 25: 109–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Chong, Alberto E., and Luisa Zanforlin. 2004. Inward-looking policies, institutions, autocrats, and economic growth in Latin America: An empirical exploration. Public Choice 121: 335–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Coatsworth, John H. 2005. Structures, Endowments, and Institutions in the Economic History of Latin America. Latin American Research Review 40: 126–44. Available online: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3662825 (accessed on 14 December 2022). [CrossRef]
  30. Coe, David, Elhanan Helpman, and Alexander Hoffmaister. 2009. International RandD spillovers and institutions. European Economic Review 53: 723–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Cole, Harold L., Lee E. Ohanian, Alvaro Riascos, and James A. Schmitz. 2004. Latin America in the Rearview Mirror. Journal of Monetary Economics 52: 69–107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Correa, Rafael. 2002. Reformas estructurales y crecimiento en América Latina: Un análisis de sensibilidad. CEPAL Review 76: 86–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Daude, Christian, and Eduardo Fernández-Arias. 2010. On the Role of Productivity and Factor Accumulation in Economic Development in Latin America and the Caribbean. Working Paper IDB-WP-155. Washington, DC: Research Department, Inter-American Development Bank. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Deacon, Robert. 2011. The Political Economy of the Natural Resource Curse: A Survey of Theory and Evidence. Santa Barbara: Foundations and Trends® in Microeconomics, vol. 7, No. 2, pp. 111–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. De Gregorio, José, and John-Wha Lee. 2004. Growth and Adjustment in East Asia and Latin America. Economía 5: 69–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Diao, Xinshen, Margaret McMillan, and Dani Rodrik. 2019. The recent growth boom in developing economies: A structural-change perspective. In The Palgrave Handbook of Development Economics. Edited by Nissanke Machiko and José Antonio Ocampo. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Doucouliagos, Chris, and Mehmet Ali Ulubasoglu. 2004. Institutions and economic growth: A systems approach. In Econometric Society 2004 Australasian Meetings. (No. 63). Cleveland: Econometric Society. [Google Scholar]
  38. Easterly, William. 2005. National Policies and Economic Growth: A Reappraisal. Handbook of Economic Growth, 1 Part A. New York: New York University, Chapter 15. pp. 1015–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 2001. It’s Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized Facts and Growth Models. World Bank Economic Review 15: 177–219. Available online: https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/17440 (accessed on 14 December 2022). [CrossRef]
  40. Easterly, William, Norman Loayza, and Peter Montiel. 1997. Has Latin America’s Post-Reform Growth Been Disappointing? Policy Research Working Paper 1708. Washington, DC: The World Bank. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Escaith, Hubert, and Samuel A. Morley. 2000. The Impact of Structural Reforms on Growth in Latin America and the Caribbean: An Empirical Estimation. CEPAL-SERIE. Santiago: Macroeconomia del Desarrollo. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Égert, Balázs. 2016. Regulation, Institutions, and Productivity: New Macroeconomic Evidence from OECD Countries. American Economic Review 106: 109–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Fajnzylber, Pablo, and Daniel Lederman. 1999. Economic reforms and total factor productivity growth in Latin America and the Caribbean (1950–1995): An empirical note. World Bank Policy Research Working Papers 19: 171–90. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=614974 (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  44. Farla, Kristine, Denis de Crombrugghe, and Bart Verspagen. 2016. Institutions, Foreign Direct Investment, and Domestic Investment: Crowding Out or Crowding In? World Development 88: 1–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Fay, Marianne, Luis Alberto Andres, Charles Fox, Ulf Narloch, Stephane Straud, and Michael Slawson, eds. 2017. Rethinking Infrastructure in Latin America and the Caribbean: Spending Better to Achieve More. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications. Available online: https://documents1.worldbank.org/curated/pt/676711491563967405/114110-REVISED-Rethinking-Infrastructure-Low-Res.pdf (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  46. Feenstra, Robert C., Robert Inklaar, and Marcel Timmer. 2015. The Next Generation of the Penn World Table. The American Economic Review 105: 3150–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Fernández-Arias, Eduardo, and Peter Montiel. 2001. Reform and growth in Latin America: All pain, no gain? IMF Staff Papers 48: 522–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Fernández-Arias, Eduardo, and Nicolás Fernández-Arias. 2021. The Latin American Growth Shortfall: Productivity and Inequality. Working Paper No. 04. Background Paper for the UNDP LAC Regional Human Development Report 2021. New York: UNDP LAC. [Google Scholar]
  49. Fernández-Arias, Eduardo, ed. 2017. On the Role of Productivity and Factor Accumulation in Economic Development in Latin America and the Caribbean: 2017 Update. Department of Research and Chief Economist, IDB-TN-1329. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. Available online: https://publications.iadb.org/en/role-productivity-and-factor-accumulation-economic-development-latin-america-and-caribbean-2017 (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  50. Ferreira, Pedro Cavalcanti, and Leonardo Fonseca da Silva. 2015. Structural transformation and productivity in Latin America. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 15: 603–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Ferreira, Pedro Cavalcanti, Samuel De Abreu Pessôa, and Fernando A. Veloso. 2013. On the evolution of total factor productivity in Latin America. Economic Inquiry 51: 16–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Forman, Chris, and Nicolas van Zeebroeck. 2012. From wires to partners: How the Internet has fostered RandD collaborations within firms. Management Science 58: 1549–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Frankel, Jeffrey A. 2012. The Natural Resource Curse: A Survey of Diagnoses and Some Prescriptions. HKS Faculty Research Working Paper Series RWP12-014. Cambridge: John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University. Available online: http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:8694932 (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  54. Fukumi, Atsushi, and Shoji Nishijima. 2010. Institutional quality and foreign direct investment in Latin America and the Caribbean. Applied Economics 42: 1857–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Gnangnon, Sèna Kimm. 2020. Effect of the internet on services export diversification. Journal of Economic Integration 35: 519–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Gnangnon, Sèna Kimm. 2021. Productive capacities, economic growth and economic growth volatility in developing countries: Does structural economic vulnerability matter? Journal of International Commerce, Economics and Policy, 2550001. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Goldfajn, Illan, Lorenza Martínez, and Rodrigo O. Valdés. 2021. Washington Consensus in Latin America: From raw model to straw man. Journal of Economic Perspectives 35: 109–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Grazzi, Matteo, and Carlo Pietrobelli. 2016. Firm Innovation and Productivity in Latin America and the Caribbean: The Engine of Economic Development. Edited by Inter-American Development Bank, Mateo Grazzi and Carlo Pietrobelli. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, p. 346. [Google Scholar]
  59. Grazzi, Matteo, and Juan Jung. 2016. Information and communication technologies, innovation, and productivity: Evidence from firms in Latin America and the Caribbean. In Firm Innovation and Productivity in Latin America and the Caribbean. Edited by Inter-American Development Bank, Mateo Grazzi and Carlo Pietrobelli. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Gygli, Savina, Florian Haelg, Niklas Potrafke, and Jan-Egbert Sturm. 2019. The KOF Globalisation Index revisited. Review of International Organizations 14: 543–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Haber, Stephen, and Victor Menaldo. 2012. Natural resources and democracy in Latin America: Neither curse nor blessing. In The Oxford Handbook of Latin American Political Economy, online ed. Edited by Javier Santiso and Jeff Dayton-Johnson Handbooks. Oxford Handbooks. Oxford: Oxford Academic, November 21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Haider, Franz, Robert Kunst, and Franz Wirl. 2021. Total factor productivity, its components and drivers. Empirica 48: 283–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Hall, Robert, and Charles Jones. 1999. Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 83–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Haltiwanger, John, Stefano Scarpetta, and Helena Schweiger. 2014. Cross country differences in job reallocation: The role of industry, firm size and regulations. LabourLabor Economics 26: 11–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Hofman, André, Claudio Aravena, and Vianka Aliaga. 2016. Information and communication technologies and their impact in the economic growth of Latin America, 1990–2013. Telecommunications Policy 40: 485–501. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Hulten, Charles, and Robert Schwab. 2000. Does infrastructure investment increase the productivity of manufacturing industry in the US? In Econometrics and the Cost of Capital. Edited by Lawrence J. Lau. Cambridge: MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
  67. Isaksson, Anders. 2007. Determinants of total factor productivity: A literature review. Research and Statistics Branch UNIDO 1: 101. [Google Scholar]
  68. Jayakar, Krishna, and Eun-A Park. 2013. Broadband availability and employment: An analysis of county-level data from the National Broadband Map. Journal of Information Policy 3: 181–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Jerzmanowski, Michal. 2007. Total Factor Productivity Differences: Appropriate Technology vs. Efficiency. European Economic Review 51: 2080–110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Jones, Charles. 2016. The Facts of Economic Growth. In Handbook of Macroeconomics. Edited by John B. Taylor and Harald Uhlig. Amsterdam: Elsevier, vol. 2, Chapter 1. pp. 3–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Kao, Chihwa, and Min-Hsien Chiang. 2000. On the estimation and inference of a cointegrated regression in panel data. In Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration and Dynamic Panels. Edited by Badi H. Baltagi, Thomas B. Fomby and Hill Cartereds. Amsterdam: Elsevier, vol. 15, pp. 179–222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Keita, Kouramoudou. 2017. Does Corruption Affect Total Factor Productivity? An Empirical Analysis. Working Papers 1714. Tampere: Tampere University, School of Management and Business, Economics. Available online: https://urn.fi/URN:ISBN:978-952-03-0394-5 (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  73. Kim, Young E., and Norman V. Loayza. 2019. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants Across the World. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 8852. Washington, DC: World Bank. Available online: https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/31710 (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  74. Kim, Young E., Norman V. Loayza, and Claudia M. Meza-Cuadra. 2016. Productivity as the Key to Economic Growth and Development. World Bank Research Policy Brief No. 3. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3249552 (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  75. Koengkan, Matheus, José Alberto Fuinhas, Emad Kazemzadeh, Fariba Osmani, Nooshin K. Alavijeh, Anna Auza, and Mônica Teixeira. 2022. Measuring the economic efficiency performance in Latin American and Caribbean countries: An empirical evidence from stochastic production frontier and data envelopment analysis. International Economics 169: 43–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Kristjanpoller, Werner, Josephine E. Olson, and Rodolfo I. Salazar. 2016. Does the commodities boom support the export-led growth hypothesis? Evidence from Latin American countries. Latin American Economic Review 25: 1–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Krueger, Anne O. 2002. Economic Policy Reform: The Second Stage. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Kuczynski, Pedro P., and John Williamson. 2003. After the Washington Consensus: Restarting Growth and Reform in Latin America. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. ISSN 0328-7998. [Google Scholar]
  79. Kühl Teles, Vladimir, and Caio Cesar Mussolini. 2012. Infrastructure and productivity in Latin America: Is there a relationship in the long run? Journal of Economic Studies 39: 44–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Le Clech, Néstor A., and Carmen Fillat-Castejón. 2017. International aggregate agricultural supply for grain and oilseed: The effects of efficiency and technological change. Agribusiness 33: 569–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Le Clech, Néstor A., and Carmen Fillat-Castejón. 2020. New estimates of total factor productivity, technical and efficiency changes for the global agricultural economy. Spanish Journal of Agricultural Research 18: e0104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Le, Hoang Phong, and Ho Hoang Gia Bao. 2019. Renewable and non-renewable energy consumption, government expenditure, institution quality, financial development, trade openness, and sustainable development in Latin America and Caribbean emerging market and developing economies. International Journal of Energy Economics and Policy 10: 242–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Levitsky, Steven, and Kenneth M. Roberts. 2011. The Resurgence of the Latin American Left. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Lloyd, Peter, and Cassey Lee. 2018. A review of the recent literature on the institutional economics analysis of the long-run performance of nations. Journal of Economic Surveys 32: 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Lora, Eduardo, and Felipe Barrera. 1997. El crecimiento económico en América Latina después de una década de reformas estructurales. Coyuntura Económica 27: 81–99. [Google Scholar]
  86. Lora, Eduardo, and Felipe Barrera. 1998. El Crecimiento Económico en América Latina Después de una década de Reformas Estructurales. Pensamiento Iberoamericano N° Extra 31. Madrid: América Latina después de las reformas, pp. 55–86. ISSN 0212–0218. [Google Scholar]
  87. Lugones, Gustavo E., Patricia Gutti, and Néstor A. Le Clech. 2007. Indicadores de Capacidades Tecnológicas en América Latina. CEPAL, Serie Estudios y Perspectivas (México, DF) No. 89. Available online: https://hdl.handle.net/11362/5014 (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  88. Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil. 1992. A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 407–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Miller, Stephen M., and Mukti P. Upadhyay. 2000. The Effects of Openness, Trade Orientation, and Human Capital on Total Factor Productivity. Journal of Development Economics 63: 399–423. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. 1994. Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. The Review of Economic Studies 61: 631–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Nicoletti, Giuseppe, and Stefano Scarpetta. 2003. Regulation, productivity and growth: OECD evidence. Economic Policy 18: 9–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. North, Douglass. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. O’Donnell, Christopher. 2008. An Aggregate Quantity-Price Framework for Measuring and Decomposing Productivity and Profitability Change. Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis WP 07/2008. St. Lucia: University of Queensland. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. O’Donnell, Christopher. 2010. Measuring and Decomposing Agricultural Productivity and profitability Change. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 54: 527–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. O’Donnell, Christopher. 2011a. DPIN 3.0: A Program for Decomposing Productivity Index Numbers. Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis. St. Lucia: University of Queensland. [Google Scholar]
  96. O’Donnell, Christopher. 2011b. The Source of Productivity Change in the Manufacturing Sector of the U. S. Economy. Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis WP 07/2011. St. Lucia: University of Queensland. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. O’Donnell, Christopher. 2012. An Aggregate Quantity-Price Framework for Measuring and Decomposing Productivity and Profitability Change. Journal of Productivity Analysis 38: 255–72. Available online: https://www.jstor.org/stable/43549951 (accessed on 14 December 2022). [CrossRef]
  98. O’Donnell, Christopher. 2014. Econometric estimation of distance functions and associated measures of productivity and efficiency change. Journal of Productivity Analysis 41: 187–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  99. O’Donnell, Christopher. 2018. Productivity and Efficiency Analysis: An Economic Approach to Measuring and Explaining Managerial Performance. Singapore: Springer. ISBN 978-981-13-2984-5. [Google Scholar]
  100. Papyrakis, Elissaios. 2019. The resource curse. What have we learned from two decades of intensive research: Introduction. In Why Does Development Fail in Resource Rich Economies. Edited by Elissaios Papyrakis. Abingdon: Routledge, pp. 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  101. Papyrakis, Elissaios, and Lorenzo Pellegrini. 2019. The Resource Curse in Latin America. Oxford: Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  102. Pedroni, Peter. 1996. Fully Modified OLS for Heterogeneous Cointegrated Panels and the Case of Purchasing Power Parity. Bloomington: Manuscript, Department of Economics, Indiana University, vol. 5, pp. 1–45. [Google Scholar]
  103. Pedroni, Peter. 1999. Critical values for cointegration tests in heterogeneous panels with multiple regressors. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 61: 653–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  104. Pedroni, Peter. 2000. Fully modified OLS for heterogeneous cointegrated panels. In Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration and Dynamic Panels. Edited by Badi H. Baltagi, Thomas Fomby and R. Carter Hill. Amsterdam: Elsevier, vol. 15, pp. 93–130. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  105. Pedroni, Peter. 2001. Purchasing power parity tests in cointegrated panels. Review of Economics and Statistics 83: 727–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  106. Pedroni, Peter. 2004. Panel cointegration: Asymptotic and finite sample properties of pooled time series tests with an application to the PPP hypothesis. Econometric Theory 20: 597–625. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  107. Pedroni, Peter. 2019. Panel cointegration techniques and open challenges. Panel Data Econometrics 1: 251–287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  108. Pesaran, M. Hashem. 2007. A simple panel unit root test in the presence of cross-section dependence. Journal of Applied Economics 22: 265–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  109. Pesaran, M. Hashem. 2015. Testing weak cross-sectional dependence in large panels. Econometric Reviews 34: 1089–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  110. Pesaran, M. Hashem. 2021. General diagnostic tests for cross-sectional dependence in panels. Empirical Economics 60: 13–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  111. Pesaran, M. Hashem, and Takashi Yamagata. 2008. Testing slope homogeneity in large panels. Journal of Econometrics 142: 50–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  112. Rodrik, Dani. 2018. Populism and the economics of globalization. Journal of International Business Policy 1: 12–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  113. Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi. 2004. Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth 9: 131–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  114. Rodríguez-Apolinar, Sergio, and Eduardo Fernández-Arias. 2016. The Productivity Gap in Latin America: Lessons from 50 Years of Development. Working Paper No. IDB-WP-692. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  115. Sachs, Jeffrey, and Joaquín Vial. 2001. Can Latin America Compete? The Latin American Competitiveness Report, 2001–2002. pp. 10–29. Available online: https://web.worldbank.org/archive/website00969/WEB/PDF/GCR_LAC_.PDF (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  116. Santiago, Renato, José Alberto Fuinhas, and António Cardoso Marques. 2020. The impact of globalization and economic freedom on economic growth: The case of the Latin America and Caribbean countries. Economic Change and Restructuring 53: 61–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  117. Siddiqui, Danish Ahmed, and Qazi Masood Ahmed. 2013. The effect of institutions on economic growth: A global analysis based on GMM dynamic panel estimation. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 24: 18–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  118. Toscani, Frederik. 2017. The Impact of Natural Resource Discoveries in Latin America and the Caribbean: A Closer Look at the Case of Bolivia (February 2017). IMF Working Paper 17–27. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2938326 (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  119. Ugur, Mehmet. 2010. Institutions and Economic Performance: A Review of the Theory and Evidence. SSRN Electronic Journal, 1–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  120. UNCTAD. 2006. The Least Developed Countries Report 2006: Developing Productive Capacities. No. E.06.II.D.9. New York and Geneva: United Nations Publication. Available online: https://unctad.org/publication/least-developed-countries-report-2006 (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  121. UNCTAD. 2021. Productive Capacities Index: Methodological Approach and Results. Geneva: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. Available online: https://unctad.org/system/files/official-document/aldc2020d3_en.pdf (accessed on 14 December 2022).
  122. Van Beveren, Ilke. 2012. Total factor productivity estimation: A practical review. Journal of Economic Surveys 26: 98–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  123. Van Biesebroeck, Johannes. 2007. Robustness of productivity estimates. The Journal of Industrial Economics 55: 529–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  124. Van der Ploeg, Frederick. 2011. Natural resources: Curse or blessing? Journal of Economic Literature 49: 366–420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  125. Velasco Guachalla, V. Ximena, Calla Hummel, Sam Handlin, and Amy Erica Smith. 2021. Latin America Erupts: When Does Competitive Authoritarianism Take Root? Journal of Democracy 32: 63–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  126. Wagner, Joachim. 2012. International trade and firm performance: A survey of empirical studies since 2006. Review World Econonomics 148: 235–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  127. Zeeshan, Muhammad, Jiabin Han, Alam Rehman, Hazrat Bilal, Naveed Farooq, Muhammad Waseem, Arif Hussain, Muhammad Khan, and Ilyas Ahmad. 2020. Nexus between foreign direct investment, energy consumption, natural resource, and economic growth in Latin American countries. International Journal of Energy Economics and Policy 11: 407–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Variables, definitions and sources.
Table 1. Variables, definitions and sources.
AreaDescriptionVariable
Policy
(International Opening)
Mean tariff rate is the unweighted mean of tariff rates applied to imports.MTR
Tariff is an index that includes aspects, such as; revenues from trade taxes (% of trade sector), mean tariff rate and its standard deviation.Tariff
Capital control is an index based on the International Monetary Fund reports on up to 13 types of international capital controls.CC
Financial openness and capital control is the simple average of these two indexes. The former is an index of de jure financial openness, based on “codify the tabulation of restrictions on cross-border financial transactions reported in the IMF’s Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions”. The second is CC previously defined.FOCC
Controls of the movement of capital and people is a general index that includes; ‘financial openness’, ‘capital controls’, and ‘freedom of foreigners to visit’.CMCP
Freedom to trade internationally is a general index that includes; ‘Tariff’, ‘Regulatory trade barriers’, ‘Black-market exchange rates’ and ‘Controls of the movement of capital and people’.FTI
Policy
(Domestic Regulations)
Credit market regulations consider issues, such as; ‘ownership of banks’, ‘private sector credit’, and ‘interest rate control’.Credit
Labor market regulations include; ‘hiring regulations and minimum wage’, ‘hiring and firing regulations’, ‘Centralized collective bargaining’, ‘hours regulations’, ‘mandated cost of worker dismissal’, and ‘conscription’.Labor
Business regulations consider areas, such as; ‘administrative requirements’, ‘bureaucracy costs’, ‘starting a business’, ‘impartial public administration’, ‘licensing restrictions’, and ‘cost of tax compliance’.Business
Source: Own elaboration.
Table 2. Pesaran (2007) panel unit root tests.
Table 2. Pesaran (2007) panel unit root tests.
Level1st Difference
VariablesConstantConst. + TrendConstant
CIPSCIPSCIPS
TFP−1.216−1.434−2.240 **
NatK−1.296−2.305−3.070 ***
Energy−1.722−1.639−3.168 ***
Transport−1.991−1.699−2.878 ***
ICT−1.775−2.521−2.917 ***
Institutions−1.261−2.229−2.789 ***
MTR−1.800−2.608−3.688 ***
Tariff−1.489−2.194−3.022 ***
CC−1.548−2.031−2.631 ***
FOCC−1.644−2.029−2.857 ***
CMCP−1.478−2.264−2.960 ***
FTI−1.849−1.811−2.963 ***
Credit−1.758−2.441−3.776 ***
Labor−2.070−2.305−3.231 ***
Business−1.905−1.958−2.494 ***
Pesaran’s (2007) critical values: ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.
Table 3. Pesaran’s (2015) CSD test and Bersvendsen and Ditzen’s (2021) slope homogeneity test.
Table 3. Pesaran’s (2015) CSD test and Bersvendsen and Ditzen’s (2021) slope homogeneity test.
ModelsCSD TestSlope Homogeneity Test.
CD-Stats.p-ValueDelta Adj.p-Value
Model 10.8350.404−0.0410.967
Model 2−0.1740.862−0.2360.813
Model 3−0.3460.729−0.9290.770
Model 4−0.7800.436−0.1980.873
Model 50.0610.951−0.0220.983
Model 6−0.1780.859−0.1520.879
Model 7−0.8790.379−0.3850.700
Model 8−0.3310.741−0.0650.948
Model 90.4720.637−0.1550.877
Table 4. Pedroni’s cointegration tests. Group-mean statistics.
Table 4. Pedroni’s cointegration tests. Group-mean statistics.
ModelsModified Phillips–PerronPhillips–PerronAugmented Dickey–Fuller
tp-Valuetp-Valuetp-Value
Model 16.28830.0000−1.81130.0350−3.33930.0004
Model 26.21880.0000−2.31570.0103−2.72030.0033
Model 36.14960.0000−4.31810.0000−3.10190.0010
Model 46.40220.0000−4.58670.0000−2.42650.0076
Model 56.29880.0000−2.18290.0145−2.90330.0018
Model 65.95600.0000−6.41850.0000−4.30570.0000
Model 76.58210.0000−5.15110.0000−2.60470.0046
Model 86.61020.0000−6.05770.0000−4.21230.0000
Model 95.99850.0000−3.63310.0001−7.84110.0000
Table 5. Grouped-mean FMOLS. Models 1, 2 and 3.
Table 5. Grouped-mean FMOLS. Models 1, 2 and 3.
Model 1: Policy = MTRModel 2: Policy = TariffModel 3: Policy = CC
VariablesCoef.p-ValueVIFCoef.p-ValueVIFCoef.p-ValueVIF
NatK1.2000.0061.1811.4950.0011.1061.7510.0001.388
Energy0.8900.0001.3230.9310.0001.5270.9920.0001.216
Transport0.0600.0241.1260.0730.0011.1770.0510.0901.132
ICT0.2420.0001.5380.2690.0001.5420.2870.0001.764
Institutions0.2270.0001.0730.2810.0001.1290.1770.0001.079
Policy0.4540.0001.1170.1380.0451.0890.0740.0001.032
CD-Stat. and p-values in brackets0.114(0.909) 1.020(0.294) 0.262(0.793)
Table 6. Grouped-mean FMOLS. Models 4, 5 and 6.
Table 6. Grouped-mean FMOLS. Models 4, 5 and 6.
Model 4: Policy = FOCCModel 5: Policy = CMCPModel 6: Policy = FTI
VariablesCoef.p-ValueVIFCoef.p-ValueVIFCoef.p-ValueVIF
NatK1.2210.0011.5161.1800.0011.0811.0250.0031.123
Energy1.0940.0001.2030.8200.0001.1730.6820.0001.127
Transport0.0550.0601.1270.0560.0561.0990.0360.2161.086
ICT0.2580.0001.8230.2540.0001.2910.2600.0001.232
Institutions0.2100.0001.0760.2550.0001.0350.2030.0001.040
Policy0.1780.0001.0240.0680.0011.0100.1290.0001.061
CD-Stat. and p-values in brackets3.712(0.000) −1.618(0.106) −0.804(0.421)
Table 7. Grouped-mean FMOLS. Models 7, 8 and 9.
Table 7. Grouped-mean FMOLS. Models 7, 8 and 9.
Model 7: Policy = CreditModel 8: Policy = LaborModel 9: Policy = Business
VariablesCoef.p-ValueVIFCoef.p-ValueVIFCoef.p-ValueVIF
NatK1.9520.0001.0511.2170.0011.0751.6660.0001.252
Energy0.8690.0001.5930.7050.0001.3090.9150.0001.279
Transport0.0630.0411.2710.0190.5631.180−0.0290.3911.190
ICT0.2870.0001.7070.2810.0001.4790.2840.0002.004
Institutions0.1940.0001.1050.1490.0011.1000.2000.0001.098
Policy0.1730.0001.126−0.0140.5371.0730.0520.0221.303
CD-Stat. and p-values in brackets0.997(0.319) −0.728(0.467) 0.052(0.959)
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Le Clech, N.; Guevara-Pérez, J.C. Latin America and the Caribbean’s Productivity: The Role of Pro-Market Policies, Institutions, Infrastructure, and Natural Resource Endowments. Economies 2023, 11, 142. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11050142

AMA Style

Le Clech N, Guevara-Pérez JC. Latin America and the Caribbean’s Productivity: The Role of Pro-Market Policies, Institutions, Infrastructure, and Natural Resource Endowments. Economies. 2023; 11(5):142. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11050142

Chicago/Turabian Style

Le Clech, Néstor, and Juan Carlos Guevara-Pérez. 2023. "Latin America and the Caribbean’s Productivity: The Role of Pro-Market Policies, Institutions, Infrastructure, and Natural Resource Endowments" Economies 11, no. 5: 142. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11050142

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop