Next Article in Journal
The Ownership Structure, and the Environmental, Social, and Governance (ESG) Disclosure, Firm Value and Firm Performance: The Audit Committee as Moderating Variable
Next Article in Special Issue
Income-Related Inequality in Health Care Utilization and Out-of-Pocket Payments in China: Evidence from a Longitudinal Household Survey from 2000 to 2015
Previous Article in Journal
Supply and Demand Model for a Chili Enterprise System Using a Simultaneous Equations System
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Industrial Pattern of Italian Regions: A Disaggregated Sectoral Analysis Based on Input–Output Tables
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Financial Development and Language Structures

by
Gregory W. Caskey
1 and
Nabamita Dutta
2,*
1
Tommy & Victoria Baker School of Business, The Citadel, The Military College of South Carolina, 89 Hagood Avenue, Charleston, SC 29409, USA
2
Department of Economics, College of Business Administration, University of Wisconsin-La Crosse, 1725 State St., La Crosse, WI 54601, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2022, 10(12), 313; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10120313
Submission received: 18 March 2022 / Revised: 18 October 2022 / Accepted: 4 November 2022 / Published: 8 December 2022

Abstract

:
Using cross country data, we explore the role of linguistic structures for the financial development of countries. Specially, we investigate if future time reference (FTR), the requirement of an obligatory future tense marking in languages, matters for financial development or not. Our results show that countries speaking weak FTR language or a language not needing a dedicated future tense marking have enhanced financial development relative to countries speaking strong FTR language. Discounting the future less or having a connection between the present and the future—characteristics of weak FTR languages—has implications for caring about saving and investment, having efficient property rights, protection of shareholders and cost of acquiring information. Our results are robust to multiple measures of financial development and inclusion of determinants of the same. Finally, results show that weak FTR language speaking countries benefit more when their financial development is low.

1. Introduction

The findings related to the role of financial development for economic growth is ambiguous in the literature.1 While an extensive set of studies have stressed the impact of financial development on economic growth to be positive (Bekaert et al. 2005; Christopoulos and Tsionas 2004; Arestis et al. 2001; Xu 2000; Levine et al. 2000; Levine and Zervos 1998), other studies find financial development’s effect on growth to be insignificant (Ho and Saadaoui 2022; Demetriades and Hussein 1996). More recent investigations utilizing time series data exploring the impact of financial development on growth find the effect to be weak or even negative (Cevik and Rahmati 2020; Nwani and Bassey Orie 2016; Adeniyi et al. 2015; Samargandi et al. 2014; Quixina and Almeida 2014). Such findings are of interest, particularly because in the context of other development outcomes, financial development has been shown to be beneficial for poverty alleviation (Rewilak 2017), enhancing the effectiveness for aid-recipient countries (Nkusu and Sayek 2004), promoting foreign direct investment (Desbordes and Wei 2017) and generating comparative advantage for manufacturing economies (Beck 2002).
Given these findings, many studies have explored the determinants of financial development, including institutional determinants (Roe and Siegel 2011; Herger et al. 2008; Beck and Levine 2004; Galindo and Micco 2004; Rajan and Zingales 2003; Johnson et al. 2000), policy determinants (Chinn and Ito 2006; Boyd et al. 2001; Huybens and Smith 1999) and economic development-related determinants (Levine 1997, 2003, 2005; Jaffee and Levonian 2001). We add to this strand of literature by exploring the role of linguistic structures for financial development. Specifically, we explore a specific linguistic trait—future time reference—and investigate if it explains differences in financial development across countries along with other factors.
In recent years, a number of studies have investigated the effects of linguistic traits on economic outcomes (Chen 2013; Galor et al. 2016; Mavisakalyan et al. 2018). One in particular, future time reference (FTR), is a linguistic trait indicating whether languages require an obligatory future tense marking. Languages such as English and French are strong FTR languages, as these languages require a dedicated form when referring to future events. In English, we state she will go to New York tomorrow. The same in French is stated as Elle ira à New York demain. Words like “will go” and “ira” represent a marked future tense. In contrast, languages such as German and Finnish are weak FTR languages, as the same grammatical form can be used for the future and the present. In German, for example, the same sentence can be stated as Morgen geht sie nach New York. The word ”geht” indicating “goes” can be used for present and future tense.
We hypothesize that financial development is benefitted in countries where agents speak “weak” FTR languages relative to countries speaking “strong” FTR languages. In the context of FTR, the notion of “temporal displacement” (Mavisakalyan et al. 2018) suggests that dedicated used of grammar to indicate future events can make the future very distant for the individual. In the case of these strong FTR languages, the future can potentially appear discontinuous to the present relative to speakers of weak FTR languages.
As emphasized in the literature, the five key functions of the financial system include ex-ante production of information and allocating capital, generating effective corporate governance, mobilization of savings into investment, efficient risk management and minimizing cost in financial transactions (Dutta and Meierrieks 2021; World Bank 2012). We argue that FTR has effects on these outcomes, particularly through the channel of individual differences in future discounting. For example, individuals speaking strong FTR languages may be likely to care less about savings and financial intermediaries under such language structures, are less likely to be bothered less about easing the cost of acquiring capital as that can be put away for the future.2 Likewise, well-functioning property rights are considered to be an essential part of financial development. The incentive for structuring such operational property rights might be lacking for agents speaking strong FTR languages. Since the future does not seem connected to the present, essential functions of the financial system—allocating resources effectively, protecting investors, sharing of information—can appear less rewarding. Thus, financial development is likely to suffer in countries speaking strong FTR languages. In contrast, agents speaking weak FTR languages are likely to discount the future less, as they cognitively associate the connection between the present and the future relative to strong FTR language speakers, and thus, are incentivized to generate an effective financial system. Under weak FTR language structures, agents are likely to place effort in effectively allocating capital towards saving and investment, create systems that protect investors and shareholders, and work towards minimizing the cost of acquiring information about financial decision making.
Our contribution in this paper is adding to the extensive strand of studies that have looked into the determinants of financial development and highlighting the role of language structures. Our results show that countries speaking weak FTR languages are likely to have between 10 and 25% percentage more financial development (depending on the specific measure of financial development used) relative to countries speaking strong FTR languages. Our results are robust to the inclusion of an array of controls, including political institutions. We check our results to alternate measures of financial development assessing its different characteristics—financial depth, size of the financial system, efficiency and extent of equity market activities.
Section 2 provides a brief background and literature review. Section 3 explains data and the sources. In Section 4, we describe the empirical methodology and benchmark results. Robustness analysis is described in Section 5, and Section 6 concludes.

2. Literature Review

The idea that linguistic traits can influence thought, and thus have effects on human behavior, has long been investigated. Based on the works of de Saussure (1916) and Wittgenstein (1922), the Sapir–Whorf hypothesis (SWH) stresses the idea that language can influence thought. Subsequent lines of research have explored this idea in various context. Though the hypothesis has been supported by many studies, the seminal works of Chomsky (1957) and Pinker (1994) have contested these findings, stressing that languages do not shape human cognition or ways of thinking. In subsequent decades, the Linguistic Relativity Hypothesis (LRH) was developed, which advances the Sapir–Whorf hypothesis by stating that both human cognition and behavior can be shaped by languages. While LRH was regarded as misguided by some linguists and cognitive scientists (Mavisakalyan et al. 2018), a substantial and ever-growing body of literature emerged starting in the 1990s testifying to the validity of the theory (Levinson and Wilkins 2006; Kay and Regier 2006; Boroditsky et al. 2003; Slobin 2003; Levinson 1996).
The idea that there’s a direct influence of language on cognition and behavior is at the heart of the Linguistic Relativity Hypothesis (LRH). In a nutshell, the LRH states that the structure of one’s language has a systematic influence on cognition and behavior, and as such, different languages represent the world in different ways by emphasizing different aspects of reality. As a result, speakers of a certain language may be more sensitive to various features of the world relative to speakers of another language. For example, studies in psychology like Harner (1981) show that for children speaking English, the use of future tense begins as early as age 3. English is considered to be a strong FTR language or a language requiring a dedicated future marker. Szagun (1978) also investigate differences in FTR for English (strong FTR language) and German (weak FTR language). He found no differences in future verb usage among children but did find such differences being reflected among adults.
As Mavisakalyan and Weber (2018) point out, the studies in economics on the effects of language on social outcomes differ from those studies in linguistics and psychology in a few significant ways. Whereas the former utilize much larger sample sizes and focus on the connection between language and broader economic and social outcomes, those studies in linguistics and psychology tend to use smaller sample sizes and focus on smaller, more specific cognitive effects. While studies like Licht et al. (2007) and Tabellini (2008) have considered linguistic structures as a source of exogenous variation in culture (Mavisakalyan and Weber 2018), more recent studies have considered linguistic traits as proxies for culture (Bhalotra et al. 2015; Santacreu-Vasut et al. 2014). Some studies have focused on investigating the effect of linguistic traits on various outcomes, explaining the association through the channels of both culture and cognition, but without distinguishing well between the two (Hicks et al. 2015; Santacreu-Vasut et al. 2013). Studies like Chen (2013) and Mavisakalyan (2015) claim that linguistic structures affect behavior and, thus, outcomes by directly altering individual’s cognition. Studies such as these form the base of the new LRH literature.
As an example of the future marker, we can give the example of English where specific words like “will” or “is going to” has to be used to indicate “ it will snow tomorrow”. On the other hand, a language like German can imply the same thing by stating Morgen schneien es and not using grammar to indicate marked future events. Chen (2013) emphasizes that languages requiring grammar to indicate marked future events or strong future time reference (FTR) languages have speakers that are less future-oriented behavior which, in turn, lead inefficient outcomes.3 As examples of inefficient outcomes, Chen finds that individuals speaking strong FTR languages save less, have less wealth after retirement, smoke more, tend to be obese and engage in unsafe sex.4
Galor et al. (2016) mention that speakers of languages that do not have marked grammar use indicating future tense are likely to have long-term orientation. Long term orientation or the lack of it affects individual’s discounting of future. A reduction in an agent’s discount rates can be because of long term orientation. Speakers of strong FTR languages are likely to discount much more relative to speakers of weak FTR languages (Mavisakalyan et al. 2018). As such, FTR is relevant to the long tradition of studies on the human tendency to discount future costs and rewards (Frederick et al. 2002; Kirby and Herrnstein 1995; Solnick et al. 1980; Ramsey 1928).5

3. Data

3.1. The Sample

Our sample consists of an unbalanced panel of 100 developed and developing countries over the period 2001 to 2018. The panel is unbalanced because our variables of interest are not available for each country for every year. Overall, we have 844 observations for 100 countries, or approximately 8.44 observations for each country. We compile our data from the World Bank’s Global Financial Development Database (GFDD) and World Development Indicators (WDI), as well as from Chen (2013). Below we describe our variables of interest in detail.

3.2. The Main Variables

As our benchmark measure of financial development, we consider the most used measure in the literature—private credit to GDP (Ibrahim and Alagidede 2017a; Jauch and Watzka 2015; Adeniyi et al. 2015; Nikoloski 2012; Clarke et al. 2006; Levine 2005). Specifically, this variable is defined as “domestic private credit to the real sector by deposit money banks” as a percentage of GDP (World Bank 2012). Private credit does not include credits issued to governments and public enterprises, nor does it include credits issued by central banks. This variable is a common measure of financial dept, which captures the financial sector relative to the economy, and has been documented in the literature as having a strong association with long-term economic growth (Beck et al. 2009). A measure of efficient credit allocation, private credit to GDP, signals the credit worthiness of private institutions, as well as accessibility of the credit market to private individuals (Jauch and Watzka 2015). The mean of the variable for our sample is about 73.5 percent with the range of the variable being from 6 percent to about 300 percent,6 and the median of the variable is about 65%. For example, countries like Nigeria, Algeria, Pakistan, Mexico, Argentina and Ghana all have less than 22.5% private credit, which is the 10th percentile value of our sample.
The other alternate measure we considered is private money by deposit money bank and other financial institutions and other financial institutions to GDP. This is a standard alternate indicator of financial depth that has been used in the finance and growth literature (Beck et al. 2000, 2009). The mean for the variable for our sample is 81.34%, and the median of the variable is about 71%. We consider additional financial development measures as part of robustness analysis, which we discuss in subsequent sections.

3.3. Independent Variable

Based on Chen (2013), we classify languages that need a dedicated future marking (such as English and French) as a strong FTR language. On the other hand, languages like German and Finnish that do not require dedicated grammar use to mark future events are categorized as weak FTR languages.7 We construct a dummy, taking the value of 1 for weak FTR languages and 0 for strong FTR languages. We chose this as our independent variable because, as Chen (2013) indicates, agents’ intertemporal preferences and decision making are represented via strong and weak FTR languages. Likewise, Mavisakalyan et al. (2018) argue that future tense (for strong FTR languages) can be used to indicate cultural factors, and that usage of such can effect speakers’ cognition and behavior (or both).
For our sample of countries, 28.2 percent of observations are assigned a dummy of 1 (indicating weak FTR languages), while the remaining 71.8 are assigned 0 (representing strong FTR languages). Our sample has sufficient regional and continental variation. For example, a number of European countries including Denmark, Belgium, Estonia, Germany, Finland, Iceland and Luxembourg have weak FTR languages. Yet, other European countries like France, Czech Republic, Latvia, Greece, Italy, Lithuania, Poland and United Kingdom have strong FTR languages.
Following Chen (2013) and Mavisakalyan et al. (2018), the language considered for each country is the major spoken language. Chen (2013) mentions that, for the majority of countries in our sample, there is no intra-country variation in terms of FTR strength. This implies that, in most countries, either one language dominates or a common FTR structure is shared among the languages for multi-lingual countries. As an example of the latter, Chen points to the example of Canada. While the country has significant English and French speaking populations, both are strong FTR languages. Likewise, Mavisakalyan et al. (2018) mentions that since available information on multi-lingual countries is not easily available, checking results with an alternate measure—share of total population speaking a strong FTR language—reduces the sample. As part of robustness analysis, we consider this measure and check our results.

3.4. Controls

We follow the literature in our choice of benchmark controls, which consist of GDP per capita growth, urban population as a percentage of total population, labor force participation rates, trade openness and polity as a measure of political institutions. Studies like Huang and Temple (2005) and Svaleryd and Vlachos (2002), for instance, show that trade openness is a significant determinant of financial development. Based on both demand and supply side arguments, studies like Jung (1986), Goldsmith (1969), Gurley and Shaw (1967) and Patrick (1966) have stressed a causal relationship from economic growth to financial development. For this reason, we include GDP per capita growth as a measure of economic development within our benchmark controls. As a further measure of economic development (based on the demand side argument), we control for urban population as a percentage of total population. Lastly, since multiple studies have shown that democratic institutions are an important determinant for financial development, we consider the Polity 2 variable, which runs from −10 to +10 with higher values implying more democratic institutions (Begović et al. 2017; Bhattacharyya 2013; Yang 2011; Huang 2010; Clague et al. 1996).

4. Empirical Methodology and Benchmark Results

4.1. Empirical Specification and Methodology

Based on our hypothesis, we test the following regression specification:
FD i t = β 0 + β 1 F T R i + c o n t r o l s + t + ϵ i t
FDit represents the specific financial development measure considered for country i in time t. Our main independent variable of interest is FTR, which represents the future time reference dummy. We remind our readers that FTR dummy takes 1 for weak FTR countries, and 0 for strong FTR countries. According to our hypothesis, we expect β 1 to be positive and significant. This would imply that financial development is higher in weak FTR countries (i.e., those with languages that do not require a dedicated form when referring to future events) relative to strong FTR countries. β 1 being negative and significant would mean the opposite.
Our benchmark measure of financial development is private credit to the real sector by deposit money banks as a percentage of GDP. As an alternate benchmark measure of financial development, we consider private credit to the real sector by deposit money banks and other financial institutions as a percentage of GDP. Our robustness analysis considers alternate measures of financial development.
Since linguistic features and financial development are likely the product of deeper, unobserved factors, we follow the literature in constructing our battery of controls, including observables that can help explain differences in financial development across countries. These, in turn, are unlikely to make the effect of FTR on financial development exogenous and uncorrelated with the error term. Controlling for observables that can help explain differences in financial development across countries is the first step to mitigate bias arising out of omitted variable bias.8 As explained, our benchmark controls are GDP per capita growth, urban population as a percentage of total population, labor force participation rates, trade openness and polity as a measure of political institutions. These variables have been shown to matter for financial development. In the robustness section, we discuss further controlling for additional variables as well as mitigating the effect of unobserved heterogeneity with respect to the effects of FTR on financial development.
Our benchmark analysis consists of ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions. t , our time fixed effects, help us take into account time shocks. For example, global shocks, like the 2009 recession, that likely impact financial development should be captured in time fixed effects. In addition to our OLS specifications, we consider quantile regressions to make sure our results are not driven by the presence of outliers. We talk about endogeneity and how our findings should be interpreted in subsequent sections.

4.2. Benchmark Results

In Table 1, we present our first set of benchmark results with OLS regressions. The dependent variable considered is private credit to GDP. In column (1), we run a bivariate regression without any controls to assess the variation in financial development that is attributed to weak and strong FTR languages. Based on column (1), we find that, relative to strong FTR countries, weak FTR countries have 41 percent more private credit (as a percentage of GDP). Providing an example, this suggests that when compared against strong FTR countries (such as India), weak FTR countries (such as Indonesia) should have much more private credit. However, the coefficient of the FTR dummy in column (1) is capturing effects of other variables that also affect financial development. We add controls in subsequent columns. In column (2), we add labor force participation rate, and in column (3), we control for urban population as a percentage of total population. In column (4), GDP per capita growth is included, and in column (5), we control for trade as a percentage of GDP. Finally in column (6), we add the polity score, which is a measure of how relatively democratic a nation is in terms of its governance.
Once we include all of the aforementioned controls, the effect of FTR on private credit drops to 23 percentage points. This implies that weak FTR countries have 23 percentage points more private credit than strong FTR countries. Our controls are predominantly significant and are of expected sign and significance.9
To account for potential outliers driving our results, we replicate the specifications from Table 1 in Table 2 by using quantile regressions. The results are very similar. The magnitude of FTR dummy is marginally higher compared to Table 1.
For example, in column (1), when we do not include any control variables, the magnitude of difference between weak FTR and strong FTR countries in terms of private credit is 46 percentage points. Once we control for all the variables, it drops to 26 percentage points. The sign and significance of the control variables remain similar to our previous table.
In Table 3, we consider an alternate measure of financial development—private credit to the real sector by deposit money banks and other financial institutions as a percentage of GDP. As mentioned earlier, this is a broader measure of financial depth. We consider both OLS and quantile regressions including all controls. Column (1) in Table 3 presents OLS regression, while column (2) presents quantile regressions. Here, we find that the impact of the FTR dummy for the OLS regression is stronger than in the case of quantile regression. While weak FTR countries have 21 percentage points more private credit (including financial institutions) relative to strong FTR countries in the case of OLS regression, the effect drops to 15 percentage points in the case of quantile regression. Labor force participation rate (LFPR) and urban population are positive and significant in both regressions, while GDP per capita growth is negative and significant in both cases. Trade is not significant in Table 3 specifications.

5. Robustness Analysis

For our robustness analysis, we conduct an array of tests to make sure our results are not sensitive additional controls, alternate fixed effects, or other measures of our linguistic variable (FTR). We start our robustness analysis by controlling for continent fixed effects within our benchmark specifications, the importance of which is emphasized by Ang (2019). Additionally, we consider regional dummies based on the country income classification by the World Bank, as is commonly used in the literature. As Mavisakalyan et al. (2018) point out, because linguistic features can be spatially correlated, this implies that linguistic features can be concentrated in certain areas. Thus, the effect of FTR can be biased due to geographic and climatic factors that are correlated. We present the results in Table 4 with both measures of financial development considered in our benchmark analysis.
Our main conclusions remain unchanged. The impact for private credit as evident from specification (1) is around 12 percentage points, which again implies that weak FTR countries have more private credit compared to strong FTR countries. As anticipated, controlling for continent fixed effects does reduce the magnitude of FTR dummy relative to previous specifications.
We continue our robustness analysis by controlling for additional variables to further mitigate omitted variable bias. Following the extensive literature on the determinants of financial development, we include different measures of human capital in Table 4 to bolster our benchmark set of controls. As Ibrahim and Sare (2018) found, human capital has a robust influence on financial development, thus creating greater demand for financial intermediation and services that constitute the process of financial development.10 In Table 4 column (1), we consider a measure of human capital—net primary enrollment. As an alternate measure of human capital, secondary (net) enrollment in considered in column (2).
Likewise, political institutions have been shown to be an important determinant of financial development in the literature. As Pagano and Volpin (2001) point out, self-interested policy makers can intervene in financial markets for promotion of group interests. Rajan and Zingales (2003) also emphasize the role that interest groups can play in financial development. As Huang (2010) argues, the presence of a stronger elite group favors the interests of elites and restricts democratic participation. Greater shift of power towards elite groups potentially makes the system more autocratic and results in greater obstacles for financial development. In this context, Girma and Shortland (2008) have shown that both democracy and regime change matters for financial development.
With these in mind, we check the sensitivity of our findings with alternate measures of political institutions (other than polity, which we used in our benchmark regressions). The first variable we use is constraints on the chief executive. Based on the data and definition provided by Marshall et al. (2019), the variable, “refers to the extent of institutionalized constraints on the decision-making powers of chief executives, whether individuals or collectivities”. It ranges from 1 to 7, with higher numbers denoting greater constraints as measured by the ability in which “accountability groups” may impose limitations. For example, in Western democracies, these typically take the form of legislatures. Column (3) of Table 4 considers the constraint measure instead of polity.
As an alternate measure, we consider the durability of the political system. Based on the definition set forth by Marshall et al. (2019), it is measured as the number of years “since the last substantive change in authority characteristics (defined as a 3-point change in the POLITY score)”. We consider this measure in column (4). Finally, in column (5) of the table, we consider inflation as an additional control variable.
For all the specifications in Table 4, we consider private credit by deposit money banks (excluding other financial institutions) as the dependent variable. As we can see from the table, the coefficient of FTR is positive and significant for all specifications. In terms of magnitude, for weak FTR countries, weak FTR countries have between 11 and 15 percentage points more private credit. These findings, given our additional controls, suggest that greater constraints and a more durable political system enhance financial development. Likewise, the effects of both education measures are positive and significant as well.
Next, we next consider alternate measures of financial development as dependent variables. We present these results in Table 5. The first alternate measure we consider is liquid liabilities as a percentage of GDP. The measure, used by King and Levine (1993), is the broadest indicator of financial intermediation as it encompasses currency as well as interest bearing liabilities of banks and other financial intermediaries. One other alternate measure considered is bank credit as a percentage of bank deposits. As Beck et al. (2009) state, this measure indicates the ratio of claims on the private sector to deposits in money banks. It is a measure of the efficiency of the financial system as it assesses the extent to which “banks intermediate society’s savings into private sector credits”. The other two measures considered are equity market indicators, including stock market capitalization and stock market total value, both as a percentage of GDP. The size of the equity markets relative to the size of the economy are captured by these two indicators. The first measure, stock market capitalization to GDP, assessing activity of the stock market equals total shares traded on the stock market as a percentage of GDP. The second measure, stock market total value to GDP, also measures activity of the stock market but in terms of trading volume as a share of national output.
In Table 5, we find that the FTR dummy is positive and significant across all measures. The effect of the FTR dummy is the strongest in the case of the liquid liabilities measure, while the magnitude is the least in the case of stock market capitalization measure. In the case of liquid liabilities, weak FTR countries have 34 percentage points more liquid liabilities relative to strong FTR countries. In the case of bank deposits, the magnitude is about 23 percentage points.
For the final part of our robustness analysis, we investigate if strong or weak FTR matters differently for high or low levels of financial development. In other words, do countries speaking weak FTR languages benefit more if they have lower levels of financial development relative to countries speaking weak FTR countries but have higher levels of financial development? We run quantile regressions for the 25th, 50th and 75th percentiles of financial development based on our sample. In Table 6, we consider our benchmark measure of financial development—private credit. We also consider the other broader measure of private credit—private credit to the real sector by deposit money banks and other financial institutions as a percentage of GDP. In column (1), we consider the private credit measure, and in column (2), we consider the private credit (plus financial institutions) measure. We report the results for our main variable of interest, FTR dummy, for the 25th, 50th and 75th percentiles of financial development.11
We find that the FTR dummy has the strongest effect for both measures of financial development for the 25th percentile. For both measures, weak FTR language speaking countries with financial development in the 25th percentile have about 26–27% more private credit or private credit (plus financial institutions) relative to strong FTR language countries in the same financial development percentile. For countries in the highest percentile (75th percentile) of financial development, weak FTR language speaking countries also benefit more than strong FTR language speaking countries but by a lesser magnitude. Thus, across all specifications, we observe that weak FTR languages are associated with enhanced financial development relative to strong FTR countries.

6. Conclusions

Given the implications of financial development for economic growth and varied development outcomes (Ibrahim and Alagidede 2017b; Mishra and Narayan 2015; Masten et al. 2008; Rioja and Valev 2004; Calderon and Liu 2003), the factors that shape a country’s economic development remains an important research question to consider. Our results add to the literature on the determinants of financial development by finding that linguistic structures of countries play an important role in affecting financial development. Specifically, our results show that countries speaking weak future time reference (FTR) language experience enhanced financial development relative to countries speaking strong future time reference (FTR) languages. In light of this, weak FTR languages discount the future relatively less and maintain the connection between present and the future. Due to this, individual speakers of these languages are more likely to work towards creating and bettering property rights institutions, investor protection, efficient corporate governance and information symmetry for all participants in financial markets. In terms of policy implications, it does not seem reasonable to build policies to change language structures. Linguistic structures are exogenous factors and prevalent in countries over the very long term. Yet, being aware of how such language structures can affect financial development can help policy makers to create an environment that can mitigate the adverse effect of strong FTR languages.
We want to point out that this is a preliminary analysis exploring the relationship between linguistic traits and financial development. We want to remind our readers again that our results and economic interpretations should be read as significant correlation between the variables and not as causation. Future studies can establish identification considering external instruments or matching techniques. We have stuck to the benchmark measure of FTR used in the literature, which is the dummy indicating strong or weak FTR countries based on major spoken language. Additional nuanced measures considering language family or verb ration is beyond the scope of our analysis. We hope this study leads to further research on the important topic of language structures and financial markets and institutions.

Author Contributions

N.D. obtained the data and conducted the empirical analysis. N.D. and G.W.C. discussed the results and wrote the paper. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

N. Dutta gratefully acknowledges the financial support from Menard Family Initiative (MFI), University of Wisconsin-La Crosse.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Data supporting reported results is available upon request.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Notes

1
“Financial development” generally refers to a financial system’s ability to engage in information and capital allocation, effective corporate governance, the mobilization of savings into investment, efficient risk management, and minimizing the costs of financial transactions (Dutta and Meierrieks 2021; World Bank 2012).
2
For instance, see Dar and Sahu (2022), who highlight three possible channels through which the effects of FTR are mediated upon financial inclusion, including patience, educational attainment, and tax morale.
3
Importantly, Chen (2013) points out that differences between weak and strong FTR language speakers, “… do not reflect innate cognitive nor early cultural differences between speakers of different languages …”.
4
In response to questions regarding spurious correlations in Chen (2013), a study by Roberts et al. (2015) introduced additional controls and robustness analyses to further account for the idea that cultures and languages co-evolve, as opposed languages being strictly exogenous. Controlling for the geographic and historical interrelatedness of languages. Their results yield weaker results than Chen (2013), but continued to find a considerably robust correlation between linguistic features and future-oriented decision making.
5
While a number of studies make the connection between FTR and future decision-making, several recent studies provide contrary evidence. See for instance Chen et al. (2019), Angerer et al. (2021), and Jäggi et al. (2022), who examined the linguistic-savings hypothesis and did not find evidence in support of the hypothesis.
6
Similar to variables like Foreign Direct Investment as a percentage of GDP or Trade as a percentage of GDP, for small countries with small GDP, the private credit share can be much larger.
7
Chen’s classification of languages that need an obligatory future time reference is adopted from the European Science Foundation’s Typology of Languages in Europe (EUROTYP) project (Dahl 2000). In the case of non-European languages, Chen uses established cross-linguistic analyses. Of the latter, see Cyffer et al. (2009); Nurse (2008); Bybee et al. (1994); Dahl (1985); Dahl and Dienes (1984).
8
That is, while our results are not causal in nature, they are strongly correlative across numerous specifications.
9
For example, the positive and significant association between trade openness and financial development has been document by several studies (Baltagi et al. 2009; Huang and Temple 2005).
10
These findings have been supported with country specific data. For Turkey, for example, see Eryiğit et al. (2015); for India, see Arora and Ratnasiri (2011).
11
Keeping space constraint in mind, additional results are available on request.

References

  1. Adeniyi, Oluwatosin, Abimbola Oyinlola, Olusegun Omisakin, and Festus O. Egwaikhide. 2015. Financial development and economic growth in Nigeria: Evidence from threshold modelling. Economic Analysis and Policy 47: 11–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Ang, Desmond. 2019. Do 40-Year-Old Facts Still Matter? Long-Run Effects of Federal Oversight under the Voting Rights Act. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 11: 1–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Angerer, Silvia, Daniela Glätzle-Rützler, Philipp Lergetporer, and Matthias Sutter. 2021. The effects of language on patience: An experimental replication study of the linguistic-savings hypothesis in Austria. Journal of the Economic Science Association 7: 88–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Arestis, Philip, Panicos O. Demetriades, and Kul B. Luintel. 2001. Financial development and economic growth: The role of stock markets. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 33: 16–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Arora, Rashmi Umesh, and Shyama Ratnasiri. 2011. Financial Development, Financial Inclusion and Human Capital: How Close is the Link? A Study of India. Paper Presented in the Indian Economy; Australian National University. Available online: https://www.crawford.anu.edu.au/acde/asarc/pdf/papers/conference/INDIA2011_05.pdf (accessed on 1 September 2022).
  6. Baltagi, Badi H., Panicos O. Demetriades, and Siong Hook Law. 2009. Financial development and openness: Evidence from panel data. Journal of Development Economics 89: 285–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Beck, Thorsten. 2002. Financial development and international trade: Is there a link? Journal of International Economics 57: 107–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Beck, Thorsten, and Ross Levine. 2004. Stock markets, banks, and growth: Panel evidence. Journal of Banking and Finance 28: 423–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Ross Levine. 2009. Financial Institutions and Markets across Countries and over Time: Data and Analysis. Policy Research Working Paper: No. 4943. Washington, DC: World Bank. [Google Scholar]
  10. Beck, Thorsten, Ross Levine, and Norman Loayza. 2000. Finance and the sources of growth. Journal of Financial Economics 58: 261–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Begović, Boris, Zorica Mladenović, and Danica Popović. 2017. Democracy, Distance from the Technological Frontier, and Economic Growth: Some Empirical Results. CLDS Working Paper #0217. Belgrade: Center for Liberal-Democratic Studies. [Google Scholar]
  12. Bekaert, Geert, Campbell R. Harvey, and Christian Lundblad. 2005. Does financial liberalization spur growth? Journal of Financial Economics 77: 3–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Bhalotra, Sonia, Damian Clarke, Joseph F. Gomes, and Atheendar Venkataramani. 2015. Maternal mortality and female life expectancy: The importance of gender inequality. Unpublished manuscript. [Google Scholar]
  14. Bhattacharyya, Sambit. 2013. Political origins of financial structure. Journal of Comparative Economics 41: 979–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Boroditsky, Lera, Lauren A. Schmidt, and Webb Phillips. 2003. Sex, Syntax, and Semantics. In Language in Mind: Advances in the Study of Language and Cognition. Edited by Dedre Gentner and Susan Goldin-Meadow. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
  16. Boyd, John H., Ross Levine, and Bruce D. Smith. 2001. The impact of inflation on financial sector performance. Journal of Monetary Economics 47: 221–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Bybee, Joan L., Revere Dale Perkins, and William Pagliuca. 1994. The Evolution of Grammar: Tense, Aspect, and Modality in the Languages of the World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [Google Scholar]
  18. Calderon, César, and Lin Liu. 2003. The direction of causality between financial development and economic growth. Journal of Development Economics 72: 321–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  19. Cevik, Serhan, and Mohammad H. Rahmati. 2020. Searching for the finance–growth nexus in Libya. Empirical Economics 58: 567–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Chen, Josie I., Tai-Sen He, and Yohanes E. Riyanto. 2019. The effect of language on economic behavior: Examining the causal link between future tense and time preference in the lab. European Economic Review 120: 103307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Chen, M. Keith. 2013. The Effect of Language on Economic Behavior: Evidence from Savings Rates, Health Behaviors, and Retirement Assets. American Economic Review 103: 690–731. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Chinn, Menzie D., and Hiro Ito. 2006. What matters for financial development? Capital controls, institutions, and interactions. Journal of Development Economics 81: 163–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Chomsky, Noam. 1957. Syntactic Structures. The Hague and Paris: Mouton. [Google Scholar]
  24. Christopoulos, Dimitris K., and Efthymios G. Tsionas. 2004. Financial development and economic growth: Evidence from panel unit root and cointegration tests. Journal of Development Economics 73: 55–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Clague, Christopher, Philip Keefer, Stephen Knack, and Mancur Olson. 1996. Property and Contract Rights under Democracy and Dictatorship. The Journal of Economic Growth 1: 243–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Clarke, George R. G., Lixin Colin Xu, and Heng-Fu Zou. 2006. Finance and Income Inequality: What Do the Data Tell Us? Southern Economic Journal 72: 578–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Cyffer, Norbert, Georg Ziegelmeyer, and Erwin Ebermann. 2009. Negation Patterns in West African Languages and Beyond. Amsterdam: John Benjamins Publishing. [Google Scholar]
  28. Dahl, Östen. 1985. Tense and Aspect Systems. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. [Google Scholar]
  29. Dahl, Östen. 2000. The Grammar of Future Time Reference in European Languages. In Tense and Aspect in the Languages of Europe. Edited by Östen Dahl. Berlin: Mouton de Gruyter. [Google Scholar]
  30. Dahl, Östen, and Dora Kós Dienes. 1984. Selected Working Papers from the Tense-Mood-Aspect Project. Stockholm: Institute of Linguistics, University of Stockholm. [Google Scholar]
  31. Dar, Shafkat Shafi, and Sohini Sahu. 2022. The effect of language on financial inclusion. Economic Modelling 106: 105693. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. de Saussure, Ferdinand. 1916. Course in General Linguistics. Edited by Charles Bally and Albert Sechehaye Harris. Translated by Roy Harris. 1983. La Salle: Open Court. [Google Scholar]
  33. Demetriades, Panicos O., and Khaled A. Hussein. 1996. Does financial development cause economic growth? Time-series evidence from 16 countries. Journal of Development Economics 51: 387–411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Desbordes, Rodolphe, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2017. The effects of financial development on foreign direct investment. Journal of Development Economics 127: 153–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Dutta, Nabamita, and Daniel Meierrieks. 2021. Financial development and entrepreneurship. International Review of Economics, and Finance 73: 114–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Eryiğit, Sibel Balı, Yasin Eryiğit Kadir, and Dülgeroğlu Ercan. 2015. Local Financial Development and Capital Accumulations: Evidence from Turkey. Panoeconomicus 62: 339–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Frederick, Shane, George Loewenstein, and Ted O’Donoghue. 2002. Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature 40: 351–401. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Galindo, Arturo, and Alejandro Micco. 2004. Creditor Protection and Financial Markets: Empirical Evidence and Implications for Latin America. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Economic Review Q2: 29–37. [Google Scholar]
  39. Galor, Oded, Ömer Özak, and Assaf Sarid. 2016. Geographical Origins and Economic Consequences of Language Structures. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 6149. Munich: Center for Economic Studies and the Ifo Institute. [Google Scholar]
  40. Girma, Sourafel, and Anja Shortland. 2008. The political economy of financial development. Oxford Economic Papers 60: 567–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Goldsmith, Raymond W. 1969. Financial Structure and Development. New Haven: Yale University Press. [Google Scholar]
  42. Gurley, John G., and Edward S. Shaw. 1967. Financial structure and economic development. Economic Development and Cultural Change 34: 333–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Harner, Lorraine. 1981. Children Talk about the Time and Aspect of Actions. 1981. Child Development 52: 498–506. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Herger, Nils, Roland Hodler, and Michael Lobsiger. 2008. What Determines Financial Development? Culture, Institutions or Trade. Review of World Economics 144: 558–87. [Google Scholar]
  45. Hicks, Daniel L., Estefania Santacreu-Vasut, and Amir Shoham. 2015. Does mother tongue make for women’s work? Linguistics, household labor, and gender identity. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 110: 19–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Ho, Sy-Hoa, and Jamel Saadaoui. 2022. Bank credit and economic growth: A dynamic threshold panel model for ASEAN countries. International Economics 170: 115–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Huang, Yongfu. 2010. Political institutions and financial development: An empirical study. World Development 38: 1667–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Huang, Yongfu, and Jonathan R. W. Temple. 2005. Does External Trade Promote Financial Development? CEPR Discussion Paper No. 5150. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=785244 (accessed on 15 September 2022).
  49. Huybens, Elisabeth, and Bruce D. Smith. 1999. Inflation, Financial Markets and Long-Run Real Activity. Journal of Monetary Economics 43: 283–315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Ibrahim, Muazu, and Paul Alagidede. 2017a. Financial Development, Growth Volatility and Information Asymmetry in Sub-Saharan Africa: Does Law Matter? South African Journal of Economics 85: 570–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Ibrahim, Muazu, and Paul Alagidede. 2017b. Financial sector development, economic volatility and shocks in sub-Saharan Africa. Physica A 484: 66–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  52. Ibrahim, Muazu, and Yakubu Awudu Sare. 2018. Determinants of financial development in Africa: How robust is the interactive effect of trade openness and human capital? Economic Analysis and Policy 60: 18–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Jaffee, Dwight, and Mark Levonian. 2001. Structure of banking systems in developed and transition economies. European Financial Management 7: 161–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  54. Jäggi, Tiziana, Sayaka Sato, Christelle Gillioz, and Pascal Mark Gygax. 2022. Is the future near or far depending on the verb tense markers used? An experimental investigation into the effects of the grammaticalization of the future. PLoS ONE 17: e0262778. [Google Scholar]
  55. Jauch, Sebastian, and Sebastian Watzka. 2015. Financial development and income inequality: A panel data approach. Empirical Economics 51: 291–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  56. Johnson, Simon, Peter Boone, Alasdair Breach, and Eric Friedman. 2000. Corporate Governance in the Asian Financial Crisis. Journal of Financial Economics 58: 141–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  57. Jung, Woo S. 1986. Financial development and economic growth: International evidence. Economic Development and Cultural Change 34: 336–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Kay, Paul, and Terry Regier. 2006. Language, thought and colour: Recent developments. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 10: 51–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  59. King, Robert G., and Ross Levine. 1993. Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108: 717–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Kirby, Kris N., and Richard J. Herrnstein. 1995. Preference reversals due to myopic discounting of delayed reward. Psychological Science 6: 83–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Levine, Ross. 1997. Financial development and economic growth: Views and agenda. Journal of Economic Literature 35: 688–726. [Google Scholar]
  62. Levine, Ross. 2003. More on Finance and Growth: More Finance, More Growth? St. Louis: The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. [Google Scholar]
  63. Levine, Ross. 2005. Finance and growth: Theory and evidence. In Handbook of Economic Growth. Edited by Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf. Amstedam: Elsevier, pp. 865–934. [Google Scholar]
  64. Levine, Ross, and Sara Zervos. 1998. Stock markets, banks, and economic growth. American Economic Review 88: 537–58. [Google Scholar]
  65. Levine, Ross, Norman Loayza, and Thorsten Beck. 2000. Financial intermediation and growth: Causality and causes. Journal of Monetary Economics 46: 31–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  66. Levinson, Stephen C. 1996. Frames of reference and Molyneux’s question: Crosslinguistic evidence. In Language and Space. Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press, pp. 109–69. [Google Scholar]
  67. Levinson, Stephen C., and David P. Wilkins. 2006. Grammars of Space: Explorations in Cognitive Diversity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  68. Licht, Amir N., Chanan Goldschmidt, and Shalom H. Schwartz. 2007. Culture rules: The foundations of the rule of law and other norms of governance. Journal of Comparative Economics 35: 659–88. [Google Scholar]
  69. Marshall, Monty G., Ted Robert Gurr, and Keith Jaggers. 2019. Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800–2018. Center for Systemic Peace: Available online: https://www.systemicpeace.org/inscr/p4manualv2018.pdf (accessed on 1 September 2022).
  70. Masten, Arjana Brezigar, Fabrizio Coricelli, and Igor Masten. 2008. Non-linear growth effects of financial development: Does financial integration matter? Journal of International Money and Finance 27: 295–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  71. Mavisakalyan, Astghik. 2015. Gender in Language and Gender in Employment. Oxford Development Studies 43: 403–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Mavisakalyan, Astghik, and Clas Weber. 2018. Linguistic Structures and Economic Outcomes. Journal of Economic Survey 32: 916–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Mavisakalyan, Astghik, Yashar Tarverdi, and Clas Weber. 2018. Talking in the present, caring for the future: Language and environment. Journal of Comparative Economics 46: 1370–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  74. Mishra, Sagarika, and Paresh Kumar Narayan. 2015. A nonparametric model of financial system and economic growth. International Review of Economics and Finance 39: 175–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Nikoloski, Zlatko. 2012. Financial Sector Development and Inequality: Is there a Financial Kuznets curve? Journal of International Development 25: 897–911. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Nkusu, Mwanza, and Selin Sayek. 2004. Local Financial Development and the Aid-Growth Relationship. IMF Working Paper No. 04/238. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=879063 (accessed on 1 September 2022).
  77. Nurse, Derek. 2008. Tense and Aspect in Bantu. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  78. Nwani, Chinazaekpere, and Jacob Bassey Orie. 2016. Economic growth in oil-exporting countries: Do stock market and banking sector development matter? Evidence from Nigeria. Cogent Economics and Finance 4: 1153872. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Pagano, Marco, and Paolo Volpin. 2001. The Political Economy of Finance. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 17: 502–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  80. Patrick, Hugh T. 1966. Financial development and economic growth in underdeveloped countries. Economic Development and Cultural Change 14: 174–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  81. Pinker, Steven. 1994. The Language Instinct: How the Mind Creates Language. New York: William Morrow and Company. [Google Scholar]
  82. Quixina, Yuri, and A. Almeida. 2014. Financial Development and Economic Growth in a Natural Resource Based Economy: Evidence from Angola. FEP Working Papers No: 542. Porto: School of Economics and Management, University of Porto. [Google Scholar]
  83. Rajan, Raghuram G., and Luigi Zingales. 2003. The great reversals: The politics of financial development in the twentieth century. Journal of Financial Economies 69: 5–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Ramsey, Frank Plumpton. 1928. A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal 38: 543–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Rewilak, Johan. 2017. The Impact of Financial Crises on the Poor. Journal of International Development 7: 169–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  86. Rioja, Felix, and Neven Valev. 2004. Does one size fit all? A re-examination of the finance and growth relationship. Journal of Development Economics 74: 429–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Roberts, Seán G., James Winters, and Keith Chen. 2015. Future tense and economic decisions: Controlling for cultural evolution. PLoS ONE 10: e0132145. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
  88. Roe, Mark J., and Jordan I. Siegel. 2011. Political Instability: Its Effects on Financial Development, Its Roots in the Severity of Economic Inequality. Journal of Comparative Economics 39: 279–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  89. Svaleryd, Helena, and Jonas Vlachos. 2002. Markets for risk and openness to trade: How are they related? Journal of International Economics 57: 369–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  90. Samargandi, Nahla, Jan Fidrmuc, and Sugata Ghosh. 2014. Financial development and economic growth in an oil-rich economy: The case of Saudi Arabia. Economic Modelling 43: 267–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Santacreu-Vasut, Estefania, Amir Shoham, and Victor Gay. 2013. Do female/male distinctions in language matter? Evidence from gender political quotas. Applied Economics Letters 20: 495–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Santacreu-Vasut, Estefania, Oded Shenkar, and Amir Shoham. 2014. Linguistic gender marking and its IB ramifications. Journal of International Business Studies 45: 1170–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Slobin, Dan I. 2003. Language and thought online: Cognitive consequences of linguistic relativity. In Language in Mind: Advances in the Investigation of Language and Thought. Edited by Dedre Gentner and Susan Goldin-Meadow. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 157–91. [Google Scholar]
  94. Solnick, Jay V., Catherine H. Kannenberg, David A. Eckerman, and Marcus B. Waller. 1980. An experimental analysis of impulsivity and impulse control in humans. Learning and Motivation 11: 61–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Szagun, Gisela. 1978. On the frequency of use of tenses in English and German children’s spontaneous speech. Child Development 49: 898–901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Tabellini, Guido. 2008. Presidential address institutions and culture. Journal of the European Economic Association 6: 255–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  97. Wittgenstein, Ludwig. 1922. Tractatus Logico-Philosophicus. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. [Google Scholar]
  98. World Bank. 2012. Global Financial Development Report 2013: Rethinking the Role of the State in Finance. Available online: https://www.worldbank.org/en/publication/gfdr (accessed on 15 September 2022).
  99. Xu, Zhenhui. 2000. Financial development, investment, and economic growth. Economic Inquiry 38: 331–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  100. Yang, Benhua. 2011. Does democracy foster financial development?: An empirical analysis. Economic Letters 112: 262–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Private Credit and FTR. OLS regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variable is private credit by deposit money banks as a percentage of GDP. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05.
Table 1. Private Credit and FTR. OLS regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variable is private credit by deposit money banks as a percentage of GDP. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Weak FTR41.22 ***33.35 ***29.12 ***29.45 ***24.51 ***23.25 ***
(3.355)(3.306)(3.484)(3.491)(3.597)(3.620)
LFPR---0.827 ***0.778 ***0.785 ***0.911 ***0.801 ***
(0.131)(0.127)(0.126)(0.129)(0.122)
Urban Population------0.402 ***0.329 ***0.299 ***0.232 ***
(0.087)(0.092)(0.088)(0.087)
GDP per cap. growth ---------−1.520 ***−1.812 ***−1.890 ***
(0.508)(0.521)(0.515)
Trade ------------0.165 ***0.146 ***
(0.024)(0.025)
Polity ---------------0.307
(0.298)
Constant60.40 ***19.64 **−6.692−0.061−13.49−3.707
(7.559)(9.414)(10.91)(11.23)(11.33)(11.19)
Time F.E.YesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations778778778777769748
R-squared0.1920.2410.2610.2700.3040.262
Table 2. Private Credit and FTR. Quantile regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variable is private credit by deposit money banks as a percentage of GDP. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05.
Table 2. Private Credit and FTR. Quantile regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variable is private credit by deposit money banks as a percentage of GDP. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Weak FTR46.60 ***38.34 ***34.06 ***33.66 ***27.87 ***26.28 ***
(3.228)(4.089)(4.230)(4.237)(4.238)(4.044)
LFPR---0.552 ***0.389 ***0.364 **0.353 **0.378 ***
(0.146)(0.146)(0.147)(0.145)(0.140)
Urban Population------0.465 ***0.446 ***0.432 ***0.424 ***
(0.109)(0.113)(0.109)(0.109)
GDP per cap. growth ---------−0.465−1.129 **−1.394 **
(0.590)(0.570)(0.547)
Trade ------------0.164 ***0.139 ***
(0.032)(0.033)
Polity ---------------0.182
(0.354)
Constant60.12 ***36.99 ***14.7016.855.0885.892
(8.152)(12.10)(14.01)(14.25)(14.10)(13.81)
Observations778778778777769748
Table 3. Private Credit (including Financial Institutions) and FTR. OLS and Quantile regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variable is private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions as a percentage of GDP. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 3. Private Credit (including Financial Institutions) and FTR. OLS and Quantile regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variable is private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions as a percentage of GDP. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
(1)(2)
OLSQuantile
Weak FTR21.76 ***15.36 ***
(4.326)(5.561)
LFPR0.869 ***0.571 ***
(0.135)(0.193)
Urban Population0.411 ***0.614 ***
(0.100)(0.150)
GDP per cap. growth −1.962 ***−1.667 **
(0.562)(0.752)
Trade 0.0430.049
(0.028)(0.046)
Polity 0.606 *0.733
(0.326)(0.486)
Constant−5.785−10.72
(13.33)(19.00)
Observations748748
R-squared0.224NA
Table 4. Private Credit and FTR—Including additional controls. OLS regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variable is private credit by deposit money banks as a percentage of GDP. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The benchmark controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. The additional controls are school enrollment (primary), school enrollment (secondary), foreign direct investment inflows, constraints on the chief executive, durability (democracy) and inflation. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05.
Table 4. Private Credit and FTR—Including additional controls. OLS regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variable is private credit by deposit money banks as a percentage of GDP. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The benchmark controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. The additional controls are school enrollment (primary), school enrollment (secondary), foreign direct investment inflows, constraints on the chief executive, durability (democracy) and inflation. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Weak FTR12.46 ***11.79 ***12.94 ***15.14 ***13.17 ***
(3.719)(3.892)(3.703)(3.283)(3.492)
LFPR0.905 ***1.361 ***0.898 ***0.514 ***0.698 ***
(0.126)(0.139)(0.127)(0.122)(0.119)
Urban Population−0.095−0.325 ***−0.118−0.238 **−0.050
(0.112)(0.099)(0.111)(0.105)(0.107)
GDP per cap. growth −4.297 ***−3.438 ***−4.270 ***−3.580 ***−4.153 ***
(0.642)(0.598)(0.635)(0.567)(0.517)
Trade 0.188 ***0.123 ***0.179 ***0.163 ***---
(0.027)(0.022)(0.026)(0.027)
Polity 1.554 ***−0.347---------
(0.327)(0.376)
School enrollment (primary)2.186 ***---2.185 ***1.946 ***2.094 ***
(0.280) (0.282)(0.285)(0.264)
School enrollment (secondary)---1.515 ***---------
(0.111)
Constraints (chief exec)------5.424 ***---3.029 ***
(1.023) (0.994)
Durable (dem)---------0.369 ***---
(0.054)
FDI ------------0.142
(0.141)
Inflation ------------15.34 ***
(1.354)
Constant−212.6 ***−110.5 ***−232.5 ***−161.1 ***−332.4 ***
(26.53)(15.54)(27.76)(25.72)(27.49)
Observations587524585587587
R-squared0.3920.4760.3970.4620.468
Table 5. Alternate Measures of Financial Development and FTR. OLS regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variables are liquid liabilities (% of GDP), stock market capitalization (% of GDP), stock market total value traded (% of GDP) and bank deposits as percentage of bank credits in columns (1), (2), (3) and (4), respectively. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The benchmark controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 5. Alternate Measures of Financial Development and FTR. OLS regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variables are liquid liabilities (% of GDP), stock market capitalization (% of GDP), stock market total value traded (% of GDP) and bank deposits as percentage of bank credits in columns (1), (2), (3) and (4), respectively. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The benchmark controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Liquid Liabilities Stock Market Cap.Stock Market Total Val.Bank Deposits
Weak FTR 35.84 ***9.224 **18.77 ***23.44 ***
(5.558)(3.896)(5.146)(6.098)
LFPR−0.307 *1.179 ***0.980 ***1.237 ***
(0.168)(0.134)(0.141)(0.302)
Urban Population0.581 ***0.450 ***0.137−0.273
(0.126)(0.113)(0.105)(0.176)
GDP per cap. growth −0.4700.282−0.1850.268
(0.659)(0.482)(0.552)(0.660)
Trade 0.601 ***0.053 **−0.207 ***0.092
(0.133)(0.025)(0.032)(0.080)
Polity −1.223 ***0.3550.130−1.913 **
(0.414)(0.270)(0.398)(0.882)
Constant1.542−42.24 ***5.33870.73 ***
(18.04)(11.62)(16.61)(16.98)
Observations744601600729
R-squared0.3620.2800.2100.127
Table 6. Financial Development Percentiles and Private Credit. OLS Regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variables are liquid liabilities (% of GDP), stock market capitalization (% of GDP), stock market total value traded (% of GDP) and bank deposits as percentage of bank credits in columns (1), (2), (3) and (4), respectively. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The benchmark controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05.
Table 6. Financial Development Percentiles and Private Credit. OLS Regressions with time fixed effects: The dependent variables are liquid liabilities (% of GDP), stock market capitalization (% of GDP), stock market total value traded (% of GDP) and bank deposits as percentage of bank credits in columns (1), (2), (3) and (4), respectively. FTR is future time reference dummy with 1 indicating weak FTR countries and strong FTR countries. The benchmark controls for labor force participation rate (LFPR), urban population as a percentage of total population, GDP per capita growth, trade as percentage of GDP and polity. Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05.
(1)(2)
Private Credit Private Credit (including fin. Inst.)
25th Percentile
Weak FTR 26.391 ***27.667 ***
(6.562)(6.084)
O.25 Pseudo R0.1550.134
50th Percentile
Weak FTR26.277 ***15.355 **
(6.040)(7.199)
O.50 Pseudo R0.1710.154
75th Percentile
Weak FTR16.236 ***17.922 **
(4.301)(7.203)
O.75 Pseudo R0.1790.186
Observations748748
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Caskey, G.W.; Dutta, N. Financial Development and Language Structures. Economies 2022, 10, 313. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10120313

AMA Style

Caskey GW, Dutta N. Financial Development and Language Structures. Economies. 2022; 10(12):313. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10120313

Chicago/Turabian Style

Caskey, Gregory W., and Nabamita Dutta. 2022. "Financial Development and Language Structures" Economies 10, no. 12: 313. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10120313

APA Style

Caskey, G. W., & Dutta, N. (2022). Financial Development and Language Structures. Economies, 10(12), 313. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10120313

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop