1. Introduction
Currently, shipping logistics is the predominant means of cargo transport, accounting for up to 90% of global freight transport annually [
1]. The shipping industry supports the global economy by lowering logistics costs for the entire population and providing a solid assurance for improving global connectivity. The development of a safe, stable, seamless, effective, and mutually beneficial global supply chain system significantly boosts the long-term growth of the world economy and commerce. China Ocean Shipping Company is currently committed to creating a global digital supply chain platform and establishing a global digital supply chain service ecosystem that integrates ports, logistics, and shipping.
1 Decentralized, traceable, collaborative, open, and transparent blockchain technology is actively used by a number of shipping companies as the underlying architecture for logistics platforms [
2,
3,
4]. With its many benefits, blockchain, as a unique data structure, facilitates decision-making for all parties involved in the shipping supply chain. By using timestamps to demonstrate data sharing and visibility, blockchain technology can efficiently link the shipping supply chain, enhancing traceability and transparency and improving customs clearance efficiency [
5]. These characteristics have led to the gradual application of blockchain technology in global logistics in the shipping supply chain, helping companies improve service efficiency, track the status of goods in real time, and increase logistics transparency [
6]. In the digital age, blockchain technology helps maritime freight business to remain competitive in order to establish sustainable, efficient and effective maritime freight transportation [
7]. To enhance their competitiveness, freight forwarders actively utilize blockchain technology as participants in shipping logistics to establish a blockchain platform.
There have been many studies on blockchain technology in supply chain-related areas. Nonetheless, the majority of research operates under the assumption that all decision-makers are completely rational and seek to maximize their interests [
8]. However, fairness concern and other variables can influence decision-makers during the actual decision-making process, making them less likely to make completely rational decisions. Fairness concern has been defined as “the decision-maker chooses to forego some monetary gain in order to achieve a fairer outcome” [
9]. In other words, the decision-maker prioritizes maximizing their personal gain while simultaneously considering how fairly the gain would be distributed [
10]. For example, JD.com forces merchants to participate in promotions and locks up background inventories, which seriously infringes on the rights of registered businesses and causes dozens of brands to retreat from JD.com [
11]. The minimum discounts, which are often required by the platform, exceed the merchant’s cost line, forcing the cost of promotion to be passed on to the supplier. This preoccupation with self-interest and neglect of the survival and development needs of partners has led to an imbalance in the distribution of profits, creating a stronger fairness concern among vendors. Similarly, in China, XuZhou Waji Trading, a key partner of Procter & Gamble [
12], announced the termination of cooperation. Its public declaration points out that there are disputes concerning fairness between the two parties over pricing strategies and profit-sharing mechanisms. When shipping supply chain participants contribute to the development of the blockchain platform, there is a strong emphasis on striking a balance between cost and profit. The final profit is influenced by various factors, including costs, ocean freight, and total freight. Such “free-riding” behaviors tend to upset the party with expensive inputs and increase its sensitivity to profit sharing. Functional logistics service providers are concerned about their profits, but they are also concerned about fairness and consider the profits of others in the supply chain as a reference [
13]. Fair profits can encourage supply chain participants to collaborate to deliver high-quality logistics services, maximizing the overall efficiency of the logistics network [
14].
Driven by fairness concerns, enterprises are more willing to jointly invest in shipping blockchain platforms for cooperation. They share initial fixed costs to reduce average costs and achieve economies of scale. This cooperative model can not only effectively utilize the economies of scale but also alleviate cost pressures to a certain extent. Consequently, supply chain participants are more likely to share the costs of building a blockchain and determine the level of fairness they are willing to tolerate based on personal experience. Fairness concern affects not only cost sharing but also profit allocation [
11], which in turn increases the sensitivity of firms to the level of input costs and cost structures. By rationally allocating costs and profits, companies are able to optimize production decisions and improve the overall efficiency and stability of the supply chain. Fairness concern has become an important factor for companies to deal with cost structure changes and achieve sustainable cooperation.
In practice, companies’ production costs are generally non-linear, specifically referring to economies of scale and diseconomies of scale. There is a certain correlation between non-linear production cost and fairness concern. Under economies of scale, unit costs decline as production expands, creating greater profit margins for supply chain members and facilitating consensus on fair profit distribution. Comparatively, Changhong, Konka, Hisense, and other Chinese firms are experiencing rising costs due to diseconomies of scale. This is squeezing their profit margins and making the importance of mitigating diseconomies of scale even more pronounced [
15]. Under cost pressure, supply chain members need fairness concerns more to maintain cooperation stability and sustainability. The firms with fairness concerns tend to favor a rational allocation of output to prevent individual members from over-expanding and triggering diseconomies of scale. When profit distribution is fair, firms are more motivated to optimize production processes and leverage economies of scale to reduce costs. This enhances the efficiency of the entire supply chain while ensuring the interests of all members are properly safeguarded. In summary, fairness concern is not only about profit distribution but also an important reflection of enterprises’ sensitivity and adaptability to non-linear production cost.
It is common for manufacturers to experience economies or diseconomies during the production process due to a number of factors, such as technical capacity, product variety, and production experience [
16,
17]. Generally, production diseconomies occur when a manufacturer’s capacity to produce goods is constrained or when the cost of coordination increases as the quantity of items increases [
13]. For instance, Mollick [
18] finds that as Japanese automakers scaled up, their marginal costs increased, causing diseconomies of scale, which can also occur in smaller businesses operating below industry-specified minimum sizes. Companies can enhance their competitiveness by maintaining a certain degree of economies of scale. The presence of economies of scale lowers the threshold of competitive intensity, according to a comparison between supply-side economies of scale and competitive intensity [
19]. For example, Amazon is the world’s largest internet retailer in terms of total sales and market capitalization, offering a wide selection of products at low prices. However, Amazon can sell at low prices due to its ability to leverage economies of scale to remain competitive.
2 In addition to the savings gained from employing advanced production methods or modular design, reducing unit production costs can also lead to increased productivity [
20,
21]. Thus, non-linear production costs impact companies’ choices and earnings to some extent, and it is critical to investigate their implications for the operational effectiveness of the shipping supply chain.
In summary, there is a lot of literature on supply chain research regarding fairness concern and non-linear production costs, but fewer studies address the consideration of non-linear production costs and fairness concern when supply chain members invest in blockchain applications. Due to the high expenses associated with establishing and implementing blockchain technology, supply chain members take fairness concern into account while developing a blockchain platform. The shipping company’s non-linear production costs affect the level of its production costs, which in turn affects its own profit. In the context of the application of blockchain, and considering non-linear production costs, fairness concern behavior enables the shipping company and freight forwarder to adapt their decisions. Thus, it is crucial to investigate how non-linear production costs and fairness concern affect supply chain participants’ decision-making to enhance the overall operational efficiency of the supply chain. In the context of the freight forwarder building a blockchain platform, this paper considers non-linear production costs and fairness concern within a two-echelon supply chain consisting of a shipping company and a freight forwarder. Our research aims to address three specific questions.
- (1)
How do economies of scale and diseconomies of scale affect profit distribution and fairness concern choices among members in the shipping supply chain?
- (2)
Compared to fairness neutrality, can fairness concern bring more profits to the freight forwarder and the shipping company?
- (3)
How do economies of scale or diseconomies of scale and fairness concern jointly influence supply chain equilibrium decisions and profitability?
To study the above problems, we establish a two-echelon shipping supply chain consisting of a shipping company and a freight forwarder. In this study, we assume that the shipping company plays a dominant role as the leading player, while the freight forwarder follows and subsequently determines the total freight offered to the shipper. Based on the non-linear production costs of the shipping company and the fairness concern of the freight forwarder, this paper constructs four models: (1) Scenario EN, where there are economies of scale for the shipping company and fairness neutrality for the freight forwarder. (2) Scenario EF, where there are economies of scale for the shipping company and fairness concern for the freight forwarder. (3) Scenario DN, where there are diseconomies of scale for the shipping company and fairness neutrality for the freight forwarder. (4) Scenario DF, where there are diseconomies of scale for the shipping company and fairness concern for the freight forwarder.
By comparing the four scenarios above, the above three questions can be answered one by one. Here are several key conclusions emerging from the study. First, the freight forwarder views fairness concern as a means to boost its profit margin within the shipping supply chain. The freight forwarder’s choice of fairness concern is unaffected by economies of scale or diseconomies of scale. However, regardless of economies of scale or diseconomies of scale, the profit of the shipping company under fairness neutrality is higher than that under fairness concern. Second, in the case of economies of scale or diseconomies of scale, the freight forwarder’s profit and utility do not always increase in direct proportion to the degree of fairness concern. However, regardless of economies of scale or diseconomies of scale, the profit of the shipping company is inversely proportional to fairness concern. Finally, when there are economies of scale or diseconomies of scale, the interaction of these factors with the fairness concern influences the choices made by the freight forwarder and the shipping company, which may ultimately impact final earnings. As a result, to sustain supply chain coordination, both the shipping company and the freight forwarder maintain a reasonable level of fairness concern and economies of scale. These studies not only enrich previous research but also reveal the interaction of non-linear production costs and fairness concern.
In summary, this research makes three primary contributions. First, we analyze how the decisions and profits of supply chain participants are affected by economies of scale and diseconomies of scale when the freight forwarder takes fairness concern into account. Prior research has examined the influence of various factors or a single degree of fairness concern on the supply chain. However, non-linear production costs and fairness concern have not been thoroughly examined. This work can narrow the research gap in this field by considering both non-linear production costs and fairness concern simultaneously. Second, we examine the combined effects of economies of scale, diseconomies of scale, and fairness concern on supply chain members. This demonstrates that the degree of scale economies, scale diseconomies, and fairness concern influences the final choices and financial gains of supply chain participants. Thus, maintaining the intensity at a manageable level ensures the durability and stability of the supply chain. Finally, we analyze the effects of economies of scale and diseconomies of scale on the decisions and profits of supply chain members in cases of fairness neutrality and fairness concern. We find that the supply chain participants become more profitable when there are economies of scale. Both the shipping company and the freight forwarder need to increase their focus on fairness concern and economies of scale to more effectively integrate the two aspects.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In
Section 2, we review three relevant streams of literature.
Section 3 describes the model setup. Under economies of scale, the effects of economies of scale and fairness concern on supply chain participants are illustrated in
Section 4. Under diseconomies of scale,
Section 5 illustrates the impact of the degree of diseconomies of scale and fairness concern on supply chain members.
Section 6 examines the influence of economies of scale and diseconomies of scale on the shipping company and freight forwarder when fairness concern exists.
Section 7 presents numerical simulations.
Section 8 presents main results and suggests possible future research directions. All proofs are provided in the
Appendix A.
3. The Model
We consider a two-echelon shipping supply chain consisting of a single shipping company and a single freight forwarder. This paper focuses on a scenario in which a freight forwarder invests in the establishment and use of a blockchain platform and analyzes the profit sharing and decision-making choices between the freight forwarder and the shipping company. In the traditional shipping supply chain structure, the freight forwarder and the shipping company are the two core subjects and the two sides of the profit maximization goal through the interaction with each other’s decision-making. Due to the asymmetry of market information and the difference between the two sides in the negotiation position, the freight forwarder is often in a relatively passive position in the traditional cooperation mode. The introduction of the Stackelberg game model provides a theoretical framework for this asymmetric decision-making relationship, in which the shipping company, typically acting as the leader, leverages its resource advantages and market position to make strategic decisions first. The freight forwarder, acting as the follower, makes its own optimization adjustments based on the shipping company’s decisions [
62]. This game-theoretic relationship, to some extent, reinforces the disadvantaged position of the freight forwarder.
However, with the application of blockchain technology in the shipping industry, the freight forwarder has gained an opportunity to enhance its market position. By investing in a blockchain platform, the freight forwarder can not only consolidate logistics resources and enhance information transparency but also provide more intelligent services to shippers and the shipping company. For example, with the blockchain platform’s big data analysis and forecasting capabilities, the freight forwarder can accurately grasp the dynamics of market demand and the supply of capacity, enabling better advanced planning and booking of space. By using the blockchain platform to share real-time warehouse information among all logistics participants, the freight forwarder facilitates faster cargo transfers between warehouses, enhances storage space utilization, and reduces both cargo transit time and operational costs. It also enables warehouse inventory management to accurately forecast demand, ensuring that the appropriate quantity and types of products are always available to meet the anticipated demand [
28]. The establishment of the blockchain platform has transformed the freight forwarder from a passive recipient in traditional models into a pivotal coordinator within the supply chain, effectively replacing the conventional functions of freight forwarders. This transformation has endowed the freight forwarder with enhanced bargaining power in its collaboration with the shipping company, thereby partially mitigating its historically disadvantaged position within the strategic equilibrium.
In this paper, the freight forwarder uses the new bargaining power gained by the blockchain platform to strive for fairer cooperation terms, particularly in decision-making scenarios that prioritize fairness. Especially for the freight forwarder, investing in and applying a blockchain platform requires significant costs, which include the development of blockchain technology, the operation and maintenance of the platform, and the training of personnel. Due to the high cost of blockchain technology, the freight forwarder needs to obtain a reasonable return in the supply chain to cover its investment. However, the “free-riding” behavior of the shipping company, which affects the return on investment of the freight forwarder, has led the freight forwarder to take fairness concerns seriously. If the freight forwarder perceives unfair profit distribution, it may express discontent by slacking off, which reduces production efficiency, increases costs, and impacts the compensation of investment costs. Considering the willingness of consumers to pay for fair production, the freight forwarder can cover the increase in costs with this additional revenue, which brings potential benefits for the freight forwarder to apply the blockchain platform. Simultaneously, the freight forwarder’s leadership in addressing fairness concerns facilitates its establishment of robust reputation and trust relationships within the supply chain ecosystem. By fairly distributing profits and costs, the freight forwarder can boost its willingness to cooperate with other supply chain members and promote the formation of long-term and stable cooperative relationships.
After examining how the freight forwarder can use the blockchain platform to enhance its position and have fairness concerns, we explore the impact of the complexity of the cost structure in the shipping supply chain on the decision-making of the members. Specifically, this paper adopts Zhao and Li’s [
20] cost categorization method. It categorizes the production costs of manufacturers into two types: diseconomies of production, where marginal cost per unit increases, and economies of production, where marginal cost per unit decreases. On this basis, this paper further examines the impact of the shipping company’s non-linear production cost and the freight forwarder’s concern about fairness on the decision-making of supply chain participants. We refer to the shipping company as facing diseconomies of scale when its marginal cost per unit rises as the quantity of units produced increases. We refer to the shipping company as facing economies of scale when its marginal cost per unit decreases as the number of units produced increases.
In this context, the freight forwarder studied in this paper not only focuses on increasing the overall profits of the shipping supply chain but also on the fairness of the distribution of those profits throughout the supply chain. The model construction demonstrates superiority in several ways. Firstly, the model combines fairness concern with profit maximization, breaking through the limitation of the traditional model that only focuses on efficiency and reflecting more comprehensively the interests in the practical supply chain. Secondly, by applying the Stackelberg game structure, the model captures the shift in the supply chain power dynamics due to blockchain technology. It moves from the conventional leader/follower relationship to a more balanced interaction, thereby strengthening the bargaining power of the freight forwarder. Finally, by quantitatively analyzing the impact of the fairness coefficient on profit distribution, the model provides supply chain members with practical management strategies to help them achieve a balance between fairness and profit.
For ease of reference, we use the feminine pronoun “she” for the freight forwarder and the masculine pronoun “he” for the shipping company. In this paper, we assume that the shipping company is the leader in the shipping supply chain, while the freight forwarder is the follower. Both aim to maximize their own profits. The freight forwarder provides the shipper with total freight, denoted as
, and secures shipping services from the shipping company at an ocean freight, specified as
.
Table 2 presents the notations used throughout this study.
Following Shang et al. [
13], we consider that the production costs of the shipping company to be
, where
denotes diseconomies of scale and
denotes economies of scale. Similarly,
denotes diseconomies of scale and
denotes economies of scale
. We use
to denote the value of the blockchain platform. For the freight forwarder, we assume that the construction cost of the blockchain platform is
, where
is the cost factor of building the blockchain platform [
31]. The higher
results in a higher expense of effort for freight forwarder. The quadratic cost function for the freight forwarder captures the diminishing marginal returns of investments in blockchain technology. Therefore, we employ the quadratic cost function to more accurately measure the investment effects for the freight forwarder. Moreover, this quadratic functional form is widely used in the supply chain and operation management literature [
60,
63].
In this paper, the total market demand function is sensitive to the total freight and the value of the blockchain platform applied by the freight forwarder. To simplify the subsequent comparative analysis, we assume that the total market demand follows a linear relationship with the total freight and the value of the blockchain platform. According to Zhao and Li [
20], the total market demand can be defined as
, where
is the underlying demand in the shipping market,
is the total freight by the forwarder to the shipper,
is the value provided by the blockchain platform, and
is the sensitivity factor of aggregate market demand to changes in
[
13,
20]. Such a demand function has been widely used in previous studies [
60,
64,
65].
We denote the profits of the shipping company and the freight forwarder by and , respectively. The decision variables are for the shipping company and and for the freight forwarder. So we obtain the profit function of the shipping company: , where represents the revenue of the shipping company and is the non-linear production cost of the shipping company. Thus, we obtain the profit function of the freight forwarder: , where represents the profit of the freight forwarder and is the total cost of the freight forwarder.
In our model, both the shipping company and freight forwarder are attempting to maximize their profits. However, in practice, this raises the question of whether cooperation among supply chain members is fair. Due to factors such as unfair profit distribution and information asymmetry, supply chain members often develop a sense of unfairness, which can significantly affect their final decision. When the freight forwarder invests in building the blockchain, she considers not only her own profit but also her profit in comparison to that of other members. When participants believe that the benefits from the supply chain are not allocated fairly, they may act to penalize one another at the expense of their own interests [
66]. The freight forwarder is particularly concerned about the fairness of profit distribution in the supply chain, as she incurs significant costs to maintain the blockchain platform. At this point, the freight forwarder’s primary goal shifts from profit maximization to utility maximization.
In order to accurately reflect the fairness concern of the freight forwarder towards the shipping company, it is crucial to introduce a reference point of fairness concern in the model. Exploring fairness concern, Fehr and Schmidt [
9] introduce the concepts of unfavorable inequality and favorable inequality, noting that individuals are not only concerned with their own gains but also with comparing their relative gains with others. Therefore, this study employs the utility function used to depict unfairness aversion in logistics decision-making. The fairness concern utility function is constructed using the absolute profit of the other party as the reference point. In this function, the freight forwarder focuses primarily on her own utility, while referring to the shipping company’s profit to assess the fairness of her own profit. To simplify the formula while maintaining its general applicability, we can derive the fairness utility function for the freight forwarder as [
67,
68]:
where
and
denote the profits of the shipping company and the freight forwarder, respectively.
is the freight forwarder’s fairness concern degree, which represents the freight forwarder’s level of fairness concern.
is positively related to the level of fairness concern of the forwarder, i.e., the higher
is, the higher the level of fairness concern of the forwarder is. This utility function is also applied in the studies of Liu et al. [
53], Wu et al. [
56], and Chen et al. [
69]. The utility function of the shipping company remains the same as his profit function if he does not participate in building the blockchain, namely,
.
To explore the impact of whether a freight forwarder adopts fairness concern on a shipping company’s decision-making under both economies of scale and diseconomies of scale, we construct the following four scenarios, as shown in
Table 3 and
Figure 1, i.e., (1) Scenario EN, with economies of scale for the shipping company, fairness neutrality for the freight forwarder. (2) Scenario EF, with economies of scale for the shipping company, fairness concern for the freight forwarder. (3) Scenario DN, with diseconomies of scale for the shipping company, fairness neutrality for the freight forwarder. (4) Scenario DF, with diseconomies of scale for the shipping company, fairness concern for the freight forwarder. Next, we express the four scenarios using functional formulas:
- (2)
Scenario EF
- (3)
Scenario DN
- (4)
Scenario DF
According to the backward induction method of the Stackelberg game, the optimal solutions for the decision variables and profits in the four scenarios are summarized in
Table 4 and
Table 5. To ensure that the shipping company and freight forwarder remain in the supply chain, we need to make
Table 4 and
Table 5 realistic and guarantee that the earnings of the supply chain members are positive. In the following sections, we explore the best options for the various scenarios based on these findings and perform a comparative analysis to provide some management insights.
4. Economies of Scale
Under the premise of economies of scale, to better study the impact of the freight forwarder’s fairness concerns about various decision-making processes and profits within a shipping supply chain, we need to establish a “fairness neutrality” model for comparison. Fairness neutrality refers to the scenario where the shipping company and freight forwarder make decentralized decisions under completely rational conditions. Therefore, under the case of economies of scale, we mainly discuss two decision-making scenarios i.e., the decision-making in the shipping supply chain under fairness neutrality (denoted as Scenario EN) and the decision-making in the shipping supply chain under fairness concern (denoted as Scenario EF). Based on these two scenarios, we calculate the equilibrium profits of all parties in the shipping supply chain.
4.1. Scenario EN
Under Scenario EN, the shipping company has economies of scale, and the freight forwarder does not consider fairness concern, i.e., the freight forwarder operates under fairness neutrality. The impacts of on each of the equilibrium results under Scenario EN are examined below.
Corollary 1. (a) , , , .
(b) When
,
, then ; if , then When , then .
Corollary 1 shows that the level of economies of scale impacts both shipping company and freight forwarder. As the economies of scale expand, the blockchain platform’s value, the shipping company’s profit, and the freight forwarder’s profit all experience significant increases. This may be due to the fact that economies of scale have led to lower freight costs for shipping, which makes the blockchain platform more valuable and profitable for both parties. For the shipping company, as economies of scale increase, his cost of production decreases, prompting the shipping company to reduce ocean freight to enhance his competitiveness.
For Corollary 1(b), when the degree of economies of scale and the cost of blockchain platform are not large, the total freight increases with the level of economies of scale. This is because the freight forwarder decides to raise the total freight to save costs while still maintaining her profit margin, given that the blockchain platform is currently operating less effectively. The blockchain platform is more developed and functions much more effectively when economies of scale are smaller and its cost is higher. When economies of scale increase, the forwarder’s input cost also declines, which leads the forwarder to consider reducing the total freight. The freight forwarder has some flexibility in determining the total freight when economies of scale are sufficiently large. Therefore, in both scenarios, the freight forwarder chooses to reduce the total freight cost to maintain an efficient supply chain.
4.2. Scenario EF
Under Scenario EF, the shipping company has economies of scale, and the freight forwarder has fairness concerns. This section examines the impacts of and on each of the equilibrium results under Scenario EF.
Corollary 2. (a) , , , , .
(b) When , , if , then ; if , then . When and , then . When , if , then ; if , then . (, , ).
According to Corollary 2(a), as the degree of economies of scale increases, the value of the blockchain platform rises, the profits for both the shipping company and the freight forwarder increase, and the utility for the freight forwarder is enhanced. Conversely, ocean freight tends to decline as economies of scale expand. All stakeholders in the supply chain may benefit from decreased unit costs for the shipping company resulting from increased economies of scale. For the shipping company, the increased level of economies of scale reduces cost to a certain extent and enables it to be more flexible regarding ocean freight. Given that the freight forwarder is focusing more on fairness, the shipping company chooses to reduce ocean freight to enhance his own competitiveness.
In Corollary 2(b), under Scenario EF, the freight forwarder decides to increase the total freight when the cost of the blockchain platform is lower, provided that both the level of economies of scale and the shipping company’s linear production cost are also lower. Given that the shipping company’s economies of scale have a lesser impact and the freight forwarder’s efficiency in leveraging the blockchain platform during her initial stages is relatively low, the freight forwarder chooses to raise the total freight to bolster her profit. When the shipping company’s linear production cost is higher and the cost of the blockchain platform is lower, the freight forwarder decides to increase the total freight to counteract the initial inefficiencies associated with the blockchain platform. When the cost of the blockchain platform is higher, it indicates that the efficiency of the blockchain platform has increased. The freight forwarder decides to lower the total freight when the shipping company’s linear production cost is comparatively low and the level of economies of scale is high. The total freight tends to decrease as a result of the increased economies of scale, which lessen the financial burden on the supply chain participants.
Corollary 3. (a) , , .
(b) When , if , then ; if , then . When , then .
(c) When , then ; when , then .
(d) When , then ; when , then . (
For Corollary 3(a), when the level of fairness concern increases, the value of the blockchain platform decreases, as does the profitability of the shipping company. At this point, the profit of the forwarder is reduced, but her utility rises accordingly. This suggests that the behavior of fairness concern can help the forwarder narrow the gap in profit sharing with the shipping company and increase her share of profit sharing in the supply chain.
In Corollary 3(b), when economies of scale are relatively low and the cost of the blockchain is also relatively low, the profit of the freight forwarder is inversely proportional to fairness concern. This phenomenon can be attributed to the significantly high input cost associated with the blockchain platform, coupled with its relatively inefficient operations, particularly during the initial investment phase of its development. Additionally, lower economies of scale can provide even smaller economic benefits to the firm. As the degree of fairness concern increases, the freight forwarder’s profit margin becomes insufficient to offset the significant expenses incurred. Therefore, the profit of the freight forwarder is inversely proportional to the fairness concern. With relatively low economies of scale and high blockchain cost, freight forwarder profit is proportional to the level of fairness concern. The blockchain platform is currently operating more effectively, allowing the freight forwarder to offer high-quality logistics services, thereby increasing her profit. Furthermore, when economies of scale are relatively high, the profit of the freight forwarder is inversely proportional to fairness concern. Greater economies of scale allow the shipping company to achieve higher profits while lowering his cost burden. However, as a participant in the supply chain, the freight forwarder has experienced a decrease in profit. The freight forwarder shifts from profit maximization to utility maximization as the level of fairness concern increases. Therefore, the profit of the freight forwarder is inversely proportional to the fairness concern.
In practice, Walmart China commercially launched its Blockchain Traceability Platform in June 2019 [
70]. When the blockchain platform increases efficiency and improves supply chain processes, it effectively reduces the cost burden and leads to lucrative profits. A fair profit distribution mechanism enhances supply chain cooperation by sustaining members’ engagement incentives and fostering long-term stable partnerships. Therefore, Walmart focuses on optimizing profit distribution and avoiding excessive squeezing of profit margins of supply chain members. In addition, the integration of fairness concern with blockchain technology enables enterprises to offer higher-quality products and services. This strengthens their market competitiveness, helps expand their market share, and promotes the upgrading and development of the entire industry.
For Corollary 3(c), a decrease in total freight results from the freight forwarder’s increased behavior regarding fairness concern when the cost of the blockchain platform is low. When the cost of the blockchain platform is relatively high and fairness concern escalates, this leads to an increase in total freight. Considering market demand, the freight forwarder decides to lower total freight when the blockchain platform has relatively low input cost. To ensure an increase in her own profit, the freight forwarder chooses to enhance the quality of logistics services and pursue fairness when the input into the blockchain platform is high. This suggests that the impact of fairness concern behavior on total freight depends on the cost level of the blockchain platform.
Corollary 3(d) shows how the ocean freight varies with in the presence of fairness concern. When the cost of the blockchain platform is relatively low, ocean freight increases as the level of fairness concern increases. The lower cost of the blockchain platform indicates that it is less efficient to operate in the early stages. To ensure his profit, the shipping company decides to gradually raise ocean freight. When the cost of the blockchain platform is relatively high, ocean freight decreases as the level of fairness concern increases. This is because the shipping company has realized that the freight forwarder is currently more concerned with fairness than ever before. To cater to the freight forwarder’s preference, the shipping company chooses to reduce ocean freight to enhance its competitiveness.
Based on Corollaries 1 and 2, it can be deduced that, under the economics of scale, the application value of the blockchain platform, the profits of both the shipping company and the freight forwarder, as well as the utility of the freight forwarder, all increase positively as the economics of scale expand. This holds true regardless of whether the freight forwarder adopts fairness concern. From Corollary 3, we can conclude that, after adopting fairness concern, the freight forwarder is able to reduce the cost of upfront investment in the shipping supply chain and increase her own share of profit to satisfy her own fair demand.
4.3. Comparison
In the following section, the equilibrium results of the EN scenario and the EF scenario are compared and examined to allow a full understanding of how economies of scale affect decision-making.
Proposition 1. (a) When , then ; when , then .
(b) When , if , then ; if , then . When , then .
(c) , .
Proposition 1(a) shows that the shipping company’s ocean freight under Scenario EF is higher when the cost of the blockchain platform is lower. When the blockchain platform is more expensive to build, the shipping company has lower ocean freight in Scenario EF. A lower cost for the blockchain suggests that it may operate less effectively. The shipping company pursues higher ocean freight to lower the investment cost and make up for the shortfall resulting from the high cost. The shipping company decides to lower ocean freight to strengthen his competitive advantage as platforms run more smoothly. This further suggests that the cost of the freight forwarder’s investment in the blockchain platform influences the shipping company’s decision regarding ocean freight.
Proposition 1(b) states that the total freight under Scenario EN is higher than the total freight under Scenario EF when both the economies of scale and the building cost of the blockchain platform are low. Otherwise, the opposite is true in other scenarios. It also demonstrates how the shipping company’s level of economies of scale and the freight forwarder’s cost input play a major role in the forwarder’s decision regarding total freight. When economies of scale and the cost of building a blockchain platform are relatively low, and fairness concern is not considered, the freight forwarder increases the total freight to mitigate her disadvantage within the supply chain. At this time, the competition between shipping company is based on price competition. Given concern about fairness, the freight forwarder may decide to set higher total freight to offset the significant costs associated with developing a blockchain platform. When economies of scale are relatively high, the freight forwarder chooses to increase the total freight to cover the cost of investing in the blockchain and ensure her own profitability. It additionally illustrates that when the freight forwarder’s costs are quite high, they become more concerned about these costs due to fairness concerns. Therefore, at this point, the freight forwarder’s total freight under Scenario EF is higher than that under Scenario EN.
Proposition 1(c) states that, under economies of scale, the fairness concern behavior of the freight forwarder diminishes the value of the blockchain platform and also reduces the profitability of the shipping company. Compared to fairness neutrality, the value of the blockchain platform is lower when the freight forwarder considers fairness concerns. This indicates that fairness concern behavior reduces the incentive for the freight forwarder to invest in the blockchain platform. At this point, the shipping company is also making more conservative decisions. This suggests that fairness concern behavior can have an adverse effect on the shipping company; i.e., the profit of the shipping company under fairness concern is less than the profit of the shipping company under fairness neutrality.
5. Diseconomies of Scale
In the context of diseconomies of scale, this section focuses on how decision-makers in the shipping supply chain consider fairness concern. In the context of diseconomies of scale, we discuss two decision-making scenarios, i.e., the decision-making of supply chain members under fairness neutrality (denoted as Scenario DN) and the decision-making of supply chain members under fairness concern (denoted as Scenario DF).
5.1. Scenario DN
Under Scenario DN, the shipping company has diseconomies of scale and the freight forwarder does not consider fairness concern, i.e., the freight forwarder has fairness neutrality. Under Scenario DN, the impact of on each of the equilibrium results is examined below.
Corollary 4. (a) , , , .
(b) If , then ; if , then .
Corollary 4(a) shows that the value of blockchain platform, shipping company’s profit, and freight forwarder’s profit gradually decrease as the diseconomies of scale increase. Ocean freight rises further as diseconomies of scale worsen. This suggests that changes in diseconomies of scale can lead to subsequent changes for both the shipping company and the freight forwarder. Diseconomies of scale that worsen progressively cause all supply chain participants’ input costs to rise while their potential rewards decline. The increase in production scale substantially raises the production cost for the shipping company, prompting him to increase ocean freight to improve his profit margins.
In Corollary 4(b), when the input cost of the freight forwarder is relatively low, the total freight decreases as diseconomies of scale increase. When the input cost of the freight forwarder is relatively high, the total freight increases as diseconomies of scale increase. This phenomenon can be attributed to the fact that when cost is lower, the freight forwarder experiences lesser cost pressure, which in turn results in a decrease in total freight. To minimize losses, the freight forwarder raises total freight as higher input costs increase the risk of decreased profit. However, this can lead to a loss of competitiveness in the market and increases the risk of losing customers.
5.2. Scenario DF
Under Scenario DF, the shipping company faces diseconomies of scale while the freight forwarder has fairness concerns. Under diseconomies of scale and fairness concerns, the impacts of and on ocean freight, total freight, the value of the blockchain platform, the profit of the shipping company, and the profit and utility of the forwarder are presented in Corollaries 5 and 6.
Corollary 5. (a) , , , , .
(b) When , if , then ; if , then When , then .
Corollary 5(a) shows how increasing diseconomies of scale progressively diminishes the value of the blockchain platform, as well as the shipping company’s profit, the freight forwarder’s profit, and the freight forwarder’s utility. When the degree of diseconomies of scale increases, the ocean freight continues to rise. As with Corollary 4(a), a rise in the degree of diseconomies of scale drives up the shipping company’s production cost, which in turn impacts and lowers the profits of the supply chain participants. As a result, the shipping company decides to raise ocean freight in an effort to lessen the negative effects of diseconomies of scale on his earnings.
Corollary 5(b) shows that when both the cost and the diseconomies of scale for the freight forwarder are low, the total freight decreases as the diseconomies of scale increase. However, in other scenarios, the opposite is true. This is because when the shipping company’s production scale is relatively small and the input cost for the freight forwarder’s blockchain platform is low, the freight forwarder decides to decrease the total freight in order to increase market demand, enhance competitiveness, and improve the operational efficiency of the blockchain platform. As the input cost for the freight forwarder increases or as the diseconomies of scale for the shipping company improve, the freight forwarder chooses to increase the total freight in order to maximize a specific profit margin and compensate for a particular cost already invested.
Corollary 6. (a) , , , .
(b) When , then ; when , then .
(c) When , if , then ; if , then . When , then .
Corollary 6(a) demonstrates that when fairness concern rises, the value of the blockchain platform and the freight forwarder’s profit increase, while ocean freight and the shipping company’s profit decrease. In Scenario DF, the freight forwarder invests in and applies the blockchain platform to enhance the company’s operational efficiency, which subsequently boosts the value of the blockchain platform and her profit. However, higher fairness concern results in the shipping company receiving a smaller share of the supply chain’s overall profits, which in turn lowers his profit. As fairness concern increases, the shipping company tends to keep ocean freight relatively low. This implies that the shipping company prefers to make cautious decisions and lowers ocean freight the more the freight forwarder considers fairness. This suggests that fairness concern can lead to an increase in the profit share of the freight forwarder and effectively reduce the profit gap between it and the shipping company, resulting in a more balanced distribution of benefits in the supply chain. This also shows that fairness concerns can reduce cooperation friction and enhance alliance stability. Cooperation disputes and conflicts are mitigated and members cooperate more harmoniously when all parties are more focused on fairness, which is important for long-term strategic alliance relationships. In addition, traditional vertical alliances led by a shipping company may shift to a shared decision-making model. The freight forwarder can gain more power of discourse through a blockchain platform and its fairness concern. It can play a more active role in alliance decision-making, thereby enhancing the competitiveness and adaptability of the alliance.
From Corollary 6(b), when diseconomies of scale are small, the freight forwarder’s utility is positively correlated with fairness concern. Conversely, when diseconomies of scale are relatively large, the freight forwarder’s utility is negatively correlated with fairness concern. This is because the freight forwarder’s emphasis on fairness implies that the more efficiently the blockchain platform operates, the more valuable the freight forwarder becomes, particularly when the diseconomies of scale are relatively small. Therefore, the utility of the freight forwarder increases with the level of fairness concern. When the diseconomies of scale are relatively large, the increase in production scale raises the production costs for the shipping company. As the operating efficiency of the blockchain platform increases, it generates profit for the freight forwarder but concurrently raises her production cost. Under such circumstances, the freight forwarder’s efforts to minimize production cost may not yield as significant an impact as before. Thus, the utility of the freight forwarder is inversely proportional to fairness concern.
In Corollary 6(c), if the freight forwarder’s cost and diseconomies of scale are low, then the total freight increases as fairness concern increases. In other scenarios, the opposite is true. When the diseconomies of scale are relatively low, there is less pressure on production cost for the shipping company. In instances where the blockchain platform operates at relatively low efficiency, the freight forwarder raises the total freight to achieve the desired profit margin. A more efficient blockchain platform increases the freight forwarder’s profit margin within the supply chain. At this point, as fairness concerns rise, the freight forwarder chooses to reduce the total freight to maintain an efficient supply chain. If diseconomies of scale increase, total freight is inversely proportional to fairness concern. This occurs because of the freight forwarder’s decision to reduce prices to ensure demand and generate fair earnings.
In conjunction with Corollaries 4 and 5, under diseconomies of scale, ocean freight is positively correlated with diseconomies of scale. Meanwhile, the shipping company’s profit, the freight forwarder’s profit, and the freight forwarder’s utility are negatively correlated with diseconomies of scale. This implies that the value of the blockchain platform, the shipping company’s profit, the freight forwarder’s profit, and the freight forwarder’s utility decrease as the degree of diseconomies of scale increases. This is because diseconomies of scale result in higher expenses for the shipping company and the freight forwarder. Therefore, as diseconomies of scale increase, the shipping company and freight forwarder incur higher costs, ultimately leading to a decline in their profits.
5.3. Comparison
Next, we compare and examine the equilibrium of the DN and DF scenarios to fully understand how diseconomies of scale affect decision making.
Proposition 2. (a) When , if , then ; if , then . When , then .
, , .
Proposition 2(a) demonstrates that when both the degree of diseconomies of scale and the cost of building a blockchain platform are low, the total freight under Scenario DN is lower than the total freight under Scenario DF. In other cases, the opposite is true. This is because, in Scenario DF, the freight forwarder incurs certain costs associated with applying the blockchain platform, and the operating efficiency of the blockchain platform is not very high. As a result, the freight forwarder chooses to raise the total freight in order to offset the investment costs and increase profit. When the construction cost of the blockchain platform is relatively high, the total freight under Scenario DN is higher than the total freight under Scenario DF. Similarly, when diseconomies of scale are higher, the costs incurred by supply chain members are also higher, but the total freight under Scenario DF is lower. This suggests that the freight forwarder’s fairness concern can mitigate the adverse effects of diseconomies of scale. Fairness concern can have a positive effect on the market, and traditional price competition is no longer the basis of competitiveness in the shipping industry.
By contrasting with Proposition 2(b), we find that the freight forwarder’s final decision regarding the total freight is influenced by the degree of economies of scale, the degree of diseconomies of scale, and the input cost incurred by the freight forwarder. For the same range of cost intensities, total freight changes in the opposite direction. When cost input is relatively high, fairness concern under Scenario EF increases the freight forwarder’s cost concern, which in turn raises the total freight. When cost input is relatively high, the fairness concern of the freight forwarder under Scenario DF reduces her concern for cost, which in turn reduces the total freight. To meet her own profit and other demands, the freight forwarder can make this choice by selecting the optimal total freight based on market demand, customer preferences, and decision-making objectives.
According to Proposition 2(b), the freight forwarder’s fairness concern reduces ocean freight. This implies that the shipping company makes more conservative decisions as the freight forwarder becomes more concerned about fairness. The value of the blockchain platform under fairness concern is higher compared to fairness neutrality. This results from growing diseconomies of scale, which raise production costs for participants in the supply chain but enable them to achieve balance when the freight forwarder invests more in addressing fairness concerns. Therefore, under the diseconomies of scale, the freight forwarder determines that fairness concerns can increase the value of the blockchain platform. At the same time, fairness concern can adversely affect the shipping company, i.e., the profit of the shipping company under fairness concern is less than the profit of the shipping company under fairness neutrality.
This is consistent with Proposition 1(c). This indicates that, regardless of whether the shipping company’s production scale is economical, the freight forwarder’s fairness concern behavior has a negative impact on the shipping company’s profit. This also reflects the reality that the shipping company’s share of overall profits within the supply chain is diminished. This finding is similar to the findings of Wu et al. [
56]. Wu et al. [
56] indicate that under the same green subsidy strategy, fairness concern has a positive impact on retailers and a negative impact on manufacturers. This is because retailers with fairness concerns tend to pay more attention to the fairness of profit sharing with manufacturers. In such cases, retailers usually tend to strive for a larger share of the profits. Thus, for supply chain members considering fairness concerns, it can bring positive effects; however, it may continuously adversely affect the profits of other supply chain members.
6. Comparative Analysis
To provide shipping supply chain companies with resources and cutting-edge management insights, as well as to more fully explain the underlying causes of members making irrational decisions, this section focuses on a comparative analysis of the equilibrium results of economies of scale and diseconomies of scale under fairness neutrality and fairness concern.
Proposition 3. (a) , .
(b) , .
(c) , , .
Proposition 3(a) demonstrates that, regardless of fairness neutrality or fairness concern, ocean freight under diseconomies of scale is always greater than that under economies of scale. This implies that when there are diseconomies of scale, the shipping company’s production cost is higher and he decides to raise ocean freight to offset those expenses. This results from the fact that economies of scale can help the shipping company lower input cost, which reduces ocean freight and preserves an effective supply chain.
Propositions 3(b) and 3(c) show that the value of the blockchain platform, the profit of the shipping company, and the fairness utility of the freight forwarder are higher under economies of scale than under diseconomies of scale. This implies that supply chain participants’ decisions to pursue economies of scale are unaffected by the freight forwarder’s consideration of fairness concern. Fairness concern drives logistics service providers to enhance their offerings, which in turn raises overall demand for supply chains. In this way, all parties in the supply chain can effectively balance their respective interests, ensuring the continued and smooth operation of the supply chain. Furthermore, this underscores the positive impact of economies of scale on all parties within the supply chain, enabling their interests to potentially grow in unison under the same conditions.
Proposition 4. (a) (i) When , if , then ; if , then .
(ii) When , we have .
(b) (i) When , if and , then ; if and , then ; if , .
(ii) When , if , then ; if , and , then ; if , and , then ; if and , then . (, , , , ).
In Proposition 4(a), the total freight under Scenario EN is higher than the total freight under Scenario DN when both the degree of economies of scale and the cost invested by the freight forwarder are low. When the degree of economies of scale is low and the investment by the freight forwarder is relatively high, the total freight under Scenario EN is lower than the total freight under Scenario DN. Additionally, when the level of economies of scale is relatively high, the total freight cost for Scenario EN is relatively low. Because of inexperience and other factors, the relatively low degree of economies of scale means that during the pre-manufacturing phase of the shipping company’s production, the benefits of economies of scale have less of an influence on the financial efficiency of the shipping company. Meanwhile, the freight forwarder chooses to increase the total freight to compensate for the inefficiency in order to ensure high-quality logistics services and profitability. Therefore, the total freight under Scenario EN is higher. The overall operating efficiency of the supply chain increases as the freight forwarder’s cost increases. At this point, the freight forwarder is able to realize the anticipated profit and decides to lower the total freight in order to become more competitive. The shipping company decides to lower his own ocean freight to boost market demand and his competitive advantage once the economies of scale reach a particular point. Therefore, the total freight under Scenario EN is lower. At this time, the freight forwarder is at the peak of economies of scale, making profit targets easier to reach. To attract more clients, the freight forwarder decides to cut the total freight to better serve the market and meet the demands of the target customers. Additionally, this establishes the freight forwarder’s brand and creates the foundation for expanding into potential markets.
Proposition 4(b) shows that total freight is closely related to non-linear costs and the input costs of supply chain members. The total freight cost under Scenario EF is higher than that under Scenario DF when the degree of economies of scale, diseconomies of scale, and the construction cost of the blockchain platform are all low. When economies of scale and diseconomies of scale are not significant, both have less influence on the decisions made by supply chain participants. When the blockchain platform is less effective, the freight forwarder should take action to increase her operational efficiency while considering her preference for fairness concern. Under Scenario EF, the freight forwarder raises the total freight to lower the overall input cost, as the lower degree of economies of scale prevents her from achieving the anticipated profit. When diseconomies of scale and the cost of the blockchain platform are lower while economies of scale and linear production cost are higher, the total freight cost under Scenario EF is higher. This is because, in Scenario DF, the level of diseconomies of scale is lower, the shipping company’s linear cost inputs are larger, and the shipping company’s total costs remain within a manageable range. When the blockchain platform’s investment cost is low, it indicates that the platform operates less effectively, and the freight forwarder strives for more advantages to meet her own fair demands. In Scenario EF, higher levels of economies of scale are not well matched with an inefficient platform, leading to wasted resources. The freight forwarder decides to increase the total freight in an attempt to achieve a more favorable result by maximizing fairness utility.
In other cases, the opposite is true. When both the degrees of economies of scale and diseconomies of scale are relatively low, and the cost of the blockchain platform is relatively high, the total freight under Scenario EF is lower than that under Scenario DF. Driven by fairness concern, the freight forwarder adjusts her freight strategy to balance her profitability according to different economic environments. Specifically, the freight forwarder, leveraging the high efficiency and decision-making flexibility of the blockchain platform, moderately reduces the total freight under economies of scale. This not only enhances her fair image in the supply chain but also prevents harming the shipping company’s interests through excessive total freight, thus promoting the overall coordination and stability of the supply chain. Under diseconomies of scale, the freight forwarder’s fairness concern is less effective, leading her to increase the total freight to compensate for cost pressures. When economies of scale are relatively low and diseconomies of scale are relatively high, the total freight under Scenario EF is lower than the total freight under Scenario DF. In Scenario DF, the shipping company’s production cost rises dramatically with increasing production size, prompting the freight forwarder to raise total freight to offset her own profit loss.
Under Scenario EF, total freight is lower than under Scenario DF when economies of scale are relatively significant and linear production cost is relatively low. At this point, economies of scale provide considerable benefits and help the freight forwarder maintain an efficient supply chain. When the degree of diseconomies of scale is relatively low, while the degree of economies of scale, linear production cost, and blockchain platform cost are all relatively high, the freight forwarder is better able to adapt to changes in market demand and remain competitive. Therefore, in this case, the total freight under Scenario EF is lower. Total freight under Scenario EF is lower than total freight under Scenario DF when the degree of economies of scale, linear production cost, and diseconomies of scale are significant. Diseconomies of scale limit the benefits associated with rising demand and cause the shipping company’s production cost to rise non-linearly, whereas economies of scale benefit the shipping company. Consequently, the freight forwarder may control the total freight at a relatively low level and increase her market share due to the economies of scale.
These findings are consistent with reality. The shipping company can efficiently control production cost as the degree of economies of scale increases. For instance, Galanz adopts the “economies of scale, cost leadership” strategy to improve competitiveness by reducing average costs through increased production scale and market dominance while mitigating the negative effects of diseconomies of scale.
3 A company experiencing diseconomies of scale needs to implement appropriate solutions to manage the situation, as these are likely to have a negative impact on the organization. For example, Procter & Gamble concentrates on its most crucial product lines to minimize costs and boost efficiency when faced with diseconomies of scale. The company also sells off or eliminates some of its brands.
4The shipping company shifts from enhanced demand-side management to cost-side control as diseconomies of scale worsen. Under Scenario DN and Scenario DF, the shipping company decides to raise ocean freight in an effort to reduce production cost and boost his own reduced profit. To achieve greater profit more quickly, the freight forwarder also decides to raise the total freight. However, this choice often reduces the freight forwarder’s ability to compete in the market. This is due to the freight forwarder’s tendency to prioritize her own interest over those of the market and clients, making it easy to disregard these demands. Although raising the total freight has helped the freight forwarder achieve larger profit in the short term, it may lead to unfavorable opinions among customers, which could result in a loss of market share and ultimately harm its profitability.
8. Conclusions
8.1. Summary
Freight forwarders are actively pursuing strategies to address their challenges and enhance their competitiveness within the increasingly competitive shipping industry. In the framework of freight forwarder investing in the development and implementation of a blockchain platform, this research examines the effects of non-linear cost of a shipping company and fairness concern behavior of a freight forwarder on the shipping supply chain. The conclusions of this paper are as follows.
First, in the context of economies of scale or diseconomies of scale, the freight forwarder’s profit is more favorable under fairness concern than under fairness neutrality, while the shipping company’s profit exhibits the opposite trend. Considering fairness concern when making decisions is more advantageous to the freight forwarder’s profit if the shipping company’s production involves economies of scale. The same applies under diseconomies of scale. Conversely, the shipping company is unlikely to take fairness concern into account if he experiences economies of scale or diseconomies of scale in his production. In addition, economies of scale increase the earnings of all supply chain members.
Second, when fairness is considered, the freight forwarder’s profit and utility do not necessarily increase in tandem with the degree of fairness concern. The profit of the freight forwarder does not always rise in direct proportion to fairness concern when economies of scale are present for the shipping company. When diseconomies of scale exist for the shipping company, the utility of the freight forwarder does not always increase in proportion to fairness concern. However, regardless of whether there are economies of scale or diseconomies of scale, the profit of the shipping company is inversely proportional to the degree of fairness concern.
Finally, the interaction among the degree of economies of scale, diseconomies of scale, and fairness concern affects changes in total freight. Furthermore, the impact of fairness concern on total freight varies in the opposite direction at different production scales. The freight forwarder’s fairness concerns have an impact on the blockchain platform’s cost. Under economies of scale, the existence of fairness concerns raises the level of concern of the freight forwarder about the cost of inputs. In the presence of diseconomies of scale, fairness concerns can reduce the extent to which the freight forwarder is concerned about the cost of inputs.
8.2. Management Insights
The results of this study provide some useful information for supply chain members to address fairness concerns and non-linear production costs. We propose the following relevant management insights.
First, when investing in and applying blockchain platforms, businesses need to balance fairness concerns with profit consideration. When pursuing fairness in supply chain profit distribution, enterprises may take punitive measures due to fairness concerns, such as sacrificing their own profits, which could undermine supply chain stability. Therefore, enterprises establish a fair profit distribution mechanism that considers the costs, risks, and contributions of each member. This helps prevent the cooperative relationship from being strained or ruptured due to unequal distribution while safeguarding the long-term stability and efficient operation of the supply chain.
Second, firms should upgrade their productive capacities to enhance their core supply chain competencies. Economies of scale are significant when production is large enough, so firms need to expand their production capacity to take full advantage of economies of scale to increase total supply chain profits. However, firms must be careful when expanding to avoid falling into diseconomies of scale through overexpansion. Meanwhile, the application of blockchain technology can improve production transparency and traceability and help enterprises accurately control the scale and cost of production. When investing in blockchain, companies should comprehensively assess its impact on cost structures, including increases in fixed costs and changes in variable costs, to better balance costs and benefits in production decisions.
Finally, managers must consider how economies of scale and fairness concerns influence their decisions, as well as how to calculate the appropriate level of inputs. While an excessively high level of fairness concern may easily disturb the balance of supply chain profits and create an uneasy situation, a relatively low level may fail to meet the organization’s expectations. Similarly, economies of scale tend to become diseconomies of scale if the production scale is not adequately regulated, placing the company in a new predicament. Therefore, companies should continuously explore new ways to optimize production processes and reduce costs using blockchain technology. Meanwhile, they should encourage innovative collaboration within the company and among supply chain partners to adapt to changes in non-linear production costs and the evolution of market demand.
8.3. Future Research Directions
This paper has some limitations and potential avenues for further research. First, there are numerous one-to-two or one-to-many scenarios in the shipping logistics market. However, this study exclusively examines a shipping supply chain involving a single shipping company and a single freight forwarder. Second, in this paper, only the freight forwarder has taken the fairness concern into account. However, there are situations in which the shipping company or both parties consider fairness concerns. Therefore, in addressing the issue of profit distribution in the shipping supply chain, it would be beneficial to study the behavior of multiple supply chain members regarding fairness concern. Third, fairness concern is merely one form of social preference that influences decision-makers in this work. Other preferences, such as altruistic preferences [
71] and reciprocal preferences [
72,
73], might also be significant. Companies will gain a better understanding of the benefits and drawbacks, thereby increasing their competitiveness. Fourth, it is important to note that in an increasingly digital and increasingly complex shipping supply chain, the above research is limited to solutions for typical linear demand relationships. However, the total market demand often exhibits non-linear characteristics, suggesting that non-linear demand models provide a more accurate representation of reality. Consequently, this discrepancy creates substantive avenues for further exploration and theoretical development in subsequent research. Finally, in future research, to make the model more adaptable and flexible, we can integrate new economic factors into the current model as additional modules or partially revise the relevant models. For example, to address the impact of inflation [
74] on the cost structure, a separate cost model can be constructed to consider its impact on purchasing, production costs, etc. This modular approach ensures both model flexibility and ease of maintenance and updates. In summary, these potential research directions could refine the findings of this paper and significantly enrich the theory in this field.