1. Introduction
When a business is operating, its managers frequently only consider their own earnings and disregard corporate societal responsibilities (CSR). They believe that participating in CSR will raise product prices, which will have an impact on company profits. CSR and corporate earnings appear to be at odds with one another. However in reality, CSR will undoubtedly boost businesses’ profits. More precisely, integrating CSR impact means that businesses should consider the community, the environment, and customers when generating earnings for their stockholders and staff. Additionally, CSR mandates that companies focus on elements of human value in the manufacturing process, the ecosystem, and consumer behavior rather than profit as their only objective. As a result, the company will forge a regarded reputation among clients and the general public. Customers will consequently implicitly believe that the company’s goods are higher caliber and more dependable. Customers are likely to make purchases, and the business will make more money. Given the context mentioned above, many businesses now seek CSR initiatives as opposed to their original goal of profit growth. Several scholars have examined and analyzed how static games incorporate CSR in their research [
1,
2,
3,
4,
5,
6,
7,
8,
9]. According to Zhou et al. research [
10], the duopoly game created by taking into account consumer surplus and bounded reasoning are more practical than the standard duopoly game, which is limited to focusing on maximizing profits. An incorporated oligopoly with a publicly traded firm competing against two private companies that may adopt CSR is analyzed in [
11]. The study identifies optimal privatization regulations based on CSR levels and price differences, highlighting nationalization or full privatization as possible outcomes.The balance occurs in a dual-monopoly industry where companies engage in CSR activities with management oversight. The financial prosperity of the companies (as opposed to the well-being of customers and community) is benefited (as opposed to damaged) by the CSR decisions, as shown in the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium aspect of the competition [
12]. Companies social responsibility’s impacts For the CSR company, CSR on the nutritional content of the food business increases both the level of quality and amount of the food, while it decreases those for optimizing revenues company. Furthermore, CSR encourages both the overall business quality and amount. Additionally, CSR lowers the revenue of the MP company but [
13] focused on the inverted U-formations connection that exists between CSR and the revenues of the CSR company. Both rival Companies aim to optimize two distinct objective functions; the first a company wants to do this by optimizing the standard of societal welfare and revenue while the second a company only wants to do this by optimizing relative revenue as indicated in [
14]. The forms of the quasi that describe the stages plane of a couple of companies whose generates are a lot where the initial company thinks about optimizing its revenue whereas the next company thinks about optimizing its social welfare discover that the model’s route is noninvertible of form
have been examined in [
15]. A combining triopoly with product distinction and customer perception was proposed by Wen et al. [
16] in which quantities rivalry is carried out by a public firm that seeks to maximize welfare and private companies that are interested in CSR. Liu and Matsumura [
17] analytically examine how shared ownership influences the total volume of foreign trade in an oligopoly market and its effects on global welfare.
In [
18], the bounded rationality method was used to study oligopoly market patterns with customer excess, focusing on global dynamics, stability, and synchronization in a duopoly. Critical curves were introduced to analyze global bifurcation, and a Cournot game with customer excess and limited reasoning was described. Because there are numerous complicated attractors present, multi-stability is seen to address the possibility of varying attractors coexisting, an examination of the regions of attraction are given and the complaints of each company are a mixture of their revenue and the consumer surplus, then a nonlinear duopoly bounded rational companies do not only seek to optimize revenues but also take consumer surplus through consideration in [
19].
The dynamic Cournot duopoly model depicts rival companies operating without complete knowledge of the demand function. Due to this informational gap, they adopt a local benefit optimization approach, making adjustments based on marginal revenue approximations within their respective regions. When the marginal prices set by both firms are not excessively high, a non-cooperative Nash equilibrium can be established. When companies exhibit relatively slow adjustment speeds, this equilibrium solution is locally asymptotically stable. This implies that the local adjustment process converges towards the unique Nash equilibrium, provided that the duopoly game begins with an initial output strategy within a well-defined restricted region around the Nash equilibrium, as explored in [
20]. The study delves into synchronized dynamics involving a dual non-invertible map with an invariant one-dimensional submanifold, as discussed in [
21]. Through investigations into synchronization, intermittency, and the complex organization of attraction collections within discrete-time systems featuring nonlinear demand and price functions, the system reveals intriguing stability and multi-stability issues. Significantly, the study reveals V-shaped stable configurations known as aperiodic stable structures and variously shaped attraction basins that incorporate the convergence of attractors, as outlined in [
22]. Additionally, an examination is conducted on the dynamic interactions within a duopoly system consisting of closely matching or nearly identical suppliers to evaluate the impact of minor differences among players. The behavior of these systems transitions towards uneven patterns in the presence of similar entities, hinting at the possibility of achieving synchronized dynamics, as explained in [
23,
24].
In a dynamic duopoly Cournot model, Y. Cao et al. [
25] illustrate that the presence of multiple attractors results in scattered locations within two-dimensional bifurcation diagrams, highlighting the discovery of Milnor attractors and various other attractors. Within the framework of a mixed duopoly dynamic model characterized by bounded rationality, which involves a collaboration between a public-private joint venture and a private firm producing homogeneous goods and operating within a shared market, the investigation detailed in [
26] explores the system’s stability and multi-stability. Furthermore, the map representing market heterogeneity with isoelastic demand functions is both nonlinear and noninvertible, necessitating an analysis of stable attractors, as explored in [
27,
28,
29]. The objective presented in [
30] is to investigate these dynamics within a banking duopoly model characterized by varying requirements. In this model, small and large financial institutions follow distinct forecasting rules, enabling an assessment of how regulations affect them differently. Notably, the model incorporates an asymmetry in cost structures: small financial institutions adhere to a linear cost function, whereas large financial institutions operate under a quadratic cost function.
According to [
3], an oligopoly occurs when a small number of companies that produce unique goods control the market. One usually aims to maximize earnings in oligopoly models. Since one frequently has multiple objectives, this is not realistic. Weights are used to model a multiobjective oligopoly in [
1], where both profit and sales maximization are considered. Then, profit maximization is combined with risk minimization. Numerous state-owned public companies compete with private companies in product markets in numerous nations. Government strategy in many developing nations has recently included the partial privatization of public companies. The research that examines the impact of partial privatization on public firms on the choice of R&D risk in a mixed duopoly market is strongly linked to [
6]. There has been a recent emergence of literature on “mixed markets,” which include both public and private businesses. Indeed, in many nations, a large number of public companies compete with private companies in the private products market. A mixed oligopoly in which public firms compete with private firms that may adopt corporate social responsibility (CSR) is described by [
11,
15,
31]. Many existing works assume that the public firm maximizes social welfare while the private firm maximizes its own profits. The best privatization strategy is then determined based on the degree of corporate social responsibility and the cost variations across companies; either full privatization or nationalization may be the best option.
This paper aims to explore a game model that incorporates a linear inverse demand function and linear marginal costs. Using a bounded rationality approach, the model is developed by optimizing objectives that balance profit, a share of consumer surplus and weighted social welfare. In our game, the first firm is privately owned and adopts a strategy where its owners maximize the sum of its profit and a share of consumer surplus. The second firm is publicly owned and implements a strategy focused on maximizing a combination of profit and social welfare. The study delves into the analysis of the game model through local stability, examining aspects such as the bifurcations and chaos. The following sections outline the structure of this paper.
Section 2 introduces the nonlinear map depicting the current game. Moving on to
Section 3, we determine the fixed points of the map and explore its stability criteria.
Section 4 conducts a comprehensive analysis of the map’s complex dynamic properties, including bifurcations, periodic cycles, and chaotic attractors. Lastly,
Section 5 presents the conclusions drawn from the research.
2. Cournot Model Structure
Throughout this section, the game involves two firms, identified as
i, which adopt a strategy based on quantities and offer goods with differentiations. The output levels produced by these firms are represented as
. To derive the firms’ demand functions, we must consider the following utility function:
where the parameter
denotes the magnitude of the market demand, while
indicates the extent of horizontal product differentiation. Assuming the consumer’s budget constraint is:
In this context,
M symbolizes the budget allocated by consumers for the product, while
denotes the prices of the goods. This setup leads us to the subsequent maximization problem:
Building on [
32], one can derive the demand system resulting from this type of product differentiation by starting with a budget constraint. Using the Lagrange method, we formulate the optimization problem (1) to (3), where products are differentiated. The normalized linear (inverse) demand functions, based on quadratic preferences, are presented below. By solving this optimization problem and setting the partial derivative with respect to with respect to
to zero, we obtain the inverse demand functions for firms
i,
in the following manner:
With the cost function of firm
i taking the form
, where
denotes the marginal cost for the firm, we can deduce that
In the business world, many organizations prioritize corporate social responsibility alongside their financial prosperity. Numerous empirical studies have illustrated how the integration of corporate social responsibility impacts business performance, where it is defined in terms of either consumer surplus
or social welfare
. In this examination, we focus on two firms with distinct objectives due to their differing natures. firm 1 not only aims to maximize its profits but also considers
, while firm 2 strives for profit maximization while also factoring in corporate social responsibility
considerations.
, often termed as consumer surplus, represents the disparity between the total amount consumers were willing to pay for a specific quantity of goods and the actual price paid. Given the context provided,
[
10,
11] can be mathematically expressed as:
We regarded social welfare
is used to represent corporate social responsibility (CSR). Consumer surplus (CS) and the income of two firms are combined to form the
,
Kople [
5] examines the endogenous selection of a quantity or price contract in a mixed duopoly with a socially conscious company that optimizes both consumer welfare and profit. Price-quantity contracts may coexist in equilibrium, welfare may be lower in price competition than in quantity competition and the businesses’ profit ranking may differ from that of a private duopoly or a mixed duopoly with a public enterprise. Therefore, the degree of social concern and market competition play a critical role in determining the best market strategy for a company that employs a social strategy. Lihua Han [
7] notes that in order to investigate the impact of companies’ corporate social responsibility (CSR) initiatives on the privatization of a public company, CSR is incorporated into a conventional mixed oligopoly. Profits and consumer surplus are taken into account by private CSR companies. It has been demonstrated that as the proportion of consumer surplus that CSR enterprises consider rises, the ideal level of nationalization or privatization falls. Put another way, when the private companies are CSR rather than just profit-maximizing, the government need to own a larger portion of the partially privatized company. Additionally, we discover that it is socially desirable for CSR companies to somewhat (but not entirely) take into account the advantages of their customers.
Building on [
5,
7] we assume the first firm, as a private company (Private CSR firm), seeks to maximize the combined value of its profit and a share of the consumer surplus, embodying its socially responsible approach. In accordance with the aforementioned hypotheses above, the objective function of firm 1 may be expressed as follows:
Here,
represents firm 1’s profit, while
belongs to the interval
, indicates the exogenously determined level of social concern.
is the proportion of consumer surplus (shows how important social responsibility is to each private company’s intended purpose). Stakeholders of firm1 will have
if the entire amount is captured, and
if none is. This parameter indicates the extent to which the first firm prioritizes consumer surplus in its decision-making. The incentive scheme outlined in (
8) incorporates a weighting of consumer surplus, emphasizing the strategic role of social responsibility (as discussed in [
2,
4,
9]). The parameter
represents the weight the owner (the first player) assigns to consumer surplus, reflecting the private firm’s level of social responsibility.
However, the objective function of firm 2 can be formulated differently. The second firm, as a public company, strives to maximize its objective function by combining profit and social welfare. Since this study considers a public firm, its goal is not only to maximize its own profit but also to take social welfare into account. Therefore, the objective function of this firm can be expressed as follows:
where
represents the degree of public ownership of the second firm. If
means that firm 2 is a complete public firm and it maximizes the social welfare while
means that firm 2 is a complete private firm. In this contract, as stated in [
9], the manager’s compensation is determined by a convex linear combination of profits and social welfare. Consequently, the weight assigned to social welfare can be greater than, less than, or equal to the weight assigned to profits. When this parameter is set below one, it encourages the manager to adopt a more aggressive market approach by operating with a lower marginal cost.
Establishing the information sets of both firms in relation to the objective function is essential for understanding how firm behavior evolves over time. The concept of bounded rationality offers a different perspective, acknowledging that players may not always fully comprehend each other’s actions or make perfectly rational decisions. As a result, firms determine their output based on expected marginal payoffs. In a dynamic competitive environment, players with bounded rationality may not be able to make optimal decisions instantly. Instead, they gradually refine their strategies based on marginal profits. For instance, if a firm experiences a positive marginal profit in the current period, it is likely to assume that increasing its investment in the next period will enhance profitability. Conversely, if it incurs a negative marginal profit, it will likely scale back its investment in the following period to mitigate losses. This adaptive decision-making process closely reflects real-world business behavior in complex and uncertain environments. Many researchers [
18,
19,
20,
21,
22,
23,
24,
25,
26,
27,
28] refer to this specific mechanism as the dynamic gradient adjustment mechanism.
In this model, we consider that two firms with restricted rationality make choices concurrently in a discrete-time
dynamic environment. That is, all firms have little knowledge about the choices made by their rivals and the needs of the market. To determine the output at period
, they can only utilize the local estimation of the objective function’s sharpest slope at period
t. The quantity adjustment method for company
i concerning time may be determined by applying F. Wu et al. [
33] and is given as follows:
where
represents the net profits of the firm at time
t, while
captures the rate at which the quantity adjustment for firm
i responds to a marginal change in profits denoted by
. If
, the firm will increase its output in period
; conversely, if
, the firm will decrease its output in period
. By combining Equations (
10) and (
11), we derive the two-dimensional nonlinear map that illustrates the dynamics of the game:
The adjustment speed reflects how rapidly firms react to changes in their marginal profit signals. By analyzing model (
12), we can identify the benefits firms gain, the achievement of their objectives, and the overall market stability when two firms choose different parameters. Furthermore, this study enables us to predict firms’ development status and trends under specific fixed parameter combinations. These insights provide theoretical guidance for managers and business owners, helping them navigate the market more effectively and ensure stable growth.
3. Dynamic Behavior of the Equilibrium Points
This section is dedicated to analyzing the stability criteria of equilibrium points within the given model under different parameter settings. To simplify computation, we introduce specific quantities such that
,
,
, and
, thus simplifying model (
12) to:
The Nash equilibrium is considered a set of strategies where a modification in the strategy of any participant does not lead to an enhancement in the profits of all involved parties. As a result, to optimize their gains, each participant persists with their current strategy.
Table 1 summarizes the stability of the Nash equilibrium solution within model (
13).
So, we can get four points of equilibrium for model (
13) through calculation as follows:
We refer to the equilibrium points
,
, and
as border equilibrium points since they are all on the coordinate axis, whereas
is also known as a Nash equilibrium point or an internal equilibrium point. The positivity of equilibrium point
is guaranteed since
can never be negative, and for equilibrium point
to be non-negative, it is essential that
. In cases where the selected parameters align with economic significance, the condition of non-negativity is consistently met. Therefore, the aforementioned parameters must fulfill at least one of the following criteria for equilibrium point
to remain non-negative:
or
3.1. Stability of the Border Equilibrium
We investigate the four equilibria mentioned above for stability. Let’s start by calculating the Jacobian matrix for model (
13) at any position, as shown below.
Four equilibrium points are individually substituted into matrix (
17) to produce the Jacobian matrices of each equilibrium point. The eigenvalues of each equilibrium point’s Jacobian matrix are then calculated to ascertain the kind and stability of the point.
Proposition 1. The trivial equilibrium is unstable source node.
Proof. It is evident that the Jacobian matrix at
has the following structure:
It is evident that
forms a diagonal matrix. Consequently, the eigenvalues can be expressed as
where
The parameters
and
A being non-negative allows us to determine that both the moduli of
and
are greater than 1. As a result of both eigenvalues being beyond the unit circle, then node
is unstable. □
Proposition 2. Borderline equilibrium point has at least four distinct topological types for every value of the parameters:
- 1.
is a sink stable point if and
- 2.
is unstable source node if and
- 3.
is a saddle point for the other values of parameters except the values in (1) and (2),
- 4.
is a non-hyperbolic point if and .
Proof. Through computation, we can find the Jacobian matrix at the equilibrium point
, which is depicted as:
which has two eigenvalues,
Since for values
,
(1): If
and
then
hence
if,
This leads to
is a sink stable point. (2): If
and
then
hence
if
In this case,
is an unstable source node. (3): For the other values of parameters except the values in (1) and (2)
is a saddle point, (i.e.)
if
and
and if
then
(4): It is clear that one of these eigenvalues of
equals 1, while the other is neither 1 nor −1. Then, each parameter is found in the following area:
Consequently,
may undergo a flip bifurcation as the parameters vary within a small vicinity of
□
Proposition 3. Borderline equilibrium point has at least four distinct topological types for every value of the parameters:
- 1.
is a sink stable point if and
- 2.
is unstable source node if and
- 3.
is a saddle point if and
- 4.
is a non-hyperbolic point if and
Proof. Substitute
into
, then the Jacobian matrix of model (
13) at point
takes the form:
we derive two related eigenvalues of such
as form:
Since for values
,
(1): If
and
then
hence
if,
This leads to
is a sink stable point. (2): If
and
then
hence
if
In this case,
is an unstable source node. (3): For
and
then
and
if,
at this moment
is a saddle point. (4):
is an unstable node in all other respects. The possibility of a flip bifurcation should be noted at the following region:
□
3.2. Nash Equilibrium Stability
In the field of economics, the boundary equilibrium point
signals the failure of two firms, whereas
and
exemplify a situation where one firm dominates the market, resulting in a monopoly. Generally, a stable Nash equilibrium point in the economic market signifies that both firms ensure the market’s steady growth while securing their own profits. Following this, we will assess the local stability of
. Determining the eigenvalues linked with matrix (
17) directly at the Nash equilibrium point
is intricate due to the complex structure of the matrix in that specific context. However, by using merely the Jury criteria [
34], we may investigate the local stability of
. The following form can be used to represent the matrix
of the system (
13) at
:
Then the trace
and determinant
of the matrix
can be obtained as:
By utilizing the Jury criteria, we can assess the local stability of
. Meeting all the conditions outlined in the Jury requirement allows us to establish the asymptotic stability of the Nash equilibrium
. The specific expression of the Jury criteria is as follows:
The above set of inequalities may be calculated using a complicated formula if we replace the particular mathematical expressions of
and
into the aforementioned equations:
As a result, Equation (
24) illustrates the stable domain of
. Failure to satisfy the first criterion may lead to a fold bifurcation, a transcritical bifurcation, or a pitchfork bifurcation. If the second criterion is not fulfilled, a flip bifurcation could occur. Additionally, the Neimark-Sacker bifurcation might occur if the third criterion is not satisfied.
Proposition 4. The unique Nash equilibrium is stable if and only if condition (24) holds. The stability criteria of four equilibria are given by the aforementioned assertions. Decision-makers can influence a company’s behavior in the real economic market by ensuring that certain requirements are satisfied, such as stability, and by selecting parameters that fall within the range of stability. This will allow the firm to grow steadily or arrive at the desired state. We provide a demonstration with several examples to validate the accuracy of our results and to elaborate on how parameters influence the stable region. This discussion explores the system’s behavior, showing how it transitions between chaos and stability for certain parameter values. It also examines how changes in parameters affect the stability of the Nash equilibrium, illustrated with a clear bifurcation diagram. This helps validate the results and provides a better understanding of the system’s dynamics.
4. Numerical Simulation
In this section, we will delve into an in-depth examination of the complex dynamical patterns exhibited by model (
13). We will employ numerical simulation methods to thoroughly explore the system’s behaviors and characteristics. This section studies the game’s dynamics. It focuses on how differences in objectives affect behavior under the gradient rule. It examines how the stability threshold changes with each firm’s level of CSR. The analysis explores whether CSR and social welfare stabilize or destabilize market equilibrium. It aims to understand the impact of CSR on market robustness. We will conduct a thorough investigation into the appearance of a flip bifurcation and a Neimark-Sacker bifurcation through comprehensive numerical simulations. These simulations will involve the use of bifurcation transition diagrams, computations of the maximum Lyapunov exponent (MLE) for assessing chaos, phase plane diagrams to visualize system trajectories, and an array of related techniques. By employing these tools, we aim to gain a detailed understanding of the system’s behavior at critical points and transitions [
35].
Considering a specific set of constant parameters, namely
and
,
Figure 1 depicts the alteration in the stable region within the parameter planes of
and
.
Figure 1a, demonstrates the system’s stable area and bifurcation curves when
, curves are shown by the
curves, the flip bifurcation curve by the black arc, and the green curve shows Neimark-Sacker bifurcation and the stable zone of the system is defined as the region enclosed by the blue and green bifurcation curves. In the detailed analysis presented in
Figure 1b, focusing on an alternate parameter configuration denoted by
, a comprehensive exploration of the system’s behavior unfolds. As the system evolves, the pivotal moment arises when either
or
traverses the green curve within the stability domain. At this juncture, the stable Nash equilibrium point experiences a critical loss of stability, marking the onset of a Neimark-Sacker bifurcation. Subsequently, the system undergoes a transformative phase as the value of
or
surpasses the blue curve within the stability domain, initiating a flip bifurcation. This bifurcation event propels the system into a regime where it oscillates between periods 1 and 2, periods 4 and 8, and further periodic intervals. This progressive transition towards chaos signifies a significant shift in the system’s dynamics, eventually leading to a state of intricate and unpredictable behavior.
Figure 1c displays the system’s stable zone and bifurcation curves with an emphasis on parameters
, ranging in
. The system will traverse the flip bifurcation curves, as indicated by the black curve. A flip bifurcation will cause
to lose its stability, for example, if we choose parameters like
. Following this type of bifurcation, a pair of stable fixed points and stable period-4 fixed points will emerge one after the other.
The red curve in
Figure 2 represents the outputs
of firm 1, whereas the blue curve represents the outputs
of firm 2. The bifurcation parameters are
and
with initial condition
, and we fix the parameter values,
and
. The rate of quantity adjustment for enterprise 2 is determined by
as the bifurcating parameter first in
Figure 2a when enterprise 1 is a fully private enterprise and
,
According to these bifurcation diagrams, both firms’ outputs are stable throughout the interval
, as is the distinct positive Cournot-Nash equilibrium point
. However, during flip bifurcation, the system enters chaos when
reaches the critical value
A 2D bifurcation diagram for the rate of quantity adjustment for firm 1,
, with parameters
,
. This is shown in
Figure 2b. For instance, the output systems of both businesses are stable and disturbed when
as
The system’s dynamical behavior is extremely complex between
. A period-doubling bifurcation, sometimes called a period-halving bifurcation, is caused by an increase in
When
, four multiperiodic windows may be observed, and the system thereafter descends into chaos. We look at how the differentiation index
affects system stability in
Figure 2c. For parameters
,
, indicating that firm 2 is completely private and solely wants to maximize its own profit. When the degree of public ownership of firm 1 satisfies
, system (
13) is in a period-1 stable state, indicating that the market has stabilized and that the stakeholders of firm 1 will have a partial amount of social responsibility. This indicates that
has a significant impact on the stability of the system. Moreover, flip bifurcation is seen to occur as the parameters continue to change (i.e., as
lowers
), it indicates that the market would be unstable when firm 1 gets completely private. To analyze the impact of fully privatizing firm1 on the market, we show the parameters
in
Figure 2d We find that firm 2’s output stabilizes when
and that the sum of the producer and consumer surpluses is greatest at the ideal level of nationalization.
An evident chaotic perturbation emerges, as depicted by the Lyapunov exponent breaching zero during the tangential bifurcation phase for the fixed parameters
, as illustrated in
Figure 3. By analyzing the Lyapunov exponent diagram in
Figure 3a with specific values
, distinctions among stable, quasi-periodic, chaotic, and divergent states become discernible. When the maximum Lyapunov exponent remains below 1 concerning
, the dynamical system corresponds to either a periodic or stable state. For a varied range of
values with
, an examination of the average Lyapunov exponent reveals the periodic nature of the system’s orbit when the value is negative. This observation is highlighted in
Figure 3b, distinguishing the system’s behavior under different conditions.
Figure 3c, where
is taken as the variable parameter, for fixed parameters
and
Figure 3d, where
is taken as the variable parameter, for fixed parameters
are provide the transverse Lyapunov exponent.
The attractor is a period-1 takes place when the parameters
which can be seen in
Figure 4a. Fixed the parameters as
the numerical simulation can provide the attractor under various weights of
Figure 4b describes 2-cycle of model (
13) for
While when the parameters
varied as
we can see the portrait starts to create new phenomena due to breakdown of the invariant closed curve, in
Figure 4c. As seen in
Figure 4d, the broken attractor keeps spreading and merging to generate two invariant closed curve as
.
Figure 4e,f show the dynamic behaviors that two previously stated chaotic attractors exhibit as they expand and combine to produce a single chaotic attractor component.
Figure 5 shows the chart of dynamic modes for fixed parameters
It is commonly known that the dynamic modes chart can show the market strategy area of these two firms. Various periodic modes are denoted by various colors in
Figure 5. The Color bar is located on the right side of the dynamic modes chart and provides readers with further information about each color’s specific meaning. A quasiperiodic state or a chaotic state with a period longer than 30 is represented by the red zone in the diagram of dynamic modes. In
Figure 5a, the dynamic modes are portrayed within the parameter plane of
with
and
. Transitioning to
Figure 5b, which represents the chart of dynamic modes in the parameter plane
with
and
, the system exhibits a bifurcation sequence as
increases. This progression is characterized by a shift from period-1 to period-2, then from period-2 to period-4, and so forth, eventually culminating in a chaotic state. Moving on to
Figure 5c with
while considering
as variable parameters, the system cyclically transitions through periods 1, 2, 4, and beyond. Through a flip bifurcation, the stable Nash equilibrium point loses stability, transforming into a stable period-2 cycle. Subsequently, a Neimark-Sacker bifurcation induces the stable period-2 cycle to lose stability, leading to the emergence of a quasiperiodic state, as elucidated in
Figure 5d. Finally,
Figure 5e illustrates the system progressing through period-4, period-8, period-16, and onward, ultimately transitioning into a chaotic state. This comprehensive visual depiction encapsulates the system’s evolution through various dynamic states as influenced by the interplay of parameters and bifurcation phenomena.