Learning from the Co-operative Institutional Model: How to Enhance Organizational Robustness of Third Sector Organizations with More Pluralistic Forms of Governance
Abstract
:1. Introduction
“democratic societies are necessarily placed at risk when people conceive of their relationships as being grounded on principles of command and control rather than on principles of self-responsibility in self-governing communities of relationships.”
- Mitigating information asymmetries and leadership opportunism through stakeholder involvement and monitoring, which then elevates stakeholder voice into actionable strategy while promoting more equitable stakeholder treatment [14];
- Diversifying collective choice arrangements, modes of inclusivity, and sets of rules, thereby enhancing organizational robustness through an arena of experimentation.
Principle | Description |
---|---|
1A | User boundaries: Clear boundaries between legitimate users and nonusers must be clearly defined. |
1B | Resource boundaries: Clear boundaries are present that define a resource system and separate it from the larger biophysical environment. |
2A | Congruence with local conditions: Appropriation and provision rules are congruent with local social and environmental conditions. |
2B | Appropriation and provision: The benefits obtained by users from a common-pool resource (CPR), as determined by appropriation rules, are proportional to the amount of inputs required in the form of labor, material, or money, as determined by provision rules. |
3 | Collective-choice arrangements: Most individuals affected by the operational rules can participate in modifying the operational rules. |
4A | Monitoring users: Monitors who are accountable to the users monitor the appropriation and provision levels of the users. |
4B | Monitoring the resource: Monitors who are accountable to the users monitor the condition of the resource. |
5 | Graduated sanctions: Appropriators who violate operational rules are likely to be assessed graduated sanctions (depending on the seriousness and the context of the offense) by other appropriators, by officials accountable to the appropriators, or by both. |
6 | Conflict-resolution mechanisms: Appropriators and their officials have rapid access to low-cost local arenas to resolve conflicts among appropriators or between appropriators and officials. |
7 | Minimal recognition of rights to organize: The rights of appropriators to devise their own institutions are not challenged by external governmental authorities. |
8 | Nested enterprises: Appropriation, provision, monitoring, enforcement, conflict resolution, and governance activities are organized in multiple layers of nested enterprises. |
2. Analyzing Institutional Design
2.1. Introducing the Ostrom Design Principles: From Unitary to More Pluralist Governance Arrangements
- The abundance and diversity of common property regimes. While this may seem self-evident, documenting this fact was crucially important for demonstrating that actors do indeed self-govern in many instances, despite the “Tragedy” hypothesis.
- Stakeholders are capable of “careful coordination and management of use” [16] (p. 43) of scarce, complex resources, and individuals are motivated not just by self-seeking outcomes but also concern for others and their communities.
- Empirical evidence of successful self-governing capabilities challenges the application of top-down modes of governance for large-scale social dilemma. Indeed, evidence derived from analyses of institutions providing public goods have noted that excluding stakeholders may impede organizational performance [17,18], thereby calling into question the “unitary-as-the-mode-of-efficiency” hypothesis [19].
2.2. The Design of the Co-Operative Institutional Model
“an autonomous association of persons united voluntarily to meet their common economic, social, and cultural needs and aspirations through a jointly-owned and democratically-controlled enterprise.”
“Co-operatives are based on the values of self-help, self-responsibility, democracy, equality, equity and solidarity. In the tradition of their founders, co-operative members believe in the ethical values of honesty, openness, social responsibility and caring for others.”
Principles | Values |
---|---|
1. Voluntary and Open Membership * | Self-Help |
2. Democratic Member Control | Self-Responsibility |
3. Member Economic Participation | Democracy |
4. Autonomy and Independence | Equality |
5. Education, Training, and Information | Solidarity |
6. Cooperation Amongst Co-operatives | Honesty |
7. Concern for Community | Openness |
Social Responsibility | |
Caring for Others |
“the socially constructed, historical patterns of cultural symbols and material practices, including assumptions, values, and beliefs, by which individuals and organizations provide meaning to their daily activity, organize time and space, and reproduce their lives and experiences.”
The “benefits of co-operative approaches must be considered in light of their costs, particularly as non-trivial organisational resources are likely to be needed if policy value-for-the-money is to be increased above that of the current system”.
3. Archival Analysis: Identifying the Member Governance Ruptures in Choctaw Electric Co-operative
3.1. The Case of Choctaw Electric Co-operative
“They [CEC] buy their electricity from Western Electric Co-op, even though Western Electric prices were cheaper in 2012, they actually raised our rates to cover Mr. Matlock’s $2 million gift and the doubling of their salaries,” Hammons said. “That’s the whole problem is the membership is not informed enough about what’s going on financially”[35]
- Post the agenda for the monthly meetings;
- Publish the official board meeting minutes across a number of mediums;
- Initiate a new board question and answer session before the monthly meetings;
- Implement an employee whistleblower protection policy, and;
- Initiate a bylaws review committee that includes both board members and two rank-and-file member-owners from each of CEC’s nine districts.
3.2. Application of the ODP Diagnostic to an Analysis of CEC’s Governance Structure
ODP 1A. User boundaries: Clear boundaries between legitimate users and nonusers must beclearly defined.
ODP 2A. Congruence with local conditions: Appropriation and provision rules are congruent with local social and environmental conditions and ODP 2B. Appropriation and provision: The benefits obtained by users from a common-pool resource (CPR), as determined by appropriation rules, are proportional to the amount of inputs required in the form of labor, material, or money, as determined by provision rules.
ODP 4A. Monitoring users: Monitors who are accountable to the users monitor the appropriation and provision levels of the users, and ODP 4B. Monitoring the resource: Monitors who are accountable to the users monitor the condition of the resource.
3.3. Discussion: Identifying Structural Opportunities to Reconfigure Unitary Capture in Pluralistically Governed Enterprise
ODP 1A. User boundaries: Clear boundaries between legitimate users and nonusers must be clearly defined.
ODP 6. Conflict-resolution mechanisms: Appropriators and their officials have rapid access to low-cost local arenas to resolve conflicts among appropriators or between appropriators and officials, and ODP 8. Nested enterprises: Appropriation, provision, monitoring, enforcement, conflict resolution, and governance activities are organized in multiple layers of nested enterprises.
4. Conclusions: Extrapolating Empirical Findings from Co-operative Enterprise to Third Sector Organizational Governance
Supplementary Materials
Supplementary File 1Conflicts of Interest
References
- Taylor, K. Governing the Wind Energy Commons; West Virginia University Press: Morgantown, WV, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Coule, T.M. Nonprofit Governance and Accountability: Broadening the Theoretical Perspective. Nonprofit Volunt. Sect. Q. 2013, 44, 75–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wagner, A. “Third sector” and/or “civil society”: A critical discourse about scholarship relating to intermediate organisations. Volunt. Sect. Rev. 2012, 3, 299–328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, V. Artisanship and artifact. Public Adm. Rev. 1980, 40, 309–317. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ghoshal, S. Bad management theories are destroying good management practices. Acad. Manag. Learn. Educ. 2005, 4, 75–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lindblom, C.E. Who Needs What Social Research for Policymaking? Sci. Commun. 1986, 7, 345–366. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cook, M.L. The role of management behavior in agricultural cooperatives. J. Agric. Coop. 1994, 9, 42–58. [Google Scholar]
- Cornforth, C. Nonprofit Governance Research: Limitations of the Focus on Boards and Suggestions for New Directions. Nonprofit Volunt. Sect. Q. 2012, 41, 1116–1135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wagner, A. Good Governance: A Radical and Normative Approach to Nonprofit Management. Volunt. Int. J. Volunt. Nonprofit Organ. 2014, 25, 797–817. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, V. The Meaning of Democracy and the Vulnerability of Democracies: A Response to Tocqueville’s Challenge; University of Michigan Press: Ann Arbor, MI, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Bell, D. Labor in the post-industrial society. Dissent 1972, 19, 163–189. [Google Scholar]
- Mooney, P.H. Democratizing rural economy: Institutional friction, sustainable struggle and the cooperative movement. Rural Sociol. 2004, 69, 76–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Müller, R.; Turner, R.; Andersen, E.S.; Shao, J.; Kvalnes, Ø. Ethics, Trust, and Governance in Temporary Organizations. Proj. Manag. J. 2014, 45, 39–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hansmann, H. The Ownership of Enterprise; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Hardin, G. The tragedy of the commons. Science 1968, 162, 1243–1248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Poteete, A.R.; Janssen, M.A.; Ostrom, E. Working Together: Collective Action, the Commons, and Multiple Methods in Practice; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Aligica, P.D.; Boettke, P. Challenging Institutional Analysis and Development: The Bloomington School, 1st ed.; Routledge: New York, NY, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
- Lee, L.; Reinicke, B.; Sarkar, R.; Anderson, R. Learning through Interactions: Improving Project Management through Communities of Practice. Proj. Manag. J. 2015, 46, 40–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Heikkila, T.; Schlager, E.; Davis, M.W. The Role of Cross-Scale Institutional Linkages in Common Pool Resource Management: Assessing Interstate River Compacts. Policy Stud. J. 2011, 39, 121–145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, E. Understanding Institutional Diversity; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2005. [Google Scholar]
- Ostrom, E. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action; Cambridge University Press: New York, NY, USA, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Cox, M.; Arnold, G.; Villamayor Tomas, S. A Review of Design Principles for Community-Based Natural Resource Management. Ecol. Soc. 2010, 15, 38. Available online: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol15/iss4/art38/ (accessed on 29 March 2015). [Google Scholar]
- McGinnis, M.D. An introduction to IAD and the language of the Ostrom Workshop: A simple guide to a complex framework. Policy Stud. J. 2011, 39, 169–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, E. A diagnostic approach for going beyond panaceas. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 2007, 104, 15181–15187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- International Co-operative Alliance. Available online: http://ica.coop/en/what-co-op/co-operative-identity-values- principles (accessed on 29 March 2015).
- Falconer, K. Developing Cooperative Approaches to Agri-Environmental Policy: A Transaction Cost Perspective on Farmer Participation in Voluntary Schemes. In Environmental Co-Operation and Institutional Change: Theories and Policies for European Agriculture; Hagedorn, K., Ed.; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 2007. [Google Scholar]
- Sherwood, A.; Taylor, K. Unique expectation of co-operative boards: Taking on the challenges of the democratic enterprise. Int. J. Co-op. Manag. 2014, 7, 29–42. [Google Scholar]
- Chaddad, F.R.; Cook, M.L. Understanding New Cooperative Models: An Ownership-Control Rights Typology. Appl. Econ. Perspect. Policy 2004, 26, 348–360. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McGinnis, Michael D. Updated Guide to IAD and the Language of the Ostrom Workshop: A Simplified Overview of a Complex Framework for the Analysis of Institutions and their Development. Available online: http://pages.iu.edu/~mcginnis/iad_guide.pdf (accessed on 29 March 2015).
- Suhler, D.R.; Cook, M.L. Origins of a Current Conflict? An Examination of Stock-Nonstock Cooperative Law. J. Agric. Coop. 1993, 8, 54–62. [Google Scholar]
- Center for Cooperatives. Available online: http://reic.uwcc.wisc.edu/ (accessed on 24 April 2013).
- Gidron, B. The (continued) search for an appropriate name for the third sector. Volunt. Sect. Rev. 2013, 4, 303–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Molk, P. The Puzzling Lack of Cooperatives. Tulane Law Rev. 2014, 88, 899–958. [Google Scholar]
- Station KTEN TV. CEO Responds To Facebook Claims From Upset Electric Customers Near Hugo. KTen News. Available online: http://www.kten.com/story/26168957/ceo-responds-to-facebook-claims-from-upset-electric-customers-near-hugo (accessed on 29 March 2015).
- News 12 KXII. Okla. electric cooperative shareholders petition to rid of trustees. 3 November 2014. Available online: http://www.kxii.com/home/headlines/Okla-electric-cooperative-shareholders-petition-to-rid-of-trustees-280916692.html (accessed on 29 March 2015).
- Hugo News. Choctaw Electric Cooperative Board Terminates CEO Terry Matlock. Available online: http://www.hugonews.com/choctaw-electric-cooperative-board-directors-terminatesceo-terry-matlock/ (accessed on 29 March 2015).
- Marks, J. 8 members resign from Oklahoma Choctaw Electric Cooperative board. NewsOK. Available online: http://newsok.com/8-members-resign-from-oklahoma-choctaw-electric-cooperative-board/article/5379034/?page=2 (accessed on 29 March 2015).
- Schmidt, M. Petition filed against Choctaw Electric Cooperative now void. News 12 KXII. Available online: http://www.kxii.com/home/headlines/Petition-filed-against-Choctaw-Electric-Cooperative-voided-288371861.html (accessed on 29 March 2015).
- Choctaw Electric Cooperative. Press Release. Official Facebook Page of Choctaw Electric Cooperative. 25 March 2015. Available online: https://www.facebook.com/choctawelectriccooperative/posts/857303447673703 (accessed on 29 March 2015).
- Pozzobon, D.M.; Machado-Filho, C.A.P. In search of cooperative governance: A Brazilian agricultural co-op case study. In Proceedings of the International PENSA Conference, Ribeirão Preto, Brazil, 24–26 October 2007; Available online: http://www.fundacaofia.com.br/PENSA/anexos/biblioteca/1592008135938_Governan%C3%A7aCooperativas.pdf (accessed on 29 March 2015).
- Ledwith, M. Community Development: A Critical Approach; Policy Press: Bristol, UK, 2011. [Google Scholar]
© 2015 by the author; licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution license ( http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Taylor, K. Learning from the Co-operative Institutional Model: How to Enhance Organizational Robustness of Third Sector Organizations with More Pluralistic Forms of Governance. Adm. Sci. 2015, 5, 148-164. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci5030148
Taylor K. Learning from the Co-operative Institutional Model: How to Enhance Organizational Robustness of Third Sector Organizations with More Pluralistic Forms of Governance. Administrative Sciences. 2015; 5(3):148-164. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci5030148
Chicago/Turabian StyleTaylor, Keith. 2015. "Learning from the Co-operative Institutional Model: How to Enhance Organizational Robustness of Third Sector Organizations with More Pluralistic Forms of Governance" Administrative Sciences 5, no. 3: 148-164. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci5030148
APA StyleTaylor, K. (2015). Learning from the Co-operative Institutional Model: How to Enhance Organizational Robustness of Third Sector Organizations with More Pluralistic Forms of Governance. Administrative Sciences, 5(3), 148-164. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci5030148