Relative Deprivation: How Subjective Experiences of Income Inequality Influence Risk Preferences
Abstract
1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
2.1. Relative Deprivation Theory
2.2. Relative Deprivation and Risk Preferences
3. Methods
3.1. Study Design and Data Collection
3.2. Experimental Procedures
3.3. Risk Aversion
Individuals who initially chose the first job were asked to consider a job with a smaller downside risk of one-fourth, while those who selected the second job were presented with a riskier option that could reduce their income by one-half. If participants declined the first job with a one-fourth downside risk, they were subsequently offered a job with only a one-tenth downside risk. Similarly, those who accepted the job with a potential 50% income reduction were further asked about an even riskier job with a downside risk of three-quarters. These five questions resulted in six possible categories of risk aversion, providing a coarse ranking of the individual’s willingness to avoid financial risk (see Appendix B). These rankings and the downside risks for each condition establish the lower and upper bounds on relative risk aversion (Table 1).“Suppose that you are the only income earner in the family, and you have a good job.... You are given the opportunity to take a new and equally good job, with a 50–50 chance that it will double your income and a 50–50 chance that it will reduce your income by a third. Would you take the new job?”
3.4. Interval Regression
4. Results
5. Discussion
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Data Description
Study 1 (N = 564) | Study 2 (N = 584) | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Mean or Freq. | % | Mean or Freq. | % | |
Age (25–59) | 42.7 | 43.3 | ||
Gender | ||||
Male | 288 | 51.1 | 298 | 51.0 |
Female | 276 | 48.9 | 286 | 49.0 |
Marital status | ||||
Married | 318 | 56.4 | 335 | 57.4 |
Not married | 246 | 43.6 | 249 | 42.6 |
Education | ||||
High school graduate | 164 | 29.1 | 171 | 29.3 |
College graduate | 332 | 58.9 | 348 | 59.6 |
Post-graduate degree | 68 | 12.1 | 65 | 11.1 |
Employment | ||||
Self-employed | 46 | 8.2 | 63 | 10.8 |
Full-time worker | 494 | 87.6 | 476 | 81.5 |
Part-time worker | 24 | 4.3 | 45 | 7.7 |
Monthly income | 427.6 | 422.6 | ||
Own home | 325 | 57.6 | 334 | 57.2 |
Wealth | ||||
<100 mil. KRW | 142 | 25.2 | 165 | 28.3 |
100–300 mil. KRW | 173 | 30.7 | 170 | 29.1 |
300–500 mil. KRW | 105 | 18.6 | 96 | 16.4 |
>500 mil. KRW | 144 | 25.5 | 153 | 26.2 |
Appendix B. Measures and Measurement Items
Appendix B.1. Personal Deservingness
Item | Scoring |
---|---|
When you think about the discretionary income you received compared to similar individuals, how satisfied are you? | 7-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
When you think about the discretionary income you received compared to similar individuals, how resentful are you? | 7-point Likert scale |
When you think about the discretionary income you received compared to similar individuals, to what degree do you feel that you want more discretionary income? | 7-point Likert scale |
When you think about the discretionary income you received compared to similar individuals, to what degree do you feel you deserved your discretionary income? | 7-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
When you think about the discretionary income you received compared to similar individuals, to what extent do you think that it is just that you receive this level of discretionary income? | 7-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
Appendix B.2. 20-Item Spielberger State Anxiety Inventory
Item | Scoring |
---|---|
I feel calm | 5-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
I feel secure | 5-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
I am tense | 5-point Likert scale |
I feel strained | 5-point Likert scale |
I feel at ease | 5-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
I feel upset | 5-point Likert scale |
I am presently worrying over possible misfortunes | 5-point Likert scale |
I feel satisfied | 5-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
I feel frightened | 5-point Likert scale |
I feel comfortable | 5-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
I feel self-confident | 5-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
I feel nervous | 5-point Likert scale |
I am jittery | 5-point Likert scale |
I feel indecisive | 5-point Likert scale |
I am relaxed | 5-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
I feel content | 5-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
I am worried | 5-point Likert scale |
I feel confused | 5-point Likert scale |
I feel steady | 5-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
I feel pleasant | 5-point Likert scale (reverse scored) |
Appendix B.3. Hypothetical Income Gamble Questions to Elicit Risk Aversion
“1. Suppose you are the only income earner in the family. You recently encountered some personal circumstances that require you to move, and you have to choose between two possible jobs.
If respondents answered, “second job,” the interviewer continued with the following.The first would guarantee your current total family income for life. The second is possibly better paying, but the income is also less certain. There is a 50–50 chance the second job would double your total lifetime income and a 50–50 chance that it would cut it by a third. Which job would you take—the first job or the second job?”
If respondents chose “first job” in question 1, they were given an option with a lower downside risk.“2a. Suppose the chances were 50–50 that the second job would double your lifetime income, and 50–50 that it would cut it in half. Would you take the first job or the second job?”
Respondents taking “second job” to question 2a were asked to consider one with a higher downside risk.“2b. Suppose the chances were 50–50 that the second job would double your lifetime income and 50–50 that it would cut it by twenty percent. Would you take the first job or the second job?”
Respondents who answered “first job” to question 2b were directed to the following safer alternative.“3a. Suppose the chances were 50–50 that the second job would double your lifetime income and 50–50 that it would cut it by seventy-five percent. Would you take the first job or the second job?”
“3b. Suppose the chances were 50–50 that the second job would double your lifetime income and 50–50 that it would cut it by 10 percent. Would you take the first job or the second job?”
Appendix B.4. Multiple Price Listing Lottery
Decision | Option A | Option B | E(A)–E(B) |
---|---|---|---|
1 | 1/10 of $2.00, 9/10 of $1.60 | 1/10 of $3.85, 9/10 of $0.10 | $1.17 |
2 | 2/10 of $2.00, 8/10 of $1.60 | 2/10 of $3.85, 8/10 of $0.10 | $0.83 |
3 | 3/10 of $2.00, 7/10 of $1.60 | 3/10 of $3.85, 7/10 of $0.10 | $0.50 |
4 | 4/10 of $2.00, 6/10 of $1.60 | 4/10 of $3.85, 6/10 of $0.10 | $0.16 |
5 | 5/10 of $2.00, 5/10 of $1.60 | 5/10 of $3.85, 5/10 of $0.10 | −$0.18 |
6 | 6/10 of $2.00, 4/10 of $1.60 | 6/10 of $3.85, 4/10 of $0.10 | −$0.51 |
7 | 7/10 of $2.00, 3/10 of $1.60 | 7/10 of $3.85, 3/10 of $0.10 | −$0.85 |
8 | 8/10 of $2.00, 2/10 of $1.60 | 8/10 of $3.85, 2/10 of $0.10 | −$1.18 |
9 | 9/10 of $2.00, 1/10 of $1.60 | 9/10 of $3.85, 1/10 of $0.10 | −$1.52 |
10 | 10/10 of $2.00, 0/10 of $1.60 | 10/10 of $3.85, 0/10 of $0.10 | −$1.85 |
Appendix B.5. Mapping Survey Responses to Risk Preferences
1 |
References
- Adjaye-Gbewonyo, K., & Kawachi, I. (2012). Use of the Yitzhaki Index as a test of relative deprivation for health outcomes: A review of recent literature. Social Science & Medicine, 75(1), 129–137. [Google Scholar]
- Amador-Hidalgo, L., Brañas-Garza, P., Espín, A. M., García-Muñoz, T., & Hernández-Román, A. (2021). Cognitive abilities and risk-taking: Errors, not preferences. European Economic Review, 134, 1–17. [Google Scholar]
- Barsky, R. B., Juster, F. T., Kimball, M. S., & Shapiro, M. D. (1997). Preference parameters and behavioral heterogeneity: An experimental approach in the Health and Retirement Study. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 537–579. [Google Scholar]
- Bosch-Domènech, A., & Silvestre, J. (2013). Measuring risk aversion with lists: A new bias. Theory and Decision, 75(4), 465–496. [Google Scholar]
- Brown-Iannuzzi, J. L., & McKee, S. E. (2019). Economic inequality and risk-taking behaviors. In The social psychology of inequality (pp. 201–212). Springer. [Google Scholar]
- Byrnes, J. P., Miller, D. C., & Schafer, W. D. (1999). Gender differences in risk taking: A meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 125(3), 367–383. [Google Scholar]
- Callan, M. J., Ellard, J. H., Shead, N. W., & Hodgins, D. C. (2008). Gambling as a search for justice: Examining the role of personal relative deprivation in gambling urges and gambling behavior. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 34(11), 1514–1529. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
- Callan, M. J., Shead, N. W., & Olson, J. M. (2011). Personal relative deprivation, delay discounting, and gambling. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 101(5), 955–973. [Google Scholar]
- Callan, M. J., Shead, N. W., & Olson, J. M. (2015). The relation between personal relative deprivation and the urge to gamble among gamblers is moderated by problem gambling severity: A meta-analysis. Addictive Behaviors, 45, 146–149. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
- Callen, M., Isaqzadeh, M., Long, J. D., & Sprenger, C. (2014). Violence and risk preference: Experimental evidence from Afghanistan. American Economic Review, 104(1), 123–148. [Google Scholar]
- Chang, W. C. (2011). Identity, gender, and subjective well-being. Review of Social Economy, 69(1), 97–121. [Google Scholar]
- D’Ambrosio, C., & Frick, J. R. (2012). Individual wellbeing in a dynamic perspective. Economica, 79(314), 284–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dohmen, T., Non, A., & Stolp, T. (2021). Reference points and the tradeoff between risk and incentives. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 192, 813–831. [Google Scholar]
- Eibner, C., & Evans, W. N. (2005). Relative deprivation, poor health habits, and mortality. Journal of Human Resources, 40(3), 591–620. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ermer, E., Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (2008). Relative status regulates risky decision making about resources in men: Evidence for the co-evolution of motivation and cognition. Evolution and Human Behavior, 29(2), 106–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Estepa-Mohedano, L., & Espinosa, M. P. (2023). Comparing risk elicitation in lotteries with visual or contextual aids. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 103, 101974. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fehr, D., & Reichlin, Y. (2023). Are risk preferences shaped by status concerns? [Working paper]. Heidelberg University and European University Institute. [Google Scholar]
- Festinger, L. (1954). A theory of social comparison processes. Human Behavior, 7(2), 117–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Forgays, D. K., Spielberger, C. D., Ottaway, S. A., & Forgays, D. G. (1998). Factor structure of the state-trait anger expression inventory for middle-aged men and women. Assessment, 5(2), 141–155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gerber, J. P., Wheeler, L., & Suls, J. (2018). A social comparison theory meta-analysis 60+ years on. Psychological Bulletin, 144(2), 177–197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gero, K., Kondo, K., Kondo, N., Shirai, K., & Kawachi, I. (2017). Associations of relative deprivation and income rank with depressive symptoms among older adults in Japan. Social Science & Medicine, 189, 138–144. [Google Scholar]
- Guiso, L. (2012). Trust and risk aversion in the aftermath of the great recession. European Business Organization Law Review, 13(2), 195–209. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hanaoka, C., Shigeoka, H., & Watanabe, Y. (2018). Do risk preferences change? Evidence from the great east japan earthquake. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 10(2), 298–330. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Herranz-Zarzoso, N., Sabater-Grande, G., & Jaramillo-Gutiérrez, A. (2020). Framing and repetition effects on risky choices: A behavioural approach. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 84, 101504. [Google Scholar]
- Hill, S. E., & Buss, D. M. (2010). Risk and relative social rank: Positional concerns and risky shifts in probabilistic decision-making. Evolution and Human Behavior, 31(3), 219–226. [Google Scholar]
- Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92(5), 1644–1655. [Google Scholar]
- Hopkins, E. (2018). Inequality and risk-taking behaviour. Games and Economic Behavior, 107, 316–328. [Google Scholar]
- Hounkpatin, H. O., Wood, A. M., & Brown, G. D. (2020). Comparing indices of relative deprivation using behavioural evidence. Social Science & Medicine, 259, 112914. [Google Scholar]
- Itskovich, E. (2024). Economic inequality, relative deprivation, and crime: An individual-level examination. Justice Quarterly, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. Farrar, Straus and Giroux. [Google Scholar]
- Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Keshavarz, S., Coventry, K. R., & Fleming, P. (2021). Relative deprivation and hope: Predictors of risk behavior. Journal of Gambling Studies, 37, 817–835. [Google Scholar]
- Kim, H., Callan, M. J., Gheorghiu, A. I., & Matthews, W. J. (2017). Social comparison, personal relative deprivation, and materialism. British Journal of Social Psychology, 56(2), 373–392. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kimball, M. S., Sahm, C. R., & Shapiro, M. D. (2008). Imputing risk tolerance from survey responses. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 103(483), 1028–1038. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
- Kőszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2006). A model of reference-dependent preferences. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), 1133–1165. [Google Scholar]
- Kőszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2007). Reference-dependent risk attitudes. American Economic Review, 97(4), 1047–1073. [Google Scholar]
- Kőszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2009). Reference-dependent consumption plans. American Economic Review, 99(3), 909–936. [Google Scholar]
- Kuhn, P., Kooreman, P., Soetevent, A., & Kapteyn, A. (2011). The effects of lottery prizes on winners and their neighbors: Evidence from the Dutch postcode lottery. American Economic Review, 101(5), 2226–2247. [Google Scholar]
- Linde, J., & Sonnemans, J. (2012). Social comparison and risky choices. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 44, 45–72. [Google Scholar]
- Lindskog, A., Martinsson, P., & Medhin, H. (2022). Risk-taking and others: Does the social reference point matter? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 64(3), 287–307. [Google Scholar]
- Long, J. S. (1997). Regression models for categorical and limited dependent variables. Sage. [Google Scholar]
- Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (1986). Disappointment and dynamic consistency in choice under uncertainty. The Review of Economic Studies, 53(2), 271–282. [Google Scholar]
- Lyu, S., & Sun, J. (2020). How does personal relative deprivation affect mental health among the older adults in China? Evidence from panel data analysis. Journal of Affective Disorders, 277, 612–619. [Google Scholar]
- Malmendier, U., & Nagel, S. (2011). Depression babies: Do macroeconomic experiences affect risk taking? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(1), 373–416. [Google Scholar]
- Mishra, S., Barclay, P., & Lalumière, M. L. (2014). Competitive disadvantage facilitates risk taking. Evolution and Human Behavior, 35(2), 126–132. [Google Scholar]
- Mishra, S., Hing, L. S. S., & Lalumière, M. L. (2015). Inequality and risk-taking. Evolutionary Psychology, 13(3), 1–11. [Google Scholar]
- Mishra, S., & Novakowski, D. (2016). Personal relative deprivation and risk: An examination of individual differences in personality, attitudes, and behavioral outcomes. Personality and Individual Differences, 90, 22–26. [Google Scholar]
- Müller, S., & Rau, H. A. (2019). Decisions under uncertainty in social contexts. Games and Economic Behavior, 116, 73–95. [Google Scholar]
- Odean, T. (1998). Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? The Journal of Finance, 53(5), 1775–1798. [Google Scholar]
- Pak, T. Y. (2023). Relative deprivation and financial risk taking. Finance Research Letters, 55, 103927. [Google Scholar]
- Pak, T. Y., & Choung, Y. (2020). Relative deprivation and suicide risk in South Korea. Social Science & Medicine, 247, 112815. [Google Scholar]
- Payne, B. K., Brown-Iannuzzi, J. L., & Hannay, J. W. (2017). Economic inequality increases risk taking. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 114(18), 4643–4648. [Google Scholar]
- Pickard, H., Dohmen, T., & Van Landeghem, B. (2024). Inequality and risk preference. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 69(2), 191–217. [Google Scholar]
- Runciman, W. G. (1966). Relative deprivation and social justice: A study of attitudes to social inequality in twentieth-century England. University of California Press. [Google Scholar]
- Schildberg-Hörisch, H. (2018). Are risk preferences stable? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(2), 135–154. [Google Scholar]
- Schmidt, U., Friedl, A., Eichenseer, M., & de Miranda, K. L. (2021). Social comparison and gender differences in financial risk taking. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 192, 58–72. [Google Scholar]
- Schmidt, U., Neyse, L., & Aleknonyte, M. (2019). Income inequality and risk taking: The impact of social comparison information. Theory and Decision, 87, 283–297. [Google Scholar]
- Schwerter, F. (2024). Social reference points and risk taking. Management Science, 70(1), 616–632. [Google Scholar]
- Sheehy-Skeffington, J. (2019). Social psychology of inequality. In J. Jetten, & K. Peters (Eds.), Social psychology of inequality (pp. 237–258). Springer. [Google Scholar]
- Smith, H. J., & Pettigrew, T. F. (2015). Advances in relative deprivation theory and research. Social Justice Research, 28, 1–6. [Google Scholar]
- Smith, H. J., Pettigrew, T. F., Pippin, G. M., & Bialosiewicz, S. (2012). Relative deprivation: A theoretical and meta-analytic review. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 16(3), 203–232. [Google Scholar]
- Stansbury, A., Kirkegaard, J. F., & Dynan, K. (2023). Gender gaps in South Korea’s labour market: Children explain most of the gender employment gap, but little of the gender wage gap. Applied Economics Letters, 31, 1726–1731. [Google Scholar]
- Tabri, N., Dupuis, D. R., Kim, H. S., & Wohl, M. J. (2015). Economic mobility moderates the effect of relative deprivation on financial gambling motives and disordered gambling. International Gambling Studies, 15(2), 309–323. [Google Scholar]
- Thaler, R. H., & Johnson, E. J. (1990). Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: The effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Management Science, 36(6), 643–660. [Google Scholar]
- Zhang, L., Qiao, L., Xu, M., Che, X., Diao, L., Yuan, S., Du, X., & Yang, D. (2019). Role of personal relative deprivation in promoting working memory capacity for neutral social information: Facial expressions and body motions. Personality and Individual Differences, 150, 109464. [Google Scholar]
Downside Risk of Risky Job | |||
---|---|---|---|
Accepted | Rejected | Proportion of Subjects | Range of Relative Risk Aversion |
3/4 | none | 0.14 | r < 0.31 |
1/2 | 3/4 | 0.11 | 0.31 < r < 1.00 |
1/3 | 1/2 | 0.15 | 1.00 < r < 2.00 |
1/5 | 1/3 | 0.14 | 2.00 < r < 3.76 |
1/10 | 1/5 | 0.15 | 3.76 < r < 7.53 |
none | 1/10 | 0.31 | r > 7.53 |
Decision | Option A | Option B | E(A)–E(B) |
---|---|---|---|
1 | $2.00 if the die is 1–3 $1.60 if the die is 4–10 | $3.85 if the die is 1–3 $0.10 if the die is 4–10 | $0.50 |
2 | $2.00 if the die is 1–4 $1.60 if the die is 5–10 | $3.85 if the die is 1–4 $0.10 if the die is 5–10 | $0.16 |
3 | $2.00 if the die is 1–5 $1.60 if the die is 6–10 | $3.85 if the die is 1–5 $0.10 if the die is 6–10 | −$0.18 |
4 | $2.00 if the die is 1–6 $1.60 if the die is 7–10 | $3.85 if the die is 1–6 $0.10 if the die is 7–10 | −$0.51 |
5 | $2.00 if the die is 1–7 $1.60 if the die is 8–10 | $3.85 if the die is 1–7 $0.10 if the die is 8–10 | −$0.85 |
6 | $2.00 if the die is 1–8 $1.60 if the die is 9–10 | $3.85 if the die is 1–8 $0.10 if the die is 9–10 | −$1.18 |
No. of Safe Choices | Proportion of Subjects | Range of Relative Risk Aversion |
---|---|---|
0 | 0.11 | r < −0.49 |
1 | 0.05 | −0.49 < r < −0.15 |
2 | 0.10 | −0.15 < r < 0.15 |
3 | 0.09 | 0.15 < r < 0.41 |
4 | 0.15 | 0.41 < r < 0.68 |
5 | 0.13 | 0.68 < r < 0.97 |
6 | 0.37 | 0.97 < r |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Outcome: | Risk Aversion | Perceived Social Status | Personal Deservingness | Anxiety |
Study 1: | ||||
RD | −0.342 | −0.594 *** | 0.434 *** | 0.219 *** |
(0.436) | (0.168) | (0.072) | (0.058) | |
Study 2: | ||||
RD | −0.210 *** | −0.453 *** | 0.359 *** | 0.152 *** |
(0.079) | (0.169) | (0.072) | (0.052) |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Outcome: | Risk Aversion | Risk Aversion | Risk Aversion | Risk Aversion |
Men (N = 286) | Women (N = 276) | Men (N = 298) | Women (N = 286) | |
Study 1: | ||||
RD | −0.563 | −0.250 | ||
(0.564) | (0.682) | |||
Study 2: | ||||
RD | −0.307 *** | −0.094 | ||
(0.111) | (0.112) |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2025 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Pak, T.-Y. Relative Deprivation: How Subjective Experiences of Income Inequality Influence Risk Preferences. Behav. Sci. 2025, 15, 425. https://doi.org/10.3390/bs15040425
Pak T-Y. Relative Deprivation: How Subjective Experiences of Income Inequality Influence Risk Preferences. Behavioral Sciences. 2025; 15(4):425. https://doi.org/10.3390/bs15040425
Chicago/Turabian StylePak, Tae-Young. 2025. "Relative Deprivation: How Subjective Experiences of Income Inequality Influence Risk Preferences" Behavioral Sciences 15, no. 4: 425. https://doi.org/10.3390/bs15040425
APA StylePak, T.-Y. (2025). Relative Deprivation: How Subjective Experiences of Income Inequality Influence Risk Preferences. Behavioral Sciences, 15(4), 425. https://doi.org/10.3390/bs15040425