Organized Land Transfer and Improvement in Agricultural Land Allocation Efficiency: Effects and Mechanisms
Abstract
1. Introduction
2. Theoretical Basis and Research Hypothesis
3. Model, Data, and Variable Measurement
3.1. Data Source
3.2. Variables
3.3. Estimation Strategy
3.3.1. Baseline Model: The Impact of Organized Land Transfer on Allocation Efficiency
3.3.2. Mechanism of Organized Land Transfer on Allocation Efficiency of Agricultural Land Resources
4. Econometric Results
4.1. The Impact of Organized Land Transfer on the Allocation Efficiency of Agricultural Land Recourse
4.2. Endogeneity Treatment and Robustness Checks
4.2.1. Endogeneity Treatment: IV
4.2.2. Robustness Check I: An Alternative Specification of the Independent Variable
4.2.3. Robustness Check II: Evidence from Household-Level
4.3. Mechanism Tests
4.3.1. Mechanism I: Enhancing Transfer Stability
4.3.2. Mechanism II: Expanding Transfer Scale
4.3.3. Mechanism III: Broadening Transfer Scope
4.4. Further Analysis
4.4.1. Organized Land Transfer, Collective Economy, and Allocation Efficiency of Agricultural Land Resources
4.4.2. Organized Land Transfer, Lineage Networks, and Allocation Efficiency of Agricultural Land Resources
5. Equity Effect: Organized Land Transfer and Willingness to Transfer
6. Discussion
6.1. Main Findings
6.2. Limitations and Future Directions
7. Conclusions
- (1)
- Promoting and standardizing organized land transfer to enhance efficiency. Given the demonstrated efficacy, organized land transfer should be actively supported. Central and provincial governments should encourage local governments and village collectives to serve as intermediaries. Specifically, higher-level governments should invest in strengthening the institutional capacity of rural land transaction platforms, providing dedicated funding for their operation, maintenance, and technological upgrades. At the local level, village collectives should leverage these platforms to offer professional services, such as market information and price assessments, and use policy advocacy and demonstration projects to guide farmer participation. To incentivize these grassroots efforts, the central government should establish targeted subsidies for organizational costs and link successful transfer outcomes to eligibility for other development projects, creating a synergistic policy environment for standardized and efficient land markets.
- (2)
- Safeguarding farmers’ rights and ensuring procedural fairness. To mitigate the risk of coercion and protect farmers’ autonomy, a robust regulatory and supervisory framework is essential. Higher-level governments must issue clear policy guidelines that define the functional boundaries of village collectives, restricting their role to facilitative services like information provision. All forms of coercion, whether overt (e.g., forced transfers) or disguised (e.g., undue intervention), must be strictly prohibited. Particular vigilance is required to prevent rent-seeking behaviors arising from collusion between village officials and commercial capital. To enforce this, a multi-stakeholder oversight mechanism—incorporating farmer participation, transparent reporting of village affairs, and higher-level government supervision—should be established, complemented by accessible channels for farmers to report grievances and protect their rights.
- (3)
- Implementing targeted protections for vulnerable groups. The inequitable impacts of organized land transfer on low-income and elderly farmers demand differentiated policy responses. It is recommended that tailored protection measures be implemented. First, for households unwilling to participate, establish land-exchange schemes that allow them to swap their plots for land of equivalent quality and area in a more suitable location, with financial compensation where necessary. This respects their choice while still facilitating contiguous land consolidation. Second, for households exiting agriculture, focus on ensuring their sustainable livelihoods. This includes providing vocational training to facilitate their transition into non-agricultural employment and implementing social support programs, such as “work-for-relief” to bolster their income and reduce their economic dependency on land.
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Deininger, K.; Savastano, S.; Carletto, C. Land fragmentation, cropland abandonment, and land market operation in Albania. World Dev. 2012, 40, 2108–2122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huy, H.T.; Lyne, M.; Ratna, N.; Nuthall, P. Drivers of transaction costs affecting participation in the rental market for cropland in Vietnam. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 2016, 60, 476–492. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Carter, M.R.; Yao, Y. Local versus Global Separability in Agricultural Household Models: The Factor Price Equalization Effect of Land Transfer Rights. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2002, 84, 702–715. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Deininger, K.; Jin, S. Securing property rights in transition: Lessons from implementation of China’s rural land contracting law. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2009, 70, 22–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feng, S.; Heerink, N.; Ruben, R.; Qu, F. Land rental market, off-farm employment and agricultural production in southeast China: A plot-level case study. China Econ. Rev. 2010, 21, 598–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, X.; Heerink, N.; Feng, S.Y.; Shi, X.P. Farmland Tenure in China: Comparing Legal, Actual and Perceived security. Land Use Policy 2015, 42, 293–306. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chari, A.; Liu, E.M.; Wang, S.Y.; Wang, Y.X. Property Rights, Land Misallocation, and Agricultural Efficiency in China. Rev. Econ. Stud. 2021, 88, 1831–1862. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gai, Q.E.; Chen, M.W.; Zhu, X.; Shi, Q.H. Can Land Rent Improve Land Allocation’s Efficiency? Evidence from National Fixed Point Survey. China Econ. Q. 2020, 20, 321–340. [Google Scholar]
- Shi, C.L.; Zhan, P.; Zhu, J.F. Land Transfer, Factor Allocation and Agricultural Production Efficiency Improvement. China Land Sci. 2020, 34, 49–57. [Google Scholar]
- Tang, P.; Chen, J.; Gao, J.L.; Li, M.; Wang, J.S. What Role(s) Do Village Committees Play in the Withdrawal from Rural Homesteads? Evidence from Sichuan Province in Western China. Land 2020, 9, 477. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shi, X.P.; Chen, S.J.; Ma, X.L.; Lan, J. Heterogeneity in interventions in village committee and farmland circulation: Intermediary versus regulatory effects. Land Use Policy 2018, 74, 291–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Qiu, T.W.; Shi, X.J.; Luo, B.L. Formalizing agricultural rentals in China: Does local public action help? Dev. Policy Rev. 2022, 40, e12592. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, X.Y.; Ito, J. An empirical study of land rental development in rural Gansu, China: The role of agricultural cooperatives and transaction costs. Land Use Policy 2021, 109, 105621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huang, Z.H.; Qiu, J.M. Government Intervention in Land Circulation and Concentration: Conditions, Strategy and Risks—A Research based on Land Circulation and Concentration. China Rural Surv. 2016, 2, 34–44+95. [Google Scholar]
- Wang, X.Q.; Cao, T.Y.; Zou, W. Impact of local governments’ intervention in farmland circulation on agricultural production efficiency: Based on the analysis of rice grower. China Popul. Resour. Environ. 2018, 28, 133–141. [Google Scholar]
- Ruan, J.; Zhang, Z.X. Farmland Organized Rental and Improvement in Agricultural Production Efficiency: Effect and Mechanism. China Land Sci. 2023, 37, 47–56. [Google Scholar]
- Zhai, L.M.; Xia, X.L.; Wu, A.D. The Effects of Government Behavior in Land Transfer on Farmers’ Livelihood Capital: An Empirical Analysis Based on Differences-in-Differences Propensity Score Matching Approaches. Chin. Rural Econ. 2017, 2, 2–15. [Google Scholar]
- Zhang, J.; Feng, S.Y.; Chu, P.X. Does Government Intervention on Farmland Rental Market Lead to Rural Income Inequality? J. Public Manag. 2017, 14, 104–116+158–159. [Google Scholar]
- Coase, R.H. The Problem of Social Cost. J. Law Econ. 1960, 3, 1–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Williamson, O.E. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting; Free Press: New York, NY, USA, 1985. [Google Scholar]
- Rao, F.P.; Spoor, M.; Ma, X.L.; Shi, X.P. Perceived land tenure security in rural Xinjiang, China: The role of official land documents and trust. China Econ. Rev. 2017, 60, 101038. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- North, D.C. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Coase, R.H. The nature of the firm. Economica 1937, 4, 386–405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Besley, T. Property rights and investment incentives: Theory and evidence from Ghana. J. Political Econ. 1995, 103, 903–937. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Paul, C.; Nehring, R.; Banker, D.; Somwaru, A. Scale Economies and Efficiency in U.S. Agriculture: Are Traditional Farms History? J. Product. Anal. 2004, 22, 185–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hornbeck, R.; Naidu, S. When the Levee Breaks: Black Migration and Economic Development in the American South. Am. Econ. Rev. 2014, 104, 963–990. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, J.; Mishra, A.K.; Zhu, P.X. Land rental markets and labor productivity: Evidence from rural China. Can. J. Agric. Econ. 2020, 69, 93–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tang, L.; Ma, X.; Zhou, Y.; Shi, X.; Ma, J. Social Relations, Public Interventions and Land Rent Deviation: Evidence from Jiangsu Province in China. Land Use Policy 2019, 86, 406–420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yang, J.; Huang, Z.; Zhang, X.; Reardon, T. The rapid rise of cross-regional agricultural mechanization services in China. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2013, 95, 1245–1251. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Deininger, K.; Jin, S.; Xia, F. Moving off the farm: Land institutions to facilitate structural transformation and agricultural productivity growth in China. World Dev. 2014, 59, 505–520. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, Z.; Xin, X. Can Cross-village Land Transfer Achieve Grain Productivity Growth? An Empirical Analysis Based on Rural Household Survey Data from Fifteen Provinces. China Rural Surv. 2022, 2, 2–18. [Google Scholar]
- Zheng, H.Y.; Ma, W.L. The Role of Resource Reallocation in Promoting Total Factor Productivity Growth: Insights from China’s Agricultural Sector. Rev. Dev. Econ. 2021, 25, 2350–2371. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xu, Q.; Rao, Q.L.; Zhang, K. Centralized Circulation and Farmland Rent: Effects and Mechanisms. Chin. Rural. Econ. 2024, 7, 35–54. [Google Scholar]
- Ostrom, E. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Crookes, T.J.; Lyne, M.C. Efficiency and equity gains in the rental market for arable land: Observations from a communal area of KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa. Dev. S. Afr. 2003, 20, 579–593. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barzel, Y. Economic Analysis of Property Rights, 2nd ed.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Hayami, Y.; Ruttan, V.W. Agricultural Development: An International Perspective; Johns Hopkins University Press: Baltimore, MD, USA, 1985. [Google Scholar]
- Zhang, L.; Wang, Y.H. How Does Village Collective Economy Affect Village Collective Action? Evidence from Farmers’ Participation in the Provision of Rural Irrigation Facilities. Chin. Rural Econ. 2021, 7, 44–64. [Google Scholar]
- Zhou, T.; Luo, Z.; Zhang, X. How do China’s villages self-organize collective land use under the background of rural revitalization? A multi-case study in Zhejiang, Fujian and Guizhou provinces. Growth Change 2023, 54, 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Variables | Variable Definition | Mean | S.D. |
---|---|---|---|
The dependent variable | |||
The allocation efficiency of agricultural land resources | OP covariance between the per-mu output and the operational area proportion of sampled households in the village | 50.81 | 127.3 |
The independent variable | |||
Organized land transfer | Degree of organized land transfer in the village (%) | 56.87 | 39.34 |
Instrumental Variable (IV) | |||
Village governance capacity | Degree of farmer participation in rural public affairs (%) | 59.50 | 26.23 |
Mechanism variables | |||
Formalization of transfer | 1 if a written contract was signed, 0 otherwise | 0.725 | 0.447 |
Transfer duration | Duration of transfer (years) | 8.217 | 4.637 |
Land management area | Operational area post-land transfer for incoming renters (mu) | 258.5 | 380.7 |
Land operational concentration | Proportion of the maximum plot area to total operational area (%) | 0.505 | 0.290 |
Cross-village transfer | 1 if the tenant is an external, 0 otherwise | 0.163 | 0.370 |
Control variables | |||
Non-agricultural employment | The proportion of employment outside the county within the village (%) | 43.64 | 25.15 |
Gig market | Proportion of gig workers within the village (%) | 24.73 | 22.62 |
Geographical location | Distance to the nearest township from the village (KM) | 22.23 | 11.87 |
Village types | 1 if the village is a suburban village, 0 otherwise | 0.250 | 0.436 |
Fragmentation degree of contracted farmland | Average number of land parcels per household | 3.943 | 4.036 |
Land consolidation | 1 if the village has implemented land consolidation, 0 otherwise | 0.569 | 0.499 |
Village governance structure | 1 if the village party secretary and village committee director are the same person, 0 otherwise | 0.958 | 0.201 |
Village collective economy | Village collective economy (CNY) (natural logarithm) | 4.716 | 1.176 |
Village income per capita | Income per capita at the village level (CNY) (natural logarithm) | 9.973 | 0.464 |
Village lineage networks | Proportion of households with the most common surname in the village (%) | 24.24 | 16.23 |
Southern Jiangsu | Dummy variable for Southern Jiangsu (1 if located in Southern Jiangsu, 0 otherwise) | 0.250 | 0.436 |
Northern Jiangsu | Dummy variable for Northern Jiangsu (1 if located in Northern Jiangsu, 0 otherwise) | 0.500 | 0.504 |
Central Jiangsu | Dummy variable for Central Jiangsu (1 if located in Central Jiangsu, 0 otherwise) | 0.250 | 0.436 |
(1) | (2) | (3) | |
---|---|---|---|
COV | COV | COV | |
Organized land transfer | 0.980 *** | 0.812 ** | 0.910 ** |
(0.369) | (0.379) | (0.419) | |
Non-agricultural employment | −0.614 | −0.384 | |
(0.407) | (0.372) | ||
Gig market | −0.160 | 0.068 | |
(0.524) | (0.537) | ||
Geographical location | 0.972 | 1.246 * | |
(0.748) | (0.723) | ||
Village types | 39.845 | 46.283 | |
(39.009) | (41.792) | ||
Village governance structure | −15.061 | −22.227 * | |
(18.770) | (12.878) | ||
Land consolidation | −27.860 | −43.757 | |
(43.114) | (52.351) | ||
Fragmentation degree of contracted farmland | 0.894 | 1.237 | |
(1.707) | (1.580) | ||
Village income per capita | −28.612 | −52.462 | |
(38.972) | (47.494) | ||
Village collective economy | 43.152 | 22.096 | |
(32.228) | (24.909) | ||
Village lineage networks | −0.552 | −0.424 | |
(0.652) | (0.525) | ||
Region effects | NO | NO | YES |
Constant | −4.914 | 125.804 | 406.876 |
(25.434) | (298.457) | (391.302) | |
Observations | 72 | 72 | 72 |
R2 | 0.092 | 0.279 | 0.325 |
IV | Robustness Check I | Robustness Check II | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
Organized Land Transfer | COV | COV | Profit per Mu (PPM) | |
Organized land transfer | 0.553 * | 0.596 ** | 159.793 *** | |
(0.330) | (0.283) | (55.253) | ||
Village governance capacity | 0.928 *** | |||
(0.419) | ||||
Control variables | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Regional effects | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Constant | −176.669 | 305.163 | 65.832 | 970.441 |
(120.350) | (315.635) | (283.722) | (859.796) | |
F-value of 1st stage | 26.02 | |||
Observations | 72 | 72 | 72 | 499 |
R2 | 0.315 | 0.280 | 0.209 |
Transfer Stability | Transfer Scale | Transfer Scope | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
Formalization of Transfer | Transfer Duration | Land Management Area | Land Operational Concentration | Cross-Village Land Transfer | |
Organized land transfer | 3.505 *** | 1.477 *** | 162.840 *** | 0.064 * | 1.565 *** |
(0.674) | (0.479) | (30.472) | (0.036) | (0.474) | |
Control variables | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Regional effects | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Constant | −9.672 | 2.924 | 0.674 | −1049.151 * | −19.878 *** |
(7.328) | (6.469) | (0.626) | (570.997) | (7.654) | |
Observations | 499 | 499 | 499 | 300 | 300 |
R2 | 0.151 | 0.292 | 0.062 |
(1) | (2) | |
---|---|---|
COV | COV | |
Organized land transfer | 0.784 ** | 0.830 ** |
(0.338) | (0.372) | |
Collective economic | 17.623 | |
(22.423) | ||
Organized land transfer * Collective economic | 0.803 * | |
(0.446) | ||
Lineage networks | −0.316 | |
(0.450) | ||
Organized land transfer * Lineage networks | −0.030 * | |
(0.015) | ||
Control variables | YES | YES |
Region effects | YES | YES |
Constant | 531.649 | 323.369 |
(456.160) | (339.858) | |
Observations | 72 | 72 |
R2 | 0.398 | 0.314 |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Willing | High Income | Low Income | Elderly | Young | |
Willing | Willing | ||||
Organized land transfer | −0.224 *** | −0.110 *** | −0.352 *** | −0.261 *** | −0.175 *** |
(0.026) | (0.029) | (0.046) | (0.043) | (0.033) | |
Control variables | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Region effects | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Constant | 2.649 *** | 1.823 *** | 3.230 *** | 2.474 *** | 1.111 * |
(0.257) | (0.552) | (0.436) | (0.442) | (0.566) | |
Observations | 1095 | 599 | 496 | 469 | 626 |
R2 | 0.098 | 0.069 | 0.140 | 0.160 | 0.094 |
p-value of coefficient difference | - | 0.002 *** | 0.074 ** |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2025 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Kong, L.; Gao, M.; Ji, Y. Organized Land Transfer and Improvement in Agricultural Land Allocation Efficiency: Effects and Mechanisms. Land 2025, 14, 1640. https://doi.org/10.3390/land14081640
Kong L, Gao M, Ji Y. Organized Land Transfer and Improvement in Agricultural Land Allocation Efficiency: Effects and Mechanisms. Land. 2025; 14(8):1640. https://doi.org/10.3390/land14081640
Chicago/Turabian StyleKong, Liping, Mengfei Gao, and Yueqing Ji. 2025. "Organized Land Transfer and Improvement in Agricultural Land Allocation Efficiency: Effects and Mechanisms" Land 14, no. 8: 1640. https://doi.org/10.3390/land14081640
APA StyleKong, L., Gao, M., & Ji, Y. (2025). Organized Land Transfer and Improvement in Agricultural Land Allocation Efficiency: Effects and Mechanisms. Land, 14(8), 1640. https://doi.org/10.3390/land14081640