Next Article in Journal
Optimal Decision Rules in Repeated Games Where Players Infer an Opponent’s Mind via Simplified Belief Calculation
Next Article in Special Issue
Space Debris Removal: A Game Theoretic Analysis
Previous Article in Journal
Vertical Relationships within Platform Marketplaces
Previous Article in Special Issue
Keeping Pace with Criminals: An Extended Study of Designing Patrol Allocation against Adaptive Opportunistic Criminals
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Sharing the Costs of Complex Water Projects: Application to the West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project, Egypt

1
CNRS UMR7243 and Laboratoire d’Analyse et Modélisation de Systèmes pour l’Aide à la Décision (LAMSADE), Paris-Dauphine University, Paris 75775, France
2
University of Genoa, Genoa 16126, Italy
3
School of Public Policy, University of California, Riverside, CA 92506, USA
4
National Research Center, Cairo 12622, Egypt
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Games 2016, 7(3), 18; https://doi.org/10.3390/g7030018
Submission received: 23 February 2016 / Revised: 17 June 2016 / Accepted: 4 July 2016 / Published: 15 July 2016
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Real World Applications of Game Theory)

Abstract

:
Effective sharing mechanisms of joint costs among beneficiaries of a project are a fundamental requirement for the sustainability of the project. Projects that are heterogeneous both in terms of the landscape of the area under development or the participants (users) lead to a more complicated set of allocation mechanisms than homogeneous projects. The analysis presented in this paper uses cooperative game theory to develop schemes for sharing costs and revenues from a project involving various beneficiaries in an equitable and fair way. The proposed approach is applied to the West Delta irrigation project. It sketches a differential two-part tariff that reproduces the allocation of total project costs using the Shapley Value, a well-known cooperative game allocation solution. The proposed differential tariff, applied to each land section in the project reflecting their landscape-related costs, contrasts the unified tariff that was proposed using the traditional methods in the project planning documents.

1. Introduction

Cost allocation is the process of dividing the costs of a multi-purpose or a multi-agent project among the various project purposes or beneficiaries. Criteria and principles used for cost allocation are decided at the planning phase of the project and can lead to a situation where some of the beneficiaries are unsatisfied and thus the project may fail. Some of the cost allocation schemes are based on simple rules, proportional to a single parameter, which can lead to allocation solutions that are not acceptable by all participants. This is especially true when the affordability of beneficiaries to share the cost widely varies, or when beneficiaries face different conditions affecting their ability to benefit from the project. This paper demonstrates the application of Cooperative Game Theory (CGT) to an irrigation project that has been considered for implementation in the West of the Nile Delta in Egypt.
The main issues to which CGT tries to address are agreements to allocate joint gains, using solution concepts. Solution concepts are rules of allocation of gains from cooperation that the cooperating members of a given group can share. The number of allocation solution concepts is quite large, due also to the diversity of the problems that CGT can address. A review of the literature of CGT cost and benefit allocations in water projects can be found in [1]. Among the most known solutions are: the Core, the Shapley Value [2], and the nucleolus [3]. For a general introduction to game theory and in particular to cooperative games see [4,5,6]. The Shapley value, in particular, has been successively used as a cost allocation method in many applications (see, for instance, the survey [7]), including the management of environmental resources (e.g., see [8]).
In most of its solution approaches, CGT ignores the strategic stages leading to coalition building and focuses on the possible results of cooperation. CGT attempts to answer questions such as which coalitions can be formed? How can the coalitional gains be divided in order to secure a sustainable agreement? Often, for joint projects, the optimal way to maximize the gains (revenues minus costs, or cost savings) is to build a facility (for example) that involves all of the interested players. Thus, in CGT, the solutions that include all possible players (Grand Coalition) are prominent, and thus most CGT solution concepts refer to a way of allocating among players the gains achieved by the Grand Coalition. As such, CGT is a good framework for allocation of joint costs or benefits among participants in a project.
An important aspect associated with the solution concepts of CGT is the equitable and fair sharing of the cooperative gains. One can refer to equity in a comprehensive framework, that is, social justice—a proper distribution of resources, welfare, rights, duties, opportunities, or in our case the costs of an investment and of Operations and Maintenance (O&M) of a project. There have been many applications of CGT to allocation issues in water projects, including the publication [9]. In most, if not all previous works, simplifications of the allocation problem have been introduced, which made the application less operational.
In this paper, we introduce an application of cooperative game theory to a cost allocation problem arising from a complex water project in Egypt, taking into account differences in the regional landscape of land sectors (sectors) of the project area that affect the benefits that can be accrued by water users in each of the project land sectors. We demonstrate the challenges faced during the application of cooperative game theory concepts and how they are addressed. The analysis produces a differential two-part tariff that differs by the project land sectors, in contrast to the unified tariff that was recommended by the traditional methods used by the planners.
We start in the next section with some basic definitions and notations on cooperative games. Section 3 is devoted to the description of the analytical framework related to the West Delta Project (WDP). In Section 4, we introduce and discuss the data and the procedures used to evaluate the relevant costs and the revenues under two different scenarios of water supply, namely, alternative A0 and A2. In Section 5 and Section 6, we describe how we computed the (cost and revenues) cooperative games associated with scenarios A2 and A0, respectively. The cooperative games defined in Section 5 and Section 6 are compared and discussed in Section 7, together with the analysis of the associated cost allocation problem. Section 8 concludes this paper.

2. Preliminaries and Notations

A cooperative cost game (or, simply, a cost game) on a finite set N = { 1 , , n } of players is a pair ( N , c ) where the characteristic function c is a map c : 2 N assigning to each coalition S N a real value c ( S ) representing the cost of coalition S, and with c ( ) = 0 . A cost game ( N , c ) is subadditive if c ( S T ) c ( S ) + c ( T ) for all S , T N such that S T = .
Given a cost game ( N , c ) , an imputation is a vector x N such that i N x i = c ( N ) and x i c ( { i } ) for each i N . An imputation is in the core of the cost game ( N , c ) if i S x i c ( S ) for all S N .
A very well studied solution from the literature of cooperative games is the Shapley value (Shapley 1953, [2]), which is defined for every cost game ( N , c ) as follows:
S h i ( c ) = S 2 N \ { i } s ! ( n s 1 ) ! n ! m i ( S ) ,
where s is the cardinality of a coalition S and m i ( S ) = c ( S { i } ) c ( S ) is the marginal contribution of i to S , for each i N and S 2 N \ { i } . Thus, S h i ( c ) is the expected marginal contribution of player i N in the cost game ( N , c ) over all possible coalitions not containing i and assuming that the probability to enter in a coalition of size s is equal to s ! ( n s 1 ) ! n ! . The Shapley value S h i ( c ) of a subadditive cost game ( N , c ) is an imputation of ( N , c ) , but S h i ( c ) is not necessarily in the core of ( N , c ) . A sufficient condition to have S h i ( c ) in the core of ( N , c ) is that ( N , c ) is submodular or concave, i.e., c ( S T ) + c ( S T ) c ( S ) + c ( T ) for all S , T N .

3. The Analytical Framework

As an example, tailored to the West Delta Project (WDP) scheme presented below, of a cooperative game, considers a three-player game, whose players are 1, 2, and 3 1. Each player faces a different physical situation that affects his performance (costs and benefits). Assume that the players want to build a system of irrigation infrastructure to be used by all of them for production. The presence of joint costs will require some way of attributing them to each player. One way of allocating joint costs is to apply approaches used in cooperative game theory. The idea is quite simple in principle. One has to find what would be the costs if the infrastructure would be built just for one player (singleton coalitions). Then do the same for each group of two players (partial coalitions), and finally, for the entire group (grand coalition) of the three players. In such a way one gets a string of numbers (costs), that we shall call c(1), c(2), c(3), c(1,2), c(1,3), c(2,3) and, of course, c(1,2,3) (the later is the cost of the project as appears in the project documents). This is a cooperative (cost) game, and one looks for “allocation solutions” to this game; namely, how to allocate the project cost among 1, 2, and 3. In general, a solution is assumed to be an imputation. That is, it will share exactly the total joint cost among the players, without attributing to anyone a cost higher than its “stand-alone” cost, c(i), i = 1, 2, 3 in our case. In our model, we will develop a cooperative cost game to see the feasibility and interest of all the players in the construction of the surface irrigation system. We use the Shapley Value to allocate the costs among the players.
While the project documents suggest a certain tariff to be charged to the players, we have investigated which would be the tariff (or the tariffs) proposed by the cooperative game theory analysis. We will develop a cooperative cost game to analyze the feasibility of different methods for sharing the costs for building the surface irrigation infrastructure, using the Shapley Value. We develop a cooperative cost game to see the feasibility and interest of all the players in the construction of the surface irrigation system. Finally, based on the cooperative game, we find out which operational two-part tariff for surface water could be used to reproduce the fair solution (which is, in our case, the Shapley Value). The challenge, of course, is the setting of various characteristic functions, which is the focus of this paper.

3.1. Features of the West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project

The West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project (WDP) was a unique attempt of the Government of Egypt to prevent the environmental degradation of the flourishing West Delta region. The massive agriculture development of the region (about 107,000 ha) led to depletion and salinization (seawater intrusion) of groundwater resources. The project is based on the premise that supplementing the groundwater in the region with imported Nile water to irrigate the existing land and even extending it, can be done in both an ecologically and financially sustainable way. An innovative component of the project was the inclusion of a for-profit private sector entrepreneurship that will fund the investment, manage the cost recovery, and operate the surface irrigation system according to specified rules of operation. Another innovative component was the introduction of full cost recovery and volumetric pricing. The Government of Egypt was supposed to provide guarantees to mitigate financial risks faced by the private entrepreneur from non-payments by farmers in the project. Eighty five percent of the cost of the first phase of the project (about 38,000 ha) was supposed to be funded by the World Bank ($145 million) and the French Development Agency (EUR 30 million). The other 15% of the first phase cost and the cost of the next phases had to be raised by the private operator. More information on the project and its closure can be found in [12].
The most critical question related to the project was how to design the cost recovery scheme that will fully cover all costs, will be acceptable to the various users (farmers), and at the same time will be attractive to a private investor. The reason for that can be seen in the map of the region below (Figure 1). The project area can be divided into three distinguished sectors: Central (player 1), Southern (player 2) and Northern (player 3). The three sectors differ in both their size of land holding, and in the (average) depth to water table (i.e., the depth at which the ground beneath the surface is saturated with water)2. Sectors’ size will affect the investment cost per unit of land due to economies of scale and pumping cost. Sectors’ depth to water table will affect the cost of pumping groundwater and, thus, the willingness to pay for imported surface Nile water (Table 1).
The cost3 per player will affect the profit level and, therefore, the willingness to participate in the project and contribute to the cost recovery, which is a fundamental condition for the risk a private investor may be willing to take.

3.2. The Empirical Framework

In this model we consider three players, each one is formed by a subset of land owned by farmers in various sectors of the project (Figure 1). We assume that all farmers in each sector, or sub-region, can be represented by one voice. Player 1, central region, consists of sectors {S01, S02, S03, S04, S05, S09}; player 2, southern region, consists of sectors {S06, S07, S08}; and player 3, northern region, consists of sectors {S11, S12, S13, S14, S15, S16}. This choice of sectors and sub-regions for the players is very close to the situation of Market and Demand Parameters (MDP) project option for alternative A24 (PPIAF, 2005 [14]). Therefore, our cost allocation game is based on three players/regions characterized by different size of land and depth to groundwater table as shown in Table 1 5.

4. Description of the Data and Procedures Used

This section describes the various types of costs and revenues that are considered under the two alternatives scenarios of water supply to the project: A0 and A2. All the data used in our analysis originated from several reports prepared by the World Bank [12,15] and several local and international consultants [13,14,16,17,18]. Since the project is funded mainly by the World Bank, it has to follow the World Bank procedures. As such, [13,14,16,17,18] are reports that prepared the project design and different assessments (e.g., irrigation efficiency, net benefits and their distribution across beneficiaries, soil and groundwater quality, environmental and social assessment, and public–private partnership performance and risk—the private sector had a major role in this project). The report [15] is the project appraisal report, which is based on the reports cited above and a series of discussions with the Government of Egypt. This report triggered the approval of the project and the initiation of the procedures in the project plan. The [12] report addresses the termination of the project.
Under both alternatives, investment costs for irrigation equipment are considered for a time period of 20 years, and running costs (O&M and labor) are considered on a per-year basis. Yearly revenues have been calculated on the basis of the cropping patterns derived from the farm survey results (Annex 1 and 3 in [13]). Net benefits are calculated, based on an optimal allocation of land use for irrigated crops in each sub-region [13]. When the net benefits from irrigated agriculture under Alternative A0 (business as usual) turn negative due to high level of salinity, the reference cropping pattern is replaced by a more salt tolerant (and less profitable) cropping pattern. This switch consists primarily on a different allocation of the area for crops (e.g., an increase in the area cultivated with grapes, which has been supposed to double after Year 13).
Under alternative A0, it has been evaluated that after 13 years from the first year of connection to surface water the loss in agricultural production in the Nile Delta would make it more profitable for farmers to leave the project area. Consequently, alternative A0 has been considered to produce revenues for only 13 years. The main assumptions, sources of data, etc. used in the financial part of the model, are presented in Annex 3 of the WDWCIARP Drainframe Analysis, Main Report [13]. The chosen time period is 13 years, starting from the first year of connection to surface water. This rather short timeframe has been chosen in order to provide consistent results for the different evaluated impacts. This is also the timeframe of the National Water Resources Plan (NWRP); therefore, we adopted a financial model with a similar time horizon. Extending the timeframe by 20–30 years would show even more clearly that the impacts on agricultural production under A0 are unsustainable.

4.1. Scenario A2

Scenario A2 considers no groundwater use. Thus the capacity of the conveyance system should be designed to meet the peak monthly surface water requirement of 222 million cubic meters in June, [14].
Under scenario A2, we have considered the investment costs categories reported in Table A1 in Appendix (from [13]) and the running cost (O&M) shown in Table A2 in the Appendix (based on [16]).
For alternative A2, a reference crop pattern is reported in Table 2. It consists of high value crops with a higher share of perennial trees (79%) and vegetables (21%). Under A2, where the surface irrigation system is designed in order to meet peak summer requirements, it is assumed that farmers will maintain the current cropping pattern.
For summer and winter vegetables, double cropping has been assumed in a six-month periods for both summer and winter crops under the reference cropping pattern only. Revenues from production of different cropping patterns are assumed to depend on the expected yields according to Mass-Hofman formula [19]. This means that under this alternative they depend on the average soil salinity under Nile water irrigation.

4.2. Scenario A0

Scenario A0 represents the case of continued dependence on ground water only (business as usual).
Under scenario A0, we have considered the investment costs categories shown in Table A3 in the Appendix (based on [16]) and the running cost categories reported in Table A4 in the Appendix (based on [16]).
Under scenario A0, the reference cropping pattern is assumed to be the same as in A2 (Table 2). For summer and winter vegetables, double cropping has been assumed in a six-month periods for both summer and winter crops of the reference cropping pattern only. It is also assumed in A0 that farmers will continue to grow the reference cropping pattern as long as the net benefits remain positive. More precisely, after Year 13, the model yields negative benefits and it is assumed that the (less sensitive to water salinity) cropping pattern shown in Table 2 is adopted. The switch consists primarily in a different allocation of the area for each crop (i.e., a relative increase in the area cultivated with grapes), while only in one case a particularly salt sensitive crop (pear) is replaced by a more tolerant one (maize). Moreover, we assume that at the Year 15, after the intense use of water during the previous years, the yield of the crop pattern in Table 2 would be at 80% of the saline non-stressed fields.
Revenues from production of the two different crops are assumed to depend on the expected yields [13], and hence ultimately on the expected behavior of groundwater salinity [16]. When the switch to cropping pattern in Table 2 occurs, we considered a single cropping for vegetables and a 20% of yield reduction with regards to the non-stress situation for the other products in Table 2 (grapes and other crops).

5. Assigning the Investment and Running Costs and the Revenues to the Various Coalitions in the Game under Alternative A2

We use the existing cost items provided by in the World Bank project document [15]. Our goal is to assign costs to each possible coalition, i.e., each possible sub-group of the three land sections. Since the project documents [15] were prepared to estimate the cost of implementation on the overall area (grand coalition consideration), we developed a methodology for assessing the costs for the intermediate coalitions. We used the cost data on investment and running cost items related to the project. For certain items the information is provided for the entire project, and for some items data is aggregated for land sectors and yet for some other cost items the data is provided for each individual sector (see Figure 1 and first paragraph of the Empirical Framework Section).
According to this information and assuming equal distribution of cost per hectare among all land blocks we used the available information to estimate the cost of coalitions in three different cost games as explained in more detail in the next section. The resulting cost allocations of investments and running costs per region (that were used below to create the cost per coalition) can be found in an excel file that is provided in the auxiliary dataset to this paper [‎9]. In the following, we describe how we estimated the amount of investment costs for each coalition of players.
Finally, in the last part of this section (namely, in Section 5.3), we introduce the procedure used to determine the revenues of each coalition under alternative A2 on the basis of the information provided in [14] and [13,16,17].

5.1. Evaluation of the Investment Costs under Alternative A2

To determine our cost game, we shall consider it as the sum of three games, cA2,1, cA2,2 and cA2,3. This decomposition into three different cost games is based on our ability to apportion the various costs from available data [20,21] to the various coalitions.
In game cA2,1, only the cost of the grand coalition {1,2,3} can be directly assessed. In game cA2,2, only the costs of coalitions {1,2},{3} and {1,2,3} can be assessed directly, and, in game cA2,3, the costs of all coalitions are assessed from the available data6. All three games are used in the calculation of the Shapley Value. We use all three games to produce the cost of all seven coalition-sections in the project area. Both cA2,1 and cA2,3 are additive cost games. cA2,1 is calculated starting from the value of the grand coalition (taken from the costs presented in [21]), and then proportionally allocated by the area of each sub-coalition (See footnote 6). cA2,3 is also additive but the cost items in this game are a priori assigned to the three section in the data taken from [15], so the cost of each larger coalition is computed additively based on these data. In the following discussions and tables, all costs have been considered in 106 LE (Egyptian Pounds)7.

5.1.1. Costs Items in Game cA2,1

Costs considered in game cA2,1 are the following (Table 3).

5.1.2. Cost Items in Game cA2,2

Costs considered in game cA2,2 are presented in Table 4.
The cost in Table 4 allow us to assess the total amount, for coalitions {1,2}, {3} and {1,2,3}, as cA2,2(1,2) = 599.941; cA2,2(3) = 176.796; and cA2,2(1,2,3) = cA2,2(1,2) + cA2,2(3) = 776.737, respectively.

5.1.3. Costs in Game cA2,3

Costs considered in game cA2,2 are presented in Table 5. All costs considered here concern components that can be directly attributed to each region in Figure 1. The resulting cost game is an additive game, that is, the cost for coalition S ⊆ {1, 2, 3} is equal to the sum of the individual costs for players in coalition S. Note that these kinds of costs correspond to those cost components of the project which can be directly allocated to each participant.
The resulting additive cost game ({1,2,3},cA2,3) is presented in Table 6.

5.1.4. Missing cost Estimation for Intermediate Coalitions

In Section 5.1.4.1 and Section 5.1.4.2, we present how we estimated the value of coalitions in games cA2,1 and cA2,2, whose costs were not possible to be evaluated from the data spreadsheet in the project documents [13,14,20].

5.1.4.1. Estimation of the Cost of Intermediate Coalitions in Game cA2,1

Costs of intermediate coalitions have been estimated in game cA2,1 proportionally to the area of the corresponding region covered by the coalition. For example, for coalition {1,2}, the cost assigned to such coalition has been estimated as the fraction (area of central and southern region)/(area of the entire region) of the total cost evaluated from the spreadsheet for the entire region c({1,2,3}). Of course the assumption of direct proportionality produces a rough approximation of the costs for each coalition, but it is needed to address the lack of information in the project documents.

5.1.4.2. Estimation of the Cost of Intermediate Coalitions in Game cA2,2

This case, which is directly assessable from the spreadsheet, is the cost for two distinct regions, region {1,2} and region {3}. The main characteristics affecting the value of these costs have been assumed to be the water intake that is assumed to be proportional to the dimension of the served area. A secondary variable, which has been assumed to affect the costs considered in this game is the average depth to water table of the served lands.
Therefore, we considered a model for cost estimation where costs are mainly function of the area of the served regions plus another term representing the interaction between the area and the average level of the regions served. In formula, we considered the model
C = b·F + a·F·H + K
where F is the size of the served area (Feddan), H is the average depth to water table of the served area (meter), a and b are coefficients, K is a fixed cost component, and C is the total cost for cost items presented in Table 4 and analyzed in game cA2,2. Note that the parameter F for a coalition S has been calculated as the sum of the area (in Feddan) of players in S, whereas the parameter H has been obtained as a weighted average of depth to water table for players in S. For example, if S = {1,2}, then F(S) = (141,600 + 48,400) = 190,000 Feddan and H(S) = (141,600 × 85 + 48,400 × 110)/(141,600 + 48,400) = 91.37 m.
Fitting the model in Equation (2) to data presented in Section 5.1.2, the resulting optimal coefficients are a = 0.002, b = 9.43844 × 106 and K = 0 and the corresponding costs for game cA2,2 are shown in Table 7.

5.1.5. Total Investment Costs Game under Alternative A2

Summing up, the cost games related to the investment costs under alternative A2 are shown in Table 8 (costs in 106 LE), where ({1,2,3},cA2(S)) is the total investment cost game under alternative A2.
The game cA2(S)/20 is the amount of investment cost that should be supported each year by the corresponding coalitions under alternative A2, in an ideal situation where the principal amount can be amortized over 20 years.
Next, we consider a situation with a more accurate estimation of the effects of time on the cash flows.

5.2. Evaluation of Running Costs under Alternative A2

Running costs (O&M) are costs that farmers should support every year for operating and maintaining all the agriculture procedures. Similar to what was observed for investment cost, we observed three different kind of running cost games, the games rA2,1, rA2,2 and rA2,3, again different from each other by the possibility to assess the cost of each coalition of players directly from data presented in [20]. In game rA2,1, only the cost of the grand coalition {1,2,3} is directly assessed. In game rA2,2, only the costs of the coalitions {1,2},{3} and {1,2,3} are directly assessed and, in game rA2,3, the costs of all the coalitions are assessed, from direct attribution of costs presented for the regions depicted in Figure 1.

5.2.1. Costs in Game rA2,1

Costs considered in game rA2,1 are the following (Table 9).
For costs in Table 9 it is possible to assess the total amount, for the grand coalition, that is rA2,1 = 60.691.

5.2.2. Costs in Game rA2,2

Costs considered in game rA2,2 are the following.
For costs in Table 10 it is possible to assess the total amount for coalitions {1,2}, {3} and {1,2,3}, precisely as rA2,2(1,2) = 60.06; rA2,2(3) = 11.5; and rA2,2(1,2,3) = rA2,2(1,2) + rA2,2(3) = 71.56, respectively.

5.2.3. Costs in Game rA2,3

Costs considered in game rA2,3 correspond to Sub Mains Boosters costs (see Table A1 in Appendix for a short description of the cost categories). All costs considered here concern those components that can be directly attributed to each area in Figure 1. The resulting cost game is an additive game. The total cost for the entire area is 767.888 × 106 LE.
The resulting game ({1,2,3},rA2,3) is presented in Table 11.

5.2.4. Cost Estimation for Intermediate Coalitions

As for the investment costs, costs of intermediate coalitions in game rA2,1 have been assumed to be directly proportional to the area of each region.

Estimation of Game rA2,2

For running costs, where the cost of energy employed for the operations is the main variable that affects the costs considered in Section 5.2.2, we assumed that both land area and average level have the same weight in the model for cost estimation. For this reason, we assumed the following model for running cost estimation
C′ = a′·F·H + K
where C′ is the total cost for cost items presented in the Section 5.2.2, F′ is the extension of the area served (Feddan), H′ is the average level of depth to water table in the area (meter), a′ is coefficient which represents the variable cost component and K′ is the fixed component for running costs. Fitting the model in relation (3) to data presented in Section 5.2.2, the resulting optimal coefficients are a′ = 0.003457258 × 10−3 and K′ = 1.393520161, and the corresponding game rA2,2 has the characteristic function shown in Table 12.

5.2.5. Evaluation of Labor Cost and Production rlp

Cost of seasonal labor is assumed to depend both on the total cultivated area (70% weight) and on the level of production (30% weight), while permanent labor is assumed to only depend on the cultivated area. These coefficients and assumptions are based on [16]. Other costs of production (seeds, fertilizers, machinery, etc.) are reported on a per Feddan basis, taking into account the reference cropping pattern [16]. Resulted costs appear in Table 13 and Table 14.
The reference-cropping pattern considered is the one shown in Table 2. The total area is 255,000 Feddan. Given these parameters, the aggregated labor and production cost game rlp is shown in Table 15. Note that the cost estimation for labor and production has been done to provide a holistic picture in the project area only because the allocation problem for these costs is clearly defined: each individual farm will support its own costs of labor and production.

5.2.6. Total Running Cost Game under Alternative A2

Summing up, the cost games related to the running costs (on a per year basis) under alternative A2 are shown in the following table (106 LE), where rA2(S) is the total running cost game under alternative A2.

5.3. Revenue Evaluation under the Alternative A2

Under this alternative the cultivated area is assumed to reach the full area of 255,000 Feddan. Unit revenues from production of different crops are reported in Table 16.
Under alternative A2 (no use of groundwater), we assume that the salinity of (Nile) water has been assumed to remain constant over the entire period of 20 years, which has been considered in this analysis [13,14,16,17]. According to [13,16,17], the revenues from production of different crops are assumed to depend on the expected yields and, ultimately, on the expected behavior of groundwater salinity under alternative A2. Therefore, yields, costs and profits remain constant over time under alternative A2.
Summing up, the revenue game ({1,2,3},vA2), which provides the revenue of each coalition under alternative A2, is shown in Table 17.

6. Assigning the Investment and Running Costs and the Revenues to the Various Coalitions in the Game under Alternative A0

In this section, we use again World Bank project document [14,15] and the same approach previously introduced in the previous section to assign costs and revenues to each possible sub-group of the three land areas under alternative A0.

6.1. Investment Cost Evaluation under the Alternative A0

Investment costs in irrigation equipment include groundwater pumping equipment (wells, pumps, engines, and fuel tank) and the cost of the irrigation system (drip lines, hydrants, etc.). The assumed average lifetime of these elements for A0, where the ground water (GW) pumping equipment has a relatively short life expectancy, is the following: 10 years for well, pump and engine, 30 years for fuel tank [17]. The cost of this equipment is reported in Table 18.
As shown in Table 18, the size of the needed equipment depends on the size of the area served. Thus, the investment cost game ({1,2,3},cA0) under alternative A0 is depicted in Table 19.

6.2. Running Cost Evaluation under the Alternative A0

Running costs incorporate O&M costs, labor costs, production costs and energy costs. O&M costs have been assumed equal to 5% of the yearly investment in equipment. Costs of supply of irrigation water include energy costs for water pumping. Energy cost per unit water has been estimated in [16] to be 0.029 LE/m3. The annual water requirement for a reference-cropping pattern for 100 Feddan has been than estimated at about 6250 m3/year.
Cost of labor and production per year have been calculated according to cost values shown in Table 13 and Table 14, with respect to the cultivated area under alternative A0. As we already indicated, the cost allocation for labor and production is already allocated (each farm will pay its own cost of labor and production cost) but it is included in the calculation to provide a more detailed account of all costs. The running cost game ({1,2,3},rA0) is then the one depicted in Table 20.

6.3. Revenue Evaluation under the Alternative A0

This alternative assumes continued use of groundwater, which is deteriorated in quality over time. The reference-cropping pattern is reported in Table 2. For this cropping pattern only, for summer and winter vegetables double cropping has been assumed in six-month periods for both summer and winter crops. Under alternative A0 the cultivated area is assumed to reach the partial area of 123,848 Feddan. After Year 13, the reference-cropping pattern has been substituted by the cropping pattern in Table 2.
Under alternative A0 the effect of salinity of irrigation water on yields is determined following the methodology reported in the economic model in the Annex 3 of [16], with the effect of salinity on yields being calculated according to the formula [19]:
Y(t) = [100 – B × (ECe(t) − A)] × Yns
where Y(t) is the absolute yield, A is threshold salinity at which a crop start to suffer from salinity (dS/m), B is rate of yield decrease % per dS/m increase in salinity, ECe(t) is mean electrical conductivity of saturated paste of the soil in (dS/m) at time t, and Yns is the non stress yield level (ton/Feddan). Consequently, each year, each coalition gets an incremental decrease of its revenues of about 4%. All revenue games are shown in the Table A5.
Therefore, and due to the annual decrease of revenues, we face 20 revenue games vtA0, where t = 0, 1, …, 19 is the year index. All revenue games shown in Table A5 are also depicted in Figure 2. It has been shown in the simulation presented by [16] that after Year 13, alternative A0 produces a negative net benefit under the reference-cropping pattern. Because of these negative net benefits, farmers are supposed to switch the cropping pattern in Table 4 (Scenario A0) to the one in Table 2 (Scenario A2), which yields the revenues reported in italics in Table A5.

7. Game Comparison for Alternatives A0 and A2

In this section, we present a comparison of alternatives A0 and A2 in terms of their Net Present Values (NPVs). Running cost games rA0 and rA2 are computed on an annual basis, so they have to be paid by regions at each period. On the other hand, we suppose that the annual investment cost that each coalition should bear every year under the two alternatives and over the entire period of 20 years is:
cyA0 = 1.065 × cA0/20 and cyA2 = 1.065 × cA2/20
where the coefficient 1.065 takes into account the Interest During Construction (IDC), which is assumed to be 6.5% according to [14].
For harmony with other studies concerning this project, we chose to actualize all these (running and investment) using the conservative estimate of the interest rate of 10%, as it appears in [16]. As also indicated in [16], 10% is the conservative estimate of the real interest rate for Egypt, computed on the basis of the nominal interest rate and the average inflation rate according to the formula in Table 21.
The present values of investment and running costs together with the present values of the revenues under the two different alternatives over a period of twenty years are shown in Table 22 and Table 23. The present values of the investment costs under alternatives A0 and A2 are denoted by iA0 and iA2, respectively. The present value of the running costs for alternative A0 is denoted by aA0. Under alternative A2, we distinguish between the present value of running cost game rlp due to labor, denoted by alp, and the present value of the sum of running cost games rA2,1 + rA2,2 + rA2,3, denoted by aA2 (the present values games iA2 and aA2 will be also used in the cost sharing problem introduced in the next section). Finally, the present values of the revenue games under the two alternatives A0 and A2 are denoted by VA0 and VA2, respectively.
The last rows of Table 22 and Table 23 provide the difference between the present values of the revenue game minus the present value of the cost games under the two alternatives A0 and A2, respectively. Note that the NPV of alternative A2 is larger than the one of alternative A0, for each coalition S ⊆ {1,2,3}, suggesting that alternative A2 is more profitable than A0 over the entire period. The data presented in Table 22 and Table 23 are synthetically reported in Figure 3 and Figure 4, respectively.
From the results in Table 22 and Table 23 we can realize that the net present value of alternative A2 is superior to that of alternative A0 for each coalition of land sections in the project. Therefore, the implementation of alternative A2 is the best option for all intermediate coalitions of all regions. This is consistent with the analysis in Section 7.1, where the allocation problem of the joint implementation costs for alternative A2 is studied. Of course, such allocation problem must take into account both the effects of time on the cash flow (mainly affecting the actualization of the yearly running costs) and the strength of each coalition S ⊆ {1,2,3} in contributing to the total cost of implementation of alternative A2 in the entire region N. Our next assignment in the paper is to find an allocation of the (investment plus running) cost game in which all the players (land sections) are not unhappy with such an allocation, that is, we will find an allocation which is in the core of the game. We will show that the Shapley Value of the cost game under alternative A2 (for both investment and running costs) is in the core of the cost game (see Figure 5). Moreover the Shapley value satisfies some nice properties of fairness in general. Thus, we propose the Shapley value of the cost game under alternative A2 as a basis for allocating the costs of implementation of alternative A2 of this game. The Core and the Shapley Value are displayed in Figure 5.

7.1. Cost Allocation Problem under Alternative A2

We are now ready to suggest ways to allocate the joint costs among the various players (regions). First we summarize which games have been considered, that is, the costs of implementation of alternative A2 that have been adopted for the three regions and analyzed in the previous sections.
Concerning the running costs, in this section we consider the cost allocation problem related to the running cost game aA2 provided in Table 23, that is the present value of the sum of the running cost games rA2,1 + rA2,2 + rA2,3. Note that the game rlp concerning the cost of labor and production is not considered here because, as we previously said, the allocation problem for these costs is clearly defined: each individual farm will support its own cost of labor and production.
Investment costs cA2 (see Table 8) are deflated to present time and, as described in [13], will be probably depreciated over 20 years. Similar to the previous section, for the investment costs, from [14] we estimated IDC costs at 6.5%, yielding the game îA2 = 1.065 × cA2 as shown in Table 24. Table 25 summarizes the present value aA2 of the total running cost for the implementation of alternative A2, as defined in the previous section (Table 23).
The Shapley values Sh of the games îA2(S) and aA2(S) computed according to relation (1) are shown in Table 26.
The Shapley allocations in the games Sh(îA2) and Sh(aA2) are in the core of games iA2 and aA2, respectively, and, consequently, the allocations under Sh(îA2 + aA2) is in the core of game iA2 + aA2.
Normalizing all data with respect to the cost allocated by the Shapley value to one single Feddan in the central region, the remaining regions should pay proportionally to the values presented in the Table 27.
Note that, if the Shapley value is implemented as an allocation method, then because the investment cost game is almost additive, the fraction of investment costs allocated to one Feddan on the project area is the same for all regions. In other words, the Shapley value assigns to one Feddan in the Northern region a smaller fraction of the running costs than in the Southern region and an intermediate fraction in the Central one.
Finally, based on the previous analysis we propose a tariff based on the Shapley value of the cost game that was considered in this paper. We assume a loan for the entire cost of investments (with annual fixed interest rate equal to 4.5%). Table 28 reports our proposed tariff based on the Shapley Value allocations. The tariff is composed of a fixed amount (per Feddan) plus a per m3 cost.

8. Conclusions and Epilogue

The Government of Egypt and several financing institutions, led by the World Bank designed the West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project. The project was motivated by the loss in agricultural land productivity and deteriorated groundwater quality that jeopardized the promising development of the region of the West Delta in Egypt. The project was based on several premises, including a maximum surface water delivery of 5000 m3 per year per Feddan; a conjunctive use of surface and groundwater resources; a full cost recovery of all investment and operation and maintenance costs; and management of the project by the private sector with only government guarantees to reduce risk faced by the private operator. An independent regulator will monitor and enforce the terms of contracts between the beneficiaries and the service provider.
The project documents [15] propose a single two-part tariff to be charged to all users. The fixed part of the tariff (1272 LE/Feddan per year) was intended to cover capital cost, concession fees, and operator profit. The volumetric part of the tariff (0.15 LE/m3) was designed to cover the operating costs. These tariffs differ from the once we calculated in our Shapley Value8.
The Shapley Value tariff per volumetric unit of water is designed such that it takes into consideration the heterogeneous conditions in the different land sections of the project site, which are reflected in differential volumetric fees computed for each section, based in this paper, on height to water table of the aquifer9. The Shapley Value fixed tariff of 849 (LE/Feddan/year) for all sections is the result of the investment data we had, which was available for the entire land area of the project.
After tireless attempts to recruit private sector bidders to the project with no success, the project was canceled on 30 June 2011 [12]. Reasons for no interest in the project on the part of the private sector bidders were: (1) high financial risks; (2) proposed government guarantees were not sufficient for private sector entrepreneurs under existing institutions in the country; and (3) collection of the irrigation tariff seemed subject to high transaction costs. From the government point of view, the reasons were: (1) lack of private sector interest in the project; and (2) unrealistically high tariff in the only submitted bid [12]. Given the dire need of farmers’ for new water supply and their continued request for a solution, the idea of the project will remain alive. It takes more proactive role from all parties if the private sector involvement will be an option.
Based on the above, one could look at our paper as an unsuccessful academic effort. However, the fact that the proposed Shapley-based differential tariff could be by itself an improved version of the single tariff, taking into account the physical characteristics of the main land sections of the project, and the fact that the proposed Shapley-based differential tariff was efficient (recovering all costs) is by itself a reason for making it more attractive to the users and thus reducing the no-payment risk faced by the service provider. Our paper demonstrated the use of cooperative game theory approach in real life decision associated with development and sustainability of scarce water resources. We guided the interested reader through the process we developed to calculate the needed parameters in the cost allocation scheme we proposed. If indeed the Government of Egypt and the World Bank, or any other international development agency will revive this project, we would suggest to use the results of our Shapley Value to conduct a study that will estimate the willingness to pay based on the Shapley Value and on a comparative one tariff to represent alternative A2. Having these responses from the project beneficiaries could shed light on the stability and sustainability of projects that rely on cost allocation of the joint cost.

Author Contributions

S.M. wrote the first draft of a report leading to this paper, including all data analysis, and participated in the internal revision. F.P. provided logical feedback on all game theory applications and numerical results, and participated in the internal revision. A.D. wrote the first draft of the manuscript and participated in the internal revision. S. A.-D. mined the literature, which was the basis for the engineering assumptions in the basis of the models used in the paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Investment Cost Categories under Scenario A2.
Table A1. Investment Cost Categories under Scenario A2.
DescriptionFunction
Supplementary WorksThis cost component includes the cost of the transformers required to supply electricity to the plant. It also includes any crossing structure required to transfer water under the railway and Rayah El-Behary.
IntakesPumping surface water from the Rayah El-Nasery to the project area high lands. This component includes the electricity supply requirements such as transformers.
Intermediate BoostersPumping water in the system locally to serve the high areas within the project. These boosters are intermediate pump stations at mains to supply water from mains to different served farms with the required pressure and volume. This component includes the electricity supply requirements such as transformers.
Sub-Mains BoostersThese boosters lift water from the mains (gravity flow) to connected sub-mains (pressurized flow). Each sub-main booster serves one sub-main.
Electricity SupplyFeeds all pumping stations, intakes, boosters in the project with electricity. This component includes a transformer plant at each intake. All required transmitting lines are included.
MainsConvey pumped water to the different zones in the project area. Each main serves one sector in the project area. These mains are carriers and have no direct farm connections. Also, any minor crossings required for mains construction are included in this component. Other main crossing structures are included in component “CS”.
Sub-MainsReceives water from the main through the sub-main boosters and distributes it within the zone. These sub-mains deliver water to the different farms the project area. Water flow in the sub-main pipes is pressurized flow. Usually, sub-mains are soft pipes to allow the farm connections easier.
Farm ConnectionsServes the different farms in the project area. Each farm connection serves one farm or several (depending on the design). Each farm connection delivers water to the farm with the required pressure and volume. Soft pipes are recommended. Design of each farm connection will be subject to case-by-case evaluation, depending on the farm size, farm level and its location from the sub-main.
Crossing StructuresThese structures result due to the different crossings of the planed delivery and distribution system with the existing roads in the project area. Any crossing with SOMID pipeline, Railways or Cairo-Alexandria Desert road forms a crossing structure. The construction method of these crossing structures depend on the crossing type and its governing characteristics.
Roads SystemThis system connects the project area through a two-degree road system, main and secondary roads.
O&M ProgramCovers the technical and managerial assistance, equipment and facilities required for the O&M program. This component includes also institutional development and capacity building program and establishment of Monitoring and Evaluation programs.
Source: Adapted from [13].
Table A2. Running Cost Categories under Scenario A2.
Table A2. Running Cost Categories under Scenario A2.
DescriptionFunction
Supplementary WorksCompensate the consumed water from the Rayah El-Nasery by pumping the same water volume from the Rosetta Branch to the Rayah El-Nasery downstream the project under the Rayah El-Behary to serve the downstream areas.
O&M ProgramPumping surface water from the Rayah El-Nasery to the project area high lands. This component includes the electricity supply requirements such as transformers.
Intermediate BoostersPumping water in the system locally to serve the high areas within the project.
IntakesPumping surface water from the Rayah El-Nasery to the project area high lands.
Sub-Mains BoostersThese boosters lift water from the mains (gravity flow) to connected sub-mains (pressurized flow). Each sub-main booster serves one sub-main.
Cost of Labor (permanent)Costs of permanent labor are assumed to only depend on the cultivated area.
Cost of Labor (seasonal)Costs of seasonal labor are assumed to depend both on the total cultivated area (70% weight) and on the level of production (30% weight)
Other Production Costs (seeds, fertilizers, etc.)Other costs of production (seeds, fertilizers, machinery, etc.) are on a per Feddan basis, taking into account the cropping pattern
Source: Adapted from [16].
Table A3. Investment Cost Categories under Scenario A0.
Table A3. Investment Cost Categories under Scenario A0.
DescriptionFunction
Pumping EquipmentGroundwater pumping equipment (wells, pumps, engines, fuel tank). The GW pumping equipment has a relatively short life expectancy: 10 years for well, pump and engine, 30 years for fuel tank
Source: Adapted from [16].
Table A4. Running Cost Categories under Scenario A0.
Table A4. Running Cost Categories under Scenario A0.
DescriptionFunction
ECEnergy costs for water pumping
O&M ProgramOperation and maintenance costs have been assumed equal to 5% of the yearly investment in equipment (PE)
Cost of Labor (permanent)Costs of permanent labor are assumed to only depend on the cultivated area.
Cost of Labor (seasonal)Costs of seasonal labor are assumed to depend both on the total cultivated area (70% weight) and on the level of production (30% weight)
Other Production Costs (seeds, fertilizers, etc.)Other costs of production (seeds, fertilizers, machinery, etc.) are on a per Feddan basis, taking into account the cropping pattern
Source: Adapted from [16].
Table A5. Annual revenues for coalitions in games vtA0 for t = 0, …, 19 under Alternative A0.
Table A5. Annual revenues for coalitions in games vtA0 for t = 0, …, 19 under Alternative A0.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{2,3}{1,3}{1,2,3}
v0A0443.26140.69339.13583.95479.82782.39923.08
v1A0425.53135.06325.56560.60460.62751.10886.16
v2A0408.51129.66312.54538.17442.20721.05850.71
v3A0392.17124.47300.04516.65424.51692.21816.68
v4A0376.49119.49288.04495.98407.53664.52784.02
v5A0361.43114.71276.52476.14391.23637.94752.65
v6A0346.97110.13265.45457.09375.58612.42722.55
v7A0333.09105.72254.84438.81360.56587.93693.65
v8A0319.77101.49244.64421.26346.13564.41665.90
v9A0306.9897.43234.86404.41332.29541.83639.26
v10A0294.7093.54225.46388.23319.00520.16613.69
v11A0282.9189.79216.44372.70306.24499.35589.15
v12A0271.5986.20207.79357.79293.99479.38565.58
v13A0260.7382.75199.48343.48282.23460.20542.96
v14A0308.4397.89235.97406.32333.86544.40642.29
v15A0296.0993.98226.53390.07320.51522.62616.60
v16A0284.2590.22217.47374.47307.69501.72591.94
v17A0272.8886.61208.77359.49295.38481.65568.26
v18A0261.9683.15200.42345.11283.56462.38545.53
v19A0251.4979.82192.40331.30272.22443.89523.71
Note: In italics are the net benefits after switching to a less sensitive cropping pattern.

References

  1. Dinar, A.; Hogarth, M. Game Theory and Water Resources: Critical Review of its Contributions, Progress and Remaining Challenges. Found. Trends 2015, 11, 1–139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Shapley, L.S. A Value for n-person Games. In Contributions to the Theory of Games, Volume II; Kuhn, H.W., Tucker, A.W., Eds.; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1953. [Google Scholar]
  3. Schmeidler, D. The nucleolus of a characteristic function game. SIAM J. Appl. Math. 1969, 17, 1163–1170. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Myerson, R.B. Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1991. [Google Scholar]
  5. Osborne, M.; Rubinstein, A. A Course in Game Theory; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  6. Owen, G. Game Theory, 3rd ed.; Academic: San Diego, CA, USA, 1968. [Google Scholar]
  7. Moretti, S.; Patrone, F. Transversality of the Shapley value. Top 2008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Parrachino, I.; Dinar, A.; Patrone, F. Cooperative Game Theory and Its Application to Natural, Environmental, and Water Resource Issues: 3. Application to Water Resources. Application to Water Resources (November 2006); The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  9. Wang, L.Z.; Fang, L.; Hipel, K.W. Water Resources Allocation: A Cooperative Game Theoretic Approach. J. Environ. Inform. 2003, 2, 11–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Young, H.P.; Okada, N.; Hashimoto, T. Cost Allocation in Water Resource Development. Water Resour. Res. 1982, 183, 463–482. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Esteban, E.; Dinar, A. Cooperative Management of Groundwater Resources in the Presence of Environmental Externalities. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2013, 54, 443–469. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. World Bank. Note on Cancelled Operation Project on a Loan in the Amount of US$145 Million to the Arab Republic of Egypt for A West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project. Sustainable Development Department, Middle East and North Africa Region, Report No. NCO00002221; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  13. Attia, F.; Fahmi, H.; Gambarelli, J.; Hoevenaars, R.; Slootweg, R.; AbdelDayem, S. West Delta Water Conservation, Irrigation and Rehabilitation Project (WDWCIARP): Impact on Net Benefits of an Average Farm in the Project Area; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2005a. [Google Scholar]
  14. PPIAF (Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility); The World Bank Group; Government of Egypt, Ministry of Water Resources and Irrigation. Conceptual Framework and Transaction Model for a Public Private Partnership in Irrigation in the West Delta, Egypt. Available online: https://www.ppiaf.org/sites/ppiaf.org/files/documents/West_Delta_Final_Draft_Report.pdf (accessed on 18 March 2015).
  15. World Bank. Project Appraisal Document on a Proposed Loan in the Amount of US$145 Million to the Arab Republic of Egypt for West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project, May 22. Sustainable Development Department, Middle East and North Africa Region, Report No: 32393-EG; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  16. Attia, F.; Fahmi, H.; Gambarelli, J.; Hoevenaars, R.; Slootweg, R.; AbdelDayem, S. West Delta Water Conservation, Irrigation and Rehabilitation Project (WDWCIARP) Drainframe Analysis, Main Report; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2005b. [Google Scholar]
  17. Attia, F.; Fahmi, H.; Gambarelli, J.; Hoevenaars, R.; Slootweg, R.; AbdelDayem, S. West Delta Water Conservation, Irrigation and Rehabilitation Project (WDWCIARP). A Report on the Survey Results and Analysis, ANNEX 1 of the Drainframe Analysis, Main Report; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2005c. [Google Scholar]
  18. Attia, F.; Fahmi, H.; Abdel, R.; Hussam, F.; Manal, E. The West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project (WDWCIRP), Environmental and Social Impacts Assessment and Framework Management Plan; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA; Government of Egypt Ministry of Water Resources and Irrigation: Giza, Egypt, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  19. Maas, E.V.; Hoffman, G.J. Crop salt tolerance-current assessment. J. Irrig. Drain. Div. Am. Soc. Civ. Eng. 1997, 103, 115–134. [Google Scholar]
  20. Draft Technical Report, West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project; Government of Egypt Ministry of Water Resources and Irrigation: Giza, Egypt, 2006.
  21. Moretti, S. Excel File Costs.XLS on Allocation of Project Costs among Various Project Regions. (Auxiliary Dataset to this Paper). In Alternative Cost and Benefit Sharing Cooperative Arrangements in the West Delta, Egypt; ARD-World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  • 1Players F1, 2, and F3 are sub-regions in the project that differ in their landscape and sensitivity to groundwater salinity. We use the notion presented in previous works in the literature (e.g., Young, Okada and Hashimoto, 1982 [10]; Esteban and Dinar, 2013 [11]) that there is an authority (project manager, government authority) that can decide on combinations of the regions of the project for realization of economies of scale in the case of a benefit sharing game or diseconomies of scale in a cost sharing game. The project manager or the government authority could be in charge of such calculations.
  • 2Note that, according to a land satellite imagery of January 2002, more than 123,000 Feddans were under cultivation. When fully developed, the net cultivable area under alternative A2 is estimated to reach 255,000 Feddans.
  • 3One important factor is the salinity of groundwater, which is a main driver of the interest of the farmers. However, we were not able to find information on salinity levels in the three project land sections. Available information on salinity in the groundwater refers to the entire project only.
  • 4The West Delta Irrigation Project analyses considered four alternatives (choices): (i) Alternative A0, which assumes business as usual, i.e., doing nothing; (ii) Alternative A1, which provides a maximum surface water supply capacity of 4.5 mm/day with the conjunctive use of ground water to meet peak water requirements during the summer months; (iii) Alternative A2, where surface water supply follows the crop water requirement through the year and no ground water pumping is needed; and (iv) Alternative A3, where groundwater recharge is combined with conjunctive use of surface water and groundwater [13].
  • 5We did not compare between the alternatives A1, A2, and A3, but only between alternative A2 and status quo/business as usual (A0).
  • 6We use costs presented in a spreadsheet of the project report that can be attributed to each region depicted in Figure 1 [21].
  • 7The exchange rate used at the time of conducting study (2002) is 5.8 LE = 1$.
  • 8The cost charged according to World Bank calculation and the cost charged by us in the Shapley value refer to different alternatives (alternative A2 for the Shapley Value) so it is not surprising that the total cost each of them ought to allocate are different.
  • 9Salinity in the groundwater is another factor that affects in reality the fee. However, we did not have data on salinity levels in the groundwater by land sectors.
Figure 1. Project area: The areas marked with red lines indicate the Southern sub-region (player 2); the areas marked with purple lines indicate the Northern sub-region (player 3); and the unmarked blocks indicate the Central sub-region (player 1).
Figure 1. Project area: The areas marked with red lines indicate the Southern sub-region (player 2); the areas marked with purple lines indicate the Northern sub-region (player 3); and the unmarked blocks indicate the Central sub-region (player 1).
Games 07 00018 g001
Figure 2. Annual revenues for coalitions in games vtA0 for t = 0, …, 19 under Alternative A0 (from the data shown in Table A5 in Appendix). After Year 13, alternative A0 produces a negative net benefit (i.e., the revenues minus the costs) under the reference cropping pattern in Table 2 (Scenario A0) and farmers are supposed to switch the cropping pattern in Table 2 (Scenario A2).
Figure 2. Annual revenues for coalitions in games vtA0 for t = 0, …, 19 under Alternative A0 (from the data shown in Table A5 in Appendix). After Year 13, alternative A0 produces a negative net benefit (i.e., the revenues minus the costs) under the reference cropping pattern in Table 2 (Scenario A0) and farmers are supposed to switch the cropping pattern in Table 2 (Scenario A2).
Games 07 00018 g002
Figure 3. Present values of cost and revenues games under Alternative A0. Investment cost: Present values of coalitions in the investment cost game iA0. Running cost: Present values of coalitions in the running cost game iA0. Revenue: Present values of coalitions in the revenue game VA0. NPV (revenues minus costs): Total net present value obtained as the difference between revenues and costs.
Figure 3. Present values of cost and revenues games under Alternative A0. Investment cost: Present values of coalitions in the investment cost game iA0. Running cost: Present values of coalitions in the running cost game iA0. Revenue: Present values of coalitions in the revenue game VA0. NPV (revenues minus costs): Total net present value obtained as the difference between revenues and costs.
Games 07 00018 g003
Figure 4. Present values of cost and revenues games under Alternative A2. Investment cost: Present values of coalitions in the investment cost game iA2. Running cost: Present values of coalitions in the running cost game iA2. Labor cost: Present values of coalitions in the labor cost game alp. Revenue: Present values of coalitions in the revenue game VA2. NPV (revenues minus costs): Total net present value obtained as the difference between revenues and costs.
Figure 4. Present values of cost and revenues games under Alternative A2. Investment cost: Present values of coalitions in the investment cost game iA2. Running cost: Present values of coalitions in the running cost game iA2. Labor cost: Present values of coalitions in the labor cost game alp. Revenue: Present values of coalitions in the revenue game VA2. NPV (revenues minus costs): Total net present value obtained as the difference between revenues and costs.
Games 07 00018 g004
Figure 5. The Core and the Shapley Value of the cost game aA2. Note: Vectors of numbers in the format (×1, ×2, ×3) represent the allocation for players 1, 2 and 3, respectively. Values of game aA2 in Table 25 are rounded to the nearest integer.
Figure 5. The Core and the Shapley Value of the cost game aA2. Note: Vectors of numbers in the format (×1, ×2, ×3) represent the allocation for players 1, 2 and 3, respectively. Values of game aA2 in Table 25 are rounded to the nearest integer.
Games 07 00018 g005
Table 1. Area and depth to water table by the 3 sub-regions (players).
Table 1. Area and depth to water table by the 3 sub-regions (players).
PlayerRegionGross Farm Area under A2 (Feddan)Gross Farm Area under A0 (Feddan)Average depth to GW (m)
1Central141,60059,47285
2South48,40018,876110
3North65,00045,50045
TOTAL255,000123,848
Note: 1 Feddan = 0.42 hectares.
Table 2. Cropping Patterns under Scenario A2 and A0.
Table 2. Cropping Patterns under Scenario A2 and A0.
Cropping Pattern for Year 1–13, Scenario A2Cropping Pattern for Year 14–20, Scenario A0
#Crop% area% area
1Apricot84
2Pears60
3Mango1010
4Peaches1513
5Grapes2346
6Citrus1717
7Summer Vegetables105
8Winter vegetables115
Note: All the assumptions on data concerning the cropping patterns for the three regions originates from the Annex 3 of the main report, where the reference cropping pattern has been derived from the farm survey results in Annex 1.
Table 3. Costs in Game cA2,1.
Table 3. Costs in Game cA2,1.
DescriptionTotal Cost in the Project Area
Supplementary Work107.68
Electricity supplies29.60
(O&M Program)11.30
Physical Contingencies126.39
Price Contingencies126.39
Source: [20]. Note that we considered in this game only the cost of investment in the project region depicted in Figure 1. From costs in Table 3, it is possible to assess the total amount for the grand coalition {1,2,3} as cA2,1(1,2,3) = 401.36. This was mentioned in the definition of this game earlier in the section.
Table 4. Costs in Game cA2,2.
Table 4. Costs in Game cA2,2.
DescriptionTotal Cost for Central and Southern Region (Player 2)Total Cost for the Northern Region (Player 3)
Intakes290.10*
Intakes*64.48
Intermediate Boosters62.78*
Intermediate Boosters*31.78
Electricity Supply IN-0130.60*
Electricity Supply IN-02*16.70
Electricity Supply IB-0117.70*
Electricity Supply IB-02*16.70
Mains (pressurized)57.27*
Mains (gravity)66.85*
Mains (pressurized)15.39*
Mains (pressurized)15.39*
Mains (pressurized)8.33*
Mains (gravity)*17.00
Mains (pressurized)*17.93
Crossing Structure29.08*
Crossing Structure12.08*
Crossing Structure*2.18
Road system2.72*
Road system*1.70
Source: [20]. Note: * means that the corresponding cost item on the row does not affect the corresponding player on the column. For example, the description “Electricity Supply IN-01” refers to the cost component “Electricity Supply” corresponding to the intake (IN) 01 [20].
Table 5. Costs in Game cA2,3.
Table 5. Costs in Game cA2,3.
DescriptionCost for the Entire Project Area
Crossing structure11.92
Road system189.40
Sub mains boosters767.89
Electricity Supply18.40
Mains152.51
Sub-Mains124.44
Farm Connections203.05
Table 6. Additive cost (LE) in Game cA2,3.
Table 6. Additive cost (LE) in Game cA2,3.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
cA2,3(S)812.55265.57389.491078.121202.04655.061467.61
Note that the total cost of investment under alternative A2 in the project area depicted in Figure 1 is equal to 2645.712 × 106 LE.
Table 7. The calculated costs for game cA2,2.
Table 7. The calculated costs for game cA2,2.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
F (Feddan)141,60048,40065,000190,000206,600113,400255,000
H (level)851104591727380
cA2,2(S)438.60161.39176.80599.94615.40338.13776.74
Table 8. Total investment cost game under alternative A2.
Table 8. Total investment cost game under alternative A2.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
cA2,1(S)222.8876.18102.31299.06325.19178.49401.37
cA2,2(S)438.60161.34176.80599.94615.40338.13776.74
cA2,3(S)812.55265.57389.491078.121202.04655.061467.61
cA2(S)1474.03503.09668.601977.122142.631171.682645.71
cA2(S)/2073.7025.1533.4398.86107.1358.58132.29
Table 9. Costs in game rA2,1.
Table 9. Costs in game rA2,1.
DescriptionTotal Cost on the Project Area
(i.e., Figure 1 Area, 45% of the Total Served Area)
Supplementary Work6.16
(O&M Program)0.25
(O&M Program)54.28
Table 10. Costs in game rA2,2.
Table 10. Costs in game rA2,2.
DescriptionTotal Cost for Central and Southern Region (Coalition {1,2})Total Cost for the Northern Region (Coalition {3})
Intakes50.699.28
Intermediate Boosters9.372.22
Table 11. Coalitional costs in the game ({1,2,3},rA2,3).
Table 11. Coalitional costs in the game ({1,2,3},rA2,3).
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
rA2,3(S)27.169.5712.7936.6839.9022.3649.48
Note that the total running costs under alternative A2 in the project area depicted in Figure 1 is equal to 181.681 × 106 LE.
Table 12. Characteristic Function Values for game rA2,2.
Table 12. Characteristic Function Values for game rA2,2.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
F (Feddan)141,60048,40065,000190,000206,600113,400255,000
H (meter)851104591727380
rA2,2(S)43.0619.8011.5161.4153.1229.9171.52
Table 13. Labor cost.
Table 13. Labor cost.
Type of LaborSalary LE/monthTotal Person-Hours per Year (100 Feddan, Year 2005)
Permanent-skilled40025,200
Permanent-unskilled30046,500
Seasonal270109,000
Table 14. Production cost by crop.
Table 14. Production cost by crop.
CropCost (LE/ Feddan)
Summer and winter vegetables1670
Maize1024
Fruit trees1000
Table 15. Aggregated labor and production cost game rlp.
Table 15. Aggregated labor and production cost game rlp.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
rA2,1(S)33.7011.5215.4745.2249.1726.9960.69
rA2,2(S)43.0119.8011.5161.4153.1229.9171.52
rA2,3(S)27.119.5712.7936.6839.9022.3649.47
rlp(S)482.28164.85221.39647.13703.67386.24868.52
rA2(S)586.09205.74261.16790.44845.86465.501050.20
Table 16. Unit revenues from production of different crops.
Table 16. Unit revenues from production of different crops.
CropFarmgate Price LE/TonNon Stress Yield (Ton/Fedan)
Apricot8003.5
Pears32006.9
Mango16803.2
Peaches10407.4
Grapes12006.8
Citrus6006.7
Winter Vegetables47014.9
Summer Vegetables45019.6
Table 17. Revenue of the coalitions under alternative A2.
Table 17. Revenue of the coalitions under alternative A2.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
vA2(S)812.55265.57389.491078.121202.04655.091467.61
Table 18. Cost of pumping and irrigation network.
Table 18. Cost of pumping and irrigation network.
ItemUnit Capital Cost (LE)No. per Farm (100 Feddan)Lifetime (Years)
Well construction (100 m) [16]60,000210
Engine100,000210
Pump80,000210
Irrigation network (including hydrants and drip lines) on 100 Feddan250,000120
Fuel tank5000130
Table 19. The investment cost game ({1,2,3},cA0) under alternative A0.
Table 19. The investment cost game ({1,2,3},cA0) under alternative A0.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
cA0(S)437.12138.74334.42575.86771.54473.16910.28
cA0(S)/2021.866.9416.7228.7938.5823.6645.51
Table 20. The running cost game ({1,2,3},rA0).
Table 20. The running cost game ({1,2,3},rA0).
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
rA0(S)232.3773.75177.78306.16410.14251.53483.89
Table 21. Calculation of a conservative estimate for interest rate.
Table 21. Calculation of a conservative estimate for interest rate.
Real Interest Rate = [(1 + Nominal Rate)/(1 + Inflation Rate)] − 1
nominal interest rate12%
inflation rate3%
real interest rate8.74%
conservative estimate10%
Table 22. Present values of cost and revenues games under Alternative A0.
Table 22. Present values of cost and revenues games under Alternative A0.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
iA0(S)217.9869.19166.77287.17384.76235.96453.94
aA0(S)2176.08690.671664.842866.743840.922355.514531.59
VA0(S)3321.101054.092540.864375.195861.963594.966916.05
NPV(A0)927.04294.23709.251221.281636.291003.491930.52
Table 23. Present values of cost and revenues games under Alternative A2.
Table 23. Present values of cost and revenues games under Alternative A2.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
iA2(S)735.07250.88333.42985.951068.49584.301319.37
aA2(S)972.18382.92372.431342.071331.58742.301701.44
alp(S)4516.541543.792073.276060.336589.813617.068133.60
VA2(S)7609.482487.023647.5410096.5011257.026134.5713744.04
NPV(A2)1385.68309.43868.421708.152267.141190.912589.63
Table 24. Investment cost game plus IDC costs are calculated as îA2 = 1.065 × cA2, where cA2 are the costs reported in Table 8.
Table 24. Investment cost game plus IDC costs are calculated as îA2 = 1.065 × cA2, where cA2 are the costs reported in Table 8.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
îA2(S)1569.84535.79712.052105.632281.901247.842817.68
Table 25. NPV of the total running cost for implementation of alternative A2.
Table 25. NPV of the total running cost for implementation of alternative A2.
S{1}{2}{3}{1,2}{1,3}{2,3}{1,2,3}
aA2(S)972.18382.92372.431,342.071331.58742.301701.44
Table 26. Shapley Values for games îA2(S) and aA2(S).
Table 26. Shapley Values for games îA2(S) and aA2(S).
PlayerCentral (Player 1)South (Player 2)North (Player 3)
Sh(îA2)1569.84535.79712.05
Sh(aA2)963.49374.22363.73
Sh(îA2 + aA2)2533.33910.011075.78
Table 27. Normalized Shapley Value payments of the investment game, and the combined game.
Table 27. Normalized Shapley Value payments of the investment game, and the combined game.
Central (Player 1)South (Player 2)North (Player 3)
Sh(îA2)111
Sh(aA2)11.1360.822
Sh(îA2 + aA2)11.0510.925
Table 28. Proposed tariff, based on the Shapley Value allocation of the joint costs.
Table 28. Proposed tariff, based on the Shapley Value allocation of the joint costs.
Central (Player 1)South (Player 2)North (Player 3)
Fixed charge per unit area (LE/Feddan/year)849849849
Volumetric water charge (LE/m3)0.120.130.10

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Moretti, S.; Patrone, F.; Dinar, A.; Abdel-Dayem, S. Sharing the Costs of Complex Water Projects: Application to the West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project, Egypt. Games 2016, 7, 18. https://doi.org/10.3390/g7030018

AMA Style

Moretti S, Patrone F, Dinar A, Abdel-Dayem S. Sharing the Costs of Complex Water Projects: Application to the West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project, Egypt. Games. 2016; 7(3):18. https://doi.org/10.3390/g7030018

Chicago/Turabian Style

Moretti, Stefano, Fioravante Patrone, Ariel Dinar, and Safwat Abdel-Dayem. 2016. "Sharing the Costs of Complex Water Projects: Application to the West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project, Egypt" Games 7, no. 3: 18. https://doi.org/10.3390/g7030018

APA Style

Moretti, S., Patrone, F., Dinar, A., & Abdel-Dayem, S. (2016). Sharing the Costs of Complex Water Projects: Application to the West Delta Water Conservation and Irrigation Rehabilitation Project, Egypt. Games, 7(3), 18. https://doi.org/10.3390/g7030018

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop