The Power of Passivity in the Hirshleifer Contest Under Small Noise
Abstract
1. Introduction
2. Set-Up and Preparations
- (i)
- Theequilibrium strategy of any contestant randomizes over a finite number of bids, denoted as , where ;
- (ii)
- Zero is contained in the support of the equilibrium strategy for at least contestants, and each of them receives a payoff no greater than .
- (i)
- At least two constants, including contestant one if , bid more than with positive probability;
- (ii)
- ;
- (iii)
- No contestant such that
- (iv)
- If , for at least two contestants .
- (i)
- ;
- (ii)
- If there exists some , for any large , then
3. The Main Results
- (i)
- For any , there exists such that at any , no less than two contestants among the top ones bid , and all the others, including each contestant if any, bid zero with certainty;
- (ii)
- When , at least contestants among the top ones bid zero with positive probability at any , and the only one, if any, who does not do so bids arbitrarily close to zero as grows unboundedly;
- (iii)
- When, contestant one’s highest bid is arbitrarily close to and the lowest bid, which remains positive at any finite , is arbitrarily close to zero as grows unboundedly, while any contestant bids zero with such that is arbitrarily close to as grows unboundedly.
4. Illustrative Examples: Quick Convergence to Passivity and Passivity Under Risk Aversion
5. Concluding Remarks
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
- (i)
- approaches at least as ;
- (ii)
- (iii)
- The value of is unboundedly large as grows unboundedly;
- (iv)
1 | Another hurdle faced by the Hirshleifer contest technology, especially in applied analysis, is that it does not admit any interior pure equilibrium (refer to, for instance, Hirshleifer, 1989, p. 107). In contrast, interesting enough, the Tullock contest does not admit any corner pure equilibrium (one or more contestants bid zero effort). |
2 | That said, it is not to say that defense, or even surrender, is necessarily costless. It could be costly, even very costly indeed, especially because defense sometimes serves a temporary measure to enable the player to be on the offensive side later. Alternatively put, the nature of defense or passivity as a strategy in a multi-stage game may remarkably differ from that in a static one. Nevertheless, in general, it is much more effort demanding and costly to be offensive than defensive. Admittedly, the present analysis focuses on a single one-shot contest only. |
3 | The term used in the following claims (i) and (ii) can be replaced by any infinitesimal such that as . We choose the specific for ease of exposition. |
4 | The following argument, once carefully refined, can be developed into a rigorous proof of Proposition 1 for the contest between risk-neutral contestants with CARA utiliyu functions. But the proof offered in the appendix, which separately deals with the cases of and is of value, not least because it plays an important part in the proof of both Proposition 2 and Corollary 1. |
5 | It is worth noting that, technically, Lemma 3 is independent of the risk attitude of the contestants, and that such a small increase in bid from also possibly causes a marginal change of the value of some other terms (when contestant happens to stand against other bid profile rather than the said in the expression of . |
6 | By saying that term approaches term , we mean that the gap between them is an infinitesimal as |
7 | This estimation of the upper bound of bid by some contestant such that is a restatement of Lemma A.4 in Ewerhart and Sun (2024), yet deliberately put in a slightly different format to facilitate analysis below. |
References
- Alcalde, J., & Dahm, M. (2007). Tullock and Hirshleifer: A meeting of the minds. Review of Economic Design, 11, 101–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baik, K. H. (1998). Difference-form contest success functions and effort levels in contests. European Journal of Political Economy, 14, 685–701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baye, M. R., Kovenock, D., & de Vries, C. G. (1996). The all-pay auction with complete information. Economic Theory, 8, 291–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baye, M. R., Kovenock, D., & de Vries, C. G. (1999). The incidence of overdissipation in rent-seeking contests. Public Choice, 99, 439–454. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beviá, C., & Corchόn, L. C. (2015). Relative difference contest success function. Theory and Decision, 78, 377–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beviá, C., & Corchόn, L. C. (2024). Contests: Theory and applications. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Che, Y.-K., & Gale, I. (2000). Difference-form contests and the robustness of all-pay auctions. Games and Economic Behavior, 30, 22–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Corchόn, L. C., & Serena, M. (2018). Contest theory. In Handbook of game theory and industrial organization (Vol. II). Edward Elgar Publishing. [Google Scholar]
- Cubel, M., & Sanchez-Pages, S. (2016). An axiomatization of difference-form contest success functions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 131, 92–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dupuy, T. N. (1987). Understanding war: History and theory of combat. Paragon House. [Google Scholar]
- Ewerhart, C. (2015). Mixed equilibria in Tullock contests. Economic Theory, 60, 59–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ewerhart, C. (2017). Contests with small noise and the robustness of the all-pay auction. Games and Economic Behavior, 105, 195–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ewerhart, C., & Sun, G.-Z. (2018). Equilibrium in the symmetric two-player Hirshleifer contest: Uniqueness and characterization. Economics Letters, 169, 51–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ewerhart, C., & Sun, G.-Z. (2024). The n-player Hirshleifer contest. Games and Economic Behavior, 143, 300–320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Glicksberg, I. L. (1952). A further generalization of the Kakutani fixed point theorem, with application to Nash equilibrium points. Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society, 3, 170–174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hillman, A. L., & Riley, J. G. (1989). Politically contestable rents and trasfers. Economics and Politics, 1, 17–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hirshleifer, J. (1988). The analytics of continuing conflict. Synthese, 76, 201–233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hirshleifer, J. (1989). Conflicts and rent-seeking success functions: Ratio vs difference models of relative success. Public Choice, 63, 101–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hirshleifer, J. (2000). The macrotechnology of conflict. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44, 773–792. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hirshleifer, J. (2001). The dark side of the force: Economic foundations of conflict theory. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Hirshleifer, J., & Riley, J. G. (1992). The analytics of uncertainty and information. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Jia, H. (2008). A stochastic derivation of the ratio form of the contest success function. Public Choice, 135, 125–130. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kimbrough, E. O., Laughren, K., & Sheremeta, R. (2020). War and conflict in economics: Theories, applications and recent trends. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 178, 998–1013. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Konrad, K. A. (2009). Strategy and dynamics in contests. Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Lawrence, C. A. (2017). War by numbers: Understanding conventional combat. Potomac Books, University of Nebraska Press. [Google Scholar]
- Levine, D. K., & Mattozzi, A. (2022). Success in contests. Economic Theory, 73, 595–624. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McFadden, D. (1974). Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior. In P. Zarembka (Ed.), Frontiers on econometrics. Academic Press. [Google Scholar]
- Skaperdas, S. (1996). Contest success function. Economic Theory, 7, 283–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sun, G.-Z. (2017). Characterizing the symmetric mixed-strategy equilibrium in rent-seeking contests: A real analysis approach (Unpublished working paper). SSRN. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2965369 (accessed on 26 August 2025).
- Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In J. Buchanan, R. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of rent seeking society (pp. 91–112). Texas A&M University Press. [Google Scholar]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2025 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Sun, G.-Z. The Power of Passivity in the Hirshleifer Contest Under Small Noise. Games 2025, 16, 43. https://doi.org/10.3390/g16050043
Sun G-Z. The Power of Passivity in the Hirshleifer Contest Under Small Noise. Games. 2025; 16(5):43. https://doi.org/10.3390/g16050043
Chicago/Turabian StyleSun, Guang-Zhen. 2025. "The Power of Passivity in the Hirshleifer Contest Under Small Noise" Games 16, no. 5: 43. https://doi.org/10.3390/g16050043
APA StyleSun, G.-Z. (2025). The Power of Passivity in the Hirshleifer Contest Under Small Noise. Games, 16(5), 43. https://doi.org/10.3390/g16050043