Next Article in Journal
Co-Construction Mechanisms of Spatial Encoding and Communicability in Culture-Featured Districts—A Case Study of Harbin Central Street
Previous Article in Journal
Upcycling of Sunflower and Sesame Press Cakes as Functional Ingredients in Cookies
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Study of Multi-Stakeholder Mechanism in Inter-Provincial River Basin Eco-Compensation: Case of the Inland Rivers of Eastern China

1
Center for Chinese Migration, Hohai University, Nanjing 211100, China
2
National Research Center for Resettlement, Hohai University, Nanjing 211100, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2025, 17(15), 7057; https://doi.org/10.3390/su17157057 (registering DOI)
Submission received: 18 June 2025 / Revised: 15 July 2025 / Accepted: 29 July 2025 / Published: 4 August 2025

Abstract

Based on a comprehensive review of the current research status of ecological compensation both domestically and internationally, combined with field survey data, this study delves into the issue of multi-stakeholder participation in the ecological compensation mechanisms of the Xin’an River Basin. This research reveals that the joint participation of multiple stakeholders is crucial to achieving the goals of ecological compensation in river basins. The government plays a significant role in macro-guidance, financial support, policy guarantees, supervision, and management. It promotes the comprehensive implementation of ecological environmental protection by formulating relevant laws and regulations, guiding the public to participate in ecological conservation, and supervising and punishing pollution behaviors. The public, serving as the main force, forms strong awareness and behavioral habits of ecological protection through active participation in environmental protection, monitoring, and feedback. As participants, enterprises contribute to industrial transformation and green development by improving resource utilization efficiency, reducing pollution emissions, promoting green industries, and participating in ecological restoration projects. Scientific research institutions, as technology enablers, have effectively enhanced governance efficiency through technological research and innovation, ecosystem value accounting to provide decision-making support, and public education. Social organizations, as facilitators, have injected vitality and innovation into watershed governance by extensively mobilizing social forces and building multi-party collaboration platforms. Communities, as supporters, have transformed ecological value into economic benefits by developing characteristic industries such as eco-agriculture and eco-tourism. Based on the above findings, further recommendations are proposed to mobilize the enthusiasm of upstream communities and encourage their participation in ecological compensation, promote the market-oriented operation of ecological compensation mechanisms, strengthen cross-regional cooperation to establish joint mechanisms, enhance supervision and evaluation, and establish a sound benefit-sharing mechanism. These recommendations provide theoretical support and practical references for ecological compensation worldwide.

1. Introduction

The previous development model oriented toward economic growth has led local governments to neglect environmental protection, causing pollution issues in the atmosphere, soil, and other domains. Among these, watershed water pollution requires systematic governance due to its transboundary nature, fluidity, and externality characteristics. Watershed ecological compensation, as an institutional arrangement aimed at protecting and sustainably utilizing ecosystems through primarily economic means to regulate stakeholders’ interest relationships [1], has gained widespread attention for its effectiveness in addressing watershed water pollution. The “Regulations on Ecological Conservation Compensation” implemented on 1 June 2024 marks a significant advancement in the legalization process of China’s ecological protection compensation system, signaling the transition of China’s ecological protection compensation mechanism from localized pilot programs to a new stage of institutional standardization. As China’s first cross-provincial watershed ecological compensation pilot project exploring multi-stakeholder collaboration involving governments, enterprises, social organizations, and the public, the Xin’an River watershed has not only provided crucial experience for the formulation of the regulation but also become a vital sample for testing the effectiveness of multi-stakeholder mechanisms post-implementation. The Xin’an River Basin’s practices have provided pivotal empirical experience for the regulation’s formulation, with their innovative approach gradually evolving into a universal “Chinese model” that offers replicable and scalable institutional references for addressing cross-regional ecological governance challenges. This paper adopts the Xin’an River as a case study to analyze the interactive relationships among multiple stakeholders in cross-provincial ecological compensation. It serves as practical verification of the regulation’s “multi-party collaboration” principle and provides theoretical support for the transition from policy to institutionalization in ecological governance, contributing to the construction of a modern Chinese-style ecological governance system.
Theoretical research on ecological compensation originated from the exploration of ecosystem service functions and value [2]. By regulating the supply–demand balance of ecosystem services, ecological compensation can alleviate conflicts between ecological protection and economic development, thereby enhancing natural resource management efficiency [3]. Domestic and international research on watershed ecological compensation is abundant, generally categorized into two types: ecological compensation system evaluation research and ecological compensation system design research. In ecological compensation evaluation research, scholars primarily focus on whether ecological compensation achieves its objectives, namely ecological environment improvement. Existing studies suggest that watershed ecological compensation can positively improve and protect the ecological environment, including by reducing watershed water pollution [4,5].
Beyond the primary objectives of ecological compensation, scholars have also noted its economic and social value. However, existing research shows no consensus regarding its economic value. Some studies suggest that the watershed ecological compensation promotes economic growth in compensated regions [6], with significant poverty reduction effects [7]. In the long term, ecological compensation mechanisms demonstrate notable effects in alleviating poverty [8]. Meanwhile, some scholars argue that ecological compensation hinders regional economic development [9,10]. Ecological compensation system design research has also attracted significant scholarly attention, focusing on compensation standards, compensation methods, and participating entities. Regarding compensation standards, existing studies measure them through market-based and non-market-based approaches. Market methods determine supply–demand equilibrium points through market mechanisms, including the opportunity cost [11] and income method [12]. Non-market methods establish compensation standards through supply costs or willingness to pay [13]. Both approaches have their respective advantages and disadvantages. To ensure scientific rigor and accuracy in measurement, some studies combine the strengths of multiple methods. Regarding compensation methods, traditional approaches are regarded as effective [14], though certain issues persist. Some studies propose improvement measures accordingly [15], while others suggest that market-based compensation methods and diversified approaches can adapt to broader regions [16] and address more diverse scenarios.
The subject of watershed ecological compensation has also garnered substantial attention. Regarding participating entities, scholars have reached a consensus on establishing a multi-stakeholder ecological compensation system. From the theoretical perspective of national governance. Ansell and Gash agree that such governance issues necessitate equal and voluntary negotiations and consultations among governing bodies [17]. Sheng J. et al. emphasized the importance of integrating market participation with government intervention [18]. Yisheng Ren et al. introduced the concept of institutional “stickiness” into the scale political theory and analyzed the characteristics and mechanisms of government subject game behavior in the process of implementing ecological compensation in the Xin’anjiang River Basin [19].
While the existing literature acknowledges the importance of multi-stakeholder participation, there remains a lack of in-depth analysis regarding how different entities can effectively collaborate and form synergies. This study focuses on the multi-stakeholder participation mechanism within cross-provincial watershed ecological compensation systems. This perspective further investigates the collaborative relationships among different actors including governments, markets, the public, research institutions, social organizations, and communities, thereby addressing the gap in existing research regarding inter-stakeholder interaction mechanisms.

2. Research Location and Data Sources

The Xin’an River, historically known as Zhejiang or Hui Port, traverses the present-day Anhui and Zhejiang Provinces. Originating from Fengcun Township in Xiuning County, Huangshan City, Anhui Province, it flows through Xiuning County, Tunxi District, Huizhou District, and She County before entering Chun’an County of Hangzhou City, Zhejiang Province, ultimately converging into Qiandao Lake. With a total length of 373 km and a watershed area exceeding 11,000 square kilometers, its mainstream spans approximately 242.3 km in Anhui Province and 116.7 km in Zhejiang Province. Overview map of the Xin’an River Basin sketch map (see Figure 1). The terminal reservoir Qiandao Lake, long renowned as an important water source for both provinces, has experienced severe water quality deterioration since 1998, causing significant challenges for Zhejiang Province. Approximately 70% of Qiandao Lake’s annual average inflow originates from the Anhui section of the Xin’an River watershed. Consequently, ecological protection in the upstream region critically impacts downstream production and livelihoods.
However, Huangshan City in the upstream area faces economic development needs that inevitably generate environmental pollution. This dual challenge of balancing downstream water quality requirements with upstream economic growth has become a pressing issue for both provinces and relevant national authorities. Zhejiang and Anhui Provinces initiated exploration of the Xin’an River watershed’s ecological compensation mechanisms in 2004. Under the guidance of the Ministry of Finance and the Ministry of Ecology and Environment, they launched China’s first cross-border watershed ecological compensation pilot program in March 2011. By 2024, three rounds of the Xin’an River ecological compensation pilot program had been completed. In June 2023, the two provinces signed the “Agreement on Jointly Building the Xin’an River-Qiandao Lake Ecological Protection Compensation Demonstration Zone”, marking the commencement of the fourth pilot phase.
As China’s first pilot project for cross-provincial eco-compensation, the Xin’an River Basin’s application of multi-stakeholder collaborative governance demonstrates pioneering, representative, and significant policy value. It pioneered a comprehensive collaborative framework featuring government leadership, corporate responsibility, social organizational support, and public participation. This provided crucial experience for formulating the “Regulations on Ecological Conservation Compensation”; subsequently, it became a key testing ground for evaluating the real-world effectiveness of the multi-stakeholder mechanisms outlined in the regulations. Through long-term implementation, this “Xin’anjiang Model” has effectively addressed cross-jurisdictional governance challenges, significantly improved the ecological environment, and promoted green transformation, offering a replicable Chinese approach for basin-wide collaborative governance both nationally and globally.
The primary data for this study were obtained from the official websites of the Huangshan City and Hangzhou City governments, supplemented by field investigations conducted by the authors in Huangshan City, Anhui Province, during July 2024. Utilizing these data, this paper examines the background and current status of multi-stakeholder collaborative governance in the ecological compensation practices of the Xin’an River watershed, while analyzing the internal mechanisms of the watershed ecological compensation system from the perspective of multi-stakeholder governance.

3. Analysis of the Reasons for the Participation of Multiple Stakeholders in Ecological Compensation in the Xin’anjiang River Basin

3.1. Analysis of the Necessity of Multi Subject Participation in Ecological Compensation in the Xin’anjiang River Basin

The imperative for multi-stakeholder participation in ecological compensation stems from the defining characteristics of ecological resources as public goods [21]: commonality and externality [22,23,24]. The commonality of ecological resources signifies that they belong not to any single individual or group but instead constitute shared assets for humanity. This inherent nature determines that no individual actor or institution can solely take responsibility for their protection and management. Consequently, collaborative engagement from diverse stakeholders is essential—governments representing public interests, enterprises as primary resource users and influencers, and the public as ultimate beneficiaries and practitioners. Simultaneously, ecological resources exhibit externality, whereby actors’ decisions inadvertently generate positive or negative impacts beyond their domains. When negative ecological externalities occur (e.g., environmental degradation), the consequences often transcend geographical boundaries without full cost internalization by responsible parties. Such free-rider problems and market failures necessitate multi-stakeholder collaboration to internalize external costs through governance mechanisms, thereby preventing resource overexploitation and pollution dispersion [25]. It is precisely these dual attributes—commonality as shared heritage and externality as spillover effects—inherent in ecological resources as public goods that fundamentally dictate the operational efficacy of ecological compensation mechanisms. Effective implementation must rely on extensive participation and deep collaboration among multiple stakeholders to achieve shared responsibility for conservation and the equitable distribution of costs and benefits, thereby addressing the free-rider dilemma and market failures to ensure the sustainability of ecological protection.

3.2. Theoretical Analysis of Multi-Subject Participation in Ecological Compensation in the Xin’anjiang River Basin

Rational Choice Theory (RCT), a classical sociological framework, originated from the “homo economicus” hypothesis in economics. Through sociological elaborations—particularly Max Weber’s typology of rationality and the contributions of scholars like Coleman—it has evolved into a vital analytical tool for social behavior. This theory posits that individuals engage in rational deliberation before acting, aiming to maximize utility or benefits while accounting for constraints imposed by social structures, norms, and resource availability. Rational behavior encompasses not only economic gains but also social, cultural, and emotional utilities. Coleman and colleagues integrated RCT with sociology, proposing that actors (as “rational agents”) pursuing personal goals are constrained by social environments, norms, and resource conditions, thereby establishing connections between individual actions and macro-social phenomena. Rational choice can be characterized as optimization or utility maximization, where rational actors tend to adopt optimal strategies to achieve maximum returns with minimal costs [26]. In the Xin’an River watershed context, the core participation motivations of different stakeholders in ecological compensation are illustrated in Table 1.
As the guardian and administrator of public interests, the government’s rational objectives encompass balancing and maximizing multidimensional benefits, ensuring public safety and environmental quality, promoting regional coordination and economic development, optimizing resource allocation, and strengthening governance legitimacy. Participation in ecological compensation represents the optimal approach to achieving its integrated objectives of environmental governance, economic development, and public administration. This facilitates coordinated regional development and advances common prosperity [27].
As participants and beneficiaries in environmental governance, the public demands high-quality living environments coupled with the right to information and participatory rights [28]. They expect watershed water resources to remain unpolluted, providing safe and healthy drinking water and domestic water supply, along with esthetically pleasing living conditions. Simultaneously, there exists an aspiration to engage in the formulation and implementation of ecological compensation mechanisms, contributing individual agency to watershed ecological conservation. Participation constitutes a rational choice to safeguard core environmental rights, enhance quality of life, and fulfill social engagement needs.
Enterprises engage in ecological compensation to secure access to premium ecological resources and fulfill corporate social responsibilities. Participation represents the comprehensive optimal solution for achieving economic returns, mitigating risks, and cultivating positive social reputation.
Research institutions are primarily motivated by technological conversion benefits and social responsibility incentives. Engagement enables the transformation of research outcomes into practical applications, enhancing academic influence while securing direct financial support. As producers of public knowledge, their participation elevates social reputation and aligns with the rational objective of public value maximization.
Social organizations’ participation is driven by the dual imperatives of social benefit maximization and value-role alignment. With a mission to enhance public welfare, their core motivation lies in achieving the scaled amplification of social benefits. By mobilizing citizens, monitoring policies, and advocating equity, these organizations amplify societal impact to gain greater discursive power and resource allocation in public governance spheres. As societal stewards, they reinforce their identity as “guardians of public interest” through ecological governance engagement. This value-driven approach resonates with members’ ethical aspirations while securing social legitimacy and sustainable operational space.
Community engagement is driven by demands for economic returns and environmental well-being. Rural communities’ primary motivation lies in obtaining quantifiable economic benefits. Through green industries like eco-agriculture and carbon sink trading, farmers transform environmental conservation into income-generating channels, actualizing the “conservation-as-benefit” paradigm. Ecological essentials such as clean water sources and healthy soil form the livelihood foundation, where compensation participation enables low-cost environmental improvements (e.g., pollution reduction and resource quality enhancement).

4. Exploration of the Participation Mechanism of Ecological Compensation in the Xin’anjiang River Basin

The multi-stakeholder participation mechanism in ecological compensation enhances operational efficiency by reconstructing relationships among governments, enterprises, the public, research institutions, social organizations, and communities. This mechanism fully leverages stakeholders’ comparative advantages, culminating in the establishment of a coordinated framework for the Xin’an River watershed featuring government leadership, public engagement as the main driving force, market and social organization participation, research institutions providing technological empowerment, and rural communities offering foundational support, as illustrated in Figure 2.

4.1. Government: Leader in Ecological Compensation

A review of the history of ecological compensation implementation in the Xin’an River Basin reveals that the government has played a leading role throughout the process. For instance, the central government has been responsible for policy formulation, macro-level regulation, supervision, and the evaluation of local government implementation, while also providing financial compensation. Through the development and implementation of relevant policies—such as the Implementation Plan for the Pilot Program of Water Environment Compensation in the Xin’an River Basin—the central government has offered scientific guidance and strategic direction for ecological compensation work in the basin. Additionally, it has allocated substantial fiscal resources, contributing several hundred million yuan annually for systematic ecological protection and restoration in the Xin’an River region, thereby laying a solid foundation for the successful execution of compensation initiatives.
Local governments, on the other hand, have been tasked with the concrete implementation and execution of specific projects, engaging in ongoing practical exploration. A collaborative yet mutually constraining relationship has emerged between the governments of Huangshan City and Hangzhou City, characterized by joint supervision and reciprocal incentives. Zhejiang Province and Anhui Province have jointly established a horizontally structured ecological compensation mechanism based on “performance-based water quality agreements.” As one of the local governments, Zhejiang Province has contributed CNY 100 million annually since the first pilot phase in 2012, increasing this to CNY 200 million in the second phase (2015–2017), and maintained this amount in the third phase (2018–2020), while also exploring market-oriented compensation mechanisms such as green funds and public–private partnerships (PPP models). Refer to Table 2 for further details.
Additionally, Hangzhou has invested substantial resources in constructing wastewater treatment facilities in Chun’an County (lower Xin’an River), effectively reducing pollutant inflows into Qiandao Lake. Through nine key industrial collaborations with Huangshan City, Hangzhou has committed cumulative investments totaling CNY 21.367 billion (2020–2022), focusing on green industries and eco-agriculture partnerships. Notable examples include Hangzhou enterprises participating in Huangshan’s spring water fish farming and organic tea plantation projects, facilitating ecological product value realization. Huangshan’s municipal and county governments have enacted environmental protection regulations for the upper watershed, mobilized public conservation initiatives, promoted green concepts, and enforced penalties against polluters. These measures comprehensively implement the sustainable development philosophy that “lucid waters and lush mountains are invaluable assets”. Director H from the Xinhua Township, Huangshan City, revealed during field research that recent institutional innovations include the “Ecological Beauty Supermarket” program. This barter-based system incentivizes farmers’ participation in waste sorting and recycling through material exchanges. The government acts as a pioneer, providing financial support, technical expertise, and institutional frameworks to facilitate public engagement in ecological conservation. Furthermore, the joint “Construction Plan for the Pilot Zone of Eco-Cultural Tourism Cooperation in the Adjacent Hangzhou-Huangshan Area” promotes a tourism development pattern characterized by “strengthening twin towns, lake–city synergy, and scenic corridor linkage”, aiming to establish a world-class “West Lake–Huangshan–Qiandao Lake” golden tourism route.
Government-oriented contracts are effective but create financial difficulties; marketization can overcome this problem very well [29]. By integrating environmental governance with industrial development, the watershed promotes corporate engagement in emissions trading and carbon sink markets. Market mechanisms stimulate corporate environmental initiatives, attracting substantial private capital to ecological projects while funding green transitions. This strategy enhances environmental quality and accelerates green economic transformation, presenting a “Chinese solution” for global climate response and sustainable development, exemplifying China’s successful balance between ecological governance and industrial progress.
Understanding public perceptions of ecosystem services is crucial for deploying adaptive management strategies [30,31,32,33]. Governments enhance environmental awareness through education campaigns, empowering communities and social organizations to engage in compensation implementation. Establishing grassroots participation networks ensures public understanding and support, strengthening policy operability and enforcement.

4.2. Public: The Main Force of Ecological Compensation

The public plays a key role in the process of ecological compensation, acting as a driving force. In the case of ecological compensation in the Xin’an River Basin, public participation primarily takes two forms: environmental protection and supervision with feedback. In terms of lifestyle, local residents treat domestic sewage through a comprehensive urban–rural sewage pipeline network that separates rainwater and wastewater. In terms of production practices, a “seven-unification” model for centralized pesticide distribution—covering unified procurement, management, and recycling—has effectively reduced non-point source pollution.
During the authors’ field research in Xiuning District, Huangshan City, it was found that many members of the public exhibited strong environmental awareness. Mr. H, a villager from Wangcun Town, Shexian County, stated that “Why should we protect the environment here? Isn’t it just because we want a cleaner living environment for ourselves? If it were like before, with garbage everywhere and the riverbanks stinking in summer, who could bear it? These past two years the country has started paying attention—look at the roads and riverbanks now, they’re so clean. Life here is more enjoyable too.”.
Mr. C, from Huizhou District, Huangshan City, when talking about participating in ecological governance, said that “As a taxpayer, I have the right to know what the government is doing and how well things are being done. I also hope the voices of the public can be heard by those in power. After all, those projects currently under construction may be temporary concerns for the authorities, but we have to live here long-term.”.
At the same time, the public also supervises the behavior of the government and enterprises and actively provides feedback on the implementation of ecological compensation policies. For instance, a villager in Huangshan City discovered that a local chemical plant was secretly discharging polluted wastewater into a tributary of the Xin’an River at night, leading to fish deaths downstream. He joined with other villagers to report the incident, eventually forcing the plant to shut down for rectification. As one of the participating villagers remarked, “It’s no longer just the government supervising enterprises—our eyes, as ordinary people, are also monitoring devices.”.

4.3. Enterprise: Participant in Ecological Compensation

Enterprises in the Xin’an River watershed ecological compensation framework serve not only as multi-stakeholders but also as market governance participants. While their production activities contribute to regional socio-economic development, they concurrently generate environmental impacts. Corporate engagement manifests in four dimensions: enhancing resource utilization efficiency, reducing pollutant emissions, developing green industries, and participating in ecological restoration projects. Through optimized resource efficiency in production processes, enterprises mitigate overexploitation of natural resources and environmental degradation. For instance, technological innovations in production techniques have enabled certain enterprises to improve energy efficiency while minimizing emissions and waste generation; Mr. Li, R&D Director of YX Enterprise, stated that “We perceive ecological compensation as a transformative opportunity. Confronted with the low competitiveness of traditional high-consumption, high-pollution technologies, our team spent nearly two years achieving breakthroughs in high-performance composite flexible packaging materials. This innovation not only reduced costs and enhanced efficiency, but also secured policy incentives while driving environmental upgrades across the supply chain.”

4.4. Research Institution: Empowerer of Ecological Compensation Technology

Research institutions serve as both technological innovation engines and governance efficiency enhancers in the Xin’an River watershed ecological compensation. Their roles manifest in three dimensions: technological R&D and innovation, ecosystem value accounting for decision-making, and public education. Through technological innovation, research institutions provide solutions for compensation challenges. For instance, low-toxicity pesticide alternatives developed by researchers have reduced pesticide application intensity in Huangshan City by 21.3%, significantly decreasing pollutant influx into the river. Scientific valuation also underpins compensation standard formulation. Collaborative efforts by the Zhejiang Provincial Academy of Ecological and Environmental Sciences, the Zhejiang Ecological Environment Monitoring Center, Zhejiang University, and Zhejiang Gongshang University produced the Technical Guidelines for Agricultural Non-point Source Pollution Investigation and Load Accounting in Zhejiang Province (Trial), standardizing pollution monitoring protocols. Additionally, the Chinese Academy of Environmental Planning quantified the watershed’s ecosystem service value, emphasizing their critical role in water environment compensation mechanisms. Finally, public engagement capacity is enhanced through science outreach. The Qiandao Lake Ecological Monitoring Station regularly publishes water quality reports and disseminates ecological knowledge, strengthening societal monitoring awareness.

4.5. Social Organizations: Promoters of Ecological Compensation

Social organizations assume dual roles as “bridges and facilitators” in the Xin’an River watershed ecological compensation, injecting dynamism and innovation into governance through social mobilization and multi-stakeholder platforms. Their functions encompass three domains: public participation mobilization, institutional optimization promotion, and social oversight reinforcement. Through organizing environmental volunteers for river cleanups and afforestation campaigns, social organizations directly enhance watershed ecology. The “Pure Waters Nurture Xin’an—Protecting the Mother River in Action” initiative employs interactive methods to educate students about watershed characteristics, ancient villages, and conservation narratives. Additionally, establishing the “Hangzhou-Huangshan Joint Expert Committee for Xin’an River-Qiandao Lake Ecological Conservation” has facilitated scientific research and institutional refinement. Finally, independent monitoring systems and public reporting mechanisms improve implementation transparency. The Xinan Village Protection Team conducted over 300 patrol missions (as of October 2024) covering fishing bans, drowning prevention, and ecological tea garden protection, while initiating 10+ special operations for watercourse maintenance and reserve boundary marking. The team member Mr. Sun remarked that “Initially we felt disconnected from river conservation, but now patrols energize us. Lifelong riverside residents clearly perceive environmental improvements, and online visitors’ compliments about our ecosystem fill us with immense pride!”

4.6. Community: Supporters of Ecological Compensation

As direct participants and beneficiaries in the Xin’an River watershed ecological compensation, communities play an indispensable role in reconciling ecological conservation with economic development. Their contributions manifest in pioneering localized compensation models and advancing infrastructure development. Rural communities integrate ecological protection with economic growth through specialized industries like eco-agriculture and eco-tourism. In Shendu Town (She County, Huangshan), the “Spring Water Aquaculture” project has increased farmers’ annual income by 12.7% while reducing chemical fertilizer and pesticide usage by 38%, effectively mitigating agricultural non-point source pollution. Jiukeng Township (Chun’an County, Zhejiang) and Huangtian Township (She County, Anhui) signed the watershed co-governance agreement, collaborating on tea talent cultivation, premium tea variety selection, and cross-regional tourism. Jointly with the County Agriculture Bureau, they formulated the “She County Modern Green Fishery Development Project”, securing funding for prefabricated stinky mandarin fish processing facilities in Tangyue Village, Zhengcun Town. Furthermore, comprehensive sewage pipeline networks enable rainwater–wastewater segregation across urban–rural areas. New rural wastewater treatment terminals achieved 100% standardized operation, with urban treatment rates reaching 98.22% upstream and 97.58% downstream. Municipal solid waste treatment attained full coverage (100%), collectively maintaining the Xin’an River’s Class II water quality standards.

4.7. The Effectiveness of Ecological Compensation Achieved Through Diversified Governance

4.7.1. Ecological Benefit

Water quality improvement constitutes a key achievement since the Xin’an River ecological compensation pilot’s initiation. During the 2012–2021 period, the upper watershed maintained excellent water quality, with the P-index consistently meeting compensation agreement targets. Under the first-phase assessment framework, the p-index decreased from 0.833 (2012) to 0.713 (2021). Analysis of 17-year monitoring data (2005–2021) revealed post-compensation reductions in key parameters: the permanganate index decreased by 28.6%, ammonia nitrogen by 41.2%, and total phosphorus by 33.5%. Qiandao Lake water quality stabilized at Class I, with the trophic state index transitioning to oligotrophic. Huangshan City has achieved marked ecological restoration through watershed compensation implementation. These data were obtained from the official websites of the Huangshan City Government and the Hangzhou City Government. The changes in the p-value of the Xin’an River water can be seen in Figure 3.

4.7.2. Economic Benefits

As previously analyzed, Huangshan City achieved economic transformation under the incentivizing pressure of the contingent compensation mechanism. Economic gains are evidenced by GDP growth: municipal GDP increased from CNY 42.49 billion (2012) to CNY 100.23 billion (2022), with an average annual growth of CNY 5.774 billion. Notably, this growth persisted despite stricter environmental access controls implemented during the pilot phase. This industrial restructuring facilitates green, circular, and low-carbon development patterns. Economic activities demonstrate dual effects on watershed ecology: while potentially enabling ecological restoration, they also drive upstream economic development through productive engagements. Traditional polluting industries are transitioning towards green high-tech sectors, with green food processing, flexible packaging, specialty chemicals, and automotive electronics emerging as four pillar industries. The integration of tourism, culture, and ecology has positioned tertiary industries as the economic growth engine, effectively converting ecological resources into ecological capital. The GDP changes of Huangshan City from 2012 to 2022 are shown in detail in Figure 4. These data were obtained from the official websites of the Huangshan City Government and the Hangzhou City Government.

4.7.3. Social Benefit

Huangshan City’s social benefits from watershed ecological compensation manifest through three primary dimensions: first, poverty reduction effects. During early industrialization phases, compensation investments directly alleviate poverty. Post-industrial upgrading, compensation enhances self-sustaining development capacity through technological/policy interventions improving production conditions and educational investment, thereby intensifying and sustaining poverty reduction impacts. The second dimension is social equity enhancement. Horizontal compensation transfers narrow urban–rural income gaps by facilitating agricultural labor mobility and industrial structure advancement. The third dimension is demonstration effects. The Xin’an River horizontal compensation pilot, recognized as one of Chna’s Top Ten Reform Cases, has established replicable institutional innovations including integrated coordination, the River Chief system, Ecological Beauty Supermarkets, centralized agrochemical distribution, and transboundary pollution control mechanisms, collectively forming the “Xin’an River Model”. Following State Council Document (2016) No. 31, which designated pilot zones in the Yangtze/Yellow/Xin’an River basins and other transprovincial watersheds, over 13 provincial regions have initiated similar pilots adapting this model.

5. Discussion

5.1. Case Revelation

  • The Xin’an River case pioneered a horizontal compensation mechanism centered on the “water quality performance-based agreement”, along with an efficient multi-tiered government collaboration model and the integration of ecological compensation into performance evaluations. These innovations provide a mature template for establishing a transboundary ecological governance system with clearly defined responsibilities and incentive compatibility.
  • The Xin’an River case successfully implemented a governance model moving beyond solely government-led approaches, systematically integrating governments, the public, enterprises, research institutions, social organizations, and communities. This demonstrates that synergizing multiple stakeholders is an effective pathway for achieving sustainable watershed governance. Such a “government–market–society” collaborative model is broadly applicable to diverse public affairs governance contexts.
  • Through initiatives like eco-agriculture, eco-tourism, water rights trading, and carbon sink projects, the Xin’an River case has forged a clear pathway to transform “lucid waters and lush mountains into invaluable assets”. Its mechanism design for realizing ecological product value offers replicable experience for coordinating ecological protection and economic development around the world.

5.2. Policy Suggestion

The multi-stakeholder ecological compensation mechanism in the Xin’an River watershed has effectively improved ecological conditions while promoting equitable socio-economic development. However, cross-provincial watershed compensation nationwide still faces five key constraints: (1) Deficient Public Engagement: Government-dominated compensation frameworks lack effective public benefit mechanisms, resulting in low participation willingness and limited policy awareness in certain regions. (2) Underdeveloped Marketization: Immature market instruments like emissions trading and water rights trading systems show inadequate market participation and vitality. (3) Fragmented Regional Coordination: Disparate economic levels and interest claims between upstream and downstream regions hinder consensus on compensation standards. (4) Insufficient Monitoring Systems: The absence of unified evaluation criteria and opaque fund flows undermine policy credibility. (5) Inequitable Benefit Distribution: Current mechanisms disproportionately favor governments and enterprises, neglecting villagers and social organizations.
To advance multi-stakeholder governance in transprovincial watershed compensation, this study proposes five policy recommendations: (1) Enhance Public Participation: Ecology-oriented development (EOD) pilots should be implemented to innovate upon benefit-sharing mechanisms through interest subsidies, economic incentives, and preferential policies, ensuring tangible public gains [34]. For example, the government can establish regular public consultation meetings, community forums, or collect information on residents’ opinions and needs regarding ecological compensation through surveys. In addition, the government could launch a “Green Jobs” program to provide employment opportunities related to ecological restoration and protection, thereby enhancing the participation incentives for residents in upstream areas. These measures would not only boost public engagement but also strengthen their recognition of the ecological compensation mechanism, thus promoting the long-term sustainability of ecological protection. (2) Accelerate Marketization: Basin-wide market mechanisms as proposed in the Yellow River Ecological Conservation Symposium (12 September 2024) should be established. Emissions trading and water rights markets should be expanded to optimize ecological resource allocation [25]. For instance, in the area of water rights trading, the government could establish an ecological water rights trading platform, allowing upstream regions to receive financial compensation for water-saving efforts, while encouraging downstream regions to achieve a more rational allocation of water resources by purchasing water rights. The government may also encourage enterprises to support ecological compensation through instruments such as green bonds and carbon trading and introduce policies to attract private capital investment in ecological protection projects. These market-oriented approaches will help to diversify the funding sources for ecological compensation, improve resource use efficiency, and stimulate the enthusiasm of enterprises and private investors, thereby advancing the sustainable development of the ecological compensation mechanism. (3) Strengthen Cross-regional Collaboration: Joint compensation policies through upstream–downstream coordination should be developed, while engaging under-represented stakeholders like research institutions and NGOs [35]. For example, the government could establish an ecological compensation performance evaluation fund and regularly commission third-party institutions to conduct independent assessments of project implementation outcomes. Based on the evaluation results, the government can promptly adjust compensation policies and measures. (4) Improve Oversight and Evaluation: Monitoring mechanisms with clear mandates and methods should be established. Triennial assessments covering ecological, economic, and social dimensions should be conducted to inform policy adjustments, and information disclosure should be enhanced through annual compensation implementation reports. Furthermore, a regular cross-regional joint conference system could be established, comprising a consortium of upstream and downstream governments, enterprises, and research institutions, to discuss and determine specific measures related to ecological protection, industrial cooperation, and compensation mechanisms. (5) Optimize Benefit-Sharing Systems: (a) The “Resource Shares + Guaranteed Dividends” model should be adopted, converting villagers’ conservation efforts into equity shares based on forest/water management areas. The government could also sign “Ecological Protection Agreements” with local farmers, granting them a certain shareholding based on their actual participation in the management of forests and water bodies, while ensuring a guaranteed minimum dividend. (b) Value-chain extension mechanisms should be developed, facilitating premium-purchase contracts between eco-agricultural enterprises and farmers for profit-sharing. This dual approach ensures that ecological guardians become economic beneficiaries, realizing the vision that “lucid waters and lush mountains become invaluable assets”.

6. Conclusions

This study systematically investigates the participation mechanisms of multiple stakeholders—including governments, enterprises, the public, research institutions, social organizations, and communities—in transprovincial watershed ecological compensation, using the Xin’an River as a practical case. The research demonstrates the following: (1) The necessity of multi-stakeholder collaboration stems from the attributes of ecological resources as public goods (commonality and externality), requiring cooperative efforts to achieve shared responsibility and cost–benefit equilibrium. (2) The interactive mechanism among stakeholders manifests as a synergistic framework featuring “government leadership, public-driven initiatives, corporate engagement, research empowerment, social organization facilitation, and community support.”. (3) The Xin’an River practice delivers a universally applicable and operational “China’s Approach” whose core experiences offer significant referential value for addressing similar cross-border environmental governance challenges globally. Building on this study, future research could focus on the following aspects: (1) applying quantitative methods to analyze the differences in stakeholder participation in the Xin’an River Basin and (2) conducting comparative studies between the Xin’an River case and other multi-stakeholder participation cases around the world.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Z.C.; methodology, X.C.; investigation, X.C.; resources, Z.C.; data curation, Z.C.; writing—original draft preparation, X.C.; writing—review and editing, Z.C.; visualization, X.C.; supervision, Z.C.; project administration, Z.C.; funding acquisition, Z.C. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was supported by the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (Project No. B240207112) and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (Project No. B240207032).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data and materials are available from the corresponding author upon reasonable request.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that this research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

References

  1. Gao, X.; Shen, J.; He, W.; Sun, F.; Zhang, Z.; Zhang, X.; Zhang, C.; Kong, Y.; An, M.; Yuan, L.; et al. Changes in ecosystem services value and establishment of watershed ecological compensation standards. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 2951. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Costanza, R.; d’Arge, R.; de Groot, R.; Farber, S.; Grasso, M.; Hannon, B.; Limburg, K.; Naeem, S.; O’Neill, R.V.; Paruelo, J.; et al. The value of the world’s ecosystem services and natural capital. Nature 1997, 387, 253–260. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Jiang, Y.; Guan, D.; He, X.; Yin, B.; Zhou, L.; Sun, L.; Huang, D.; Li, Z.; Zhang, Y. Quantification of the coupling relationship between ecological compensation and ecosystem services in the Yangtze River Economic Belt. Land Use Policy 2022, 114, 105995. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Lu, Z.; Wu, X.; Zhang, S.; Li, J.; Cai, F.; Xu, R. A study of ecological compensation in watersheds based on the three-way decisions theory. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 368, 133166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Cheng, X.; Fang, L.; Mu, L.; Li, J.; Wang, H. Watershed eco-compensation mechanism in China: Policies, practices and recommendations. Water 2022, 14, 777. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Brownson, K.; Anderson, E.P.; Ferreira, S.; Wenger, S.; Fowler, L.; German, L. Governance of Payments for Ecosystem Ecosystem services influences social and environmental outcomes in Costa Rica. Ecol. Econ. 2020, 174, 106659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Pagiola, S.; Arcenas, A.; Platais, G. Can Payments for Environmental Services Help Reduce Poverty? An Exploration of the Issues and the Evidence to Date from Latin America. World Dev. 2005, 33, 237–253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Locatelli, B.; Rojas, V.; Salinas, Z. Impacts of Payments for Environmental Services on Local Development in Northern Costa Rica: A Fuzzy Multi-Criteria Analysis. For. Policy Econ. 2008, 10, 275–285. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Landell-Mills, N.; Porras, I.T. Silver Bullet or Fools’ Gold? A Global Review of Markets for Forest Environmental Services and Their Impact on the Poor; International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED): London, UK, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  10. Adams, W.M.; Aveling, R.; Brockington, D. Biodiversity Conservation and the Eradication of Poverty. Science 2004, 306, 1146–1149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  11. Rao, Q.H.; Lin, X.Z.; Qiu, Y.; Chen, F. Research on ecological compensation standard in Minjiang River basin based on opportunity cost. Mar. Environ. Sci. 2018, 37, 655–662. [Google Scholar]
  12. Ni, Q.; Xu, T.; Li, X.; Liu, J.; Zhao, M. Transboundary river basin ecological compensation standard accounting: Based on cost-benefit perspective. Resour. Environ. Yangtze Basin. 2021, 30, 97–110. [Google Scholar]
  13. Salamon, L.M.; Sokolowski, S.W.; Haddock, M.A. Measuring the economic value of volunteer work globally: Concepts, estimates, and a roadmap to the future. Ann. Public Coop. Econ. 2011, 82, 217–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Chen, S.Q.; Qin, F.Q. Fiscal ecological compensation: A theoretical logic. J. Cent. Univ. Financ. Econ. 2022, 11, 17–25. [Google Scholar]
  15. Qin, C.; Jia, J. Grain for green programme: Environment recovery and income growth. Soft Sci. 2017, 7, 126–138. [Google Scholar]
  16. Boisvert, V.; Méral, P.; Froger, G. Market-based instruments for ecosystem services: Institutional innovation or renovation? Soc. Nat. Resour. 2013, 26, 1122–1136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Ansell, C.; Gash, A. Collaborative governance in theory and practice. J. Public Adm. Res. Theory 2008, 18, 543–571. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Sheng, J.; Qiu, W.; Han, X. China’s PES-like horizontal eco-compensation program: Combining market-oriented mechanisms and government interventions. Ecosyst. Serv. 2020, 45, 101164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Ren, Y.; Lu, L.; Yu, H.; Zhu, D. Game strategies in government-led eco-compensation in the Xin’an River Basin from the perspective of the politics of scale. J. Geogr. Sci. 2021, 31, 1205–1221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Yu, H.; Chen, C.; Shao, C.F. Spatial and temporal changes in ecosystem service driven by ecological compensation in the Xin’an River Basin, China. Ecol. Indic. 2023, 146, 109798. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Bennett, D.E.; Gosnell, H. Integrating multiple perspectives on payments for ecosystem services through a social-ecological systems framework. Ecol. Econ. 2015, 116, 172–181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Qiao, X.N.; Yang, Y.J.; Yang, D.G. Review of payments for ecosystem services and the key issues in a watershed. Prog. Geogr. 2012, 31, 395–402. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  23. Zhang, Y.; Min, Q.; Bai, Y.; Li, X. Practices of Cooperation for Eco-environmental Conservation (CEC) in China and theoretic framework of CEC: A new perspective. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 179, 515–526. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Holtermann, S.E. Externalities and public goods. Economica 1972, 39, 78–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Uzoigwe, M.U. Exploring Multi-Stakeholder Initiatives for Natural Resource Governance: The Example of the Nigerian Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (NEITI). Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Birmingham, Birmingham, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  26. Ostrom, E. A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of collective action: Presidential address, American Political Science Association. Am. Political Sci. Rev. 1998, 92, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Liu, S.; Zhang, H.; Jiang, G. Spatiotemporal coupling and regional differences analysis between agricultural land use efficiency and rural revitalization in the Yellow River Basin. Sci. Rep. 2025, 15, 11348. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  28. Razzaque, J.; Richardson, B. Public participation in environmental decision-making. In Environmental Law for Sustanibility; Bloomsbury Academic: London, UK, 2006; pp. 165–194. [Google Scholar]
  29. Jiang, K.; Wang, D.; Wang, Y. Individual participation and incentive coordination in watershed ecological compensation project: Insights from China’s Xin’an River Basin pilot. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. Int. 2023, 30, 32799–32813. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Li, Y.; Jin, L. Recreational Value of Rural Areas Based on Tourists’ Behavior: The Example of Yanqing County. Tour. Trib. 2016, 31, 76–84. [Google Scholar]
  31. Washbourne, C.L.; Goddard, M.A.; Le Provost, G.; Manning, D.A.C.; Manning, P. Trade-offs and synergies in the ecosystem service demand of urban brownfield stakeholders. Ecosyst. Serv. 2020, 42, 101074. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Wilhelm, J.A.; Smith, R.G.; Jolejole-Foreman, M.C.; Hurley, S. Resident and stakeholder perceptions of ecosystem services associated with agricultural landscapes in New Hampshire. Ecosyst. Serv. 2020, 45, 101153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Su, Y.; Zhu, C.; Lin, L.; Wang, C.; Jin, C.; Cao, J.; Li, T.; Su, C. Assessing the Cultural Ecosystem Services Value of Protected Areas Considering Stakeholders’ Preferences and Trade-Offs—Taking the Xin’an River Landscape Corridor Scenic Area as an Example. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 13968. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  34. Zhao, J.; Ge, Y.; Li, Y. Fairness perception, social trust, and public participation in watershed eco-compensation. China Popul. Resour. Environ. 2023, 33, 196. [Google Scholar]
  35. Yu, Z.; Zhao, Q. Research on the coordinated governance mechanism of cross-regional and cross-basin ecological compensation in the Yangtze River Delta. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 9881. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
Figure 1. Overview map of the Xin’an River Basin [20].
Figure 1. Overview map of the Xin’an River Basin [20].
Sustainability 17 07057 g001
Figure 2. Schematic diagram of the multi-stakeholder participation mechanism in the Xin’an River watershed’s ecological compensation.
Figure 2. Schematic diagram of the multi-stakeholder participation mechanism in the Xin’an River watershed’s ecological compensation.
Sustainability 17 07057 g002
Figure 3. Variation diagram of p values in Xin’an River waters.
Figure 3. Variation diagram of p values in Xin’an River waters.
Sustainability 17 07057 g003
Figure 4. Huangshan city GDP trend chart (2012–2022) (unit: CNY 100 million).
Figure 4. Huangshan city GDP trend chart (2012–2022) (unit: CNY 100 million).
Sustainability 17 07057 g004
Table 1. Summary of multi-stakeholder participation motivations.
Table 1. Summary of multi-stakeholder participation motivations.
StakeholderCore Needs
GovernmentsEcological Conservation and Governance
Economic Development with Livelihood Improvement
Rational Fund Allocation with Supervision
PublicDemands for Quality Living Environments
Information Accessibility and Participatory Rights
CorporateAccess to Ecological Resources
Social Responsibility Fulfillment
Research InstitutionTechnological Conversion Benefits
Social Responsibility Incentives
Social OrganizationSocial Benefit Maximization
Value-Role Alignment
CommunityEconomic Returns
Environmental Well-being
Table 2. Funding sources and scale in the first three pilot rounds.
Table 2. Funding sources and scale in the first three pilot rounds.
PhaseFunding SourcesFunding ScaleTotal Funding
Round 1 (2012–2014)Central Government, Zhejiang and Anhui Provincial GovernmentsCentral fiscal support: CNY 300 million/year;
Zhejiang and Anhui: CNY 100 million/year each
CNY 15 billion
Round 2 (2015–2017)Central Government, Zhejiang and Anhui Provincial GovernmentsCentral fiscal support: CNY 400, 300, and 200 (phased reduction);
Zhejiang and Anhui: CNY 200 million/year each
CNY 21 billion
Round 3 (2018–2020)Central Government, Zhejiang and Anhui Provincial GovernmentsZhejiang and Anhui: CNY 200 million/year eachCNY 20 billion
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Cao, Z.; Chen, X. Study of Multi-Stakeholder Mechanism in Inter-Provincial River Basin Eco-Compensation: Case of the Inland Rivers of Eastern China. Sustainability 2025, 17, 7057. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17157057

AMA Style

Cao Z, Chen X. Study of Multi-Stakeholder Mechanism in Inter-Provincial River Basin Eco-Compensation: Case of the Inland Rivers of Eastern China. Sustainability. 2025; 17(15):7057. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17157057

Chicago/Turabian Style

Cao, Zhijie, and Xuelong Chen. 2025. "Study of Multi-Stakeholder Mechanism in Inter-Provincial River Basin Eco-Compensation: Case of the Inland Rivers of Eastern China" Sustainability 17, no. 15: 7057. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17157057

APA Style

Cao, Z., & Chen, X. (2025). Study of Multi-Stakeholder Mechanism in Inter-Provincial River Basin Eco-Compensation: Case of the Inland Rivers of Eastern China. Sustainability, 17(15), 7057. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17157057

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop