1. Introduction
Population aging is central to achieving key United Nations Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs), such as SDG 8 (Decent Work and Economic Growth), SDG 9 (Industry, Innovation, and Infrastructure), and SDG 10 (Reduced Inequalities) (data are sourced from the Sustainable Development Goals platform (
https://sdgs.un.org/goals, accessed on 31 March 2025). As the share of elderly individuals rises, population aging increasingly shapes labor market dynamics, industrial competitiveness, and income distribution—thereby influencing the realization of these SDGs. Specifically, it affects the availability of productive labor (SDG 8), firms’ demand for technological upgrading (SDG 9), and intergenerational equity (SDG 10). Population aging represents one of the most significant demographic trends in the 21st century, particularly in China, where the rapid decline in fertility rates and increased life expectancy have led to profound societal and economic transformations. China’s population is aging at an accelerated pace, having already reached an upper-middle level globally. Between 1953 and 2021, China’s population aged 65 and above increased from 26.32 million to 200 million, or from 4.4 percent to 14.2 percent. Historically, the degree of aging increased by 0.15, 0.18 and 0.46 percentage points per year, respectively, from 1990 to 2000, from 2000 to 2010 and from 2010 to 2020, indicating a significant acceleration of aging (data are sourced from the National Bureau of Statistics of China (
http://www.stats.gov.cn, accessed on 22 November 2024). This demographic shift presents both risks and strategic opportunities: while a shrinking workforce may dampen output potential [
1,
2,
3], firms can respond by adopting automation [
4,
5,
6,
7], investing in capital, and optimizing their production technologies [
6]. This paper investigates whether population aging causally improves firm-level labor productivity in China and to what extent this relationship is mediated by capital deepening. Grounded in the neoclassical production framework, we theorize that firms facing reduced labor availability will adjust input ratios by raising capital intensity, thereby enhancing productivity.
To empirically identify this relationship, we employ firm-level panel data and use fixed-effects models to address unobserved time-invariant heterogeneity. We further adopt mediation models to assess the role of capital–labor ratio as a transmission channel, and conduct robustness checks using dynamic panel methods to strengthen the causal interpretation.
Labor productivity, a cornerstone of economic efficiency, directly influences competitiveness, innovation, and sustainable development [
8,
9,
10]. Recent research underscores the critical influence of demographic changes on productivity dynamics. Firstly, population aging leads to a shortage of young workers, and firms will replace them with more machinery. Population aging reduces the working-age population, leading to labor shortages [
11,
12,
13], particularly in sectors reliant on manual and repetitive tasks. Ref. [
4] finds that population aging drives the increased adoption of robots and other automation technologies, as the decline in middle-aged workers engaged in manual production tasks necessitates automation, and aging populations correlate with higher adoption rates of robots and automation technologies globally. Fortunately, automation technologies often improve labor productivity by substituting labor with capital [
14]. Prior research also emphasizes that aging or health-vulnerable populations tend to exhibit reduced resilience in the face of external risks, including environmental and institutional shocks [
15]. This underscores the need to consider human capital fragility when analyzing the labor productivity implications of demographic aging.
Further, the effect of population aging on the improvement of labor productivity varies across different countries and regions [
3,
4,
5,
6,
16,
17,
18]. Cross-country studies show that institutional quality, human capital levels, and technological absorptive capacity mediate this relationship [
3,
4,
5,
16,
17]. Within China, similar heterogeneity is observed: while developed coastal provinces benefit from aging-induced automation and capital deepening, rural and inland regions often experience productivity stagnation or decline [
6,
18,
19,
20].
Additionally, China’s vast size and uneven distribution of population and resources create major differences across regions, leading to significant regional and industrial variations in labor productivity [
6,
7,
20,
21]. Thus, when exploring the relationship between population aging and labor productivity, it is crucial to consider regional and industrial variability. Ref. [
18] finds population aging has a significant positive impact on economic growth, which promotes economic growth in more developed regions as well as in rural areas [
19]. However, there are few studies on how China’s population aging affects corporate labor productivity. This paper addresses this research gap by empirically testing a structured causal pathway, where capital–labor ratio serves as a theoretically grounded mediator linking aging to productivity outcomes. This study investigated the impact of population aging on corporate labor productivity using fixed-effects models and mediation models for econometric regressions, with a specific focus on the mediating role of the capital–labor ratio. The rationale for using capital–labor ratio lies in its central role in neoclassical and endogenous growth models, where firms re-optimize input factors in response to demographic shocks. Additionally, heterogeneous effects of population aging on corporate labor productivity are examined in greater detail.
As a result, our work contributes in the following three ways to this increasing knowledge: First, this study employs firm-level data from Chinese listed companies and fixed-effect and mediation econometric models to determine the effect of population aging on corporate labor productivity. Second, we also find out the effects of aging vary across regions, industries, and skill levels, underscoring the heterogeneous nature of its economic implications. Finally, we investigate the significant positive impact on labor productivity is primarily mediated through increases in the capital–labor ratio.
The structure of this paper is as follows:
Section 2 provides a review of the relevant literature on labor productivity and the capital–labor ratio, followed by the development of the research hypotheses.
Section 3 outlines the data, empirical methodology, and variable definitions.
Section 4 presents the empirical findings and their implications.
Section 5 provides a detailed analysis of robustness checks and performs the mechanism analysis. Finally,
Section 6 summarizes the key findings and offers policy recommendations.
3. Materials and Methods
3.1. Data Sources
This study is conducted using a sample of Chinese listed companies from 2011 to 2018, a period characterized by significant demographic transitions and structural economic changes in China.We focus on this period because the data quality and consistency are well established, and the sample already provides sufficient variation and robustness to support the study’s main conclusions. The choice of listed companies is appropriate for this analysis as population aging, treated as an exogenous variable, allows for a clearer assessment of its effects on firm-level dynamics.
Firm-level data are sourced from the CSMAR and WIND databases (firm-level data are sourced from the CSMAR database (
https://data.csmar.com, accessed on 22 November 2024) and WIND database (
https://www.wind.com.cn, accessed on 22 November 2024).), while demographic statistics, including measures of population aging such as the proportion of the elderly population to the working-age population (
Old_depth), are obtained from the National Bureau of Statistics of China (region-level data are sourced from the National Bureau of Statistics of China (
http://www.stats.gov.cn, accessed on 22 November 2024).
These regional-level demographic indicators are merged with firm-level data based on the location of corporate headquarters, facilitating the analysis of the spillover effects of aging on firm operations.
To ensure the accuracy and robustness of the analysis, continuous variables are winsorized at the top and bottom 1% percentiles to mitigate the influence of outliers, which could skew regression results and lead to biased estimates. Firms in the financial sector are excluded due to their distinct regulatory and operational frameworks, which differ substantially from non-financial industries. Companies listed on the risk warning board during any sample year are excluded to avoid potential biases arising from financial instability. Delisted firms are removed to ensure data continuity and to focus on active market participants. Observations with missing key variables, such as labor productivity, demographic measures, or financial indicators, are excluded to maintain data integrity.
After applying these exclusions and refinements, the final dataset comprises 3076 listed companies, resulting in 18,775 firm-year observations. This dataset provides a comprehensive and representative sample for analyzing the relationship between population aging and labor productivity. The firm-year structure enables a robust panel data analysis, accounting for both cross-sectional and temporal variations.
3.2. Econometric Model
To explore the mechanism through which population aging affects firm-level labor productivity, we adopt a causal mediation analysis framework. Specifically, we test whether the firm’s capital–labor ratio, proxied by , mediates the relationship between aging and productivity.
We estimate the following set of fixed-effects panel regression models:
In the mediation framework, the dependent variable
denotes the labor productivity of firm
i in year
t, measured by the firm’s operating revenue per employee [
17,
22]. This indicator captures the efficiency of labor input in generating output and is widely used in productivity analyses at the firm level. The key explanatory variable
reflects the depth of population aging in province
p during year
t. It is defined as the old-age dependency ratio, i.e., the proportion of individuals aged 65 and above relative to the working-age population (15–64 years old). This variable captures demographic pressure at the regional level and is matched to firm-level data based on geographic location. The mediating variable
, proxied by the firm-level capital–labor ratio. Specifically, it is calculated as the ratio of fixed assets to the number of employees, capturing the extent of capital deepening at the firm level. This variable represents the firm’s strategic response to demographic changes via technology and capital investment. The control vector
includes a comprehensive set of firm-specific covariates that may influence both productivity and capital intensity. Specifically, we control for return on assets (roa) to capture firm profitability, leverage ratio (lev) to account for financial risk, firm size (size) measured by total assets, and capital intensity (ppe) proxied by net fixed assets. We also include cash holdings (cash) as an indicator of liquidity and Tobin’s Q (tq) to reflect a firm’s investment opportunities and market expectations. Macroeconomic and regional characteristics are controlled for by including provincial GDP growth (gdp) and average regional wages (avgwage), ensuring that local labor market conditions and economic development are accounted for. Year fixed effects (
) and industry fixed effects (
) are included to absorb time-varying macroeconomic shocks and unobserved sectoral heterogeneity. Firm-level robust standard errors clustered over time are used to mitigate issues related to heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation.
Equation (
1) estimates the total effect of aging on productivity. Equation (
2) tests whether aging significantly increases the capital–labor ratio. Equation (
3) evaluates whether the inclusion of
old_depth attenuates the effect of aging, providing evidence of a mediation mechanism. A reduction in the magnitude of
compared with
, along with a statistically significant
, supports the hypothesis that aging indirectly improves productivity through capital deepening.
Endogeneity may arise in this study due to several potential sources, including omitted variable bias, simultaneity, and reverse causality. To address these concerns, we adopt a multipronged identification strategy. First, we include firm fixed effects to absorb time-invariant unobserved heterogeneity across firms, and year fixed effects to account for macroeconomic shocks common to all firms in a given year. Second, we lag the key explanatory variable in alternative specifications to mitigate contemporaneous feedback effects. Third, we conduct multiple robustness checks. Fourth, we employ a system GMM estimator, using lagged dependent variables as instruments to address potential endogeneity arising from reverse causality and omitted variable bias.
We also test the stationarity of key variables given the panel structure of our data. As our panel is unbalanced and includes missing periods, we apply the Fisher-type unit root test based on the Phillips–Perron approach, which accommodates unbalanced panels. For
labprod, the test rejects the null hypothesis of a unit root at the 1% level across all statistics (Inverse chi-squared, Inverse normal, Inverse logit, and modified chi-squared), as shown in
Table 1. This provides strong evidence that labor productivity is stationary over time, validating the use of fixed-effects estimation in the main regressions.
3.3. Variable Selection
3.3.1. Core Explanatory Variables
The dependent variable,
, measures the labor productivity of firm
i in year
t. Following the methodology of [
39], it is calculated as the natural logarithm of the firm’s per capita operating revenue. This approach provides a consistent and robust measure of labor productivity, capturing variations in firms’ operational efficiency across years and regions.
The primary explanatory variable, , represents the old-age dependency ratio in province p, where firm i is located in year t. The old-age dependency ratio, defined as the proportion of elderly individuals (aged 65 and above) to the working-age population (aged 15–64), serves as a key indicator of population aging. By linking provincial demographic trends to firm-level productivity, captures the external pressures of aging on corporate performance.
3.3.2. Mediating Variable
The mediating variable,
, represents the capital–labor ratio of firm
i in year
t.
is constructed to reflect the per capita capital holdings within firms [
40]. It is calculated as net fixed assets over the number of employees. As a critical mechanism linking population aging to labor productivity, the capital–labor ratio highlights firms’ strategic adjustments in response to demographic shifts, such as increased investment in capital to compensate for labor shortages.
3.3.3. Other Control Variables
To ensure robustness and mitigate potential omitted variable bias, this study incorporates a comprehensive set of control variables, capturing both firm-level characteristics and regional macroeconomic conditions. The return on assets () is calculated as the ratio of pre-tax profits to total assets at year-end, reflecting the profitability of the firm. The leverage ratio () is defined as the ratio of total liabilities to total assets at year-end, capturing the firm’s financial structure. Fixed asset intensity () is measured as the net value of fixed assets divided by total assets at year-end, indicating the degree of capital intensity. The cash ratio () is calculated as the ratio of total cash to current liabilities at year-end, providing an indication of liquidity. Firm size () is measured as the natural logarithm of total assets at year-end, representing the scale of the firm. The book-to-market ratio () is calculated as the ratio of the firm’s total market capitalization to net assets at year-end, reflecting the valuation of the firm. Tobin’s Q () is defined as the ratio of market value to the difference between total assets and the net value of intangible assets and goodwill, serving as a proxy for growth opportunities. The independent director ratio () is calculated as the proportion of independent directors on the board, indicating governance quality. Finally, ownership concentration () is measured as the proportion of shares held by the largest shareholder relative to total shares outstanding, capturing the degree of control exerted by major shareholders. To account for regional macroeconomic conditions, additional controls include the GDP growth rate () of the city where the firm is registered and the local wage level (), measured as the natural logarithm of the average wage of employees in the firm’s province.
5. Results—Robust Test
5.1. Robustness Test: Changing the Dependent Variable
To ensure the robustness of the baseline results, this study employs an alternative measure of labor productivity (
), defined as the natural logarithm of a firm’s operating revenue minus non-operating income, divided by the number of employees. By excluding non-operating income, this adjusted measure better reflects changes in firms’ productivity attributable to regular production and operational efficiency. The regression results using
as the dependent variable are presented in
Table 4.
Across all three model specifications, the coefficient for remains positive and statistically significant. Specifically, in Model (1), the coefficient is significant at the level, while in Models (2) and (3), the significance improves to , with the coefficients increasing in magnitude from 0.0112 to 0.0147. Specifically, a 1% increase in the old-age dependency ratio significantly increases the adjusted labor productivity of firms by 1.47%. The values increase significantly from Model (1) (0.0116) to Model (3) (0.3453), indicating that the inclusion of firm-level controls and fixed effects substantially improves the explanatory power of the model. This highlights the importance of firm-specific and industry-level characteristics in explaining labor productivity variations.
These results confirm that population aging, proxied by the old-age dependency ratio, consistently enhances firm-level labor productivity, even when using a refined productivity measure.
5.2. Robustness Test: Changing the Independent Variable
To further validate the relationship between population aging and labor productivity, the primary explanatory variable
is replaced with
, defined as the proportion of the elderly population (aged 65 and above) to the total population. This alternative measure provides a broader perspective on population aging, allowing for a more comprehensive assessment of its impact. The regression results, presented in
Table 5, confirm the robustness of the findings across this alternative specification.
The coefficient for is consistently positive and statistically significant at the level across all three models, indicating a positive relationship between the proportion of the elderly population and labor productivity. These results verify the relationship between population aging and labor productivity when changing the independent variable.
5.3. Robustness Test: Placebo Tests
Two methods were used to perform the placebo test. Firstly, we conduct a permutation test on the explanatory variable and the dependent variable separately. Columns (1) and (2) of
Table 6 permute the core explanatory variable (old-age dependency ratio). The regression results indicate that the explanatory variable after random permutation has no significant impact on labor productivity. Columns (5) and (6) permute the dependent variables (labprod and labprod_adjust). The regression results indicate that the old-age dependency ratio has no significant effect on the dependent variables after random permutation. The permutation test enhances the robustness of regression results. Secondly, the placebo test is added by replacing the old dependency ratio with the child-age dependency ratio in some areas to construct a false explanatory variable. Columns (3) and (4) replace the old-age dependency ratio (top 75%) above 11% with the child-age dependency ratio to construct a false explanatory variable. The insignificant regression results enhance the robustness of the baseline regression.
5.4. Robustness Test: Delayed Effects of Aging
To evaluate the delayed effect of aging, this paper replaces the explanatory variable in the fixed-effects model with a lagged old-age dependency ratio. Columns (1) and (2) of
Table 7 indicate that the lagged old-age dependency ratio has a significant positive impact on labor productivity, and the coefficient is similar to the benchmark regression results. Specifically, a 1% increase in the lagged old-age dependency ratio significantly increases the labor productivity of firms by 1.26%. The regression results in
Table 7 indicate that aging has a delayed effect on labor productivity, as it takes some time for firms to optimize their factor structure to cope with the impact of population aging.
5.5. Robustness Test: Capital-Intensive vs. Labor-Intensive Firms
Population aging reduces labor supply, increasing the labor cost of firms [
43]. Besides, the increase in the age of workers will reduce labor productivity, especially for manual workers [
24,
26]. According to microeconomic principles, a change in the price of one factor of production will cause a change in the demand for another factor, known as the substitution effect between factors of production. In order to save employment costs, labor-intensive firms that rely more on labor input are more incentivized to replace labor with capital and actively transition from labor-intensive production methods to capital-intensive production methods, thereby improving labor productivity. To examine the heterogeneity of firms in the impact of population aging on labor productivity, firms are classified into capital-intensive and labor-intensive groups. To examine the heterogeneity of firms in the impact of population aging on labor productivity, firms are classified into capital-intensive and labor-intensive groups (capital intensity = total assets/operating revenue; labor intensity = the number of employees/operating revenue). The separate regressions are run for each group using both
and
as dependent variables.
Table 8 shows the coefficient for
is negative but statistically insignificant in both the
(Model 1) and
(Model 3) regressions, which suggests that for capital-intensive firms, population aging does not significantly impact labor productivity. In contrast, for labor-intensive firms, the coefficient for
is positive and highly significant (
) in both the
(Model 2) and
(Model 4) regressions, indicating that as population aging intensifies, labor-intensive firms experience significant productivity gains.Specifically, a 1% increase in the old-age dependency ratio significantly increases the labor productivity of labor-intensive firms by 0.67%.
Table 8 shows that population aging has a more direct impact on labor-intensive firms; therefore, under the pressure brought by population aging, labor-intensive firms can invest more capital and then improve labor productivity. For capital-intensive firms, due to less reliance on the input of labor factors, the impact of population aging shocks on them is small, and there is no incentive for capital deepening.
5.6. Robustness Test: Distinguishing Skilled Workers
Compared with the high-skilled labor market, population aging is more likely to impact the low-skilled labor market, resulting in a shortage of low-skilled workers, such as the shortage of migrant workers in China [
7]. For firms with a higher proportion of low-skilled workers, the shortage of young workers in the labor market will increase the employment cost. Besides, the increase in the proportion of elderly workers will push up medical and welfare expenditures, causing the relative price of labor factors to rise [
45]. Therefore, firms with a higher proportion of low-skilled workers are more willing to replace labor with capital, thus improving labor productivity. To examine the heterogeneous effects of population aging on labor productivity across different worker skill levels, firms are categorized into groups based on the proportion of high-skilled workers (high-skilled worker proportion is defined as the ratio of employees with a bachelor’s degree or higher to the total number of employees). Firms with a higher proportion of such employees are classified as employing high-skilled workers, while others are categorized as employing low-skilled workers.
Table 9 presents the regression results for these two subsamples using
labprod and
labprod_adjust as dependent variables.
As for the low-skilled workers group, the coefficient of is positive and statistically significant in both (Model 1, ) and (Model 3, ) regressions. Specifically, the coefficients are 0.0084 in Model 1 and 0.0211 in Model 3, indicating that population aging has a strong positive effect on the productivity of firms with a higher proportion of low-skilled workers. Specifically, a 1% increase in the old-age dependency ratio significantly increases the labor productivity of firms with a higher proportion of low-skilled workers by 0.84%. This suggests that population aging compels firms with low-skilled labor to enhance labor productivity.
For firms with a higher proportion of high-skilled workers, the coefficient for is statistically insignificant in both (Model 2) and (Model 4). The coefficients are −0.0024 in Model 2 and 0.0059 in Model 4, suggesting that population aging has a negligible direct impact on the productivity of high-skilled workers, which implies that firms with a high proportion of skilled employees are less affected by aging-related labor market dynamics, potentially due to their reliance on advanced skills and knowledge rather than manual labor. Compared with firms with a higher proportion of low-skilled workers, firms with a higher proportion of skilled workers usually do not rely on physical labor for production, making the impact of aging on labor productivity relatively limited, thus having no incentive to further substitute capital for labor.
5.7. Robustness Test: City-Level Heterogeneity in Population Aging Effects
The differences in industrial structure and talent structure among different types of cities have led to differences in the cost of technological upgrading for firms in response to the impact of aging. Generally speaking, big cities are dominated by financial and high-tech industries and are more able to attract young and creative talent. The aging population is forcing companies to accelerate technological substitution, and young and creative talent structures are more likely to lead and adapt to technological changes [
46], offsetting the negative impact of aging. However, small cities are mainly dominated by traditional manufacturing, making it difficult to attract young and creative talents. The cost of technological upgrading is high, and it is difficult to achieve capital substitution under the impact of an aging population. To examine the heterogeneous effects of population aging (old_depth) on labor productivity (labprod) across different city tiers, as defined by the “City Business Attractiveness Ranking” published by Yicai’s New First-Tier Cities Research Institute. Cities are classified into first-tier (including new first-tier cities), second-tier, and third-tier cities.
To examine the heterogeneous effects of population aging (
) on labor productivity (
) across different city tiers, as defined by the “City Business Attractiveness Ranking” published by Yicai’s New First-Tier Cities Research Institute. Cities are classified into first-tier (including new first-tier cities), second-tier, and third-tier cities. To account for unobserved city-specific factors, city fixed effects are included in all regressions.
Table 10 presents the results for the full sample and each city tier.
For all samples (Column 1), the coefficient for is positive and statistically significant (), suggesting that population aging has an overall positive impact on labor productivity across all city tiers, reflecting the broader structural adjustments and technological advancements triggered by demographic shifts in urban economies.
For first-tier cities (Column 2), the coefficient for remains positive and significant () and is slightly larger than that for the full sample, indicating that first-tier cities, with their advanced economic infrastructure and access to resources, benefit more from aging-related productivity enhancements. These cities are likely to leverage better technology adoption, skilled labor, and institutional frameworks to mitigate the challenges of an aging workforce. Further, the coefficient for for first-tier cities (Column 2) is even larger and remains highly significant (), which suggests that second-tier cities may experience the most pronounced productivity gains from population aging.Specifically, a 1% increase in the old-age dependency ratio significantly increases the labor productivity of firms in first-tier cities by 1.59% and increases the labor productivity of firms in second-tier cities by 2.36%. As transitional economies, these cities are increasingly adopting automation and other efficiency-enhancing technologies to address labor shortages, resulting in substantial productivity improvements.
In contrast, for the third-tier cities (Column 4), the coefficient for is statistically insignificant, indicating no measurable effect of aging on labor productivity in third-tier cities. This result may reflect the limited economic diversification, inadequate resources, and slower adoption of advanced technologies in these cities. The constrained ability to invest in education, infrastructure, and industrial upgrades hampers their capacity to transform demographic challenges into productivity gains. Compared with first-tier and second-tier cities, third-tier cities are dominated by traditional manufacturing and are difficult to attract young and creative talents. Under the impact of aging, the talent structure of these cities increases the cost of technological upgrading and makes it easier to form a low-end lock-in.
The findings reveal substantial heterogeneity in the impact of population aging on labor productivity across city tiers. These insights underscore the importance of tailored policy interventions that consider the unique economic and demographic dynamics of each city tier.
5.8. Mediating Effect of Capital–Labor Ratio
5.8.1. Mediating Econometric Model
The relationship between population aging and labor productivity is deeply rooted in the structural changes brought about by demographic shifts. A declining labor force, driven by aging populations, results in an increase in the capital available per unit of labor, thereby enhancing firm-level productivity. To formally assess the significance of the mediation mechanism, we apply the Sobel test and bootstrapping methods. The Sobel test confirms that the indirect effect of population aging on labor productivity through capital deepening (old_depth) is statistically significant at the 1% level. In addition, we conduct bootstrapping with 1000 replications, which yields similar significance levels and confidence intervals, reinforcing the robustness of the mediating effect.
5.8.2. Results: Mediating Effect of Capital–Labor Ratio
Table 11 presents the analysis of the mediating role of the capital–labor ratio (
) in the relationship between population aging (
) and labor productivity (
and
). The findings provide robust evidence that the capital–labor ratio serves as a significant channel through which aging impacts productivity.
Model (1) demonstrates that has a positive and statistically significant effect on (). This indicates that population aging leads to an increase in the capital–labor ratio. The result aligns with the hypothesis that firms respond to labor shortages caused by aging populations by increasing capital investments relative to labor inputs, thereby raising capital intensity. The inclusion of clr in models (2) and (3) significantly reduces the explanatory power of , providing strong evidence for its mediating role. In Models (2) and (3), the inclusion of as a mediating variable substantially alters the relationship between and labor productivity: The direct effect of on both and becomes statistically insignificant (), indicating that the impact of aging on productivity is fully mediated by the capital–labor ratio. itself exhibits a strong positive and significant effect on both () and (). This confirms that a higher capital–labor ratio enhances labor productivity, acting as the primary mechanism through which aging influences productivity outcomes.
These results confirm the centrality of the capital–labor ratio as a mediating variable in Hypothesis 2. Population aging prompts firms to increase capital investment relative to labor, mitigating the adverse effects of labor shortages. The increased capital–labor ratio directly improves labor productivity, emphasizing the importance of structural adjustments in aging economies.
As shown in
Table 11, we find strong empirical evidence supporting a full mediation mechanism through the capital–labor ratio. In Column (1), the coefficient on
old_depth is positive and statistically significant at the 1% level when regressed on
clr, indicating that population aging leads to greater capital deepening at the firm level. In Column (2), the direct effect of
old_depth on labor productivity is statistically insignificant. However, when
clr is included in Column (3), its coefficient is large and highly significant, while the coefficient on
old_depth remains statistically insignificant. This pattern implies that the influence of population aging on firm productivity is entirely transmitted through changes in capital intensity. These results are consistent with a full mediation relationship, wherein population aging induces capital–labor substitution, and it is this structural shift in input composition—rather than demographic changes per se—that enhances productivity. The dominance of the indirect path via
clr, coupled with the absence of a statistically significant direct effect, confirms the full mediating role of capital deepening in the demographic–productivity nexus.
This finding underscores the need for policies that encourage capital investment and technological advancements to support productivity in aging societies. Investments in automation, infrastructure, and workforce development can help sustain productivity growth amid demographic transitions.
We also conduct a formal Sobel–Goodman mediation analysis to examine whether the capital–labor ratio mediates the impact of population aging (measured by the old-age dependency ratio) on labor productivity.
Table 12 shows a statistically significant indirect effect of 0.0104 (Sobel z = 11.28,
p < 0.001), indicating that a substantial portion of the effect of aging operates through increased capital deepening. The direct effect remains statistically significant at 0.0040 (
p = 0.014), and the total effect is 0.0144. These estimates imply that approximately 72.39% of the total effect is mediated through the capital–labor ratio, and the indirect effect is over 2.6 times larger than the direct effect. This provides strong evidence for partial mediation and supports our theoretical argument that population aging enhances productivity primarily via capital–labor substitution.
Table 13 reports the heterogeneous mediation effects of the capital–labor ratio across labor-intensive and capital-intensive industries. The results show that capital–labor substitution plays a stronger mediating role in labor-intensive industries, where aging significantly increases the capital–labor ratio, which in turn enhances productivity. In contrast, the mediation effect is weaker and statistically insignificant in non-labor-intensive sectors. These findings support the view that demographic pressure amplifies capital deepening, especially where labor is a key input.
Table 14 reports the heterogeneous mediation effects of the capital–labor ratio across city tiers. The results show that the indirect effect of population aging through capital–labor substitution is most evident in first- and second-tier cities, where aging significantly increases the capital–labor ratio, which in turn enhances productivity. In contrast, the mediating channel is weaker in third-tier cities, where the effect of aging on the capital–labor ratio is statistically insignificant. This suggests that capital deepening as a response to demographic pressure is more prevalent in more developed urban areas.
6. Conclusions and Policy Implications
This paper investigates the causal relationship between population aging and labor productivity in China, using firm-level panel data and mediation analysis to reveal how demographic shifts reshape economic outcomes. The findings demonstrate that population aging, as measured by the old-age dependency ratio, significantly enhances labor productivity at the firm level. This positive effect is primarily mediated by an increase in the capital-labor ratio, suggesting that firms respond to labor shortages by deepening capital investments. Approximately 72.4% of the total effect is transmitted through this channel, while the remaining direct effect remains significant, underscoring partial mediation.
Further analyses reveal heterogeneities across firms and regions. Labor-intensive firms and those employing low-skilled workers experience stronger productivity gains, likely due to greater incentives for automation and structural adjustments. In contrast, capital-intensive and high-skilled labor environments show weaker or insignificant effects. Regionally, first- and second-tier cities benefit more from the productivity-enhancing effects of aging, while third-tier cities lag behind due to constraints in technological readiness, fiscal capacity, and human capital. These disparities highlight the importance of localized responses to demographic change.
In light of these findings, policymakers should adopt a multi-pronged approach. First, governments can promote capital investment and automation by offering tax incentives and subsidies, particularly in labor-intensive sectors where demographic pressures are most acute. Second, tailored workforce development programs—especially in third-tier cities—can help adapt labor supply to evolving technological demands. Third, infrastructure investments and targeted industrial policies are crucial to support lagging regions and reduce spatial inequalities. Fourth, innovation policies should prioritize technologies suited to aging societies, including healthcare innovations, elderly care systems, and labor-saving tools. Finally, policy interventions must consider tier-specific urban dynamics to maximize demographic dividends and mitigate structural gaps.
While this study identifies capital deepening as a key mechanism, future research should explore how technological innovation—especially artificial intelligence and advanced automation—interacts with demographic change to influence productivity. As firms increasingly integrate such technologies, the dynamics of aging and productivity may evolve in complex ways across sectors and regions. Additionally, the role of local governance, education systems, and institutional infrastructure in moderating these effects deserves closer attention. Labor market responses, such as workforce restructuring and targeted training strategies, also represent promising avenues for further investigation, particularly in understanding how firms optimize productivity under labor force aging.
In sum, this study provides robust empirical evidence on how population aging can drive firm-level productivity growth through capital accumulation and adaptive restructuring. It also underscores that this demographic transition does not inevitably hinder economic growth; instead, with the right policy mix, it can serve as a catalyst for upgrading industrial capabilities and reducing labor market inefficiencies. By addressing the structural, spatial, and institutional aspects of demographic change, this work contributes to advancing Sustainable Development Goals 8 (Decent Work and Economic Growth), 9 (Industry, Innovation, and Infrastructure), and 10 (Reduced Inequalities).