Next Article in Journal
Influence of National Culture in Companies with Different Ownership on Employees’ CSR Perception in a Developing Country: The Case of Serbia
Previous Article in Journal
Reliability Analysis of an Embankment Built and Reinforced in Soft Ground Using LE and FE
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Digital Paradox: Platform Economy and High-Quality Economic Development—New Evidence from Provincial Panel Data in China

1
Xinjiang Innovation Management Research Center, Xinjiang University, Urumqi 830046, China
2
School of Economics and Management, Xinjiang University, Urumqi 830046, China
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2022, 14(4), 2225; https://doi.org/10.3390/su14042225
Submission received: 21 December 2021 / Revised: 20 January 2022 / Accepted: 3 February 2022 / Published: 16 February 2022
(This article belongs to the Topic Big Data and Artificial Intelligence)

Abstract

:
Based on provincial panel data of China from 2011 to 2019, this paper discusses the influence and mechanism of the platform economy on the high-quality development of regional economies. It is found that the platform economy has an inverted U-shaped impact on the high-quality development of regional economies. On the left side of the inverted U-shaped inflection point, the platform economy plays a significant role in promoting high-quality economic development; on the right side of the inflection point, the platform economy has an obvious inhibitory effect on high-quality economic development. Statistical analysis showed that 85% of the observations fell on the left side of the inflection point, indicating that China’s platform economy as a whole is in the early stages of development. From the strong and weak grouping test of the degree of government intervention, it was found that the platform economy only has an inverted U-shaped effect on the high-quality development of the areas with weak intervention. From the point of view of the coefficient, the platform economy has a greater promoting effect on the high-quality development of the areas with strong intervention. From the grouping test of the quality of the market system, it was found that the inverted U-shaped curve is steeper in the areas with higher institutional quality, indicating that, in the early stage of development, the platform economy has a greater promoting effect on the high-quality development of areas with perfect institutions. In addition, the analysis of regional heterogeneity showed that, in the early stage of development, the promoting effect of the platform economy on the high-quality development of the northeastern and western regions is more significant. After exceeding the threshold, the platform economy has an inhibitory effect on the high-quality development of all regions. The mechanism test shows that technology, talent, and capital in the initial stage of development can all play a positive regulatory role; after exceeding the threshold, platform economic monopoly may restrain high-quality economic development by hindering technological progress and causing a mismatch of labor–capital elements and resources.

1. Introduction

The Fifth Plenary session of the 19th CPC Central Committee further stressed that, in order to promote high-quality development as the theme of economic and social development during the 14th five-year plan period, we must put the quality of development in a more prominent position and strive to improve the quality and efficiency of development. At the same time, the new round of scientific and technological revolution and industrial reform represented by the digital economy are reconstructing the global innovation map and reshaping the global economic structure, which is a historical opportunity for China to promote high-quality development. Developing the digital economy vigorously, promoting digital industrialization and industrial digitization, accelerating innovative breakthroughs in new-generation information and communication technologies, such as 5G, Internet of Things, cloud computing, big data, and artificial intelligence, and promoting the deep integration of the digital economy and the real economy will help to transform and upgrade traditional industries and promote the upgrading of the industrial foundation and modernization of the industrial chain, and are the strategic choices and key support for constructing a new development pattern to achieve high-quality development.
China’s economic development is in a new normal period of transformation from an investment-driven, high-speed growth model to an innovation-driven, high-quality development model. In the face of multiple pressures, such as the impact of the epidemic, the global economic downturn, and the lack of effective demand, the platform economy represented by the Internet, cloud computing, and big data has played an inestimable role. According to the report of the China Academy of Information and Communications, the added value of China’s digital economy increased from 9.5 trillion yuan in 2011 to 39.2 trillion yuan in 2020, accounting for 38.6 percent of GDP from 20.3 percent. Under the superimposed influence of the impact of the epidemic and the global economic downturn in 2020, China’s digital economy still maintained a trend of vigorous development, with a scale of 392 trillion yuan, of which the scale of digital industrialization reached 7.5 trillion yuan, accounting for 19.1 percent of the digital economy and 7.3 percent of GDP. The scale of industrial digitization reached 31.7 trillion yuan, accounting for 80.9 percent of the digital economy and 31.2 percent of GDP. The platform economy, which is based on data as the factor of production and driven by intelligence, will become a new engine and provide key momentum for the high-quality development of China’s economy. Therefore, it is of great practical significance to explore the relationship between the platform economy and high-quality development to effectively release the new momentum of the platform economy to achieve high-quality economic development.
The possible contributions and innovations of this paper are as follows: first, the existing research on the platform economy and high-quality development is mainly focused on theoretical analysis, and empirical analysis is mostly based on linear discussion. Different from the existing research, this paper comprehensively measures the high-quality development index based on the new development concept and comprehensively discusses the nonlinear relationship between the platform economy and high-quality development and its underlying mechanism, which makes up for the research gap of this topic and enriches the relevant research theory. Second, this paper takes the allocation of factor resources as mechanism variables to construct a theoretical analysis framework to explore the adjustment mechanism between platform economy and high-quality economic development, which provides a new insight for a deeper understanding of the role of the platform economy in high-quality development. Third, based on the “double-edged sword” characteristics of the platform economy, this paper discusses the heterogeneity of the impact of the platform economy on high-quality economic development in multiple dimensions and can evaluate the conditionality and effectiveness of platform economic development more comprehensively than previous studies. It provides detailed evidence for supporting and guiding the healthy development of the platform economy.

2. Literature Review

Previous studies have been carried out from both theoretical and empirical aspects: theoretical studies believe that the platform economy, represented by big data, the Internet, and artificial intelligence, mainly affects the high-quality development of the economy from micro and macro dimensions. Microscopically, digital technology is widely used in various fields, and the application scenarios are constantly being expanded and enriched, promoting the innovation and development of technology, business, and models in different fields, and creating an economic environment with economies of scale and scope. On this basis, new economic forms, such as the sharing economy and platform economy, are being produced to better match supply and demand, form a more perfect price mechanism, and improve the efficiency of economic operation as a whole [1,2,3]. Macroscopically, the platform economy promotes high-quality economic development mainly by improving the efficiency of resource allocation and total factor productivity [4,5]. Empirical research shows that the platform economy can improve entrepreneurial activity [6], technology utilization efficiency [7], and other paths to promote the high-quality development of regional economies. However, a small number of scholars have found that there are risks and problems in the development of the platform economy [8,9]. For example, excessive use of artificial intelligence may lead to a mismatch between capital and labor factors [10], inappropriate competition [11], and disorderly development of the platform economy, leading to technological risks and market monopolies [12], and other problems are not conducive to the healthy development of the economy. The platform economy has gradually become an important part of today’s social and economic development, but there is a lack of empirical research to comprehensively evaluate the relationship between the platform economy and high-quality economic development. The only relevant literature focused on how artificial intelligence affects economic and social transformation [13], economic growth and sustainable development [11,14,15], total factor productivity and employment [16], and the impact of the platform economy on economic growth and income equity [17,18] and other high-quality development sub-topics. By combing the existing literature, we found that the effect of the platform economy on high-quality economic development may not just be a simple linear relationship. Some scholars have discussed the threshold effect of the platform economy on high-quality development [17]. However, it does not give its non-linear mechanism, nor does it evaluate the regional differences in the current high-quality development level of regional economies in China.
According to the summary, the existing research has the following shortcomings: first, from the perspective of the platform economy paradox, it is rare to explore the nonlinear relationship between the platform economy and regional high-quality development. As far as the actual platform economy is concerned, some platform organizations use digital technology to carry out price monopolies; market monopolies destroy the market order and are not conducive to the healthy development of the national economy [12,19]. The existing research is not enough to fully assess the economic effects of the platform economy. Second, the existing literature on the relationship between the platform economy and high-quality development only focuses on related sub-topics, such as artificial intelligence and employment [20,21], ICT, and economic growth [22]. A few studies tried to combine the platform economy with economic growth [23]. However, it is not very good to measure the platform economy and solve endogenous problems. Third, there is still a lot of room for discussion of the relationship and mechanism between the platform economy and high-quality development. Therefore, this paper attempts to explore the non-linear relationship between the platform economy and high-quality development level and its mechanism on the basis of the comprehensive measurement of the platform economy and high-quality development level. The questions to be answered in this paper are as follows: Is there a non-linear impact of the platform economy on high-quality economic development? If so, what is the mechanism behind it? What is the non-linear relationship between the two and is it affected by the location and the degree of marketization? In order to answer the above questions, we need to analyze the regional characteristics on the basis of combing the relevant theories. This paper selects 30 provinces in China as research samples, and empirically tests the influence and mechanism of the platform economy on high-quality development.

3. Theoretical Analysis and Research Hypotheses

High-quality development is development that can well meet the growing needs of people for a better life, and embodies the new development concept of “innovation, coordination, green, openness, and sharing” [24]. The platform economy and sharing economy spawned by the platform economy not only break through physical time and space constraints and realize the real-time development of large-scale supply and demand activities, but also help to reduce production operation costs and transaction costs. It has not only become an important carrier to promote resource integration and value creation in the development of the platform economy [25], but also represents a new way of resource allocation with an emphasis on matching and connection. It has effectively solved the problems of high-quality economic development, such as the contradiction between the supply and demand of factor resources, space limitation of economic activities, efficiency, and fairness, etc. [22]. This paper holds that the platform economy can create conditions for high-quality economic development by improving the efficiency of resource allocation of talent, capital, and technology.
In terms of the allocation of technological elements, many scholars have proved that the digital economy can promote the improvement of total factor productivity and economic growth [26,27,28]. Platform enterprise productivity is a comprehensive function of enterprise technology upgrading, management mode improvement, product quality improvement, and enterprise structure upgrading. We believe that any realistic productivity is actually total factor productivity, and there is a positive correlation between technological innovation and enterprise total factor productivity. The higher the level of technological innovation, the higher the efficiency of technological factor resource allocation. Therefore, this paper focuses on the use of total factor productivity representation as a kind of technological progress brought about by the platform economy. We believe that the platform economy affects technological innovation from the following four aspects: first, the platform economy has the characteristics of versatility and high permeability, and the integration of the platform economy and real economy expands from the field of consumption to the field of production. It accelerates the new trend of the integration of production and consumption and the integration of industrial collaborative innovation, promotes the application and upgrading of new technologies in traditional industries, and accelerates the networking and intellectualization of traditional industries [29,30]. Second, platform technology is widely used in various economic and social fields, giving birth to a large number of emerging intelligent industries with a high technical level and production efficiency, such as network offices, the sharing economy, intelligent manufacturing, and so on. The increasing proportion of knowledge-intensive industries helps to promote the optimization and upgrading of the industrial structure and the improvement of production efficiency [31]. Third, in the process of deepening the integration of the platform economy and the traditional industry, it has effectively improved the original leading technology of the traditional industry and reshaped the traditional production organization mode [32]. Through the intelligent transformation of procurement, production, circulation, and other links, optimize the business process, effectively improve the production efficiency and profitability of enterprises, and then contribute to the technological innovation of enterprises [33]. Fourth, the platform economy is conducive to the birth of economies of scale and knowledge agglomeration, while the effects of economies of scale and agglomeration can promote technological innovation through technology spillover, labor costs, intermediate goods sharing, cooperation, and exchange among enterprises, reducing production costs and other aspects [34]. Therefore, we believe that the platform economy can affect high-quality economic development by improving the allocation level of technical elements.
Secondly, in terms of the allocation of talent elements, the integration of the platform economy and different industries and fields will help to give birth to new industries, new business types, and new models, on the basis of which a shared economy and a platform economy will be formed to better match supply and demand and form a more perfect price mechanism. In addition, through platform organization, enterprises improve the efficiency of information searching, break the information asymmetry barrier between the supply and demand of human resources, reduce the market transaction cost, and improve the efficiency of economic operation [35]. The platform economy is a new economic form based on information technology and data as elements. In the era of the platform economy, talents are the core elements of digital innovation. In the process of platform economy agglomeration, the infrastructure is more perfect, the policy environment is more favorable, the attraction to investment is enhanced, and more and more high-quality enterprises are attracted. With the expansion of the industrial agglomeration around the digital industry, the spatial agglomeration of digital technology, talents, and capital is conducive to the flow of new knowledge and technology between enterprises and industries, and provides intellectual and dynamic support for the innovation and development of regional economies [30]. When the saving of transaction costs further expands the scope of the market and promotes the development of division of labor, enterprises can carry out division of labor and cooperation on a global scale, and quickly adjust the industrial chain and match better partners according to changes in demand so as to improve the efficiency of resource allocation and promote high-quality economic development [33].
Finally, in the allocation of capital elements. The platform economy accelerates the flow of resources. Under the condition of market competition, the mechanism of survival of the fittest helps to optimize the allocation of resources and improve the efficiency of capital utilization. The development of digital industrialization helps to promote the formation of a wider integration of the digital economy and real economy. In the environment of economies of scale and economies of scope, the reduction of production and transaction costs attracts more factors of production. In particular, the free flow of capital factors between industries and regions is more rapid, which helps to optimize the efficiency of spatial capital allocation and improve the rate of return on capital and labor productivity [36,37], and promote the high-quality development of regional economies. In addition, due to information asymmetry, capital utilization efficiency and market efficiency are reduced. The platform organization makes use of its strong data advantages to provide online evaluation, comparison, and feedback systems, which saves search costs and negotiation costs for consumers to choose goods, reduces the information asymmetry between buyers and sellers, and improves market competition and capital utilization efficiency [38]. Therefore, the rapid development of the digital economy breaks down the distance barriers between regions, improves the degree of competition between regions and industries, and improves the efficiency of capital factor resource allocation, which is conducive to high-quality economic development.
The above analysis shows that technology, human resources, capital, and other factor resources play a positive role in regulating the relationship between the platform economy and high-quality development. However, due to psychological reactions and behavioral inertia, under certain conditions, once the economic advantage of the platform appears and reaches a certain extent, there will be a monopoly situation of "the stronger is stronger". Therefore, when the platform economy exceeds a certain threshold, it may have a negative impact and reduce the efficiency of factor resource allocation, because, when the market is monopolized by several large platform organizations, the free flow of technology, manpower, and capital may be disturbed by monopoly behavior. For example, in the past two years, some large Internet giants in China have been involved in platform monopoly events to varying degrees. Therefore, there is a double-edged sword effect in the platform economy, such as unreasonable guidance and standardization, which is ultimately not conducive to the high-quality development of the socialist market economy [12].
To sum up, the platform economy is a double-edged sword, which plays a positive role in promoting high-quality economic development at the initial stage of development, but, without reasonable supervision and guidance, the negative externalities brought about by the later development of the platform economy exceed its positive externalities, which will hinder the high-quality development of the economy. Based on the above analysis, this paper puts forward the following assumptions.
Hypothesis 1 (H1).
The platform economy has an inverted U-shaped impact on the high-quality development of regional economy. Specifically, on the left side of the inflection point, the platform economy promotes high-quality economic development, while, on the right side of the inflection point, the platform economy suppresses high-quality economic development.
Hypothesis 2 (H2).
The platform economy mainly affects the high-quality development of regional economies through labor, capital, and technology.

4. Model Settings, Variables, and Data Sources

4.1. Model Setting

4.1.1. Benchmark Model

Through the analysis of Williamson’s inverted U-shaped theory, we found that he applied Kuznets’s inverted U-shaped hypothesis of income distribution to regional economic development, and put forward the inverted U-shaped theory of regional economic differences. Ref. [39] Based on this, we analyzed the possible inverted U-shaped influence of the platform economy on regional high-quality development. The nonlinear regression model of this paper is constructed by drawing lessons from the econometric analysis methods of some international well-known scholars [40,41,42,43] to construct the following nonlinear econometric models.
ln h q u a l i t y i t = α 0 + α 1 p l a t f o r m i t + α 2 p l a t f o r m i t 2 + α c X i t + μ i + λ t + ε i t
In model (1), lnhqualitiyit indicates that the high-quality economic development level of region i in t period takes the natural logarithm; Platformit is the comprehensive index of platform economic development of region i in t period; vector Xit represents a series of control variables; μi represents the fixed effect of region i not changing with time; λt represents the fixed effect of time; and εit represents the term of random disturbance.

4.1.2. Regulation Mechanism Model

In order to identify the role of labor, capital, and technology in the mechanism between the platform economy and regional high-quality development, this paper follows the econometric model (2).
ln h q u a l i t y i t = β 0 + β 1 p l a t f o r m i t + β 2 p l a t f o r m i t 2 + β 3 R O A i t + β 4 p l a t f o r m i t × R O A i t + β 5 p l a t f o r m i t 2 × R O A i t + α c X i t + μ i + λ t + ε i t
In model (2), lnhqualitiyit indicates that the high-quality economic development level of region i in t period takes the natural logarithm; Platformit is the comprehensive index of digital economic development of region i in t period; and ROAit characterizes the resource allocation of elements, including labor, capital, and technology. This paper focuses on the positive or negative and significance of coefficients β4 and β5 of the interactive term. The meaning of the other variables is consistent with that of model (1).

4.2. Variable Measure and Explanation

4.2.1. High-Quality Economic Development

Most of the existing studies used total factor productivity as a measure of high-quality economic development, but, as an evaluation index of high-quality development, it obviously cannot meet the needs of research. Accurately grasping the connotation of high-quality development is the key to the scientific construction of a high-quality development index system. Previous studies have shown that high-quality development is development that can well meet the growing needs of people for a better life, and the development that embodies the new development concept of “innovation, coordination, green, openness, and sharing” [44,45]. On the basis of existing research, based on the new development concept, this paper constructs a comprehensive evaluation index system of high-quality economic development from five indicators: innovation, coordination, sustainability, openness, and sharing. On this basis, the principal component analysis method was used to measure the comprehensive index of regional high-quality development, which was recorded as hquality. The specific measurement index system is shown in Table 1.

4.2.2. Comprehensive Index of the Platform Economy

There are few literatures on the measurement of the platform economy, and the measurement methods are constantly improving. We referred to the practices of Zhao Tao, Huang Qunhui, and other scholars [6,46]. According to the availability of relevant data at the inter-provincial level, on the basis of taking the development of the Internet as the core measure, and adding indicators, such as platform economic business application and digital inclusive finance, the comprehensive development level of the platform economy is measured from four aspects. The specific contents include: the number of domain names of 10,000 people, the number of web pages, the number of websites, the number of undergraduates and above, the number of mobile Internet users, Internet access ports, Internet penetration, mobile phone penetration, fixed phone penetration, software technology sales revenue, e-commerce sales, e-commerce procurement, the number of e-commerce enterprises, and digital-inclusive financial development index. Principal component analysis (Principal Component Analysis, PCA) is used to measure the comprehensive development index of the platform economy, which is recorded as digital. The specific measurement index system is shown in Table 2.

4.2.3. Mechanism Variable

According to theoretical analysis, the impact of the platform economy on high-quality economic development may be realized through the allocation of technology, talent, and capital. Therefore, in order to test the role of the mechanism of technology, talent, and capital allocation, this article refers to Zhu Xi’an’s practice [47]. The location quotient index was selected to measure the provincial scientific research personnel agglomeration index and scientific research capital agglomeration index to characterize the talent factor resource allocation level (talent) and the capital factor resource allocation level (capital). Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) was used to calculate the total factor productivity of each region to characterize the level of technical factor resource allocation (tfp). About the calculation of DEA, the measurement process of provincial total factor productivity in China is relatively mature. The author draws lessons from the practices of scholars such as Zhang Jun Shan Haojie [8,48], mainly selecting the DEA-Malmquist index method to measure total factor productivity.
L Q i = e i / i = 1 n e i E i / i = 1 n E i
L Q i = q i / i = 1 n q i Q i / i = 1 n Q i
In Formulas (3) and (4), LQi represents the entropy of industrial location, qi and ei denote an area for the total output value of the industry i and number of employed persons, respectively; and summation formula i = 1 n e i and i = 1 n q i represent the total output value and employment of all industries in the country. This paper selects the formula (3) to calculate the allocation level of capital factor resources and talent factor resources in i region.

4.2.4. Control Variable

This paper chooses the following control variables: human capital level (edur), represented by the ratio of the number of students in higher education to the total population of each province. High-quality development is driven by innovation, and human capital is one of the key factors affecting innovation, so the high-quality economic development of each province is inseparable from regional human resources, and controlling the level of human capital is helpful to strip off this influencing factor. The level of financial development (finance) is characterized by the ratio of the balance of deposits and loans of financial institutions to the GDP of each province. The higher the level of financial development, the more perfect the credit system, the more conducive to support the development of local governments, industries, and enterprises, and then affect regional economic development; the level of financial development is directly related to all aspects of high-quality development. The level of economic development (pgdp) is characterized by the per capita GDP. Because the per capita GDP reflects the overall living standards of a region, the higher the per capita GDP, the more qualified the region is to pursue a high quality of life. The level of material capital (finvest) is characterized by the amount of fixed assets investment in the current year. The miracle of China’s “economic growth” in the past few decades is inseparable from fixed-asset investment, although China’s economic growth momentum has gradually shifted from investment-driven to innovation-driven; however, at present, fixed-asset investment is still an important means to promote employment-driven regional economic growth.

4.3. Data Sources and Processing Instructions

This paper takes 30 provinces and regions of China, except Hong Kong, Macao, Taiwan, and Tibet, from 2011 to 2019 as the research object. Since the digital inclusive financial index jointly compiled by the Digital Finance Research Center of Peking University and Ant Financial Services Group began in 2011, because it is an important part of the platform economy, in order to build a comprehensive platform economic development index, this paper measures the platform economic development index and high-quality development level of 30 provinces and regions from 2011 to 2019. The original data in the provincial data came from China Statistical Yearbook, China Labor Statistical Yearbook, China Science and Technology Statistical Yearbook, China Industrial Statistical Yearbook, China fixed assets Investment Statistical Yearbook, China Energy Statistical Yearbook, China Environmental Yearbook, China Internet Development Statistical report, as well as the statistical yearbooks of 30 provinces and the National Bureau of Statistics.

4.4. Descriptive Statistics

Table 3 reports the descriptive statistical results of the main variables in this paper. The results show that the average value of economic high quality development index (hquality) is 3621.211. The maximum value is 1.0 × 104. The minimum value is 1627.952, and the standard deviation is 1427.287. In the absence of the natural logarithm, it can be seen that there is a wide gap in the quality of development among the provinces. In addition, the value of 3347.991 in the 50% quantile is less than the average, indicating that the quality of development in China as a whole is on the low side. The average platform economic development level (digital) is 0.210. The standard deviation is 0.197. The maximum is 0.867, the minimum is 0.031, and the 50% quartile is 0.142, which also shows the uneven development of regional platform economy and the overall low level of platform economic development. From the perspective of control variables, there are obvious differences in the level of human capital, financial development, economic development, and material capital in different regions.

5. Empirical Analysis

5.1. Benchmark Estimation

Table 4 reports mainly the results of nonlinear estimates of the impact of the platform economy on high-quality economic development. As a comparative analysis, column (1) reports the results of linear regression of the platform economy to high-quality economic development, and the results show that the core explanatory variables are not significant. Columns (2) to (5) report the progressive regression results, which show that the platform economy has varying degrees of deviation in the estimation of high-quality economic development due to the influence of time, individuals, and other interference factors. Column (5) reports the estimated results after adding all control variables, controlling time, and individual effects, which is also the benchmark estimation result of this paper.
As can be seen from the results of the report in column (5), the coefficient of the core explanatory variable platform economy (digital) is significantly positive at the 1% statistical level, and the coefficient of the platform economy square (digital2) is significantly negative at the 1% statistical level, indicating that the platform economy has an inverted U-shaped impact on high-quality economic development. Most studies only considered the positive promoting effect of digital technology [3,28], ignoring the double-edged sword effect of the platform economy. Before reaching the extreme point (digital < 0.4329), the platform economy has an obvious promoting effect on the high-quality development of the economy. At present, 85% of the observations are to the left of the extreme point, mainly in the central and western regions. When the extreme point is exceeded (digital > 0.4329), the platform economy has an obvious hindrance effect on the development of high-quality economy. At present, 15% of the observations are located to the right of the extreme point, and the observations are mainly concentrated in Beijing, Shanghai, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, and Guangdong. According to the theoretical analysis, the development of the platform economy has exceeded a certain level. Without government guidance and supervision, platform enterprises may monopolize by virtue of their own technological and information advantages, which is not conducive to the development of the real economy and is not conducive to the high-quality development of the economy.
In order to further verify the inverted U-shaped relationship between platform economy development and high-quality development, the inverted U-shaped relationship test was further carried out by using the UTEST command. The results show that the slope of the relationship between the platform economy and high-quality development is first positive (0.3131) and then negative (−0.3380). The extreme point of the platform economic development index is 0.4329, which is just within the 95% Fieller range (0.0988, 0.57480). The overall p-value test is still significant at the 1% statistical level (pause 0.00428), so it rejects the original hypothesis that there is no inverted U-shaped relationship between the independent variables and dependent variables. The above results support the inverted U-shaped relationship between the platform economy and high-quality development, so hypothesis H1 of this paper has been verified.
The estimated results of the control variables in Table 4 show that there is a positive correlation between the human capital level (edur) and high-quality economic development, and it is significant at the 5% statistical level. It shows that the level of human capital has a significant promoting effect on high-quality economic development, so expanding the scale of higher education and improving the level of human capital are conducive to the high-quality development of regional economies. The coefficient of economic development level (pgdp) is significantly negative, which is different from expectations. The possible reason is that the per capita GDP only reflects the quantity of regional economic growth, but does not reflect the quality of economic growth. In reality, China’s economic "growth miracle" has brought a rapid increase in per capita GDP, but it also brings problems such as environmental pollution, a gap between urban and rural areas, unfair distribution, and so on, which is not conducive to high-quality economic development. The coefficient values of the material capital level (finvest) and financial development level (finance) are not statistically significant.

5.2. Robust Estimation

5.2.1. Test of Alternative Estimation Method

Although the fixed effect model is good at solving the endogenous problem that the individual within the region does not fluctuate with time, based on the consideration of robustness, this paper uses the generalized moment estimation method (GMM) to solve the possible endogenous problems, and the specific estimation results are shown in Table 5. The estimated results of the system generalized moment estimation (sys-gmm) and differential generalized moment estimation (diff-gmm) are reported in Table 5. The estimated results show that the coefficient values of the platform economy (digital) are significantly positive at the 5% statistical level, and the coefficient values of the platform economy square (digital2) are significantly negative above the 10% statistical level. According to the AR2 value of the high-order autoregressive test, there is no high-order autocorrelation and it passes the exogenous Hansen test of tool variables. This shows that the impact of the platform economy on high-quality economic development has the effect of "Going too far is as bad as not going far enough". In addition, considering that provinces and regions are excluded from the sample, and the estimated sample is a restricted subset of the population sample, this paper chooses the restricted dependent variable method (xttobit) for re-estimation, and the estimated results are shown in Table 5. The estimated results show that the inverted U-shaped impact of the platform economy on high-quality development does not change with the change of the estimation method, which verifies the robustness of the benchmark estimation results in this paper.

5.2.2. Change Variable Measure

In the process of measuring variables by principal component analysis, eigenvalue decomposition requires that the transformed matrix must be a square matrix, and in the case of non-Gaussian distribution, the principal component obtained by principal component analysis may not be optimal. Therefore, in order to make up for the limitations of the measurement method, refer to Chen Jinghua’s approach [45]. In this paper, the entropy method is used to calculate the comprehensive index of high quality development Retest as a dependent variable. In addition, this article uses the digitization degree index jointly compiled by the Digital Finance Research Center of Peking University and Ant Financial Services Group (digidegree). Robust estimation by replacing the comprehensive index of the platform economy. The estimated results of the replacement dependent variables are shown in column (1) of Table 6, the platform coefficient is significantly positive, and the digital2 coefficient is significantly negative, indicating that the platform economy has an inverted U-shaped impact on high-quality development.
Column (2) in Table 6 uses the digitization degree index (digidegree) to replace the independent variable for estimation. The results show that the platform economy still has a significant “Inverted U” effect on the high-quality economic development after changing the independent variable or dependent variable.

5.2.3. Consider Missing Variables

Based on the consideration of omitted variables, provincial scientific research investment intensity (rd) and foreign investment (lnfdi) control variables are added to the model for estimation. The intensity of scientific research investment is characterized by the ratio of the internal scientific research expenditure of each province to the financial income of each province at the end of the year, and the amount of foreign direct investment at the end of the year is characterized by the natural logarithm. The estimated results are shown in column (3) of Table 6, which shows that, after adding possible missing variables, the impact of the platform economy on high-quality development is still consistent with the basic estimates, indicating that there is no serious problem of missing variables. It shows that the benchmark estimation result of this paper is robust.

5.2.4. Endogenous Test

The development of the platform economy is conducive to the high-quality development of regional economies, and high-quality development will further promote the development of the platform economy. Therefore, there may be two-way causality; in addition, there may be measurement errors, sample selection, and other problems leading to endogenous problems. For this reason, based on the consideration of data integrity, this paper uses the number of digital circuits in each province in 1998 as the tool variable of the platform economic development index. On the one hand, platform technology is an extension of traditional technology, and the traditional platform infrastructure of each province will affect the use habits of users and the subsequent development and application of platform technology from provincial platform technology to the subsequent development of the platform economy, so as to meet the requirements of relevance. On the other hand, the impact of the number of digital circuits on the current high-quality economic development is ignored to meet exclusiveness. However, because the data of 1998 are only cross-sectional data, they cannot be used directly. With reference to the practice of Nathan Nunn [49], the panel tool variable was constructed by introducing a variable that varied with time. Specifically, the tool variable (instru) was constructed by multiplying the number of Internet domain names of each province and the number of digital circuits in 1998 as the tool variable of the platform economic index of each region. The two-stage least square method (2SLS) was used for estimation. The estimated results are shown in Table 7.
The endogenous test was carried out with reference to the practice of Wang Xianbin [50]. Table 7 shows the results of endogenous estimation. Column (2) and column (3) report the estimation results of the first stage, which show that the coefficient of tool variables (instru) is significant at the 10% and 5% statistical levels, indicating that there is a high correlation between the platform economy and tool variables, and the F value of the first stage is greater than the critical value of 10. There is no need to worry about weak tool variables, and the selection of tool variables is more reasonable. Column (1) reports the results of the second-stage estimates, which showed that, after solving the endogenous problems, the impact of the platform economy on high-quality development still had the effect of Inverted U. The endogenous estimation shows that, except for the change in size, the direction of the core explanatory variable coefficients is consistent with the basic estimation results, indicating that the basic estimation results in this paper are more reliable.

5.3. Heterogeneity Test

5.3.1. Quality of The Market System

The quality of the market system directly affects the market vitality and the degree of competition, thus affecting the speed and quality of regional economic development. The high quality of the system shows that the regional market openness, market order, and degree of freedom are good, which provides a good development environment for the development of the platform economy and contributes to the rapid development of the platform economy. The marketization index is mainly carried out from five aspects: the relationship between the government and the market, the development of the non-state-owned economy, the development of the product market, the development of the factor market, the development of market intermediary organizations, and the environment of the legal system, according to the marketization index report compiled by Wang Xiaolu: “Report on China’s Provincial marketization Index (2018)” [39]. In this paper, the marketization index is used to represent the market institutional quality (marindext). Since the sample data lasts until 2019, the marketization index in the last year is calculated by the author by hand. Additionally, the market system quality of the median was the standard for grouping, higher than the median was a higher quality of the system, and lower than the median was a lower quality of the system. The results of the grouped regression are shown in Table 8. The estimated results show that the platform coefficients are significantly positive above the 10% statistical level. The digital2 coefficient is significantly negative when the statistical level is above 10%. We calculated that, when the quality of the market system was low, the total observation value was 146, the economic threshold of the platform was 0.427, and the observation value on the left side of the inflection point was 121, accounting for about 83%. When the quality of the market system was high, the total observation value was 124. the economic threshold of the platform was 0.325, and the observation value on the left side of the inflection point was 99, accounting for 80%. Generally speaking, the observed value on the left side of the inflection point was more than that on the right side of the inflection point.
According to Table 8, it can be seen that, the higher the quality of the market system, the greater the promoting effect of the platform economy on high-quality development. At present, we can improve the degree of marketization and improve the market system and mechanism to further enhance the positive externalities of the platform economy and promote high-quality economic development.

5.3.2. Degree of Government Intervention

The degree of government intervention in the market has always been a hot topic among scholars; the degree of government intervention in different economic types is different, and the effects are also different. As a new type of economy, the initial development of the platform economy is inseparable from the support and guidance of the government; excessive intervention may not be conducive to the rapid development of the platform economy, but unreasonable guidance may lead to market monopoly in the later stage of the development of the platform economy Therefore, it is necessary to test the degree of government intervention in groups. To measure the degree of government intervention (govern), referring to the practice of most scholars, this article adopts the ratio of government general service expenditure to provincial GDP, and divides it into groups according to the median of the degree of government intervention. Higher than the median is regarded as a strong degree of government intervention, and lower than the median is regarded as a weak degree of government intervention. The results of the grouping estimation are shown in Table 8.
The results show that, under the condition of weak government intervention, the platform economy has an inverted U-shaped effect on high-quality development. We calculated that, when the government intervention was low, the total observation value was 169, the economic threshold of the platform was 0.504, and the observation value on the left side of the inflection point was 146, accounting for about 86%. When the government intervention was high, the total observation value was 101, the platform economic threshold was 0.232, and the observation value on the left side of the inflection point was 97, accounting for 96%. This shows that the observed value on the left side of the inflection point was more than that on the right side of the inflection point.
The low government intervention may be due to the low efficiency of government allocation and the utilization rate of expenditure. From the number of observations, more than 80% of the current observations were on the left side of the inflection point, so we focused on the left side of the point of view. On the left side of the inflection point, compared with the areas with stronger government intervention, the promoting effect of the platform economy on the areas with lower government intervention was more significant. However, from the slope point of view, through the derivation of the quadratic function, we can see the steepness of the slope. The slope of the inverted U-shaped curve was minus 2.92 in areas with strong government intervention and minus 0.908 in areas with weak government intervention. The absolute value shows that the inflection point of the inverted U-shaped curve is steeper on the left and right sides of the inverted U-shaped curve in areas with strong government intervention, but it is not statistically significant. The insignificant reason may be related to the current low utilization rate of overall government expenditure in China, or it may be that the median index is not accurate enough to distinguish the strength of government intervention

5.3.3. Regional Heterogeneity Test

According to the new situation of accelerated economic and social development in China, the country is divided into four major economic regions: the eastern region, the northeast region, the central region, and the western region. Therefore, this paper estimates the regional heterogeneity according to the four major economic regions. To explore whether there are differences in the impact of the platform economy on high-quality development in different regions, Table 9 shows the test results of regional heterogeneity.
From the estimated results in Table 9, we can see that, in contrast, the effect of the platform economy on the high-quality development of the northeastern and western regions is more obvious. Specifically, compared with the eastern and central regions, the promoting effect of the platform economy on the high-quality development of the northeastern and western regions is more significant; while the impact on the high-quality development of the eastern and central regions is positive, the statistical level is not significant. When the development of the platform economy exceeds the extreme point, it has an inhibitory effect on the high-quality development of the four major economies. Compared with the northeastern, central, and western regions, the inhibitory effect of platform economic development on the high-quality development of the eastern region is the lowest.
As a matter of fact, this is the case in China, where competition in the east is fiercer, the environment is freer, and the regulatory mechanism is also better. From the point of view of the steepness of the curve, the promoting effect of the platform economy on the central and western regions is greater. According to statistics, 85% of the current observations fall on the left side of the inflection point. In other words, the current platform economy is on the rise. From the perspective of the influence coefficient, the promoting effect of the platform economy on the central and western regions is greater. We think that the possible reason is that the level of high-quality development in the central and western regions is low, and there is plenty of room for growth. Therefore, the promoting effect of the platform economy on underdeveloped areas is relatively greater.

6. Test of Adjustment Mechanism Based on Resource Allocation of Elements

The platform economy is a double-edged sword that plays a positive role in promoting high-quality economic development at the initial stage of development, but without reasonable supervision and guidance, the negative externalities brought about by the later development of the platform economy exceed its positive externalities, which will hinder the high-quality development of the economy. Therefore, according to theoretical analysis, technology, human resources, capital, and other factor resources play a positive role in regulating the relationship between the platform economy and high-quality development. In order to test the regulatory role of the allocation of factor resources in model (2), this paper focuses on the significance of the coefficient of interactive items. The mechanism test results are shown in Table 10.

6.1. Resource Allocation of Technical Elements

Column (1) of Table 10 shows the estimated results of the intersection of tfp and the platform economy and its horizontal direction. The estimated results of column (1) show that the platform economy has an inverted U-shaped impact on high-quality economic development, and we focus on the significance of the coefficient of interactive terms. From the interaction between technology factor resource allocation (tfp) and the platform economy (digital), we can see that the coefficient value of digitfp is positive, which is significant at the 5% statistical level. The value of digi2tfp factor is negative, which is significant at the 5% statistical level. This shows that, on the left side of the extreme point, the resource allocation of technological factors plays a positive role in the process of the platform economy, promoting high-quality economic development. On the right side of the critical value, as the development of the platform economy exceeds the extreme point, the resource allocation of technological factors plays a negative role in the inhibitory effect of the platform economy on high-quality economic development.
In order to directly show the regulatory effect of resource allocation, we drew a diagram of the regulatory effect of resource allocation on the platform economy and high-quality development, as shown in Figure 1. As shown in Figure 1, the improvement of the efficiency of resource allocation of technological factors has enhanced the role of the lower level of the platform economy in promoting high-quality economic development, but when the development of the platform economy has reached a certain scale, the slope of the technological factor resource allocation efficiency has gradually changed from positive to negative, indicating that the positive adjustment effect of the technological factor resource allocation efficiency is gradually weakened or even negative. This strengthens the restraining effect of the platform economy on high-quality economic development. Therefore, the resource allocation of technical elements plays a regulatory role in the non-linear relationship.

6.2. Allocation of Talent Elements and Resources

The estimated results of column (2) in Table 10 show that the coefficient of the interaction term (digitalent) is significantly positive. The value of the digi2talent coefficient is significantly negative, indicating that, on the left side of the extreme point, the allocation of human resources positively adjusts the positive correlation between the platform economy and high-quality development. On the right side of the extreme point, talent elements negatively regulate the negative correlation between the platform economy and high-quality development. In order to intuitively show the regulatory role of talent factor resource allocation, we drew a diagram of the regulatory effect of talent factor resource allocation on the relationship between the platform economy and high-quality economic development, as shown in Figure 2. As shown in Figure 2, the improvement of the allocation of human resources enhanced the promotion of the lower level of the platform economy to high-quality development. When the development of the platform economy has exceeded the extreme point, the improvement of the allocation of human resources has obviously strengthened the negative impact of the platform economy on high-quality development. Therefore, the resource allocation of talent elements plays a regulatory role in the non-linear relationship.

6.3. Capital Factor Resource Allocation

The interactive items in column (3) in Table 10 show that the value of the digicapital coefficient is positive and the value of capital coefficient is negative, but it is not significant at the statistical level. In order to directly see the regulatory role of capital factor resource allocation, we drew a diagram of the regulatory effect of capital factor resource allocation on the relationship between the platform economy and high-quality development. As shown in Figure 3, the improvement of capital factor resource allocation enhances the promotion of the low-level platform economy to high-quality development, but when the development of the platform economy exceeds the extreme point, it shows that the regulating effect of capital is not obvious.

7. Conclusions and Revelations

This paper empirically analyzes the influence and mechanism of the platform economy on high-quality economic development by using Chinese provincial panel data.
The conclusions are as follows: first, the platform economy has an inverted U-shaped influence on the high-quality economic development. On the left side of the inverted U-shaped inflection point, the platform economy has an obvious promoting effect on the regional high-quality development. On the right side of the inflection point, the platform economy has an inhibitory effect on the regional high-quality development. Second, compared with areas with stronger government intervention, the platform economy has a more significant inverted U-shaped effect on high-quality development in areas with weaker intervention. Compared with areas with a higher-quality market system, the promotion effect of the platform economy on high-quality development in areas with lower institutional quality is more obvious on the left side of the inflection point and the inhibitory effect on the right side of the inflection point. Compared with the eastern and central regions, on the left side of the inflection point, the platform economy plays a greater role in promoting the high-quality development of the northeastern and western regions, while, on the right side of the inflection point, the platform economy has an inhibitory effect on the high-quality development of each region. Third, the agglomeration of factors plays a regulatory role between the platform economy and high-quality development, in which talent and technology elements play a positive regulatory role on the left side of the inflection point and a negative regulatory role on the right side of the inflection point; meanwhile, capital elements only play a positive regulatory role, and the negative regulatory role is not significant.
According to the research conclusions, several policy implications are obtained: first of all, according to the statistical analysis, 85% of the observations fell on the left side of the inverted U shape, indicating that the overall development of China’s platform economy is in its infancy. Vigorously developing the platform economy will help to promote the high-quality development of the regional economy. Therefore, the government will promote the construction of platform infrastructure, especially by accelerating the application of technology in the fields of big data, artificial intelligence, 5G, and the Internet of things, further promote the integration of the platform economy with the real economy, and speed up the in-depth development of platform technology, making the platform organization innovation vitality and potential continue to burst out, and providing new momentum for achieving high-quality economic development. Secondly, attach importance to regional coordinated development, according to regional resource endowment, improve the resource utilization rate of regional technology, talent, and capital advantages, and vigorously develop the platform economy and scope economy to make full use of agglomeration advantages to promote regional high-quality development. At the same time, the government needs to pay attention to the economic support and guidance of the platform, especially in the areas where the degree of government intervention is weak, to strengthen the reasonable guidance and supervision of the platform economy. In the eastern region, there is a high degree of market and there is a great possibility of monopoly risk. Therefore, it is necessary to strengthen the supervision of largescale platform organizations in the east, and to encourage and support the platform economy in the central and western regions and underdeveloped areas. The government should appropriately relax the market access threshold for platform enterprises and release the economic vitality of platform enterprises in backward areas. Finally, improve the supervision and management system and mechanism of platform enterprises, provide an institutional guarantee for the healthy development of the platform economy, make full use of the agglomeration advantage of the platform economy to promote high-quality economic development, and attach importance to the double-edged sword effect of the platform economy.
The article also has the following shortcomings: first, compared with the existing research, the comprehensive index of the platform economy has made great progress, but, with the continuous extension and development of digital technology in recent years, the connotation of the platform economy is becoming richer. This study is mainly based on the Internet-based comprehensive index, and index diversification is still lacking. Second, from the actual situation in China, the study found that 15% of the sample observations, such as Guangdong, Beijing, Shanghai, and other areas, fell on the right side of the inverted U shape, which does not mean that the development of the platform economy in this region should be stagnated or restrained across the board, because there is still an imbalance in the development between prefecture-level cities and counties; however, the provincial panel data cannot capture these details very well. This is also an important direction for the author to study in the next step.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, G.Y. and F.D.; methodology, G.Y.; software, G.Y. and Y.W.; validation, X.X. and G.Y.; formal analysis, F.D.; investigation, Y.W.; resources, G.Y.; data curation, G.Y.; writing—original draft preparation, G.Y.; writing—review and editing, G.Y.; visualization, Y.W.; supervision, F.D.; project administration, F.D.; funding acquisition, F.D. and X.X. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

The General Project of National Social Science Fund: “Research on the path of ‘Industrial Aid to Xinjiang’ in the problem of Regional Coordinated Development Mechanism” (18BJL083); General Project of Social Science Foundation of Autonomous region: “Research on the Construction of Modern Industrial System in Xinjiang” (21BJL038).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data used in this paper are all from the statistical database of China’s economic and social development, specific website: https://data.cnki.net/NewHome/index. However, this article does not produce any datasets.

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to acknowledge funding from the The General Project of National Social Science Fund: “Research on the path of ‘Industrial Aid to Xinjiang’ in the problem of Regional Coordinated Development Mechanism” (18BJL083) and General Project of Social Science Foundation of Autonomous region: “Research on the Construction of Modern Industrial System in Xin-jiang” (21BJL038), and the four reviewers for their valuable comments and suggestions on this study.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Acemoglu, D.; Restrepo, P. The race between man and machine: Implications of technology for growth, factor shares, and employment. Am. Econ. Rev. 2018, 108, 1488–1542. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Aghion, P.; Antonin, C.; Bunel, S. Artificial intelligence, growth and employment: The role of policy. Econ. Stat. 2019, 510, 149–164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Abdulov, R. Artificial intelligence as an important factor of sustainable and crisis-free economic growth. Procedia Comput. Sci. 2020, 169, 468–472. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Ahmad, N.; Schreyer, P. Are GDP and productivity measures up to the challenges of the digital economy? Int. Product. Monit. 2016, 30, 4–27. [Google Scholar]
  5. Bulturbayevich, M.B.; Jurayevich, M.B. The impact of the digital economy on economic growth. Int. J. Bus. Law Educ. 2020, 1, 4–7. [Google Scholar]
  6. Boyd, R.; Holton, R.J. Technology, innovation, employment and power: Does robotics and artificial intelligence really mean social transformation? J. Sociol. 2018, 54, 331–345. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Barata, A. Strengthening national economic growth and equitable income through sharia digital economy in Indonesia. J. Islamic Monet. Econ. Finan. 2019, 5, 145–168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Zhang, M.L.; Chen, M.S. China’s Digital Economy: Opportunities and Risks; International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  9. Basu, S.; Fernald, J. Information and communications technology as a general-purpose technology: Evidence from US industry data. Ger. Econ. Rev. 2007, 8, 146–173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Chakpitak, N.; Maneejuk, P.; Chanaim, S.; Sriboonchitta, S. Thailand in the era of digital economy: How does digital technology promote economic growth? In Proceedings of the International Conference of the Thailand Econometrics Society, Chiang Mai, Thailand, 10–12 January 2018; pp. 350–362. [Google Scholar]
  11. Jinghua, C.; Yao, C.; Minmin, C. China’s high-quality economic development level, regional differences and dynamic evolution of distribution. J. Quant. Tech. Econ. 2020, 37, 108–126. [Google Scholar]
  12. Domnina, S.; Podkopaev, O.; Salynina, S. The Digital Economy: Challenges and Opportunities for Economic Development in Russia’s Regions. In Current Achievements, Challenges and Digital Chances of Knowledge Based Economy; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2021; pp. 149–157. [Google Scholar]
  13. Erkomaishvili, G. Digital economy-an innovative tool for economic growth. Econ. Bus. 2019, 2, 37–46. [Google Scholar]
  14. Gopinath, G.; Kalemli-Özcan, Ş.; Karabarbounis, L.; Villegas-Sanchez, C. Capital allocation and productivity in South Europe. Q. J. Econ. 2017, 132, 1915–1967. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Gruber, H.; Koutroumpis, P. Mobile telecommunications and the impact on economic development. Econ. Policy 2011, 26, 387–426. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. He, Y. The Importance of Artificial Intelligence to Economic Growth. Korea J. Artif. Intell. 2019, 7, 17–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Hofman, A.; Aravena, C.; Aliaga, V. Information and communication technologies and their impact in the economic growth of Latin America, 1990–2013. Telecommun. Policy 2016, 40, 485–501. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Qunhui, H.; Yongze, Y.; Songlin, Z. Internet Development and Manufacturing Productivity improvement: Internal Mechanism and Chinese experience. China Ind. Econ. 2019, 8, 5–23. [Google Scholar]
  19. Irtyshcheva, I.; Stehnei, M.; Popadynets, N.; Bogatyrev, K.; Boiko, Y.; Kramarenko, I.; Senkevich, O.; Hryshyna, N.; Kozak, I.; Ishchenko, O. The effect of digital technology development on economic growth. Int. J. Data Netw. Sci. 2021, 5, 25–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Jin, G.; Yu, B.; Shen, K. Domestic trade and energy productivity in China: An inverted U-shaped relationship. Energy Econ. 2021, 97, 105234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Jin, C.; Liang, L.; Hang, W. Industrial agglomeration and innovation performance under the background of open innovation: Evidence from chinese high-tech industries. Stud. Sci. Sci. 2013, 2013, 623–629. [Google Scholar]
  22. Jorgenson, D.W.; Ho, M.S.; Samuels, J.D.; Stiroh, K.J. Industry origins of the American productivity resurgence. Econ. Syst. Res. 2007, 19, 229–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Jorgenson, D.W.; Motohashi, K. Information technology and the Japanese economy. J. Jpn. Int. Econ. 2005, 19, 460–481. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Wenjun, J.; Baowen, S. Digital Economy Promotes High-quality Economic Development: A Theoretical Analysis Framework. Economy 2019, 2, 66–73. [Google Scholar]
  25. Li, Y. The Influence of the Development of Digital Economy on the Upgrading of China’s Industrial Structure. E3S Web Conf. 2021, 235, 03062. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Li, X.; Lu, Y.; Huang, R. Whether foreign direct investment can promote high-quality economic development under environmental regulation: Evidence from the Yangtze River Economic Belt, China. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2021, 28, 21674–21683. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  27. Mardonakulovich, B.M.; Bulturbayevich, M.B. Economic Growth: Quality And The Digital Economy. Acad. Globe Indersci. Res. 2020, 1, 1–8. [Google Scholar]
  28. Michaels, G.; Graetz, G. Estimating the Impact of Robots on Productivity and Employment. VoxEU. Available online: https://voxeu.org/article/robots-productivity-and-jobs (accessed on 20 June 2021).
  29. Montani, F.; Vandenberghe, C.; Khedhaouria, A.; Courcy, F. Examining the inverted U-shaped relationship between workload and innovative work behavior: The role of work engagement and mindfulness. Hum. Relat. 2020, 73, 59–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Nunn, N.; Qian, N. US food aid and civil conflict. Am. Econ. Rev. 2014, 104, 1630–1666. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Nan, L.; Aimei, L.; Hao, D.; Hailong, S. The more, the better or going too far is as bad as not going far enough? A literature review of choice overload and consumer decision-making behavior. Foreign Econ. Manag. 2017, 39, 70–82. [Google Scholar]
  32. Niyazbekova, S.U.; Moldashbayeva, L.P.; Zhumatayeva, B.A.; Mezentseva, T.M.; Shirshova, L.V. Digital economy development as an important factor for the country’s economic growth. In Socio-Economic Systems: Paradigms for the Future; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2021; pp. 361–366. [Google Scholar]
  33. Parker, G.G.; Van Alstyne, M.W.; Choudary, S.P. Platform Revolution: How Networked Markets are Transforming the Economy and how to Make Them Work for You; WW Norton & Company: New York, NY, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  34. Pan, W.; Xie, T.; Wang, Z.; Ma, L. Digital economy: An innovation driver for total factor productivity. J. Bus. Res. 2022, 139, 303–311. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Haojie, S. Re-estimation of China’s capital stock K: 1952–2006. J. Quant. Tech. Econ. 2008, 25, 17–31. [Google Scholar]
  36. Sturman, M.C. Searching for the inverted U-shaped relationship between time and performance: Meta-analyses of the experience/performance, tenure/performance, and age/performance relationships. J. Manag. 2003, 29, 609–640. [Google Scholar]
  37. Tohang, V.; Limijaya, A.; Chitrahadi, M. An analysis of the impact of XBRL filings towards information asymmetry in Indonesia. In Proceedings of the 2020 International Conference on Information Management and Technology (ICIMTech), Bandung, Indonesia, 13–14 August 2020; pp. 330–335. [Google Scholar]
  38. Volkova, A.; Plotnikov, V.; Rukinov, M. Digital economy: Essence of the phenomenon, problem and risks of formation and development. Adm. Consult. 2019, 4, 38–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Xiaolu, W. China’s Provincial Marketization Index Report: 2018. Neri Report 2018; Social Science Literature Press: New York, NY, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  40. Xianbin, W.; Shulin, L.; Liangxiong, H. Economic growth pressure and Regional Innovation—empirical evidence from Economic growth goal setting. China Econ. Q. 2021, 21, 1147–1166. [Google Scholar]
  41. Williamson, J.G. Regional inequality and the process of national development: A description of the patterns. Econ. Dev. Cult. Change 1965, 13, 1–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Heng, X.; Yilin, Z.; Yujia, C. Digital economy, Technology spillover and dynamic Competition and Cooperation Policy. Manag. World 2020, 36, 63–84. [Google Scholar]
  43. Zhang, J.; Wu, G.; Zhang, J. Estimation of China interprovincial material capital stock: 1952–2000. Econ. Stud. 2004, 10, 35–44. [Google Scholar]
  44. Xi’an, Z.; Xiu, Z.; Hao, L. China’s high-tech industrial agglomeration and urbanization development. J. Quant. Tech. Econ. 2021, 38, 84–102. [Google Scholar]
  45. Junkuo, Z.; Yongzhi, H.; Peilin, L.; Jianwu, H.; Xian, Z. The goal requirement and strategic path of high-quality development. Manag. World 2019, 35, 1–7. [Google Scholar]
  46. Zhang, S.; Chen, C.; Xu, S.; Xu, B. Measurement of capital allocation efficiency in emerging economies: Evidence from China. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 2021, 171, 120954. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Zhang, W.; Zhao, S.; Wan, X.; Yao, Y. Study on the effect of digital economy on high-quality economic development in China. PLoS ONE 2021, 16, e0257365. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Zhang, X.-Z.; Liu, J.-J.; Xu, Z.-W. Tencent and Facebook data validate Metcalfe’s law. J. Comput. Sci. Technol. 2015, 30, 246–251. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Tao, Z.; Zhi, Z.; Shangkun, L. Digital economy, Entrepreneurial activity and High-quality Development—Empirical evidence from Chinese cities. Manag. World 2020, 36, 65–76. [Google Scholar]
  50. Zixun, Q.; Yahong, Z. Development of Digital Economy and Regional Total Factor Productivity: An Analysis Based on National Big Data Comprehensive Pilot Zone. J. Financ. Econ. 2021, 47, 4–17. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Regulating effect of the resource allocation of technical elements.
Figure 1. Regulating effect of the resource allocation of technical elements.
Sustainability 14 02225 g001
Figure 2. Regulating effect of the resource allocation of talent elements.
Figure 2. Regulating effect of the resource allocation of talent elements.
Sustainability 14 02225 g002
Figure 3. Regulating effect of the resource allocation of capital elements.
Figure 3. Regulating effect of the resource allocation of capital elements.
Sustainability 14 02225 g003
Table 1. Comprehensive measurement index system of high-quality development of regional economies.
Table 1. Comprehensive measurement index system of high-quality development of regional economies.
First-Level IndexSecondary IndexThird-Level IndexFourth-Level IndexIndex CalculationAttribute
InnovateInnovation investmentInnovation investment intensityProportion of investment in scientific researchInternal expenditure on scientific research/provincial GDP+
Proportion of investment of scientific research personnelTotal number of researchers at that time/total number of employees at the end of the provincial year+
Innovation stockHuman capital levelNumber of college students per 10,000 people+
Innovation outputNumber of patentsNumber of patents per capitaNumber of patents granted per capita in the province+
Technical turnoverProportion of turnover in technology marketTechnical market turnover/provincial GDP+
Innovation efficiencyResource allocation efficiencyCapital productivityProvincial GDP/investment in fixed assets of the whole society+
Labor productivityThe total number of employees at the end of the year in each province of GDP.+
Energy productivityGDP/10,000 tons of standard coal in each province+
Land productivityTotal grain output/total area of cultivated land in the province+
Market efficiencyPluralism of economic subjectsProportion of fixed assets investment in non-state-owned economy+
Industrial output value/gross industrial output value of non-state-owned enterprises+
Government code of conductAmount of capital in the general budget of local finance/investment in fixed assets of the whole society
Government consumption expenditure/total social consumption
Factor market developmentFinancial sector value added/provincial GDP+
Number of individual employees/total number of employees at the end of the provincial year+
CoordinationRegional coordinationPer capita GDP ratioPercentage of per capita GDP in each provincePer capita GDP of each province/per capita GDP of the whole country+
Regional consumption levelProportion of consumption level of residents in each provinceRegional resident consumption/national average consumption level+
Urban–rural coordinationIncome levelUrban–rural income ratioPer capita income of urban residents/per capita income of rural residentsModerate
Consumption gap between urban and rural areasComparison of consumption level between urban and rural areasPer capita consumption of urban residents/per capita consumption of rural residentsModerate
Industrial coordinationAdjustment of industrial structureRationalization of industrial structureReciprocal of Theil index+
Upgrading of industrial structureAdvanced industrial structureOutput value of tertiary industry/secondary industry+
SustainableSteady developmentOutput stabilityGrowth rate of total outputProvincial GDP growth rate+
Price steadinessProducer price indexEx-factory price index of industrial producers
Consumer price indexConsumer price index
Stable employmentLabor supply fluctuationRegistered urban unemployment rate
Green developmentGreen environmental protectionForest coverageForest coverage+
Nature reserve coverageArea of nature reserve/area under its jurisdiction+
Green coverage rate in built-up areasGreen coverage rate in built-up area+
Pollution reductionUnit GDP emissionSO2 emissions/provincial GDP
Unit GDP wastewater dischargeTotal wastewater discharge/provincial GDP
Unit GDP solid waste dischargeGeneral industrial solid waste production/provincial GDP
Environmental regulationIntensity of environmental pollution controlInvestment in environmental pollution control/provincial GDP+
Open upForeign trade openingDegree of dependence on foreign tradeProportion of total import and exportTotal import and export/provincial GDP+
Opening up of foreign investmentDegree of dependence on foreign capitalRatio of foreign direct investmentFDI/provincial GDP+
Foreign direct investmentProportion of foreign direct investmentOFDI/provincial GDP+
ShareIncomeIncome distributionAverage capital of on-duty staff and workersPer capita disposable income+
ConsumptionConsumption expenditurePer capita consumption expenditurePer capita consumption expenditure+
HealthHygiene and healthMedical and health levelNumber of beds in health institutions per 10,000 people+
Health technicians per 10,000 people+
EducationEducational supportInvestment in educationEducation expenditure/provincial fiscal expenditure+
LeisureLeisure welfareResidents’ tourism expenditureEngel coefficient of resident tourism+
Table 2. Comprehensive index system of the platform economy.
Table 2. Comprehensive index system of the platform economy.
First-Level IndexSecondary IndexIndex Meaning
Comprehensive index of platform economic developmentPlatform technology infrastructureNumber of domain names with ten thousand people (person/ten thousand)Describe the distribution of domain names in each province+
Number of web pages (unit)Describe the basic situation of web page information resources in each province+
Number of websites (10,000)Describe the basic situation of website construction in each province+
Number of undergraduates or above (10,000)Describe the level of human capital in each province+
Number of mobile Internet users (10,000)Describe the basic situation of platform users in each province+
Internet access ports (10,000)Describe the development of Internet infrastructure+
Internet information resourcesInternet penetration rateDepict the present situation of the development of Internet information resources in various provinces+
Mobile phone penetration rateDepict the use of platform resources of users in each province+
Fixed-line telephone penetration rateDepict the use of household platform resources in each province+
Platform business applicationSales revenue of software technology (ten thousand)Reflect the development level of upstream and downstream platform industry+
E-commerce sales (10,000)Reflect the prosperity of e-commerce+
E-commerce purchase amount (10,000)Reflect the degree of development of various e-commerce applications+
Number of e-commerce enterprises (10,000)Reflect the development degree of enterprise digitalization+
Digital financeDigital-inclusive Financial Development IndexMeasure the development of digital economy in the financial field+
Note: The data come from provincial statistical yearbooks and statistical bulletins, China Statistical Yearbook, China Internet Development Statistical report, and China Science and Technology Statistical Yearbook.
Table 3. Descriptive statistics of variables.
Table 3. Descriptive statistics of variables.
VariablesMeanp50sdMinMaxN
hquality3621.2113347.9911427.2871627.9521.0 × 104270
digital0.2100.1420.1970.0310.867270
Digital20.0830.0200.1550.0010.752270
edur0.0190.0190.0050.0080.035270
finance3.3313.0711.0701.6887.552270
pgdp5.1984.3762.6571.61916.45270
finvest180001400013000143659000270
tfp0.9630.9570.1130.5381.459270
talent18.283.21848.020.660324.7270
capital0.0120.0100.0090.0020.063270
Table 4. Platform economy and high-quality economic development.
Table 4. Platform economy and high-quality economic development.
Variables Lnhquality
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
digital0.0801.497 **1.186 *−1.186 ***0.337 ***
(1.31)(2.53)(1.96)(−3.67)(2.89)
digital2 −0.694−1.1970.738−0.389 ***
(−0.94)(−1.18)(1.23)(−3.53)
edur10.33 ** 36.81 ***9.781 **10.01 **
(2.48) (3.84)(2.23)(2.45)
finance−0.0364 0.257 ***0.190 ***−0.0334
(−1.25) (6.58)(8.35)(−1.18)
pgdp−0.0254 *** 0.0946 ***−0.0248 ***
(−3.47) (7.76)(−3.33)
finvest6.68 × 10−7 1.13 × 10−5 ***4.23 × 10−7
(0.58) (6.27)(0.36)
Time fixedYESNONONOYES
Province fixedYESNONONOYES
Constant7.673 ***7.872 ***6.405 ***6.802 ***7.650 ***
(57.44)(121.76)(32.67)(63.75)(59.06)
Observations270270270270270
R-squared0.9860.2830.5360.8240.987
Note: the t value is in parentheses; *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 5. Test of alternative estimation methods.
Table 5. Test of alternative estimation methods.
Variables Lnhquality
Sys-gmmDiff-gmmXttobit
digital3.083 **4.980 **0.385 ***
(2.53)(2.47)(3.25)
digital2−2.870 **−4.668 *−0.372 **
(−2.29)(−1.65)(−2.48)
edur0.790−7.80812.55 ***
(0.15)(−0.49)(5.28)
finance0.0809 **−0.123−0.0124
(1.99)(−1.59)(−0.92)
pgdp−0.00174−0.121−0.0178 ***
(−0.07)(−1.09)(−3.87)
finvest−9.02 × 10−6−9.92 × 10−62.14 × 10−7
(−1.53)(−0.56)(0.42)
Time fixedYesYesYes
Province fixedYesYesYes
Constant−199.3 ***-7.511 ***
(−4.91) (83.20)
AR2p = 0.167p = 0.543-
Hansenp = 0.212p = 0.212-
Observations270240270
Note: the t value is in parentheses; *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 6. Changing the variable measure and considering missing variables test.
Table 6. Changing the variable measure and considering missing variables test.
VariablesReplace Dependent VariableReplace Independent VariableResolve Missing Variables
(1) Lnhqualitys(2) Lnhquality(3) Lnhquality
digital0.118 * 0.303 ***
(1.92) (2.95)
digital2−0.150 * −0.378 ***
(−1.73) (−3.55)
digidegree 0.301 ***
(2.80)
digidegree2 −0.0314 ***
(−2.77)
edur4.029 ***12.06 ***10.87 ***
(3.01)(3.29)(2.76)
finance−0.00206−0.0642 **−0.0491
(−0.24)(−2.53)(−1.64)
pgdp0.00601*−0.0294 ***−0.0270 ***
(1.81)(−4.06)(−3.90)
finvest−5.23 × 10−75.12 × 10−74.77 × 10−7
(−0.95)(0.42)(0.49)
lnfdi 0.0114
(1.59)
rd −0.510 ***
(−6.42)
Time fixedYESYESYES
Province fixedYESYESYES
Constant−0.696−219.5 ***7.716 ***
(−0.14)(−18.80)(54.69)
Observations270270270
R-squared0.2170.9720.988
Note: the t value is in parentheses; *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 7. Endogenous test.
Table 7. Endogenous test.
(1)(2)(3)
Second StageFirst StageFirst Stage
VariablesLnqualityDigitalDigital2
digital3.766 *
(1.89)
digital2−6.344 *
(−1.89)
IV: instru −0.029−0.044 *
(−0.92)(−1.90)
IV: instru2 0.002 *0.002 **
(2.45)(2.45)
Control variableYesYesYes
Time fixedYesYesYes
Province fixedYesYesYes
Observations270270270
Note: the t value is in parentheses; ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 8. Institutional quality and government intervention.
Table 8. Institutional quality and government intervention.
VariablesLnhquality
Quality of the System Is LowQuality of the System Is HighWeak Government InterventionStrong Government Intervention
digital0.351 **0.566 *0.458 ***0.677
(2.58)(1.93)(2.93)(1.21)
digital2−0.411 ***−0.870 *−0.454 ***−1.460
(−3.17)(−1.83)(−4.32)(−0.95)
edur9.758 **9.903 *2.2945.416
(2.11)(1.90)(0.34)(1.22)
finance−0.03350.00251−0.0317−0.0493 **
(−0.88)(0.10)(−1.29)(−1.47)
pgdp−0.0289 **−0.0143 *−0.0233 ***−0.0219
(−2.44)(−1.75)(−2.93)(−1.23)
finvest−1.95 × 10−71.37 × 10−64.81 × 10−72.29 × 10−6
(-0.09)(0.89)(0.39)(0.74)
Constant7.673 ***7.495 ***7.841 ***7.602 ***
(48.20)(48.34)(39.80)(73.79)
Time fixedYesYesYesYes
Province fixedYesYesYesYes
Observations146124169101
R-squared0.9830.9900.9880.991
Note: the t value is in parentheses; *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 9. Results of the regional heterogeneity test.
Table 9. Results of the regional heterogeneity test.
Variables Lnhquality
Northeastern ChinaEastern RegionCentral RegionWestern Region
digital1.456 *0.2910.3431.163 *
(2.25)(1.35)(0.71)(2.14)
digital2−3.569 *−0.335 *−3.277 *−3.266 **
(−2.11)(−1.76)(−2.11)(−2.57)
edur8.048 **0.7645.2705.034
(4.59)(0.07)(1.12)(1.73)
financ−0.0700−0.0119−0.106 **−0.0363
(−1.05)(−0.44)(-3.12)(−1.06)
pgdp−0.0469−0.02110.0214−0.0575 **
(−1.47)(−1.64)(1.32)(−3.05)
finvest3.46 × 10−6 ***−1.42 × 10−62.72 × 10−6 *3.28 × 10−6
(7.52)(−1.22)(2.33)(0.97)
Constant7.626 ***8.073 ***7.546 ***7.640 ***
(29.21)(21.60)(49.70)(53.92)
Time fixedYesYesYesYes
Province fixedYesYesYesYes
Observations36905490
R-squared0.9990.9900.9970.991
Note: the t value is in parentheses; *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 10. Mechanism test results.
Table 10. Mechanism test results.
Variables Lnhquality
Technical Elements (1)Talent Elements (2)Capital Elements (3)
digital0.326 ***0.332 **0.271 *
(2.86)(2.66)(2.04)
digital2−0.361 ***−0.422 ***−0.225
(−3.24)(−3.82)(−1.12)
tfp−0.0151
(−0.53)
talent −0.000159
(−0.78)
capital 1.474
(0.67)
digitfp0.732 **
(2.08)
digit2fp−0.912 **
(−2.29)
digitalent 0.00279 **
(2.47)
digi2talent −0.00884 **
(−2.53)
digicapital 22.35
(1.26)
digi2capital −24.42
(−1.19)
edur9.224 **10.11 **8.149**
(2.18)(2.43)(2.06)
financ−0.0402−0.0334−0.0291
(−1.35)(−1.19)(−1.06)
pgdp−0.0263 ***−0.0274 ***−0.0172 **
(−3.45)(−3.93)(−2.48)
finvest4.36 × 10−75.40 × 10−73.14 × 10−7
(0.37)(0.45)(0.27)
Constant7.730 ***7.695 ***7.667 ***
(53.52)(58.38)(65.47)
Time fixedYesYesYes
Province fixedYesYesYes
Observations270270270
R-squared0.9870.9870.987
Note: the t value is in parentheses; *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Yang, G.; Deng, F.; Wang, Y.; Xiang, X. Digital Paradox: Platform Economy and High-Quality Economic Development—New Evidence from Provincial Panel Data in China. Sustainability 2022, 14, 2225. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14042225

AMA Style

Yang G, Deng F, Wang Y, Xiang X. Digital Paradox: Platform Economy and High-Quality Economic Development—New Evidence from Provincial Panel Data in China. Sustainability. 2022; 14(4):2225. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14042225

Chicago/Turabian Style

Yang, Guoge, Feng Deng, Yifei Wang, and Xianhong Xiang. 2022. "Digital Paradox: Platform Economy and High-Quality Economic Development—New Evidence from Provincial Panel Data in China" Sustainability 14, no. 4: 2225. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14042225

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop