Next Article in Journal
Overview of Position-Sensorless Technology for Permanent Magnet Synchronous Motor Systems
Previous Article in Journal
Research on Height Adjustment Characteristics of Heavy Vehicle Active Air Suspension Based on Fuzzy Control
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

How to Choose the Refueling of New Energy Vehicles under Swapping vs. Charging Mode: From the Consumers’ Perspective

1
School of Management, Wuhan Unversity of Science and Technology, Wuhan 430065, China
2
School of Management, Nanchang University, Nanchang 330047, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
World Electr. Veh. J. 2023, 14(8), 211; https://doi.org/10.3390/wevj14080211
Submission received: 15 July 2023 / Revised: 31 July 2023 / Accepted: 4 August 2023 / Published: 8 August 2023

Abstract

:
Battery charging mode (CM) is a prevalent method of trans-shipping power to new energy vehicles (NEVs). Unfortunately, due to the limited capacity of batteries, typical NEVs can only travel for approximately 350 miles on a single charge and require hours to be recharged. Battery swapping mode (SM), as a novel alternative, can offer an ideal solution by exchanging depleted batteries for recharged ones at swapping stations in the middle of long trips, inevitably influencing potential consumers’ purchase behaviors. To examine the impact of SM and CM on consumers’ purchase intention, this paper examines a duopolistic market consisting of two new energy vehicle manufacturers (i.e., a NEV-SM manufacturer and a NEV-CM manufacturer), who adopt SM and CM to service consumers, respectively. Considering SM is characterized by low initial investment and ease of use for consumers, NEV-CM manufacturers capitalize on extended battery warranty services in response to rivals’ utilization of SM. Thereby, non-cooperative game models are formulated, in which government subsidies are taken into account. The optimal production decision for both the NEV-SM manufacturer and the NEV-CM manufacturer are analyzed under three scenarios: without extended warranty service, with extended warranty service, and with extended warranty service and subsidy. The results show that the two manufacturers’ market dominance relies on the ratio of the swapping station’s convenience to the extended warranty service and the valuation incremental rate. Additionally, we also find that the government subsidy can dramatically improve the NEV-SM manufacturer’s performance at the initial stage, but if the subsidy is insufficient in size at the subsequent stage, this will lead to policy failure and inefficiency in propelling the diffusion of swapping mode.

1. Introduction

Compared with traditional fuel vehicles (FVs), which have low power, high emissions, susceptibility to malfunctions, and high fuel consumption, new energy vehicles (NEVs) have more potential benefits and are considered as the future alternative to alleviate global greenhouse gas emissions [1,2,3]. However, there exist a couple of critical obstacles to overcome before NEVs will be used on a mass scale. Perhaps the most significant challenge stems from the nature of recharging. Whereas fuel vehicles (FVs) can be easily refueled at accessible gas stations in a matter of minutes, NEVs require specific equipment and a significant amount of time (hours) to be recharged [4]. The shorter cruise range of NEVs than that of fuel vehicles (FVs), which necessitates more frequent recharges than gasoline refuels, only makes this problem worse. Whereas it is normal to park the NEVs at a workplace or home for a few hours or overnight, it is impractical to station the car for a recharge in the middle of a long trip [5,6].
Battery swapping mode (SM) can effectively solve the aforementioned problem [7,8]. In this mode, NEV makers (or battery-swapping service providers) deploy the network of swapping stations where NEV users may exchange their depleted batteries for full ones in the middle of long trips. The depleted batteries are then recharged at the stations and later swapped for depleted batteries on other arriving NEVs. This solution allows NEVs to be effectively “refueled” in only one to two minutes instead of hours [7]. Different from the conventional charging mode (CM), SM is somewhat analogous to cell phone service providers. It builds and operates the infrastructure system (i.e., battery-swapping stations) and provides a service (“refueling” NEVs). Because batteries can be swapped, they are not owned by the NEV users themselves but rather leased to them based on service contracts. Users will be charged based on usage (i.e., miles driven), much like cell phone users being billed based on talk time.
This arrangement poses several potential benefits. It decouples ownership of the battery and the NEV, two items with different life cycles, and makes it very easy to take advantage of future improvements in battery technology through regular battery replacements, compared with other solutions that bundle the NEV and battery as one single unit [9]. Most importantly, the significantly lower upfront cost for the user to purchase a new NEV (the battery typically costs around $10,000) can help boost adoption rates. Second, swapping mode can effectively lower the risk of battery damage in the fast-direct charging mode. It is estimated that the frequently adopted fast direct charging for NEVs shortens the life of the battery by approximately 20% due to the strong electric flows. Third, swapping mode can be utilized to recharge at night rather than during the day, which dramatically reduces electricity fees, balances the power load, and decreases the difference between the peak and valley loads on the power grid side. In addition, swapping mode could be helpful in implementing the life-cycle management of the battery. The average battery life span is approximately 8 years due to degradation in capacity. Unlike fuel vehicles, NEVs cannot use their power batteries until they reach the end of their life cycle. Instead, the power batteries must be removed when their capacities fall to around 70–80% due to performance and safety concerns, and yet they can be reused in other fields including energy storage for wind and solar power, thus in turn cutting down on operational costs.
Although SM displays remarkable merits, some problems, particularly the insufficient number of swapping stations, hamper the shape of an efficient supply network to service consumers. Meanwhile, CM still dominates in the NEV market and NEV-CM makers (i.e., new energy vehicle manufacturers using the charging mode) usually implement various strategies including extended warranty services to counteract NEV-SM manufacturers (i.e., new energy vehicle manufacturers using the swapping mode). Spurred by these practices, we address three questions in this paper: (1) What is the condition in which both NEV-SM makers and NEV-CM makers can be in equilibrium? (2) In a duopolistic market, is the competitive advantage a NEV-SM manufacturer possesses over its rivals influenced by an extended battery warranty service? (3) Which demand differences occur between the NEV-SM maker and the NEV-CM maker under the government subsidy? How does the government subsidy affect consumer surplus and social welfare at different development stages of the swapping network?
To handle the aforementioned problems, we present our theoretical models under a base model with and without an extended warranty service, and then we extend the model to incorporate government subsidies. The main academic contributions of this paper are threefold: (1) Different from prior work, we examine the impact of battery swapping mode (SM) in a competitive environment, where two NEV makers adopt different types of recharge (i.e., swapping mode and charging mode), rather than studying it on its own; (2) we employ the critical factor of an extended battery warranty service to investigate the optimal pricing for both NEV makers, which has seldom been addressed before; (3) piecewise government subsidies are taken into account to analyze the difference in optimal outcomes.
The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 reviews the most relevant literature. In Section 3, we present our theoretical models and the corresponding results. Subsequently, a numerical study and sensitivity analysis are conducted in Section 4. Section 5 provides concluding remarks and the direction of future research. All proofs are offered in Appendix A.

2. Literature Review

This paper investigates the optimal decision for new energy vehicles with a battery swapping/charging mode in the context of an extended warranty service. The main relevant studies include two domains, namely the battery swapping/charging mode and the extended warranty service.

2.1. Research on the Battery Swapping/Charging Mode for NEVs

The literature regarding NEV swapping mode mainly addresses the locations of swapping stations, including a comparison of the swapping mode and the direct charging mode for an operator under various scenarios. Ref. [10] simultaneously investigated the locations of battery swap stations for electric vehicles and the routing plan of a fleet of electric vehicles. Ref. [8] relaxed the constraint of the battery driving range limitation to examine the routing of electric vehicles and sitting decisions for charging stations, in order to support the strategic decisions of logistics fleet operators. Results show that shorter overall distances can be achieved if simultaneous sitting as well as extended recharging options are allowed. Ref. [9] further examined the battery swap station location routing problem, taking capacitated electric vehicles into account. Ref. [11] studied the optimum energy management of parking lots serving EVs with swappable batteries. More specifically, Ref. [12] emphasized three factors, namely the number of batteries needed to serve incoming EVs, potential charging damage, and electricity costs, to study the optimized charging schedule for swapped electric vehicle batteries and compare the performance between two different algorithms. And studied the service parks open to more than one type of EV, meaning that users who can access such a service nearby can decide to buy any type of EV.
Unlike the aforementioned work focusing only on the battery swapping mode, Ref. [4] established the dispatching models of microgrids with EVs in different energy supply modes, namely the plug-in charging mode and the battery swapping mode. The results demonstrate that microgrids with EVs in the battery swapping mode are more economic compared with the EV in the plug-in charging mode, and the effectiveness of the dispatching model. Furthermore, Ref. [7] modeled a multi-objective optimization problem (i.e., the minimum charging time, travel time, and charging cost) of an EV network that offers multiple charging options, including normal charging, fast charging, and battery swapping facilities, and designed a meta-heuristic solution in the form of ant colony optimization. Simulation results show that the proposed solution significantly reduces waiting time and charging costs.
In particular, for various operators, Ref. [13] examined and compared microgrid operator performance using the battery swapping mode and direct charging mode under wind power and photovoltaic power. The results show that the battery swapping mode is better than the direct charging mode for using battery discharging energy when the energy price is high, and charging when the energy price is low, thus improving the operational economy of the microgrid. In parallel, Ref. [14] examined an EV-sharing operator under battery-charging technology (battery swapping mode and direct charging mode) and an insurance contract (i.e., fixed premium insurance and per-hour-premium insurance), developing a stylized model with which to analyze the impact of different charging technologies, insurance contracts, and other related factors impacting the EV-sharing operator’s profit.
Different from the extant literature mainly addressing an operator’s choice between the swapping mode and the direct charging mode, we examine the best choice of two NEV manufacturers adopting the swapping mode and the direct charging mode, respectively, and competing in the same NEV market.

2.2. Research on the Extended Warranty Service

For durable consumer products, after-sale services play an important role in customers’ purchase decisions [15]. The basic warranty as an after-sale service is available to product owners and offers free repair and replacement. In addition to the basic warranty, extended warranty services have become popular. Ref. [16] examined an extended warranty under which an additional trade-in service is provided during the warranty coverage and found that the new extended warranty does not need to be offered at a higher price than the basic warranty. When the handling cost for used products is relatively low, the extended warranty will outperform the basic warranty. Ref. [17] considered a base warranty consisting of a two-dimensional region of age and usage, and analyzed the design and pricing models of two-dimensional extended warranty contracts, unlike the one-price-for-all extended warranties. More specifically, Ref. [18] differentiated customers according to their risk attitudes and usage rates to design residual value warranties and found that residual value warranties can price discriminate customers more effectively than traditional warranties with contingent contracts.
Extended warranty services also have an influence on the service partners. Ref. [19] researched the influence of network externalities on the extended warranty in a two-stage supply chain model. The findings reveal that the supply chain between the retailer and supplier could be coordinated and obtain Pareto improvement through an improved revenue-sharing extended warranty contract. Meanwhile, Ref. [20] examined service supply chain optimal pricing in the context of vertical competition with two extended warranty cases: one considering the retailer’s concerns regarding fairness and one without considering the retailer’s fairness concerns, and found that the two parties in the supply chain employ differential pricing strategies for extended warranties when the retailer has fairness concerns. Furthermore, Ref. [21] also built three theoretical game models to study the design of extended warranty service strategies in a dual supply channel by taking into account customer channel preferences.
The second stream of research studies extended warranty strategies in various conditions and demonstrates that warranty strategies are important to firms. In contrast, our paper investigates the interaction between extended warranties and swapping network deployment in a swapping/charging competitive context, where two different types of NEV manufacturers sell their products to heterogeneous consumers, which has seldom been studied before.

3. Theoretical Models

We study a duopolistic market where two NEV manufacturers exist, namely a NEV-SM manufacturer and a NEV-CM manufacturers. The NEV-SM manufacturer produces and sells NEVs with the adoption of the battery swapping mode, whereas the NEV-CM counterpart makes NEVs with the charging mode. Two NEV products are sold to consumers, priced p 1 and p 2 , respectively. Considering that the NEV-CM manufacturer will bundle the NEV and the battery into a package to sell to consumers, and that a consumer who prefers NEV-SM products will buy only the NEV and rent the power battery, it is reasonable to let p 1 < p 2 .
With two different ways of trans-shipping power to NEVs (i.e., SM and CM), heterogeneous consumers’ purchase behaviors are independent and separated. We assume that consumers are heterogeneous in product valuation. Similar to the previous study, the product valuation is represented by v, which is uniformly distributed over 0,1 . It means that when consumers buy vehicles, they consider various factors such as price, appearance, convenience, and warranty period, among others. Compared to CM, SM can bring convenience to consumers in terms of initial cost and recharging time. In parallel, consumers will also consider whether the number of battery-swapping stations m is sufficient to meet their travel requirements after buying NEVs with the swapping mode. In reality, it is true that the current swapping network is at the infant stage, which hinders the wide use of NEV-SM products to a degree. The main notations used in this paper are summarized in the Appendix A (Table A1).
Therefore, one prospective consumer may have three options to choose from: (1) purchase a NEV with SM, (2) purchase a NEV with CM, and (3) buy nothing. Referencing the literature [5], the three utilities of consumers are formulated as follows:
u 1 = v p 1 + δ m  
u 2 = v 1 + λ p 2
u 3 = 0  
Equation (1) indicates that consumers’ utility function of the NEV-SM is related to the valuation v of the number of battery swapping station m and price p 1 .   δ is denoted by the battery swapping stations’ convenience coefficient. Equation (2) shows that the utility function of the NEV-CM depends on v , p 2 , and λ , which is the valuation incremental rate of CM relative to SM. It is easy to know that consumers’ utility u 1 > 0   and u 2 > 0 , and when Δ u = u 1 u 2 > 0 , consumers are willing to purchase a NEV-SM rather than a NEV-CM; otherwise, when Δ u = u 1 u 2 < 0 , consumers prefer a NEV-CM instead of a NEV-SM, hence we have
Δ u = p 2 λ v p 1 + δ m
Due to the fact that consumers are heterogeneous in product valuation, v is uniformly distributed over 0,1 . Equation (4) yields the decoupling point between purchasing a NEV-SM and purchasing a NEV-CM. We can denote this point by v 0 , which is represented by v 0 = ( p 2 p 1 + δ m ) / λ . Therefore, it is easy to derive the demand function regarding NEV-SM and NEV-CM, respectively.
D 1 = 0 ( p 2 p 1 + δ m ) / λ d v = p 2 p 1 + δ m / λ
D 2 = ( p 2 p 1 + δ m ) / λ 1 d v = λ p 2 + p 1 δ m / λ

3.1. Base Model

In this subsection, we take into account the scenario where the NEV-CM maker does not leverage an extended warranty service to compete with the NEV-SM maker in the NEV market.
Building the swapping infrastructure requires the NEV-SM manufacturer to invest in fix costs. The fixed cost is closely related with the number of battery-swapping stations m. Based on the literature [22], the costs of the battery-swapping station can be presented in a quadratic form, α m 2 / 2 , where α   is the cost coefficient of the battery-swapping station. Additionally, supposing that the two firms produce NEVs with the same production cost structure, c 1 = c 2 = c .
The profits of the NEV-SM manufacturer and the NEV-CM manufacturer are expressed as follows:
π 1 ( p 1 , m ) = D 1 p 1 c 1 1 2 α m 2
π 2 ( p 2 ) = D 2 p 2 c 2
Note that, the first term of Formula (6) represents the sales revenue from NEV-SM, and the second term denotes the fixed cost of building battery-swapping stations. Formula (7) represents the profit from NEV-CM. Putting together Equations (4)–(7), we obtain
π 1 ( p 1 , m ) = p 1 c p 2 p 1 + δ m / λ 1 2 α m 2
π 2 ( p 2 ) = p 2 c λ p 2 + p 1 δ m / λ
The NEV-SM manufacturer and the NEV-CM manufacturer determine their own optimal selling prices with the aim of maximizing his own profit, using the backward induction to solve Formulas (9) and (10).
Proposition 1.
Under the swapping mode vs. the charging mode, if  λ > δ 2 / 2 α  holds on, the equilibrium outcomes are    p 1 * = 3 α c λ + α λ 2 c δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 ,  m * = λ δ 3 α λ δ 2 ,  p 2 * = 3 α c λ + 2 α λ 2 c δ 2 λ δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 ,
D 1 * = α λ 3 α λ δ 2 ,   D 2 * = 2 α λ δ 2 3 α λ δ 2
Lemma 1.
Only when the inequality  λ > δ 2 / α  holds are the optimal solutions in the base model achieved; whereas if  δ 2 / α > λ > δ 2 / 2 α  is satisfied, the optimal solutions do not exist even though the equilibrium outcomes can be obtained.
Lemma 1 shows the current situation where the CM mode dominates in the NEV market and yet the SM mode is still in its infancy. Only when λ exceeds a certain threshold value ( i . e . , λ > δ 2 / α ) will consumers perceive the price of SM-NEVs to be less than that of CM-NEVs (i.e., p 1 < p 2 ), attracting consumers to purchase a NEV-SM. This is consistent with reality. In this regard, both the NEV-CM manufacturer and the NEV-SM manufacturer obtain optimal profits under the swapping mode vs. the charging mode.
Theorem 1.
Only when   λ > δ 2 / α   is satisfied can the NEV-SM manufacturer keep their price lower than that of their rival NEV-CM maker; however, the NEV-CM manufacturer always outperforms the NEV-SM manufacturer in term of market demand and profit, i.e., D 1 < D 2 ,     π 1 < π 2 .
Theorem 1 indicates that, at the initial development stage of NEV-SM, the NEV-SM manufacturer adopts the low-price strategy with aims to tap into the market and attract potential consumers. However, this move is not a long-term solution due to the fact that the NEV-CM maker invariably occupies more market share and obtains greater profits in the NEV market. With the decrease in λ , i.e., the valuation change rate of the CM relative to the SM, the NEV-SM maker will improve their position as consumers gradually realize the NEV-SM’s advantages over that of the NEV-CM. This is why NIO Motors, one of the leading NEV-SM manufacturers, is convincing more and more customers to choose the SM mode in China.
Corollary 1.
Under the swapping mode vs. the charging mode, when  λ δ 2 / α ,     ,     π 1 / α < 0 ,  π 1 / δ > 0 .
Corollary 1 shows that, when λ δ 2 / α ,     , π 1 decreases in α , but increases with δ . The result is intuitive because the parameter of α represents the construction cost per swapping station, therefore the increase in α will inevitably lead to a reduction in profit for the NEV-SM manufacturer. Likewise, the increase in δ means consumers’ perception of usage of NEV-SM products has improved, thus driving people to purchase it and increasing the NEV-SM manufacturer’s profitability. It reminds managers of the important role of the convenience of the swapping network in practice. In other words, the NEV-SM manufacturer should not only endeavor to expand the network infrastructure, but emphasize the location of swapping stations as well.

3.2. Model with Extended Warranty Service

Under this model, as the NEV-SM manufacturer leases batteries to consumers rather than selling them bundled with vehicles, consumers’ purchase costs are significantly lowered along with the subsequent battery maintenance fees. To counteract their rival’s merit, the NEV-CM manufacturers are consolidating their dominant market position by providing consumers with an after-sales service for batteries, namely an extended warranty service, in an attempt to overcome their short broad. For instance, WeltMeister, as another leading Chinese NEV-CM manufacturer, launched the nationwide battery extended warranty service in 2018, thus leading to peers’ follow-up, including BYD and Xpeng Motors. With the extended warranty service, we define T as the duration of the extended warranty service, and k represents the extended warranty service coefficient. Similar to the base model, the consumer utility regarding NEV-CM in the setting of an extended warranty service policy is formulated as:
u 2 ~ = 1 + λ v p 2 ~ + k T      
While the consumer utility regarding NEV-SM remains unchanged, following the same reasoning as before, we derive the demand functions of NEV-SM and NEV-CM, respectively.
D 1 ~ = 1 λ p 2 ~ p 1 ~ + δ m ~ k T
D 2 ~ = 1 λ λ + p 1 ~ p 2 ~ δ m ~ + k T
Thus, the profit functions of NEV-SM and NEV-CM under the extended warranty service are expressed as below,
π 1 ~ ( p 1 ~ , m ~ ) = D 1 ~ p 1 ~ c 1 1 2 α m ~ 2
π 2 ~ ( p 2 ~ , T ) = D 2 ~ p 2 ~ c 2 β T 2 / 2                
Obviously, the first term of Formula (12) entails the sales revenue from NEV-CM, and the second term denotes the NEV-CM manufacturer incurring the cost of the extended warranty service β T 2 / 2 , where β   is the cost coefficient of the extended warranty service. We can obtain the optimal decisions and the two firms’ profit by finding the first order derivative of Formulas (14) and (15).
Proposition 2.
Under the extended warranty service, if  α k 2 > β δ 2 ,   λ > k 2 / 2 β ,  or  α k 2 < β δ 2 ,     λ > δ 2 / 2 α  hold on, the equilibrium outcomes are
T * = k ( 2 α λ δ 2 ) α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ ,     m * ~ = δ ( k 2 β λ ) α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ ,   p 1 * ~ = α β 3 c λ + λ 2 + k 2 c + λ + c β δ 2 α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ ,
p 2 * ~ = β α 3 c λ + 2 λ 2 + δ 2 c + λ + c α k 2 α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ ,   D 1 * ~ = α ( k 2 β λ ) α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ ,     D 2 * ~ = β ( 2 α λ δ 2 ) α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ
Theorem 2.
In the setting of the extended warranty service,
(i) 
When  0 < δ k < ( 2 α / β ) 1 2 , λ > k 2 / β  hold on, the NEV-SM maker’s profit is more advantageous that the NEV-CM maker’s, whereas the NEV-SM maker possesses less market share than its rival. (i.e.,  D 1 * ~ < D 2 * ~ , π 1 * ~ > π 2 * ~ );
(ii) 
When  δ k > ( 2 α / β ) 1 2 ,     λ > β δ 2 α k 2 / 2 α β  hold on, the NEV-CM maker is more competitive than the NEV-SM maker (i.e.,  D 1 * ~ < D 2 * ~ ,     π 1 * ~ < π 2 * ~ ).
Theorem 2 displays that the consumers’ choice of two modes relies on two critical factors, namely λ   a n d   δ k , where δ k denotes the ratio of the swapping station’s convenience coefficient to the extended warranty service coefficient. When the coefficient ratio does not surpass a specific threshold value ( 2 α / β ) 1 2 , and the valuation incremental rate of CM relative to SM is at a high level, although the NEV-SM maker’s demand is less than that of its competitor, its profit still surpasses the NEV-CM maker’s. On the other hand, when the valuation incremental rate of CM relative to SM remain at a relatively high level but the coefficient ratio is above a specific threshold value ( 2 α / β ) 1 2 , the NEV-CM maker dominates the market in terms of demand and profit. The results imply that regardless of 0 < δ k < ( 2 α / β ) 1 2 or δ k > ( 2 α / β ) 1 2 , the NEV-CM is more appealing to consumers from the demand perspective. Additionally, when 0 < δ k < ( 2 α / β ) 1 2 , the inequality λ > k 2 / β ensures that the price of the NEV-SM product is less than that of the NEV-CM one, yet the NEV-SM maker’s payoff is larger than its rival due to the cost of the extended warranty service. In contrast, given δ k > ( 2 α / β ) 1 2 , the inequality λ > β δ 2 α k 2 / 2 α β guarantees that the price of the NEV-SM product is less than that of the NEV-CM one. Therefore, the NEV-CM maker’s profit is larger than that of its rival due to the higher value of λ . It implies that even if the extended warranty service temporarily has a negative impact on the NEV-CM maker’s performance due to initial investment, its market dominance is indeed enhanced further.
Corollary 2.
In the setting of the extended warranty service,
(i) 
When  2 α k 2 > β δ 2 ,     λ > k 2 / β  , both  m ~  and  T  increase with  δ ;
(ii) 
When  2 α k 2 < β δ 2 ,     λ > β δ 2 α k 2 / 2 α β ,  m ~  increases with  δ ; while  T  decreases with  δ .
Corollary 2 exhibits the monotonicity of δ in the setting of the extended warranty service. The outcomes indicate that, regardless of what conditions are, the increase in the number of swapping station ( m ~ ) will enhance the perceived convenience of the swapping mode ( δ ), which is consistent with reality. However, for the duration of the extended warranty service ( T ), the impact of δ shows differences. When 2 α k 2 > β δ 2   a n d       λ > k 2 / β , T has a positive influence on δ , meaning that the NEV-SM maker improves the convenience of the swapping mode ( δ ), triggering its rival to expand the extended warranty service duration ( T ) for batteries with an aim of avoiding the loss of customers. However, when 2 α k 2 < β δ 2 ,     λ > β δ 2 α k 2 / 2 , the increase in δ will make the NEV-CM maker shorten the extended warranty service duration ( T ). The rationale of this result is that, from Theorem 2, when 2 α k 2 > β δ 2 ,     λ > k 2 / β , the NEV-CM maker’s profit is lower than that of its competitors, thus leading to his aggressive response to the NEV-SM manufacturer’s move, whereas when 2 α k 2 < β δ 2 ,     λ > β δ 2 α k 2 / 2 α β , the NEV-CM maker dominates the NEV market in terms of demand and profit, and the shortening of the extended warranty service duration ( T ) may suitable for more perspective consumers’ needs.

4. The Impact of the Subsidy Policy

From the above analysis, to effectively compete with the NEV-CM maker, the NEV-SM maker should improve their swapping network to enhance the convenience of replacing batteries, hence requiring an increase in the number of swapping stations, which in turn relies on investment from two sources, one of which is government subsidies. In this section, we further analyze the impact of the government subsidy policy on the selection of two different modes. Although the government has gradually cut down the amounts of NEV subsidies until monetary aid will be completely abolished, the subsidies for the construction of swapping stations still remain unchanged as the NEV-SM makers are unable to afford to invest in swapping infrastructure deployment alone at the initial stage of promoting the SM. To speed up the sitting-and-sizing process of swapping stations, governments usually provide financial subsidies to encourage NEV-SM makers to perfect their swapping network. In this regard, we assume subsidies are allocated to the NEV-SM maker, rather than to the NEV-CM maker.
The common practice is that the subsidy size relies on the number of power-swapping stations built. In addition, when the swapping network starts to take shape, the subsidy amount will somewhat reduce accordingly. Thus, the government’s subsidy represents a piecewise function as below,
f s = a m s ,                                                                                                       0 < m s m 1 a m 1 + b ( m s m 1 ) ,                                               m 1 < m s m 2
where m 1 represents the minimal number of swapping stations below which point, i.e., m s ( 0 ,   m 1 ) , the NEV-SM maker can obtain a subsidies per station, while m 2 stands for the maximum number of swapping stations above which point the subsidy size per station will decrease to b from a ( 0 < b < a ), i.e., m s ( m 1 ,   m 2 ) . To this end, s = a m s , m s ( 0 ,   m 1 ) , it means that the swapping network construction is at the preliminary stage (I), while when f s = a m 1 + b ( m s m 1 ) , m s ( m 1 ,   m 2 ) , it signals that swapping deployment has nearly completed, referring to the mature stage (II).
Therefore, in two different stages (I and II), the profit functions of the NEV-SM maker under the base model (without the extended warranty service) are formulated, respectively,
π 1 Ι p 1 Ι , m Ι = D 1 Ι p 1 Ι c 1 2 α m Ι 2 + a m Ι
π 1 Π ( p 1 Π , m Π ) = D 1 Π p 1 Π c 1 2 α m Π ) 2 + a ( m Π + b m Π m Ι
and the profit functions of the NEV-SM maker under the extended warranty service model in two different stages (I and II) are shown,
π 1 ~ Ι p 1 ~ Ι , m ~ Ι = D 1 ~ Ι p 1 ~ Ι c 1 2 α m ~ Ι 2 + a m ~ Ι
π 1 ~ Π ( p 1 ~ Π , m ~ Π ) = D 1 ~ Π p 1 ~ Π c 1 2 α m ~ Π 2 + a m ~ Π + b m ~ Π m ~ Ι
For the NEV-CM maker, its profit functions remain unchanged. Using a similar method as before, the optimal solutions with/without the extended warranty service are obtained, and the results are shown in the Appendix A (Table A2).
Lemma 2.
Without the extended warranty service,
When a < λ α δ 2 / 2 δ  holds on, the optimal price and demand of the NEV-SM maker at stage II are lower than at stage I (i.e.,  p 1 Π < p 1 Ι ,   D 1 Π < D 1 Ι ). When b < λ α δ 2 / 2 δ  holds on, we find the optimal price and demand of the NEV-SM maker’s rival at stage II are larger than at stage I (i.e.,  p 2 Π > p 2 Ι ,   D 2 Π > D 2 Ι ).
Lemma 2 exhibits that, in the absence of an extended warranty service, when the subsidy standards a and b are below a specific threshold value (i.e., λ α δ 2 / 2 δ ), both the demand and price for the NEV-SM maker at stage I are larger than those at stage II, whereas for the NEV-CM maker, the outcome is the opposite, which shows that government subsidies have little effect on the NEV-SM maker at stage II if the government’s subsidy size reduces slightly. With this in mind, the government should still offer subsidies of sufficient size to support the NEV-SM makers at stage II, avoiding investment inefficiency.
Lemma 3.
With the extended warranty service,
(i) 
When  α k 2 > β δ 2 + 2 a β δ ,     λ > α k 2 a β δ / α β  or  α k 2 < β δ 2 ,     λ > β δ 2 α k 2 + a β δ / α β  is satisfied, for the NEV-SM maker, the optimal price and demand at the preliminary stage I is higher than at the mature stage II (i.e.,   p 1 ~ Π < p 1 ~ Ι ,  D 1 ~ Π < D 1 ~ Ι );
(ii) 
When  λ α + b δ > α k 2 / β > δ 2 + 2 b δ  or  δ 2 > α k 2 / β > δ 2 α λ + b δ  hold on, for the NEV-SM maker, the optimal price and demand at the mature stage II is larger than at the preliminary stage I (i.e.,  p 2 ~ Π > p 2 ~ Ι ,   D 2 ~ Π > D 2 ~ Ι ).
Lemma 3 reveals that even if extended warranty services are introduced by the NEV-CM maker, at stage II, government subsidies can help the NEV-CM manufacturer improve its position compared to at stage I. However, for the NEV-SM maker, at the initial stage of the subsidy, the optimal price is maintained at a lower level, and its market share is larger than its rival, which verifies that government subsidies to the NEV-SM maker play a significant role at stage I when the NEV-CM maker provides the extended warranty services.
Corollary 3.
At stage I (or II),
(i) 
When  λ > δ 2 + 2 a δ / α  (for stage II,  λ > δ 2 + 2 b δ / α ) is satisfied, the NEV-SM maker’s optimal price and demand in the presence of a subsidy at stage I (II) are higher than those in the absence of a subsidy, i.e.,  p 1 Ι > p 1 ,   D 1 Ι > D 1  ( p 1 Π > p 1 ,   D 1 Π > D 1 ); while for the NEV-CM maker, the optimal price and demand in the presence of a subsidy at stage I (II) are lower than those in the absence of a subsidy, i.e.,  p 2 Ι < p 2 ,     D 2 Ι < D 2  ( p 2 Π < p 2 ,     D 2 Π < D 2 ).
(ii) 
When  λ > k 2 / β > ( δ 2 + 2 a δ ) / α  or  β δ 2 2 > α k 2 > β δ 2 λ α β + 2 a β δ  (for stage II,  α k 2 > β δ 2 + 2 b β δ ,     λ > k 2 / 2 β  or  α k 2 < β δ 2 ,     λ > β δ 2 α k 2 + 2 b β δ / α β ) holds on, the NEV-SM maker’s optimal price and demand in the presence of a subsidy at stage I (II) are lower than those in the absence of a subsidy, i.e.,  p 1 ~ Π < p 1 ,   ~   D 1 ~ Ι < D 1 ~  ( p 1 ~ Π < p 1 ,   ~   D 1 ~ Π < D 1 ~ ); while for the NEV-CM maker, the optimal price, the duration of the extended warranty service, and demand in the presence of a subsidy at stage I (II) are higher than those in the absence of a subsidy, i.e.,  p 2 ~ Ι > p 2 ,   ~   D 2 ~ Ι > D 2 ~ ,     T ~ Ι > T ~  ( p 2 ~ Π > p 2 ,   ~   p 2 ~ Π > D 2 ~ ,     T ~ Π > T ~ ).
Corollary 3 (i) illustrates that when λ surpasses a specific value, the government subsidy can help the NEV-SM maker to promote the swapping mode but thwart the wide adoption of the charging mode at both stages. Interestingly, even if the NEV-SM maker’s optimal price in the presence of the subsidy is higher than that in the absence of the subsidy, the demand still expands in the presence of the subsidy. Corollary 3 (ii) shows the opposite, that is when λ > k 2 / β > ( δ 2 + 2 a δ ) /   α or β δ 2 2 > α k 2 > β δ 2 λ α β + 2 a β δ , the government subsidy policy is beneficial to the NEV-CM maker rather than the NEV-SM maker, which reveals that such a policy is a two-edged sword, and reminds policymakers to trade-off between the swapping mode and the charging mode in the development of NEV.

5. Numerical Study

In this section, we further investigate the effect of battery swapping and charging modes on consumer surplus and social welfare in the setting of subsidies. We also examine the impact of key variables, including the swapping station′s convenience coefficient and the coefficient of the duration of the extended warranty service, on the production decision of the two NEV makers and consumers’ choice between the battery swapping and charging modes under different conditions (with/without the extended warranty service, with/without subsidies).
Based on the literature [23] and actual data from Nio Auto and BAIC, we could set λ as 0.7, the unit cost of the NEV-SM and NEV-CM as 1, the actual value of the products as 0.5, the service coefficient of the extended warranty service as 0.2 to 0.6, and then we assume the government subsidy under stage I and II as a = 0.4 and b = 0.1. As Nio Auto officially announced that power-swapping technology can realize the rapid replacement of power batteries within 3 min, the battery-swapping station convenience coefficient ranges from 0.5 to 0.9. The other specific parameter values are shown in the Appendix A (Table A3).

5.1. The Impact on Consumer Surplus and Social Welfare

In this sub-section, we examine the effect of two key exogenous variables (i.e., δ, k) on consumer surplus and social welfare under different conditions (with/without the extended warranty service, with/without subsidies). For a consumer with a NEV-SM or a NEV-CM, the surplus for stage I is as follows:
C S Ι p 1 Ι , m Ι = v p 1 Ι + δ m Ι × δ m Ι p 1 Ι + p 2 Ι λ + v 1 + λ p 2 Ι × 1 δ m Ι p 1 Ι + p 2 Ι λ
For social welfare, it consists of three facets: the profit from the NEV-SM maker and the NEV-CM maker, the government subsidy, and the consumers’ surplus, thus social welfare for stage I can be described as follows:
S W Ι p 1 Ι , m Ι = δ m Ι p 1 Ι + p 2 Ι λ × p 1 Ι c 1 2 α m Ι 2 + a m Ι T h e   p r o f i t   o f   t h e   N E V S M + 1 δ m Ι p 1 Ι + p 2 Ι λ × p 2 Ι c T h e   p r o f i t   o f   t h e   N E V C M a m s Ι T h e   g o v e r n m e n t   s u b s i d y   o n   s t a g e   Ι + C S Ι T h e   c o n s u m e r s’   s u r p l u s   o n   s t a g e   Ι
Similar to Formulas (21) and (22), we can obtain the corresponding consumer surplus and social welfare under other different conditions. For brevity, we have skipped it.
Figure 1a compares the effect of the convenience coefficient of swapping stations on consumer surplus at stages I and II under the extended warranty service. It reveals that there exists a threshold value ( δ = 0.84 ), above which the consumer surplus at stage II is larger than zero, hence consumers intend to purchase. Otherwise, the consumer will give up. Meanwhile, it is obvious that the consumer surplus at stage I is greater than at stage II. This means that the higher the convenience of a power-swapping station, the higher the consumer surplus, and the less effective government subsidies are. Figure 1b shows the effect of the extended warranty service coefficient on consumer surplus. With the increase in k, the consumer surplus at stages I and II increase, this means that the higher the service level, the higher the consumer surplus at both stages. However, the consumer surplus at stage II is more than at stage I, which is the opposite of Figure 1a.
Figure 1c,d demonstrates that the difference in social welfare at stages I and II with/without the extended warranty service under the influence of δ and k. We find that regardless of the change in δ or k, the social welfare at stage II with the extended warranty service is the largest, followed by that at stage I with the extended warranty service. The smallest social welfare is the case with neither the subsidy nor the extended warranty service.

5.2. The Impact on Performance

The numerical examples examine the single and joint effects of critical parameters on profits, respectively, in different conditions (with/without the extended warranty service, at stage I/II). To exclude the influence of external factors, other variables are taken to have a moderate value.
(1) 
The single effect of α and δ on profits
Figure 2a exhibits that no matter the condition, when the cost coefficient of the swapping station increases, the NEV-SM maker’s profit decreases, while the NEV-CM maker’s profit increases. Meanwhile, comparing the profits of the two makers, we find the profit of the NEV-SM maker is the largest when the NEV-CM maker does not provide the extended warranty service and the swapping network has taken shape, whereas the profit of the NEV-CM maker is the lowest when the NEV-CM maker does not provide the extended warranty service and the swapping network is at the initial stage.
Figure 2b shows that no matter the condition, the NEV-SM maker’s profit increases with δ, while the NEV-CM maker’s profit drops with δ. This means that the convenience of power swapping has brought considerable profit to the NEV-SM maker, and yet has the opposite effect on its competitor. From Figure 2b, we also observe that the NEV-SM maker is most profitable when the NEV-CM maker does not provide the extended warranty service and the swapping network is at the maturity stage.
(2) 
The single effect of β and k on profits
Figure 3a shows that in the setting of the warranty service and subsidy, the NEV-SM maker’s profit increases slightly, and yet the NEV-CM manufacturer’s profit decreases slightly with β. Although the increase of the cost coefficient of the extended warranty service brings about the related change in the two manufacturers’ profits, such are not obvious, which means that the cost coefficient of the extended warranty service is not a sensitive factor for NEV makers.
Figure 3b displays that, in the setting of the warranty service and subsidy, the profit of the NEV-SM maker decreases with k, whereas the profit of the NEV-CM maker increases with k. It implies that the increase of the extended warranty service coefficient can enhance the NEV-CM maker′s profitability, which in turn impairs the NEV-SM maker’s performance. From Figure 3b, there exists a specific value k1, below which the lowest profit occurs to the NEV-CM maker in the case where the swapping network has taken shape; otherwise, it happens when the swapping network is at an infant stage. In contrast, there is another certain value k2, above which the highest profit occurs to the NEV-SM maker in the case where the swapping network has taken shape; otherwise, it happens when the swapping network is at an initial stage.
(3) 
The joint effect on profits
In the previous analysis, we further explored the joint effects of δ and k on the profits of the two makers, with an extended warranty service in two stages, namely the preliminary stage (stage I) and the mature stage (stage II). Then, we set up two cases to examine the low (α/β = 3) and high (α/β = 1) marginal cost ratios.
Figure 4a shows the NEV-SM maker’s profit increases at stage I and yet decreases with δ and k at stage II, while the NEV-CM maker’s profit first decreases and then increases with δ and k at stage I, but continues to increase with δ and k at stage II. Overall, the NEV-SM maker’s profit at stage I is always higher than the NEV-CM maker’s profit at stage I or II. Figure 4b demonstrates a similar pattern, the only difference being that when the marginal cost ratio is higher (α/β = 3), its impact on the NEV-SM maker and the NEV-CM maker is relatively larger. When the marginal cost ratio is relatively smaller (α/β = 1), the profit of both car manufacturers does not change much.

6. Conclusions

Due to the limited capacity of batteries, a battery swapping mode (SM) and a charging mode (CM) can be offered by NEV makers to recharge batteries, thus inevitably influencing potential consumers’ purchase behaviors accordingly. To examine the impact of SM and CM on consumers’ purchase intentions, this paper examines a duopolistic market consisting of two new energy vehicle makers (i.e., a NEV-SM maker and a NEV-CM maker), who adopt SM and CM to service consumers, respectively. Considering that the SM is characterized by a low initial investment cost and ease of use for consumers, NEV-CM makers capitalize on extended battery warranty services in response to rivals’ utilization of SM. Therefore, non-cooperative game models are formulated, in which government subsidies are taken into account. Optimal decisions for both the NEV-SM maker and the NEV-CM maker are analyzed under three scenarios: without an extended warranty service, with an extended warranty service, and with both an extended warranty service and a subsidy. Our results offer some insights as follows:
(1)
In the absence of an extended warranty service, there exists an optimal equilibrium condition for both carmakers, in which the NEV-SM maker adopts the low-price strategy at the initial development stage of NEV-SM, with aims to tap into the market and attract potential consumers, yet this move is not a long-term solution due to the fact that the NEV-CM maker invariably occupies more market share and profit in the NEV market.
(2)
In the presence of an extended warranty service, the NEV-CM maker does not necessarily dominate the market. Consumers’ choice of two kinds of products relies on two critical factors, namely λ   a n d   δ k . When 0 < δ k < ( 2 α / β ) 1 2 , λ > k 2 / β , the NEV-SM maker’s profit does surpass the NEV-CM maker’s. Nevertheless, the extended warranty service ultimately enhances the NEV-CM maker’s dominance.
(3)
In the absence of an extended warranty service, when the subsidy standards a and b are below a specific threshold value (i.e., λ α δ 2 / 2 δ ), both the demand and price for the NEV-SM maker at stage I are larger than those at stage II, whereas for the NEV-CM maker, the outcome is the opposite, which shows that government subsidies have little effect on NEV-SM manufacturers at stage II if the government subsidy’s size reduces to a degree.
(4)
In the presence of an extended warranty service, the government subsidy can dramatically increase the NEV-SM maker’s market share at stage I. Meanwhile, the numerical studies show that the NEV-SM maker’s profit, consumer surplus, and social welfare have been improved by implementing the subsidy policy, which implies that the subsidy is a critical factor in propelling the diffusion of the swapping mode at the initial stage.
There is still much space for future research. Our paper only examines NEV manufacturers and did not extend to a supply chain system composed of manufacturers and suppliers, thus one of the possible directions is to investigate optimal power-swapping stations and extended warranty services when taking investment sharing into account. Moreover, replacement and trade-in activity of products is a normal phenomenon in the NEV market, and thus it would be interesting to examine optimal decisions in the context of replacement and trade-in strategy.

Author Contributions

J.L.: Conceptualization, Methodology, Investigation, Project administration, Supervision, Writing—original draft, Writing—review & editing. D.W.: Methodology, Formal analysis, Investigation, Investigation, Writing—original draft, Writing—review & editing. Y.W.: Validation, Investigation, Writing—review & editing. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

WUST: Research on Development of Smart Logistics Digital Operation Platform (2022H20537), Natural Science Foundation of China (71964023) and Key Project of Philosophy and Social Sciences of Hubei Province’s Education Department (22D021).

Data Availability Statement

Data will be made available on request.

Acknowledgments

This research is funded by WUST: Research on Development of Smart Logistics Digital Operation Platform (2022H20537), Natural Science Foundation of China (71964023) and Key Project of Philosophy and Social Sciences of Hubei Province’s Education Department (22D021).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest to report regarding the present study.

Appendix A

Table A1. Summary of notations.
Table A1. Summary of notations.
NotationsDefinition
Decisions
MThe number of battery-swapping stations
TThe duration of the extended warranty service
p i Product price of NEVs with i mode (i = 1 refers to SM, i = 2 stands for CM)
Parameters
α The cost coefficient of battery-swapping stations
β The cost coefficient of the extended warranty service
δ The battery swapping station’s convenience coefficient
kThe extended warranty service coefficient
λ The valuation incremental rate of CM relative to SM
sThe amount of the government subsidy
u i Consumer utility of NEVs with i mode (i = 1 refers to SM, i = 2 stands for CM)
v Consumer valuation of the NEV-SM product
c i Unit product cost of NEVs with i mode (i = 1 refers to SM, i = 2 stands for CM)
D i Consumer demand of NEVs with i mode (i = 1 refers to SM, i = 2 stands for CM)
π i Profit of NEVs with i mode (i = 1 refers to SM, i = 2 stands for CM)
Table A2. The optimal solutions in the presence of subsidies.
Table A2. The optimal solutions in the presence of subsidies.
Without the Extended Warranty Service With the Extended Warranty Service
Stage IStage IIStage IStage II
Extended warranty service duration T * Ι , Π T ~ * Ι , Π k 2 α λ δ 2 a δ α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ k 2 α λ δ 2 b δ α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ
Number of swapping stations m * Ι , Π λ 3 a + δ 3 α λ δ 2 λ 3 b + δ 3 α λ δ 2 m ~ * Ι , Π k 2 a + δ β λ 3 a + δ α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ k 2 b + δ β λ 3 b + δ α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ
Price p 1 * Ι , Π λ a δ + α λ + c 3 α λ δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 λ b δ + α λ + c 3 α λ δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 p 1 ~ * Ι , Π α β λ 3 c + λ + α k 2 c + λ β δ a λ c δ / α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ α β λ 3 c + λ + α k 2 c + λ β δ b λ c δ / α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ
p 2 * Ι , Π λ 2 α λ δ 2 a δ + c 3 α λ δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 λ 2 α λ δ 2 b δ + c 3 α λ δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 p 2 ~ * Ι , Π 2 α β λ 2 + c α k 2 + β δ 2 + λ β 3 c α + a δ + δ 2 / α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ 2 α β λ 2 + c α k 2 + β δ 2 + λ β 3 c α + b δ + δ 2 / α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ
Demand D 1 * Ι , Π a δ + α λ 3 α λ δ 2 b δ + α λ 3 α λ δ 2 D 1 ~ * Ι , Π a β δ + α β λ α k 2 α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ b β δ + α β λ α k 2 α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ
D 2 * Ι , Π 2 α λ δ 2 a δ 3 α λ δ 2 2 α λ δ 2 b δ 3 α λ δ 2 D 2 ~ * Ι , Π β 2 α λ δ 2 a δ α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ β 2 α λ δ 2 b δ α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ
Profit π 1 * Ι , Π λ 2 α λ 2 + α λ 9 a 2 + 4 a δ δ 2 2 a δ 2 2 a + δ / 2 3 α λ δ 2 2 λ 2 α λ 2 + α λ 9 a 2 + 6 a δ δ 2 2 b δ + 18 a 2 18 a b + 6 a b δ 2 2 δ 2 3 a 2 + a δ + 2 b 2 / 2 3 α λ δ 2 2 π 1 ~ * Ι , Π λ β 2 2 α λ 2 + α λ 9 a 2 + 4 a δ δ 2 2 a δ 2 2 a + δ 2 β k 2 2 α λ 2 + α λ a + δ 3 a δ a δ 2 a + δ + α k 4 a 2 + 2 α λ δ 2 / 2 α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ 2 α λ 2 β 2 δ 2 + 2 δ 3 a b + α λ 2 β 2 9 b 2 + 6 α β λ k 2 b 2 + 2 α β λ k 2 δ 2 2 δ 2 a b α k 4 δ 2 2 δ a b 2 β δ 2 β λ a δ + 2 b 2 + k 2 a δ + b 2 + 2 λ α 2 k 2 β λ 2 + α k 4 b 2 / 2 α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ 2
π 2 * Ι , Π λ 2 α λ δ 2 a δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 2 λ 2 α λ δ 2 b δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 2 π 2 ~ * Ι , Π β 2 β λ k 2 2 α λ δ 2 a δ 2 / 2 α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ 2 β 2 β λ k 2 2 α λ δ 2 b δ 2 / 2 α k 2 + β δ 2 3 α β λ 2
Table A3. The value of parameters.
Table A3. The value of parameters.
cvkAbδαβλ
10.50.2–0.60.40.10.5–0.90.6–0.80.3–0.50.7
Proof of Proposition 1.
The first-order derivatives of Equation (9) with respect to p 1 ,   m can be set to 0 as follows:
π 1 p 1 = c 2 p 1 + p 2 + δ m λ = 0
π 1 m = δ p 1 c λ α m λ = 0
The Hessian matrix of Equation (9) is:
H p 1 , m = 2 π 1 p 1 2 2 π 1 p 1 m 2 π 1 m p 1 2 π 1 m 2 = 2 λ δ λ δ λ α
Note that the Hessian matrix is a negative definite for all decision variables that satisfy the conditions: λ > δ 2 2 α . The first-order derivatives of Equation (9) with respect to p 2 can be set to 0 as follows:
π 2 p 2 = λ + c 2 p 2 + p 1 δ m λ = 0
Note that 2 π 2 p 2 2 = 2 λ < 0 . Since the second-order partial derivative is a joint concave function, there is always a maximum. Solving Equations (9), (10), (A1), and (A2), we derive the results of Proposition 1. □
Proof of Lemma 1.
Considering the negative conditions of the Hessian matrix in Equations (A3), we obtain that p 1 ,   p 2 , and m are positive when λ > δ 2 2 α . For further guaranteeing the demand NEV-SM and NEV-CM positive, the inequality 2 α λ δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 > 0 holds on. It is easy to explain that when p 1 < p 2 ,     λ > δ 2 2 α , the conditions of optimal solutions under the base model is given by λ > δ 2 α , whereas if δ 2 α > λ > δ 2 2 α is satisfied, the optimal solutions do not exist. □
Proof of Theorem 1.
Similar to Lemma 1, and we obtain the conditions under base model by λ > δ 2 α . Recall the optimal values p 1 * ,     p 2 * ,     D 1 * ,     D 2 * , and m * in the Appendix A (Table A2) and compare the demand and profit between NEV-SM and NEV-CM that is, D 1 * D 2 * = α λ + δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 < 0 , this inequality is always true as long as the limiting conditions are satisfied and the demand of NEV-CM exceeds the demand of NEV-SM. Furthermore, the profit of NEV-SM and NEV-CM can be recognized by π 1 * = α λ 2 2 α λ δ 2 2 3 α λ δ 2 and π 2 * = λ 2 α λ δ 2 2 3 α λ δ 2 . The profit point for NEV-SM and NEV-CM under the base model can be derived by: π 1 * π 2 * = λ 6 α 2 λ 2 + 7 α λ δ 2 2 δ 4 2 3 α λ δ 2 2 < 0 . Conclusively, we obtain that when λ > δ 2 α , the NEV-SM gain less profits than NEV-CM under the base model. □
Proof of Corollary 1.
Recall the optimal profit of NEV-SM in Proposition 1, that is, π 1 * = α λ 2 2 α λ δ 2 2 3 α λ δ 2 , we can easily find the relationship: when the condition λ > δ 2 2 α is satisfied, π 1 * α = λ 2 δ 2 α λ δ 2 2 3 α λ δ 2 3 < 0 , and π 1 * δ = α δ λ 2 α λ δ 2 3 α λ δ 2 3 > 0 . According to these inequations, it is sufficient for us to illustrate the findings in Corollary 1. □
Proof of Proposition 2.
Similar to Proposition 1, taking the first order derivatives of Equation (14) with respect to p 1 ~ and m ~ making them equal to 0, we obtain:
π 1 ~ p 1 ~ = c k T ~ 2 p 1 ~ + p 2 ~ + δ m ~ λ = 0
π 1 ~ m ~ = δ p 1 ~ c λ α m ~ + α λ λ = 0
The Hessian matrix of Equation (14) is:
H p 1 ~ , m ~ = 2 π 1 ~ p 1 ~ 2 2 π 1 ~ p 1 ~ m ~ 2 π 1 ~ m ~ p 1 ~ 2 π 1 ~ m ~ 2 = 2 λ δ λ δ λ α
Note that the Hessian matrix of π 1 ~ is a negative definite only for all decision variables that satisfy the conditions: λ > δ 2 2 α . Similar to Equation (14), we omit the specific calculation process of Equation (15), the conditions satisfied by the Hessian negative definite is: λ > k 2 2 β . To sum up, the conditions are that, when α k 2 > β δ 2 ,     λ > k 2 / 2 β ; while α k 2 < β δ 2 ,     λ > δ 2 / 2 α . By solving Equations (14), (15), and (A7), we accordingly deduce the optimal solution of Proposition 2. □
Proof of Theorem 2.
We first verify our findings in Theorem 2(i), and considering the negative conditions satisfied by the Hessian matrix in Equation (A7) and for further guaranteeing the demands are positive, we let D 1 ~ * = α k 2 a β δ α β λ α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 > 0 and D 2 ~ * = β δ 2 + a β δ 2 α β λ α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 > 0 . By solving λ   in these equations, we have the result that, when 2 α k 2 > β δ 2 ,   λ > k 2 / β ; while 2 α k 2 < β δ 2 ,     λ > δ 2 / 2 α . We compare the optimal demand and profit of NEV-SM and NEV-CM with the limiting conditions under the extended warranty service, and know that, D 1 ~ * D 2 ~ * = α k 2 2 a β δ + α β λ β δ 2 α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 ,     π 1 ~ * π 2 ~ * = 2 α λ δ 2 α k 4 3 α β 2 λ 2 + 2 β 2 δ 2 λ β k 2 δ 2 2 α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 2 . Hence, the relationships of demand and profit of NEV-SM and NEV-CM are determined by: when 2 α k 2 > β δ 2 ,   λ > k 2 / β , we obtain D 1 ~ * < D 2 ~ * ,     π 1 ~ * > π 2 ~ * , the findings in Theorem 2(i) can be proved. When 2 α k 2 < β δ 2 ,     δ 2 / 2 α < λ < β δ 2 α k 2 / 2 α β , the relationships do not exist, then when 2 α k 2 < β δ 2 ,     λ > β δ 2 α k 2 / 2 α β , we deduce that D 1 ~ * < D 2 ~ * ,     π 1 ~ * > π 2 ~ * . That means the demand of SM is always lower than CM, while the relationships of profit between them depends on the limitations. For this reason, Theorem 2(ii) can be elaborated. □
Proof of Corollary 2.
Similar to Corollary 1, we recall the optimal extended warranty service and the number of swapping stations in the setting of the extended warranty service, that is, T ~ * = k a δ 2 α λ + δ 2 α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 , m ~ * = β λ 3 a + δ k 2 a + δ α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 . We can easily obtain the monotonicity of δ , Corollary 2(i) can be validated when 2 α k 2 > β δ 2 ,   λ > k 2 / β by letting T ~ * δ = 2 α k δ k 2 β λ α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 > 0 , m ~ * δ = k 2 β λ α k 2 3 α β λ β δ 2 α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 > 0 . While 2 α k 2 < β δ 2 ,   λ > β δ 2 α k 2 / 2 α β , we obtain T ~ * δ < 0 ,     m ~ * δ < 0 . Thus, the findings in Corollary 2(ii) can be illustrated. □
Proof of Lemma 2.
Using the same method as 1, we can obtain the limit condition is λ > δ 2 + 2 α δ / α , and similarly to Propositions 1 and 2, we can discover the optimal solution of NEV-SM and NEV-CM. The specific solutions are shown in the Appendix A (Table A2). Through the inequality p 1 II p 1 I = λ δ b a 3 λ α δ 2 < 0 , p 2 II p 2 I = λ δ a b 3 λ α δ 2 > 0 , D 1 II D 1 I = δ b a 3 λ α δ 2 < 0 , D 2 II D 2 I = δ a b 3 λ α δ 2 > 0 , we can clearly see the changes in the price and demand of NEV-SM and NEV-CM in the absence of an extended warranty with different government subsidies. □
Proof of Lemma 3.
The proof of Lemma 3 is similar to Lemma 2, we will ellipsis the proof here and not explain the specifics anymore. □
Proof of Corollary 3.
Firstly, we will verify p 1 I p 1 = a λ δ 3 λ α δ 2 > 0 , p 2 I p 2 = a λ δ 3 λ α δ 2 < 0 , D 1 I D 1 = a δ 3 λ α δ 2 > 0 , D 2 I D 2 = a δ 3 λ α δ 2 < 0 . From the Appendix A (Table A2), we understand the price and demand of NEV-CM under different situations. By detecting the intersection with respect to λ of the inequality and the limiting conditions α k 2 > δ 2 + 2 a δ / α , we know that Corollary 3(i) is always correct. The Appendix A (Table A2) shows the retail price of NEV-SM and NEV-CM under the preliminary stage of the government subsidy. It is simple to attain the different cases, which can be expressed by p 1 I ~ p 1 ~ = a β δ λ α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 < 0 , p 2 I ~ p 2 ~ = a β δ λ α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 > 0 , D 1 I ~ D 1 ~ = a β δ α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 < 0 , D 2 I ~ D 2 ~ = a β δ α k 2 3 α β λ + β δ 2 > 0 . By solving the intersection with respect to λ in these inequations   α k 2 > β δ 2 + 2 a β δ , λ > k 2 β   o r   2 α k 2 < β δ 2 , λ > β δ 2 α k 2 + 2 a β δ / α β , we observe that the results of the above relationship is always true so long as the limiting conditions are satisfied. Corollary 3(ii) can henceforth be demonstrated. For stage II, the results can be verified using the same method. □

References

  1. Li, J.; Ku, Y.; Yu, Y.; Liu, C.; Zhou, Y. Optimizing production of new energy vehicles with across-chain cooperation under China’s dual credit policy. Energy 2020, 2, 1330–1340. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Liu, W.; Yi, H. What Affects the Diffusion of New Energy Vehicles Financial Subsidy Policy? Evidence from Chinese Cities. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2020, 17, 726. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Šare, A.; Krajačić, G.; Pukšec, T.; Duić, N. The integration of renewable energy sources and electric vehicles into the power system of the Dubrovnik region. Energy Sustain. Soc. 2015, 5, 271–287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Liu, C.; Wang, X.; Wu, X.; Zou, Y.; Zhang, H.; Yao, L.; Zhang, Y.; Cui, Q. Economic dispatch for microgrid with electric vehicles in plug-in charging and battery swapping modes. In Proceedings of the IEEE PES Asia-Pacific Power and Energy Engineering Conference (APPEEC), Xi’an, China, 25–28 October 2016; pp. 1158–1163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Li, J.; Ku, Y.; Liu, C.; Zhou, Y. Dual credit policy: Promoting new energy vehicles with battery recycling in a competitive environment? J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 243, 118456. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Yao, C.Z.; Luo, J. Deployment of a charging network based on a cost-benefit model and the CFSFDP algorithm. Kybernetes 2018, 48, 1989–2005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Moghaddam, Z.; Ahmad, I.; Habibi, D.; Phung, Q.V. Smart Charging Strategy for Electric Vehicle Charging Stations. IEEE Trans. Transp. Electrif. 2018, 4, 76–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Schiffer, M.; Walther, G. The electric location routing problem with time windows and partial recharging. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 260, 995–1013. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Hof, J.; Schneider, M.; Goeke, D. Solving the battery swap station location-routing problem with capacitated electric vehicles using an AVNS algorithm for vehicle-routing problems with intermediate stops. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 2017, 97, 102–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Yang, J.; Sun, H. Battery swap station location-routing problem with capacitated electric vehicles. Comput. Oper. Res. 2015, 55, 217–232. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Zhang, N.; Zhang, Y.; Ran, L.; Liu, P.; Guo, Y. Robust location and sizing of electric vehicle battery swapping stations considering users’ choice behaviors. J. Energy Storage 2022, 5, 105561. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Wu, H.; Pang, G.K.H.; Choy, K.L.; Lam, H.Y. An Optimization Model for Electric Vehicle Battery Charging at a Battery Swapping Station. IEEE Trans. Veh. Technol. 2018, 67, 881–895. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Zhang, X.; Zhang, B.; Dong, L.; Guan, Z.; Guan, J.; Xie, R. Operation optimization of electric vehicles in battery swapping mode and direct charging mode in microgrid. Autom. Electr. Power Syst. 2016, 40, 56–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Wu, P. Which battery-charging technology and insurance contract is preferred in the electric vehicle sharing business? Transp. Res. Part A 2019, 124, 537–548. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Kurata, H.; Nam, S.-H. After-sales service competition in a supply chain: Optimization of customer satisfaction level or profit or both? Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2010, 127, 136–146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Zheng, B.; Bian, Y.; Sun, Y.; Ding, H. Optimal extended warranty strategy: Uniform or nonuniform pricing? Int. Trans. Oper. Res. 2018, 28, 1441–1464. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Tong, P.; Liu, Z.; Men, F.; Cao, L. Designing and pricing of two-dimensional extended warranty contracts based on usage rate. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2014, 52, 6362–6380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Gallego, G.; Wang, R.; Hu, M.; Ward, J.; Beltran, J.L. No Claim? Your Gain: Design of Residual Value Extended Warranties Under Risk Aversion and Strategic Claim Behavior. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2015, 17, 87–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Yi, Y.Y.; Yao, J.J. Supply chain coordination for extended warranty provided by strong retailer under network externality. Comput. Integr. Manuf. Syst. 2014, 20, 1987–1999. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Zhao, D.; Zhang, X.; Ren, T.; Fu, H. Optimal Pricing Strategies in a Product and Service Supply Chain with Extended Warranty Service Competition considering Retailer Fairness Concern. Math. Probl. Eng. 2019, 8, 8657463. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. He, Z.; Huang, D.; He, S. Design of extended warranty service in a dual supply channel. Total. Qual. Manag. Bus. Excel. 2018, 29, 1089–1107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Lau, H.-S.; Su, C.; Wang, Y.-Y.; Hua, Z.-S. Volume discounting coordinates a supply chain effectively when demand is sensitive to both price and sales effort. Comput. Oper. Res. 2012, 39, 3267–3280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Widrick, R.S.; Nurre, S.G.; Robbins, M.J. Optimal Policies for the Management of an Electric Vehicle Battery Swap Station. Transp. Sci. 2018, 52, 59–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The influence on consumer surplus and social welfare.
Figure 1. The influence on consumer surplus and social welfare.
Wevj 14 00211 g001
Figure 2. The single effect of α and δ .
Figure 2. The single effect of α and δ .
Wevj 14 00211 g002
Figure 3. The single effect of β and k.
Figure 3. The single effect of β and k.
Wevj 14 00211 g003
Figure 4. The joint effects of δ and k. (a) α/β = 3; (b) α/ β = 1.
Figure 4. The joint effects of δ and k. (a) α/β = 3; (b) α/ β = 1.
Wevj 14 00211 g004
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Li, J.; Wu, D.; Wang, Y. How to Choose the Refueling of New Energy Vehicles under Swapping vs. Charging Mode: From the Consumers’ Perspective. World Electr. Veh. J. 2023, 14, 211. https://doi.org/10.3390/wevj14080211

AMA Style

Li J, Wu D, Wang Y. How to Choose the Refueling of New Energy Vehicles under Swapping vs. Charging Mode: From the Consumers’ Perspective. World Electric Vehicle Journal. 2023; 14(8):211. https://doi.org/10.3390/wevj14080211

Chicago/Turabian Style

Li, Jizi, Doudou Wu, and Yong Wang. 2023. "How to Choose the Refueling of New Energy Vehicles under Swapping vs. Charging Mode: From the Consumers’ Perspective" World Electric Vehicle Journal 14, no. 8: 211. https://doi.org/10.3390/wevj14080211

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop