Next Article in Journal
Characterization of South African Woody and Non-Woody Invasive Alien Plant Species for Sustainable Bio-Oil Production
Previous Article in Journal
How to Mitigate the Risk of Late Payments? The Case of the Largest Polish Companies Selling Electricity in 2018–2023
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Optimal Investment and Sharing Decisions in Renewable Energy Communities with Multiple Investing Members

by
Inês Carvalho
1,
Jorge Sousa
1,2,*,
José Villar
3,
João Lagarto
1,2,
Carla Viveiros
1 and
Filipe Barata
1,4,5
1
ISEL—Instituto Superior de Engenharia de Lisboa, Instituto Politécnico de Lisboa, 1549-020 Lisboa, Portugal
2
INESC-ID, Rua Alves Redol, 9, 1000-029 Lisboa, Portugal
3
INESC TEC, Rua Dr. Roberto Frias, 4200-465 Porto, Portugal
4
UnIRE, ISEL, Polytechnic University of Lisbon, 1549-020 Lisboa, Portugal
5
Low Carbon Energy Conversion Group (LCEC), Electrical Engineering Department, 1959-007 Lisboa, Portugal
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2025, 18(8), 1920; https://doi.org/10.3390/en18081920
Submission received: 1 March 2025 / Revised: 28 March 2025 / Accepted: 8 April 2025 / Published: 9 April 2025
(This article belongs to the Section A: Sustainable Energy)

Abstract

:
The Renewable Energy Communities (RECs) and self-consumption frameworks defined in Directive (EU) 2023/2413 and Directive (EU) 2024/1711 are currently being integrated into national regulations across EU member states, adapting legislation to incorporate these new entities. These regulations establish key principles for individual and collective self-consumption, outlining operational rules such as proximity constraints, electricity sharing mechanisms, surplus electricity management, grid tariffs, and various organizational aspects, including asset sizing, licensing, metering, data exchange, and role definitions. This study introduces a model tailored to optimize investment and energy-sharing decisions within RECs, enabling multiple members to invest in solar photovoltaic (PV) and wind generation assets. The model determines the optimal generation capacity each REC member should install for each technology and calculates the energy shared between members in each period, considering site-specific constraints on renewable deployment. A case study with a four-member REC is used to showcase the model’s functionality, with simulation results underscoring the benefits of CSC over ISC.

1. Introduction

Renewable Energy Communities (RECs) and self-consumption (SC) concepts included in Directive (EU) 2023/2413 [1] and Directive (EU) 2024/1711 [2] are being transposed to national regulations by the EU members to adapt national legislations to these entities. These regulations define the main concepts of individual and collective self-consumption (ISC and CSC, respectively) and the operational rules of these structures such as the proximity requirements, the electricity sharing mechanisms allowed, the treatment of the electricity surplus, the grid tariffs to be paid by the SC, and other organizational aspects, such as asset sizing and licensing rules, metering requirements, data to be exchanged, and parties’ responsibilities [3]. In addition, [4] proposes a novel multi-objective optimal power flow algorithm to assess the trade-off between ISC and CSC, minimizing individual energy costs and mitigating distribution grid constraints, especially in low-voltage networks. Moreover, the very recent reform proposal of the EU [5] states that end consumers should have the right to share renewable electricity directly, without the need for creating energy communities, trying to reduce barriers and incentivize the development of self-consumption structures and further empowering consumers to become active participants of the energy system. A comprehensive review regarding REC concepts, challenges, and recommendations is presented in [6].
The 2019 European Clean Energy Package brought to RECs a new level of autonomy. “Regulatory sandboxes” as a limited-time real-world testing environment might allow for the testing of REC incentives and the necessary business models to uncover best practices for overcoming issues caused by incompatibility with present legal and regulatory frameworks [7]. Under this context, tools are needed to incentivize and facilitate the development of self-consumption structures and energy communities [8,9], in particular for investment decisions on new distributed energy resources (DERs), for the economic assessment of business models, or digital platforms for the operation of collective self-consumption. Collective self-consumption within RECs enables local energy trading among participants, with studies illustrating various configurations and tools to optimize energy sharing. A French test case implementing a two-stage approach to separate energy management and contractual settlement yielded an 11.7% reduction in overall community energy costs, promoting individual savings [10].
In Spain, a specialized tool using genetic algorithms for multi-objective optimization of solar energy allocation achieved high self-consumption, reduced energy excess, and shorter payback periods, boosting both economic and environmental benefits of REC participation [11]. Sizing and economic assessment tools optimize individual or collective benefits depending on the selected business models [12,13]. Business models depend on the financing mechanisms available to the potential members, their profiles in terms of active investors, or the energy-sharing rules that vary among different national transpositions of the EU directives on SC [3]. Several public and private ways of financing investments in RECs are detailed in [14]. Various studies are exploring RECs’ economic, environmental, and operational optimization. One approach analyzes the economic feasibility of energy communities with different investment options, revealing that third-party investments are profitable with a 15-year payback, while joint investment benefits households despite higher initial costs [15]. Another study [16] introduces a novel bilevel programming framework combined with reinforcement learning for managing community microgrids, demonstrating up to 40% reduction in the levelized cost of energy (LCOE) and improved supply quality in a real-world case. Complementing this, a mixed-integer linear programming approach quantifies the benefits of complementarity between prosumers’ generation and demand, with cost reductions of up to 50% through price-based demand-response programs and fair cost allocation methods [17]. Additionally, a thermal–electric co-simulation method applied to an Italian REC shows significant economic and environmental gains from optimizing energy sharing and self-consumption, especially regarding photovoltaic systems and storage [18]. A case study of a residential complex in Romania demonstrates the integration of photovoltaics, energy storage, and car-charging stations, highlighting the potential for creating sustainable and efficient energy [19].
Several other studies evaluate the accessible, risk-insured community investment options across Europe to unlock citizens’ social potential for investing in community renewable energy [20], as well as options in specific countries such as Italy [21], India [22], Canada [23], Spain [24], and Australia [25].
There are numerous business initiatives that might promote small and medium enterprise (SME) participation in European renewable energy communities: long-term purchase agreements for local renewable power between an SME and an electricity provider or a local developer; leasing and servicing contracts for energy infrastructure offered by traditional electricity providers to a group of geographically close SMEs; aggregator services involving demand flexibility aggregation and peer-to-peer trading facilitation, potentially developed as “white label” by international technology companies [26]. For RECs to function well and be efficiently integrated into the electricity grid, planning of renewable energy management systems is required [27]. Renewable energy communities are a powerful tool for this collective decentralization, democratization, and decarbonization of the energy system. How its members engage in the deployment of the community, the way they interact with each other, and the decision-making power each one has within the community are highly dependent on their investment participation, the REC’s governance or operation’s rules, and the business models adopted [14].
In the end, the business model defines the objective function of the optimization process and the costs and benefits to be considered, such as the investments costs, the costs of the electricity exchanges with the grid [28,29], the annual equivalent investment costs [30,31], the costs related to demand management and demand utility [32], or even penalties to consider other objectives such as reliability [33,34].
REC operation can be addressed with several strategies, such as market-based approaches, sometimes blockchain supported, where peers freely decide the amounts they are willing to buy or to sell in the local market and the prices [35,36], post-delivery market approaches, well suited to simplify and automate members’ processes, especially when no flexibility is dispatched [37], or centralized optimization approaches when there exist flexible resources that can be dispatched. Under this last category, if collective benefits sharing is also addressed, then an internal price must be defined, either with ad hoc pricing mechanisms or relying on the dual variables of the internal energy balance constraints [38,39]. Without a defined price, facilitating electricity sharing alongside demand response (DR) becomes challenging [40], and optimality conditions are then derived to determine various pricing conditions.
In particular, blockchain’s integration in RECs enables secure, decentralized energy sharing, as explored in [41], offering a foundational review of P2P energy trading, proposing agent-based pricing schemes and optimization tools to enhance fairness and efficiency. The authors of [42] operationalize this vision, demonstrating in an industrial case study how Ethereum-based smart contracts enable automated, GDPR-compliant, decentralized transactions. The study [43] shifts focus to user behavior, showing that trading preferences in P2P communities are shaped by electricity prices, storage levels, and autarky aspirations—crucial for aligning system design with user engagement. Complementing the technical and behavioral insight, [44,45] extend this by reviewing blockchain’s role in decentralization, central authorities, privacy, and compliance with EU energy directives. Technological overviews by [46] emphasize microgrid design and energy certification, while [47] demonstrates blockchain’s application in EV charging using PV surplus.
This work presents an enhanced REC planning model that builds on previous research [48] where REC configurations were restricted to a single investing member. Key advancements and contributions of this model, based on past literature, include: (a) enabling all REC members to act as potential investors, supporting investments in both solar PV and wind generation for self-consumption at both individual and collective levels; (b) broadening investment capabilities to promote a more collaborative and flexible REC structure that accommodates diverse member profiles and objectives; (c) structuring the model as a cost-minimization problem to reduce the total annualized cost of electricity supply for the REC; (d) incorporating revenue generation from electricity surplus sales to the day-ahead market. Additionally, the model accounts for renewable generation installed “behind-the-meter” for each investing member, ensuring that individually self-consumed electricity is exempt from self-consumption tariffs, thereby optimizing cost efficiency for each participant.
To achieve the objectives of this study, several steps were followed:
  • Extension of the model presented in [48] to incorporate the possibility of investment by multiple REC members, as well as the management costs associated with managing the REC.
  • Application of the extended model to a case study of a real REC comprising four members. Specifically, the actual annual consumption profiles of REC members were used, along with solar PV and wind production profiles for their location, based on average resource availability for an average year.
  • Analysis of case study results for two scenarios: one where electricity is not shared among REC members (ISC) and another where sharing takes place (CSC). This step aims to (i) assess the economic benefits of CSC compared to ISC and (ii) evaluate the impact of CSC on encouraging investment in renewable resources, specifically wind and solar PV, in contrast to ISC.
  • Investigation of sensitivity to cost variations, by analyzing whether the insights from the previous step hold when capital costs for wind and solar PV, as well as grid electricity tariffs, change.
  • Additional economic analysis, exploring the rationale behind the amount of solar PV and wind capacity invested in by REC members. This assessment considers LCOE and the concept of the marginal realized price (MRP) of each technology.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the model used for REC optimal decision; Section 3 presents the four member REC case study; and Section 4 draws the main conclusions.

2. Model Description

The model presented in this study evolves from [48] where a planning model for a REC with a single investing member is proposed. In the current upgraded model, REC members are potential investors, so that they can invest in renewable generation capacity, such as solar PV and wind, for individual and collective self-consumption. The model is based on a real REC, where members differ in their demand profile and on-site specific conditions to install solar PV. Considering REC 4, given the type of ownership, this member is not allowed to install any renewable generation, standing only as a consumer in the community.
The modifications made to the previous model include extending the set of members allowed to invest and enabling the installation of wind and solar PV to those members. Additionally, the model considers not only the cost reductions from consuming shared electricity produced by other REC members but also the savings from self-consumption of one’s own-produced electricity. Furthermore, the upgraded model realistically incorporates the costs associated with the self-consumption grid tariff and the management costs of the REC manager.
The model is formulated as a minimization problem of the overall annualized costs of electricity supply, considering eventual revenues from selling the electricity surplus to the grid at the day-ahead market (DAM) prices. The objective function includes: (i) the annualized investment costs of the installed renewable capacity of each REC member; (ii) the cost of the electricity supplied by the retailers from the main grid; (iii) the variable costs of sharing electricity among the REC members that include the managing costs of the community manager (EGAC in Portuguese) and the SC tariff; (iv) the fixed cost of the EGAC; and (v) the revenues coming from the surplus of electricity generation that is sold to the grid.
This setting considers the renewable capacity installed behind the meter of each investing REC member, so that the self-consumption tariff does not apply to the individual self-consumed electricity.
The optimal investment and operational decisions are computed as decision variables of the problem of minimizing the sum of the individual costs of each REC member i, as presented in the constrained optimization problems (1) to (7).
min C = r C R F r · C A P E X r · i P i , r + t i T i , t · b u y G r i d i , t + + t ( T t S C + E G A C V ) i b u y R E C i , t +   E G A C F t S t D A M i s e l l G r i d i , t
C is the objective function expressing the total annualized costs of electricity supply of the overall REC members, r is the renewable technology (solar PV and wind, in the present case), C R F r is the capital recovery factor of technology r , C A P E X r is the capital expenditure of technology r , i is the REC member, P i , r is the installed capacity of REC member i in renewable technology r , t is the time period, T i , t is the electricity tariff of REC member i in period t , which includes both the electricity and grid components, b u y G r i d i , t is the electricity supplied from the grid to REC member i in period t , T t S C is the self-consumption tariff in period t , E G A C V is the variable cost of the REC management entity ( E G A C ), b u y R E C i , t is the electricity self-consumed locally by REC member i in period t supplied by other REC members using the public grid, E G A C F is the fixed cost of the REC management entity, S t D A M is the DAM price for selling electricity to the grid, s e l l G r i d i , t is the electricity sold to the grid by REC member i in period t , D i , t is the electricity demand of REC member i in period t , R r , t is the normalized generation profile of renewable technology r in period t , s e l l R E C i , t is the electricity shared by REC member i with other REC members in period t , R r , t is the specific electricity generation profile from renewable technology r in period t , P i , r m i n is the minimum installed capacity of REC member i in renewable technology r , P i , r m a x is the maximum installed capacity of REC member i in renewable technology r , and P i m a x is the maximum overall capacity installed by REC member i in all renewable technologies.
This optimization problem is subject to constraints (2) to (7). Equation (2) sets the electricity demand of REC member i in period t equal to the renewable self-production, plus the electricity supply from the grid, plus the electricity shared by other REC members, minus the outgoing electricity surplus of REC i either shared with other REC members or sold to the grid.
D i , t = r R r , t P i , r + b u y G r i d i , t + b u y R E C i , t s e l l R E C i , t s e l l G r i d i , t
Condition (3) limits the outgoing electricity of REC member i in period t to its electricity surplus to the excess of its renewable self-production over its demand.
s e l l R E C i , t + s e l l G r i d i , t r R r , t P i , r D i , t
Condition (4) sets that internal electricity exchanges among REC members in each period t must sum zero, that is, the overall incoming electricity supplied to REC members from other REC members period t should equal the overall outgoing electricity supplied from the REC members to other REC members in period t.
i b u y R E C i , t = i s e l l R E C i , t
Condition (5) sets the minimum and maximum capacity of each renewable technology that can be installed by REC member i.
P i , r m i n P i , r P i , r m a x
Condition (6) sets the maximum overall capacity installed by each REC member i in all renewable technologies, which is bound by the contracted capacity of each REC member.
r P i , r P i m a x
Condition (7) sets the non-negative condition for the variables.
b u y G r i d i , t ,   b u y R E C i , t ,   s e l l R E C i , t ,   s e l l G r i d i , t   0
The capital recovery factor of each technology, C R F r , is given by (8):
C R F r = α   1 + α τ r 1 + α τ r 1
where α is the discount rate and τ r is the lifetime of technology r.
Note that, looking into the derivative of the CRF with respect to α defined in (8), it is observed that it is always positive, meaning that an increasing discount rate (α) leads to a monotonically increasing CRF. Initially rising steeply from an undefined value at α = 0, the CRF’s rate of increase gradually diminishes as α increases. Conversely, a decreasing discount rate results in a decreasing CRF. This effect is analogous to a decrease in CAPEX, stimulating increased investment. Therefore, higher discount rates correspond to lower investment levels, while lower discount rates encourage higher investment levels.

3. Case Study

The model described in the preceding section is applied to a real REC with four members, REC 1, REC 2, REC 3, and REC 4, which are connected to the medium-voltage (MV) power grid, represented in Figure 1. All members, except REC 4, are able invest in renewable generation (solar PV and wind) for self-consumption (individual and collective), the surplus being sold to the grid at the DAM price. Since the model is based on a real REC, where members differ in their demand profile and on-site specific conditions to install renewable sources, REC 4, given its type of ownership, is not allowed to install any renewable energy, standing only as a consumer in the community.

3.1. Input Data

The computation of the REC investment and operational decisions requires to input the demand profile of each member, the characteristics of the renewable technologies that can be installed, and the tariffs and prices of the electricity supplied to and by the grid and shared among REC members.
Table 1 shows the annual electricity demand, the peak demand, and the contracted capacity of each REC member of the case study.
The renewable generation technologies considered for investing are solar PV and wind. Table 2 shows the capital expenditure (CAPEX) and the lifetime of these technologies.
The electricity generated by the PV and wind technologies is obtained by multiplying the normalized generation profile of each technology by the corresponding installed capacity. To compute the specific generation profile of each technology, hourly data for each renewable resource (solar radiation and wind speed), at the location of the investing REC member facilities, were obtained from the photovoltaic geographical information system (PVGIS) [49].
Using this information, it is possible to compute the CRF, as given by (8), and the LCOE for each renewable technology. The investment financial indicators are presented in Table 3.
The integral tariff (including grid and electricity components) applicable to the electricity supplied at the MV was set to 100 €/MWh and the grid tariff for self-consumption that uses the public grid, which is applied to the electricity shared among the REC members, was set to 10 €/MWh. Both tariffs are considered flat rates applicable in all periods. The feed-in price for the electricity surplus sold to the market was set to zero. Table 4 summarizes the tariffs and prices used in the case study.

3.2. Results

The optimization model described in (1) to (7) was implemented as a linear programming problem using the General Algebraic Modeling System (GAMS). Each simulation runs over one year of operation on an hourly basis, computing the optimal investment decision for each renewable technology and the corresponding renewable generation, the self-consumption of each REC member, the electricity sharing among REC members, and the electricity surplus sold to the grid.
The installed capacity of the renewable technologies is constrained by the site-specific conditions—constraint (5)—and by the contract capacity—constraint (6)—using the values presented in Table 1.
It is assumed that REC 4 does not invest in renewable technologies, which means that it can only be a consumer of other REC members’ surplus.
Additional to the optimal sizing of the installed solar PV and wind capacity for each REC member, the present study also compares the CSC with the ISC approaches to evaluate the actual benefits of CSC over ISC. In this regard, Table 5 shows the optimal installed capacity for PV and wind of each REC member for the CSC and ISC approaches computed by the presented model.
Results presented in Table 5 put in evidence that CSC leads to higher installed renewable capacity per technology for all REC members when compared with the ISC setting. Overall, total renewable capacity accounts for 3631 kW in the CSC and 3134 kW in the ISC, an increase of 497 kW that corresponds to 16% more renewable capacity in CSC compared to the ISC case. The reason for this comes from the increased value of the additional capacity installed that enables more electricity to be shared with the REC members at an opportunity cost equal to their integral tariff (excluding the self-consumption grid tariff), contrary to the ISC where only self-consumption is valued at this tariff. The sources of electricity supplied to each REC member to meet its demand are presented in Table 6 for the CSC, as the supplier (grid supply), self-consumption (SC) from its own renewable generation, and the electricity shared by other REC members (SC from REC).
It can be observed that REC 1 is supplied mainly by the grid and by its own generation (45% and 54%, respectively). REC 2 is supplied predominantly by self-generation (56%) and by the grid (44%). REC 3 has a similar sourcing profile to the other two investing members with a balance between the grid supply and self-consumption (47% and 52%, respectively). Finally, REC 4, which is not able to install renewable capacity, is supplied mainly from the grid (64%) but also by the electricity shared by the other REC members (36%).
Table 7 shows how the self-generation of each REC member is used for its self-consumption (SC), shared with other REC members, or injected to the grid.
Renewable generation is mostly used by the facilities’ owners for ISC, which accounts for 77% of the total usage in REC 1, 79% in REC 2, and 60% in REC 3. The electricity shared with other REC members can be as high as 17% (REC 3). Finally, as mentioned previously, REC 4 does not install any renewable capacity and, therefore, it has no self-generation available.
Overall, 69% of the demand of the REC members is supplied from the grid, 28% from self-generation, and 3% from the electricity shared within the REC (Table 6). From the renewable generation perspective, 77% of the renewable generation is used for the ISC of the REC members, 7% is shared within the REC as CSC, and 16% is surplus injected into the electricity grid (Table 7).
The amount of 418 MWh of electricity shared among the REC members consists of trades from REC 1, REC 2, and REC 3, which are net sellers, to all the REC members, especially REC 4, which is the major buyer of the electricity shared within the REC, as it does not perform renewable generation.
Table 8 shows how the overall cost of the REC is higher in the ISC approach, when no electricity sharing is allowed. Indeed, the REC adds value to the members’ surplus by reducing the electricity supplied from the grid to other members, reducing the total REC electricity cost.
It should be noted that the total costs comprise both the electricity costs and the annualized investment costs, as presented in (1).
When a REC member is unable to produce its own electricity to meet its consumption, it can acquire it from other REC members sharing their surplus. Although no internal transaction prices were considered for the REC, the internal prices for the transactions to take place should always be lower than the grid supply prices and higher than the feed-in price of selling back to the grid, saving money for all REC members [37]. Table 9 compares the electricity purchased and sold in both the CSC and ISC approaches.
As expected, the amount of electricity purchased from the grid in the ISC is larger than in the CSC, in which the electricity is partially supplied by the REC members’ electricity surplus, also incentivizing a larger installation of renewable generation capacity. In some cases, although the installed capacity in the ISC approach is lower, the sales to the grid can be higher (e.g., REC 1) as there is no other option for the surplus in the ISC case. Again, REC 4 cannot sell electricity within the REC since it does not install any generation capacity either in the ISC or in the CSC.
Figure 2, Figure 3, Figure 4 and Figure 5 show, for REC 1 to REC 4, respectively, hourly simulation results for one selected month (May). They present the demand profile, the renewable generation of PV and wind, the electricity supplied from the grid and from other REC members, and the electricity sold to the grid.
Figure 2 shows how REC 1, that performs renewable generation (PV and wind), manages to fully self-supply its demand during some solar hours, shares electricity surplus with other REC members, and sells the remaining surplus to the grid. Note that REC 1 has a profile with very different behavior between weekdays and weekends, which means that, during weekends, the lower demand results in a higher surplus. It is important to emphasize that these profiles are based on real-world case study data. Note also that the contribution of the wind generation is especially useful in periods where solar PV does not generate, helping to increase self-consumption, as is the case of the night periods.
As can be seen in Figure 3, REC 2 has a more regular profile, with lower differences between weekdays and weekends. It can also be seen that, during sunny hours, the renewable generation completely supplies REC 2 demand and creates a surplus that is mainly sold to the grid. This is because the other members cannot profit from REC 2 surplus since they also have their own surplus during the same periods.
Figure 5 shows how REC 3 produces more electricity than it consumes most of the time, especially during solar hours. Therefore, a large amount of electricity is shared with the other REC members and sold to the grid. This behavior is partly driven by already existing solar PV generation in the underlying demand (shown in Figure 5 as “REC3 Demand”).
It is also worth noting that, in some days (e.g., May 27th), the renewable generation in solar hours was not enough to supply the entire demand of some REC members (e.g., REC 1, REC 2, as shown in Figure 2 and Figure 3), which causes REC 3 to share its surplus (Figure 4) with them to complement their supply to compensate for this demand/generation gap.

3.3. Capital Costs and Integral Tariff Sensitivity Analysis

To assess the sensitivity of the results to variations in capital costs and the integral tariff, calculations were performed for a 20% increase and a 20% decrease in capital costs compared to the base case assumptions. Similarly, results were obtained for integral tariffs set 20% higher and 20% lower than in the base case. The capital costs and integral tariffs used in the sensitivity analysis are presented in Table 10 and Table 11, respectively.
The optimal installed capacities for each renewable generation for each REC member considering a decrease of 20% and an increase of 20% in capital costs are shown in Table 12 and Table 13, respectively.
An analysis of Table 12 and Table 13, in comparison with Table 5, reveals that whether in the ISC or CSC approach, a decrease in renewable capital costs leads to increased installed capacity among REC members who can invest. Lower capital costs enhance the benefits of additional renewable generation, incentivizing greater investment. Conversely, an increase in capital costs results in lower installed capacity.
These changes in installed capacity, driven by fluctuations in capital costs, naturally impact the share of electricity sources supplying each REC member. Table 14 and Table 15 present the composition of electricity sources used to meet REC members’ demand under scenarios of a 20% decrease and a 20% increase in capital costs, respectively.
Comparing Table 14 with Table 6, it is clear that lower capital costs lead to an increase in self-generation to meet the demand of REC members who can invest. The share of self-generated electricity rises to approximately 60%, resulting in reduced grid consumption. In the case of REC 4, there is also a shift towards greater supply from within the REC, further replacing grid consumption.
Conversely, Table 15 shows that, with higher capital costs, the opposite occurs. REC 1 and REC 3 rely more on grid electricity to meet their demand, as their self-generation capacity is reduced.
To further analyze how self-generated electricity is utilized by REC 1 to REC 3 under varying capital cost scenarios, Table 16 and Table 17 are presented.
Table 16 and Table 17 are compared with Table 7 for the base case. In Table 16, the increase in installed capacity leads to higher self-generation. While this results in greater self-consumption and more electricity being shared with other REC members, the most significant increase is in the surplus generation sent to the grid.
In Table 17, with lower self-generation, the available electricity is still primarily used for self-consumption, followed by supply to other REC members.
Table 18 presents the total costs associated with changes in capital costs for both the ISC and CSC approaches.
Table 18 shows that, even with changes in the capital cost of renewable generation, the CSC approach consistently results in the lowest total cost compared to the ISC approach, with reductions ranging from 4% to 6% across the studied cases. The reason remains the same in all scenarios: by sharing the surplus renewable generation, REC members rely less on grid supply, leading to lower overall costs. Regarding the electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC approaches, results are presented in Table 19 and Table 20 for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase, respectively, in capital costs.
Table 19 and Table 20 show that, like the base case in Table 9, REC members in the ISC approach purchase more electricity from the grid than in the CSC approach, as they lack the ability to share self-generated electricity within the REC. Moreover, despite the lower installed renewable capacity observed in Table 12 and Table 13 due to changes in capital costs, the surplus energy sent to the grid remains higher in the ISC approach than in the CSC approach. This is because REC members with self-generation have no alternative but to export their surplus instead of sharing it. Overall, the results for changes in capital costs confirm that the key insights from the base scenario remain valid.
Now, considering changes in the integral tariff paid by REC members for electricity supplied from the grid, Table 21 and Table 22 present the optimal installed capacity of solar PV and wind for each REC member under a 20% decrease and a 20% increase in the integral tariff, respectively.
From Table 21, it is evident that a lower integral tariff paid by REC members leads to a decrease in renewable installed capacity compared to the base case in Table 5. This occurs because a reduced tariff makes grid electricity more cost-effective, thereby diminishing the financial advantage of self-generation, which otherwise serves as a substitute for grid supply. An increase in the integral tariff has the opposite effect, as shown in Table 22, enhancing the benefits of self-generation over grid supply. Regarding the electricity balance per REC member for changes in integral tariff, results are presented in Table 23 and Table 24 for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase, respectively, in integral tariff.
With a lower integral tariff, grid supply becomes more cost-effective for REC members, leading to a higher share of grid consumption, as shown in Table 23, compared to the base case (Table 6). In fact, there is an inversion in supply shares: while self-generation dominates in the base case, a lower integral tariff results in grid supply taking the larger share. Conversely, as illustrated in Table 24 the opposite trend occurs when the integral tariff is higher.
The use of self-generation by the investing members is presented in Table 25 and Table 26 for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase, respectively, in integral tariff.
From Table 25 and Table 26, compared to Table 7, it is evident that the increase in installed capacity induced by higher tariffs (Table 26) results not only in greater renewable generation but also in a higher level of self-generation for REC members who can invest. However, the most significant change is the surplus sold to the grid. With increased self-generation, a larger share of the generated electricity is neither self-consumed nor supplied to other REC members, leading to a higher percentage being exported to the grid.
Regarding the total costs of the ISC and the CSC approaches for changes in the integral tariff, they are presented in Table 27.
As with the changes in capital costs, Table 27 shows that, despite the changes in the integral tariff, the CSC approach still delivers better results than the ISC approach. This is primarily due to the ability to share the renewable generation surplus, which reduces the need for grid supply and, consequently, lowers costs.
Table 28 and Table 29 present the electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC approaches for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase, respectively, in the integral tariff.
The results presented in Table 28 and Table 29 are closely aligned with those in Table 9 for the base case. Specifically, in the CSC approach, REC members purchase less from the grid compared to the ISC approach, as the latter does not allow for sharing the self-generation surplus with other REC members.
The results of the sensitivity analysis, considering changes in capital costs and the integral tariff paid by REC members for purchasing electricity from the grid, align with those obtained for the base case. The key takeaway is the increased benefits for REC members when sharing their self-generation surplus with other members, rather than exporting it to the grid.

3.4. Discussion

The results obtained in the previous section concerning the optimal investment portfolio of renewables (PV and wind) and the electricity shared among REC members can be analyzed using the concepts of MRP in comparison with the LCOE of each renewable technology.
The realized price is the average price weighted by the volume of each renewable generation technology for individual self-consumption, collective self-consumption, and surplus sold to the grid. From this concept we derived the MRP for technology k ( M R P k ) that measures the change in the realized price when one unit of technology k capacity is added. Therefore, the M R P k represents the additional revenue that is achieved when investing a marginal unit of capacity in each renewable technology k (PV and wind), computed by (9).
M R P k = R P k P k
The LCOE is the average net present cost of electricity generation of a power technology over its lifetime and is calculated as the ratio between all the discounted costs and the discounted sum of the electricity delivered over its lifetime. In our context, the LCOE of each renewable technology k ( L C O E k ) is given by (10).
L C O E k = C k P k C R F k t E p k , t P k
Table 30 presents the realized price, the MRP, and the LCOE for the presented case study with four REC members. The relevant indexes are only available for the investing REC members (REC 1, REC 2, and REC 3).
As presented in Table 30, the MRP of each technology of each investing REC member equals the LCOE of the corresponding technology. The installed capacity at which this occurs varies according to ISC or CSC.
In fact, in line with other studies [48], as the MRP represents the marginal revenue and LCOE represents the marginal cost of investing in an additional unit of capacity of each renewable technology, the marginal investment is profitable whenever the MRP exceeds the LCOE (43.17 €/MWh for PV and 51.42 €/MWh for wind), and it is unprofitable otherwise. Beyond that level of investment in PV and wind, the additional investment would turn out to be unprofitable as the MRP of both technologies would be lower than the respective LCOE.
As the possibility of sharing electricity among REC members increases the value of the selling electricity, the installed capacity at which the equality of MRP and LCOE occurs is higher for the CSC when compared with the ISC, as the MRP for the same installed renewable capacity would be higher.

4. Conclusions

Renewable Energy Communities, as established by the EU Renewable Energy Directive 2023/2413, are expected to play an important role in providing environmental, economic, and social community benefits for their members and for local areas where they operate. They will also contribute to the energy transition and decarbonization process, as they incentivize the implementation of renewable generation to a level beyond that of individual self-consumption.
Sharing renewable electricity within RECs has the potential to increase the installed renewable capacity and create mutually beneficial self-consumption, profiting from the complementarities among the REC members in terms of their electricity demand and generation patterns. In this sense, selling members within RECs manage to achieve additional revenues by sharing electricity with buying members.
The current work presents a model for the optimal investment and operational decisions within RECs which allows multiple members to invest in solar PV and wind generation technologies. A real-word case study, based on a REC with four members connected to the medium-voltage grid, is used to highlight the model possibilities and to assess the benefits of CSC over ISC in a specific case. The model computes the optimal capacity of each technology for each REC member, namely solar PV and wind, as well as the shared electricity in each period, while considering local constraints such as the available on-site conditions for renewable projects.
The current study emphasizes the benefits of simultaneously modeling investment and operational decisions inside a REC, and sheds light into the basic dynamics of REC renewable power generation and sharing. Moreover, the results achieved from the REC setting that result from the collective self-consumption are compared to the individual self-consumption case. It is shown that, in the presented real-world case study, total renewable capacity accounts for 3631 kW in the REC which compares to 3134 kW of the individual self-consumption setting, an increase of 497 kW that corresponds to 16% more renewable capacity in the REC. This shows the advantage of renewable energy communities as a driver to foster renewable energy generation to a level beyond that of individual self-consumption. The comparison between the MRP and the LCOE for each renewable technology supports the conclusion that incremental investments are profitable whenever the MRP exceeds the LCOE.
When increasing renewable capacity, the MRP decreases due to the surplus of renewable electricity being shared at a lower economic value. This decrease in the MRP is driven by collective self-consumption, which incurs additional costs (e.g., self-consumption grid tariffs). Moreover, excess REC electricity is sold to the grid at market prices, which is lower than the electricity tariffs of REC members.
From the presented discussion, it is also concluded that RECs increase the realized price of renewable generation and enhance investment capacity. Specifically, since the optimal investment criterion is the equality between the MRP and the LCOE, a higher MRP allows for greater investment capacity. Consequently, within a REC, the optimal investment in renewable power is higher than the individual self-consumption outcome for all investing REC members.
Future research in this area will include the extension of the model to include the active participation of RECs in electricity markets by providing flexibility services through demand response and storage including batteries and electric vehicles.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, J.S., I.C. and J.V.; methodology, J.S. and I.C.; validation, I.C., C.V. and F.B.; writing—original draft preparation, I.C., J.S., C.V. and J.L.; writing—review and editing, I.C., J.L., J.S., C.V., J.V. and F.B. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported by national funds through Fundação para a Ciência e a Tecnologia (FCT) under project UIDB/50021/2020 (DOI:10.54499/UIDB/50021/2020).

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. European Parliament Directive (EU) 2018/2001; Council on the Promotion of the Use of Energy from Renewable Sources. European Union: Brussels, Belgium, 2001.
  2. European Parliament Directive (EU) 2019/944; Council on Common Rules for the Internal Market for Electricity and Amending Directive 2012/27/EU. European Union: Brussels, Belgium, 2019.
  3. Rocha, R.; Mello, J.; Villar, J.; Saraiva, J.T. Comparative Analysis of Self-Consumption and Energy Communities Regulation in the Iberian Peninsula. In Proceedings of the 2021 IEEE Madrid PowerTech, PowerTech 2021—Conference Proceedings, Madrid, Spain, 28 June–2 July 2021. [Google Scholar]
  4. Coignard, J.; Rigo-Mariani, R.; Debusschere, V. Individual and Collective Objectives in an Energy Community with Network Constraints. Sustain. Cities Soc. 2024, 101, 105083. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. European Commission Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council. 2023.
  6. Ahmed, S.; Ali, A.; D’Angola, A. A Review of Renewable Energy Communities: Concepts, Scope, Progress, Challenges, and Recommendations. Sustainability 2024, 16, 1749. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Lowitzsch, J.; Hoicka, C.E.; van Tulder, F.J. Renewable Energy Communities under the 2019 European Clean Energy Package—Governance Model for the Energy Clusters of the Future? Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2020, 122, 109489. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Schwidtal, J.M.; Piccini, P.; Troncia, M.; Chitchyan, R.; Montakhabi, M.; Francis, C.; Gorbatcheva, A.; Capper, T.; Mustafa, M.A.; Andoni, M.; et al. Emerging Business Models in Local Energy Markets: A Systematic Review of Peer-to-Peer, Community Self-Consumption, and Transactive Energy Models. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2023, 179, 113273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Minuto, F.D.; Lanzini, A. Energy-Sharing Mechanisms for Energy Community Members under Different Asset Ownership Schemes and User Demand Profiles. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2022, 168, 112859. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Mustika, A.D.; Rigo-Mariani, R.; Debusschere, V.; Pachurka, A. A Two-Stage Management Strategy for the Optimal Operation and Billing in an Energy Community with Collective Self-Consumption. Appl. Energy 2022, 310, 118484. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Lazzari, F.; Mor, G.; Cipriano, J.; Solsona, F.; Chemisana, D.; Guericke, D. Optimizing Planning and Operation of Renewable Energy Communities with Genetic Algorithms. Appl. Energy 2023, 338, 120906. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Reis, I.F.G.; Gonçalves, I.; Lopes, M.A.R.; Henggeler Antunes, C. Business Models for Energy Communities: A Review of Key Issues and Trends. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2021, 144, 111013. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Lowitzsch, J. Energy Transition Financing Consumer Co-Ownership in Renewables; Lowitzsch, J., Ed.; Palgrave Macmillan: London, UK, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  14. Arnould, J.; Quiroz, D. Energy Communities in the EU Opportunities and Barriers to Financing. 2022. Available online: https://friendsoftheearth.eu/wp-content/uploads/2022/09/Energy-Communities-in-the-EU-opportunities-and-barriers-to-financing.pdf (accessed on 7 April 2025).
  15. Li, N.; Okur, Ö. Economic Analysis of Energy Communities: Investment Options and Cost Allocation. Appl. Energy 2023, 336, 120706. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Tomin, N.; Shakirov, V.; Kozlov, A.; Sidorov, D.; Kurbatsky, V.; Rehtanz, C.; Lora, E.E.S. Design and Optimal Energy Management of Community Microgrids with Flexible Renewable Energy Sources. Renew. Energy 2022, 183, 903–921. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Volpato, G.; Carraro, G.; Cont, M.; Danieli, P.; Rech, S.; Lazzaretto, A. General Guidelines for the Optimal Economic Aggregation of Prosumers in Energy Communities. Energy 2022, 258, 124800. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Belloni, E.; Fioriti, D.; Poli, D. Optimal Design of Renewable Energy Communities (RECs) in Italy: Influence of Composition, Market Signals, Buildings, Location, and Incentives. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2024, 235, 110895. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Ciobanu, I.; Lazaroiu, G.C.; Fulginei, F.R. Energy Community Part of Smart City. In Proceedings of the 2023 IEEE International Smart Cities Conference (ISC2), Bucharest, Romania, 24–27 September 2023. [Google Scholar]
  20. Pons-Seres de Brauwer, C.; Cohen, J.J. Analysing the Potential of Citizen-Financed Community Renewable Energy to Drive Europe’s Low-Carbon Energy Transition. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2020, 133, 110300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Di Silvestre, M.L.; Ippolito, M.G.; Sanseverino, E.R.; Sciumè, G.; Vasile, A. Energy Self-Consumers and Renewable Energy Communities in Italy: New Actors of the Electric Power Systems. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2021, 151, 111565. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Vallecha, H.; Bhola, P. Sustainability and Replicability Framework: Actor Network Theory Based Critical Case Analysis of Renewable Community Energy Projects in India. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2019, 108, 194–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Thompson, S.; Duggirala, B. The Feasibility of Renewable Energies at an Off-Grid Community in Canada. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2009, 13, 2740–2745. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. López González, L.M.; Sala Lizarraga, J.M.; Míguez Tabarés, J.L.; López Ochoa, L.M. Contribution of Renewable Energy Sources to Electricity Production in the Autonomous Community of Navarre (Spain): A Review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2007, 11, 1776–1793. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Byrnes, L.; Brown, C.; Wagner, L.; Foster, J. Reviewing the Viability of Renewable Energy in Community Electrification: The Case of Remote Western Australian Communities. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 59, 470–481. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Petrovich, B.; Kubli, M. Energy Communities for Companies: Executives’ Preferences for Local and Renewable Energy Procurement. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2023, 184, 113506. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Cai, Y.P.; Huang, G.H.; Yang, Z.F.; Lin, Q.G.; Tan, Q. Community-Scale Renewable Energy Systems Planning under Uncertainty-An Interval Chance-Constrained Programming Approach. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2009, 13, 721–735. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Fossati, J.P.; Galarza, A.; Martín-Villate, A.; Fontán, L. A Method for Optimal Sizing Energy Storage Systems for Microgrids. Renew. Energy 2015, 77, 539–549. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Maroua, H. Sizing and Management of Hybrid Renewable Energy System for Data Center. Chinese Roots Global Impact. Ph.D. Thesis, University Bourgogne Franche-Comté, Besançon, France, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  30. Cosic, A.; Stadler, M.; Mansoor, M.; Zellinger, M. Mixed-Integer Linear Programming Based Optimization Strategies for Renewable Energy Communities. Energy 2021, 237, 121559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Weckesser, T.; Dominković, D.F.; Blomgren, E.M.V.; Schledorn, A.; Madsen, H. Renewable Energy Communities: Optimal Sizing and Distribution Grid Impact of Photo-Voltaics and Battery Storage. Appl. Energy 2021, 301, 117408. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Kiptoo, M.K.; Lotfy, M.E.; Adewuyi, O.B.; Conteh, A.; Howlader, A.M.; Senjyu, T. Integrated Approach for Optimal Techno-Economic Planning for High Renewable Energy-Based Isolated Microgrid Considering Cost of Energy Storage and Demand Response Strategies. Energy Convers. Manag. 2020, 215, 112917. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Sanajaoba Singh, S.; Fernandez, E. Modeling, Size Optimization and Sensitivity Analysis of a Remote Hybrid Renewable Energy System. Energy 2018, 143, 719–731. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Secchi, M.; Barchi, G.; Macii, D.; Moser, D.; Petri, D. Multi-Objective Battery Sizing Optimisation for Renewable Energy Communities with Distribution-Level Constraints: A Prosumer-Driven Perspective. Appl. Energy 2021, 297, 117171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Zhang, B.; Du, Y.; Lim, E.G.; Jiang, L.; Yan, K. Design and Simulation of Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading Framework with Dynamic Electricity Price. In Proceedings of the 2019 29th Australasian Universities Power Engineering Conference (AUPEC), Nadi, Fiji, 26–29 November 2019. [Google Scholar]
  36. Guo, Z.; Pinson, P.; Wu, Q.; Chen, S.; Yang, Q.; Yang, Z. An Asynchronous Online Negotiation Mechanism for Real-Time Peer-to-Peer Electricity Markets. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2022, 37, 1868–1880. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Mello, J.; de Lorenzo, C.; Campos, F.A.; Villar, J. Pricing and Simulating Energy Transactions in Energy Communities. Energies 2023, 16, 1949. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Long, C.; Zhang, C.; Thomas, L.; Cheng, M.; Jenkins, N.; Wu, J. Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading in a Community Microgrid. In Proceedings of the 2017 IEEE Power & Energy Society General Meeting, Chicago, IL, USA, 16–20 July 2017. [Google Scholar]
  39. Wang, N.; Liu, Z.; Heijnen, P.; Warnier, M. A Peer-to-Peer Market Mechanism Incorporating Multi-Energy Coupling and Cooperative Behaviors. Appl. Energy 2022, 311, 118572. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Liu, N.; Yu, X.; Wang, C.; Li, C.; Ma, L.; Lei, J. Energy-Sharing Model with Price-Based Demand Response for Microgrids of Peer-to-Peer Prosumers. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2017, 32, 3569–3583. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Zhou, Y.; Lund, P.D. Peer-to-Peer Energy Sharing and Trading of Renewable Energy in Smart Communities—Trading Pricing Models, Decision-Making and Agent-Based Collaboration. Renew. Energy 2023, 207, 177–193. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Petri, I.; Barati, M.; Rezgui, Y.; Rana, O.F. Blockchain for Energy Sharing and Trading in Distributed Prosumer Communities. Comput. Ind. 2020, 123, 103282. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Hahnel, U.J.J.; Herberz, M.; Pena-Bello, A.; Parra, D.; Brosch, T. Becoming Prosumer: Revealing Trading Preferences and Decision-Making Strategies in Peer-to-Peer Energy Communities. Energy Policy 2020, 137, 111098. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Gawusu, S.; Zhang, X.; Ahmed, A.; Jamatutu, S.A.; Miensah, E.D.; Amadu, A.A.; Osei, F.A.J. Renewable Energy Sources from the Perspective of Blockchain Integration: From Theory to Application. Sustain. Energy Technol. Assess. 2022, 52, 102108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Cejka, S.; Zeilinger, F.; Veseli, A.; Holzleitner, M.T.; Stefan, M. A Blockchain-Based Privacy-Friendly Renewable Energy Community. In Proceedings of the SMARTGREENS 2020—Proceedings of the 9th International Conference on Smart Cities and Green ICT Systems, Online, 2–4 May 2020; pp. 95–103. [Google Scholar]
  46. Svetec, E.; Pašiþko, R.; Naÿ, L.; Pavlin, B. Blockchain Application in Renewable Energy Microgrids: An Overview of Existing Technology towards Creating Climate-Resilient and Energy Independent Communities. In Proceedings of the 2019 16th International Conference on the European Energy Market (EEM), Ljubljana, Slovenia, 18–20 September 2019. [Google Scholar]
  47. Cavalcante, I.; Júnior, J.; Manzolli, J.A.; Almeida, L.; Pungo, M.; Guzman, C.P.; Morais, H. Electric Vehicles Charging Using Photovoltaic Energy Surplus: A Framework Based on Blockchain. Energies 2023, 16, 2694. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Sousa, J.; Lagarto, J.; Camus, C.; Viveiros, C.; Barata, F.; Silva, P.; Alegria, R.; Paraíba, O. Renewable Energy Communities Optimal Design Supported by an Optimization Model for Investment in PV/Wind Capacity and Renewable Electricity Sharing. Energy 2023, 283, 128464. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. European Commision PVGIS. Available online: https://re.jrc.ec.europa.eu/pvg_tools/en/#MR (accessed on 24 June 2023).
Figure 1. Renewable Energy Community used in the case study with representation of the electricity flows, the renewable generation assets, the supply from the grid (buyGrid), the electricity shared among REC members (buyREC and sellREC), and the surplus sold to the grid (sellGrid).
Figure 1. Renewable Energy Community used in the case study with representation of the electricity flows, the renewable generation assets, the supply from the grid (buyGrid), the electricity shared among REC members (buyREC and sellREC), and the surplus sold to the grid (sellGrid).
Energies 18 01920 g001
Figure 2. REC 1 electricity flow for an illustrative one-month period (May) obtained from a one-year simulation with hourly resolution for CSC.
Figure 2. REC 1 electricity flow for an illustrative one-month period (May) obtained from a one-year simulation with hourly resolution for CSC.
Energies 18 01920 g002
Figure 3. REC 2 electricity flow for an illustrative one-month period (May) obtained from a one-year simulation with hourly resolution for CSC.
Figure 3. REC 2 electricity flow for an illustrative one-month period (May) obtained from a one-year simulation with hourly resolution for CSC.
Energies 18 01920 g003
Figure 4. REC 3 electricity flow for an illustrative one-month period (May) obtained from a one-year simulation with hourly resolution for CSC.
Figure 4. REC 3 electricity flow for an illustrative one-month period (May) obtained from a one-year simulation with hourly resolution for CSC.
Energies 18 01920 g004
Figure 5. REC 4 electricity flow for an illustrative one-month period (May) obtained from a one-year simulation with hourly resolution for CSC.
Figure 5. REC 4 electricity flow for an illustrative one-month period (May) obtained from a one-year simulation with hourly resolution for CSC.
Energies 18 01920 g005
Table 1. Annual electricity demand, peak demand, and contracted capacity of REC members.
Table 1. Annual electricity demand, peak demand, and contracted capacity of REC members.
Demand
(MWh)
Peak
(kW)
Contracted
(kW)
REC 12273748800
REC 2808413581400
REC 3822374400
REC 41463277300
Table 2. Characteristics of renewable technologies.
Table 2. Characteristics of renewable technologies.
Capital Cost (€/kW)Lifetime
(Years)
PV110025
Wind170020
Table 3. Investment financial indicators.
Table 3. Investment financial indicators.
CRFLCOE
(€/MWh)
PV0.0743.17
Wind0.0851.42
Table 4. Tariffs and prices used in the case study (€/MWh).
Table 4. Tariffs and prices used in the case study (€/MWh).
MV Integral TariffSC Grid TariffSurplus Price
100100
Table 5. Installed capacity of renewable generation for the ISC and CSC (kW).
Table 5. Installed capacity of renewable generation for the ISC and CSC (kW).
REC 1REC 2REC 3REC 4
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
PV45039012461110179106--
Wind29428813141124149114--
Table 6. Electricity balance per REC member and electricity sources in the CSC approach (MWh).
Table 6. Electricity balance per REC member and electricity sources in the CSC approach (MWh).
DemandGrid SupplySupply from Self-GenerationSupply from REC
REC 122731027122818
100%45%54%1%
REC 28084355745270
100%44%56%0%
REC 38223854307
100%47%52%1%
REC 414639430520
100%64%0%36%
TOTAL12,64259126185545
100%47%49%4%
Table 7. Self-generation per REC member and use in the CSC approach (MWh).
Table 7. Self-generation per REC member and use in the CSC approach (MWh).
Self-GenerationSupply from Self-GenerationSupply to RECSurplus to Grid
REC 115921228222142
100%77%14%9%
REC 2573845272021009
100%79%4%18%
REC 3719430121168
100%60%17%23%
REC 40000
----
TOTAL804061855461319
100%77%7%16%
Table 8. Total cost of ISC and CSC approaches (k€).
Table 8. Total cost of ISC and CSC approaches (k€).
Total Cost
CSCISC
978
95%
1028
100%
Table 9. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC (MWh).
Table 9. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC (MWh).
Electricity from GridElectricity from RECElectricity Sold
to REC
Electricity Surplus Sold to Grid
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
REC 1102710951802220142292
100%107%100%0%100%0%100%206%
REC 2355738900.4020201009795
100%109%100%0%100%0%100%79%
REC 3385479701210168153
100%124%100%0%100%0%100%91%
REC 49431 46352000000
100%155%100%0%0%0%0%0%
TOTAL591269275450545013191240
100%117%100%0%100%0%100%94%
Table 10. Capital costs for the base case and for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase (€/kW).
Table 10. Capital costs for the base case and for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase (€/kW).
Capital Cost
−20%Base Case+20%
PV88011001320
Wind136017002040
Table 11. Integral tariff for the base case and for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase (€/MWh).
Table 11. Integral tariff for the base case and for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase (€/MWh).
MV Integral Tariff
−20%Base Case+20%
80100120
Table 12. Installed capacity of renewable generation for the ISC and CSC considering a decrease of 20% in capital costs (kW).
Table 12. Installed capacity of renewable generation for the ISC and CSC considering a decrease of 20% in capital costs (kW).
REC 1REC 2REC 3REC 4
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
PV48544113251180203141--
Wind38636816261435189142--
Table 13. Installed capacity of renewable generation for the ISC and CSC considering an increase of 20% in capital costs (kW).
Table 13. Installed capacity of renewable generation for the ISC and CSC considering an increase of 20% in capital costs (kW).
REC 1REC 2REC 3REC 4
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
PV4183541206106515885--
Wind227234102887712288--
Table 14. Electricity balance per REC member and electricity sources in the CSC considering a decrease of 20% in capital costs (MWh).
Table 14. Electricity balance per REC member and electricity sources in the CSC considering a decrease of 20% in capital costs (MWh).
DemandGrid SupplySupply from Self-GenerationSupply from REC
REC 12273900135518
100%40%60%1%
REC 28 0843 1894 8941
100%39%61%0%
REC 38223394767
100%41%58%1%
REC 414638450618
100%58%0%42%
TOTAL12,64252736725644
100%42%53%5%
Table 15. Electricity balance per REC member and electricity sources in the CSC considering an increase of 20% in capital costs (MWh).
Table 15. Electricity balance per REC member and electricity sources in the CSC considering an increase of 20% in capital costs (MWh).
DemandGrid SupplySupply from Self-GenerationSupply from REC
REC 122731146111017
100%50%49%1%
REC 28084395341310
100%49%51%0%
REC 38224283885
100%52%47%1%
REC 4146310310432
100%70%0%30%
TOTAL12,64265585629454
100%52%45%4%
Table 16. Self-generation per REC member and use considering a decrease of 20% in capital costs (MWh).
Table 16. Self-generation per REC member and use considering a decrease of 20% in capital costs (MWh).
Self-GenerationSupply from Self-GenerationSupply to RECSurplus to Grid
REC 119001355282263
100%71%15%14%
REC 2671048942171599
100%73%3%24%
REC 3869476145248
100%55%17%29%
REC 40000
----
TOTAL947967256442110
100%71%7%22%
Table 17. Self-generation per REC member and use considering an increase of 20% in capital costs (MWh).
Table 17. Self-generation per REC member and use considering an increase of 20% in capital costs (MWh).
Self-GenerationSupply from Self-GenerationSupply to RECSurplus to Grid
REC 11359111017475
100%82%13%6%
REC 249074131182594
100%84%4%12%
REC 360938899122
100%64%16%20%
REC 40000
----
TOTAL68755629455791
100%82%7%12%
Table 18. Total cost of ISC and CSC approaches for the base case and for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase in capital costs (k€).
Table 18. Total cost of ISC and CSC approaches for the base case and for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase in capital costs (k€).
Total Cost
−20% Capital CostBase Case+20% Capital Cost
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
895954978102810501089
94%100%95%100%96%100%
Table 19. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC for a 20% decrease in capital costs (MWh).
Table 19. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC for a 20% decrease in capital costs (MWh).
Electricity from GridElectricity from RECElectricity Sold
to REC
Electricity Surplus Sold to Grid
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
REC 19009611802820263464
100%107%100%0%100%0%100%176%
REC 23189346010217015991316
100%108%100%0%100%0%100%82%
REC 3339421701450248231
100%124%100%0%100%0%100%93%
REC 4845146361800000
100%173%100%0%0%0%0%0%
TOTAL527363056440644021102011
100%120%100%0%100%0%100%95%
Table 20. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC for a 20% increase in capital costs (MWh).
Table 20. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC for a 20% increase in capital costs (MWh).
Electricity from GridElectricity from RECElectricity Sold
to REC
Electricity Surplus Sold to Grid
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
REC 111461207170174075195
100%105%100%0%100%0%100%260%
REC 239534300001820594466
100%109%100%0%100%0%100%78%
REC 342853750990122101
100%125%100%0%100%0%100%83%
REC 41031146343200000
100%142%100%0%0%0%0%0%
TOTAL6558750745404550791762
100%114%100%0%100%0%100%96%
Table 21. Installed capacity of renewable generation for the ISC and CSC considering a decrease of 20% in the integral tariff (kW).
Table 21. Installed capacity of renewable generation for the ISC and CSC considering a decrease of 20% in the integral tariff (kW).
REC 1REC 2REC 3REC 4
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
PV4103451194105414679--
Wind22122197081911181--
Table 22. Installed capacity of renewable generation for the ISC and CSC considering an increase of 20% in the integral tariff (kW).
Table 22. Installed capacity of renewable generation for the ISC and CSC considering an increase of 20% in the integral tariff (kW).
REC 1REC 2REC 3REC 4
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
PV46943213011165202133--
Wind36235315641389188138--
Table 23. Electricity balance per REC member and electricity sources in the CSC considering a decrease of 20% in the integral tariff (MWh).
Table 23. Electricity balance per REC member and electricity sources in the CSC considering a decrease of 20% in the integral tariff (MWh).
DemandGrid SupplySupply from Self-GenerationSupply from REC
REC 122731164109415
100%51%48%1%
REC 28084404540390
100%50%50%0%
REC 38224493676
100%55%45%1%
REC 4146310540409
100%72%0%28%
TOTAL12,64267125500430
100%53%44%3%
Table 24. Electricity balance per REC member and electricity sources in the CSC considering an increase of 20% in the integral tariff (MWh).
Table 24. Electricity balance per REC member and electricity sources in the CSC considering an increase of 20% in the integral tariff (MWh).
DemandGrid SupplySupply from Self-GenerationSupply from REC
REC 12273931132121
100%41%58%1%
REC 28084326048240
100%40%60%0%
REC 38223414756
100%41%58%1%
REC 414638640599
100%59%0%41%
TOTAL12,64253966620626
100%43%52%5%
Table 25. Self-generation per REC member and use considering a decrease of 20% in integral tariff (MWh).
Table 25. Self-generation per REC member and use considering a decrease of 20% in integral tariff (MWh).
Self-GenerationSupply from Self-GenerationSupply to RECSurplus to Grid
REC 11328109416965
100%82%13%5%
REC 247334039172522
100%85%4%11%
REC 355836788103
100%66%16%18%
REC 40000
----
TOTAL66195500429690
100%83%6%10%
Table 26. Self-generation per REC member and use considering an increase of 20% in integral tariff (MWh).
Table 26. Self-generation per REC member and use considering an increase of 20% in integral tariff (MWh).
Self-GenerationSupply from Self-GenerationSupply to RECSurplus to Grid
REC 118091321126362
100%73%7%20%
REC 2650248243311347
100%74%5%21%
REC 3865475169221
100%55%20%26%
REC 40000
----
TOTAL917666206261930
100%72%7%21%
Table 27. Total cost of ISC and CSC approaches for the base case and for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase in the integral tariff (k€).
Table 27. Total cost of ISC and CSC approaches for the base case and for a 20% decrease and a 20% increase in the integral tariff (k€).
Total Cost
−20% Integral TariffBase Case+20% Integral Tariff
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
853882978102810921161
97%100%95%100%94%100%
Table 28. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC for a 20% decrease in the integral tariff (MWh).
Table 28. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC for a 20% decrease in the integral tariff (MWh).
Electricity from GridElectricity from RECElectricity Sold to RECElectricity Surplus Sold to Grid
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
REC 111641236150169065174
100%106%100%0%100%0%100%268%
REC 240454406001720522401
100%109%100%0%100%0%100%77%
REC 34495546089010389
100%123%100%0%100%0%100%86%
REC 41054146340900000
100%139%100%0%0%0%0%0%
TOTAL6712765943004300690664
100%114%100%0%100%0%100%96%
Table 29. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC for a 20% increase in the integral tariff (MWh).
Table 29. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC for a 20% increase in the integral tariff (MWh).
Electricity from GridElectricity from RECElectricity SoldElectricity Surplus Sold to Grid
to REC
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
REC 19319852001260362428
100%106%100%0%100%0%100%118%
REC 23260352110331013471227
100%108%100%0%100%0%100%91%
REC 3341430601690221215
100%126%100%0%100%0%100%97%
REC 4864146359900000
100%169%100%0%0%0%0%0%
TOTAL539663996260626019301870
100%119%100%0%100%0%100%97%
Table 30. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC (MWh).
Table 30. Electricity purchased and sold for the CSC and ISC (MWh).
REC 1REC 2REC 3
CSCISCCSCISCCSCISC
PV: 450 kWPV: 390 kWPV: 1 246 kWPV: 1 110 kWPV: 179 kWPV: 106 kW
Wind: 294 kWWind: 288 kWWind: 1 314 kWWind: 1 124 kWWind: 149 kWWind: 114 kW
PVRP89.8178.2382.0784.2470.4862.26
MRP43.2743.2643.2743.2543.2743.31
LCOE43.1743.1743.1743.1743.1743.17
WindRP89.5882.1082.2884.2378.7773.94
MRP51.4351.5651.4351.4451.4351.66
LCOE51.4251.4251.4251.4251.4251.42
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Carvalho, I.; Sousa, J.; Villar, J.; Lagarto, J.; Viveiros, C.; Barata, F. Optimal Investment and Sharing Decisions in Renewable Energy Communities with Multiple Investing Members. Energies 2025, 18, 1920. https://doi.org/10.3390/en18081920

AMA Style

Carvalho I, Sousa J, Villar J, Lagarto J, Viveiros C, Barata F. Optimal Investment and Sharing Decisions in Renewable Energy Communities with Multiple Investing Members. Energies. 2025; 18(8):1920. https://doi.org/10.3390/en18081920

Chicago/Turabian Style

Carvalho, Inês, Jorge Sousa, José Villar, João Lagarto, Carla Viveiros, and Filipe Barata. 2025. "Optimal Investment and Sharing Decisions in Renewable Energy Communities with Multiple Investing Members" Energies 18, no. 8: 1920. https://doi.org/10.3390/en18081920

APA Style

Carvalho, I., Sousa, J., Villar, J., Lagarto, J., Viveiros, C., & Barata, F. (2025). Optimal Investment and Sharing Decisions in Renewable Energy Communities with Multiple Investing Members. Energies, 18(8), 1920. https://doi.org/10.3390/en18081920

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop